Financial Crises and Reform of The International Financial System
Financial Crises and Reform of The International Financial System
Financial Crises and Reform of The International Financial System
Stanley Fischer
Abstract: Between December 1994 and March 1999, Mexico, Thailand, Indo-
nesia, Korea, Malaysia, Russia and Brazil experienced major financial crises,
which were associated with massive recessions and extreme movements of ex-
change rates. Similar crises have threatened Turkey and Argentina (2000 and
2001) and most recently Brazil (again). This article discusses the reform of the
international financial system with a focus on the role of the IMF - reforms
directed at crisis prevention, and those intended to improve the responses to
crises. The article concludes with an appraisal of what has been achieved, and
what remains to be done to make the international financial system safer.
IEL no. E5, E6, F3, F4, G1
Keywords: Financial crisis; reform of the international financial system; Inter-
national Monetary Fund
1 Introduction
Remark: This is a slightly revised version of the Harms Lecture delivered at the Kiel
Institute for World Economics, June 29, 2002. I draw freely on Chapter 2 of my Rob-
bins Lectures presented at the London School of Economics, October 29-31, 2001,
The International Financial System: Crises and Reform. I am grateful to Prachi Mishra
of Columbia University for assistance, and to my former colleagues at the Interna-
tional Monetary Fund for their direct assistance and for many discussions over the
years that helped develop the views expressed in this lecture. Please address correspon-
dence to Stanley Fischer, Citigroup, 399 Park Avenue, New York, NY 10022; e-mail:
fischers@citigroup.com
Review of World Economics 2003, Vol. 139 (1)
of fixed but adjustable exchange rates among the major currencies, and
the role of the International Monetary Fund within the system. Now
the challenge is to reduce the frequency of crises among the emerging
market countries, the mostly middle-income developing countries that
are open to massive capital flows. In the last two years, Turkey, Argentina,
and most recently Brazil (again) have joined the list of emerging market
countries that have experienced major external crises.
In considering the reform of the international financial system, I will
first discuss reforms directed at crisis prevention, and then those in-
tended to improve the responses to crises. I will conclude by discussing
what has been done to make capital account crises less likely in future,
and the priorities for action.
2 Crisis Prevention
To reduce the probability of crises, changes are necessary in: first, coun-
try policies and institutions; second, the actions of the IMF and other
official international financial institutions; and third, the operation of
the international capital markets.
1 Changes in the nominal exchange rate are likely to affect the inflation rate, and -
especially in countries that are to some extent dollarized - also the health of the fi-
nancial system and the distribution of wealth between debtors and creditors. Changes
in the real exchange rate affect the current account of the balance of payments, often
generating political pressures as a result.
Review of World Economics 2003, Vol. 139 (1)
is rarely if ever the case for the United States, it is more often so among
other G-7 countries, and for smaller emerging market economies. In
Canada, the use in the past of a monetary conditions index to guide
monetary policy, based on movements in both the exchange rate and
the interest rate, formalized the impact of exchange rate movements on
monetary policy. 2 In countries that pursue an inflation-targeting ap-
proach to monetary policy, changes in the exchange rate will be taken
into account in setting monetary policy, because the exchange rate affects
price behavior.
In the reverse direction, there is an unresolved issue about whether
monetary policy in a flexible rate system should be used in the short run
to try to affect the exchange rate. In many respects, the issue is similar to
that of how monetary policy in an inflation-targeting framework should
respond to movements in output and unemployment. Mthough it has
not received much empirical attention, there is almost certainly a short-
run tradeoff between the real exchange rate and inflation, analogous to
the Phillips curve) This is an issue that deserves serious attention, for
just as answers have been developed as to how to deal with the short-
run Phillips curve in an inflation-targeting framework, so it remains
necessary to answer the question of how in such a framework to deal
with the short-run tradeoffbetween the real exchange rate and inflation.
Recognizing the difficulty for an emerging market country of defend-
ing a narrow range of exchange rates, Williamson (2000) proposes alter-
native regimes. Rudi Dornbusch has named these BBC arrangements:
basket, band, and crawl. Williamson also recommends that countries,
if necessary, allow the exchange rate to move temporarily outside the
band, so that they do not provide speculators with one-way bets that
lead to excessive reserve losses. In these circumstances, the band is serv-
ing as a weak nominal anchor for the exchange rate, and can perhaps be
thought of as a supplement to an inflation-targeting framework. 4 Gold-
stein (2002) argues that the best regime choice for emerging economies
2 Mthough the idea behind the monetary conditions index (MCI), that both the ex-
change rate and the interest rate affect aggregate demand, is correct, the MCI needs to
be used with great caution, not least because the cause of any change in the exchange
rate needs to be taken into account.
3 Cushman and Zha (1997) contain VARs from which the implied tradeoff can be cal-
culated in the Canadian case.
4 Williamson himself believes that specifying a target exchange rate range may prevent
markets from heading off on an errant exchange rate path. Another possibility is that
by committing weakly to some range of exchange rates, the authorities make it more
Fischer: Financial Crises and Reform
likely that fiscal policy will be brought into play if the real exchange rate moves too
far from equilibrium.
5 Goldstein (2002) argues that if managed floating were enhanced in this way, it
would retain the desirable features of a flexible rate regime while addressing the nomi-
nal anchor and balance-sheet problems that have historically produced a "fear of float-
ing" and handicapped the performance of managed floating in emerging economies.
6 The focus here is on the macroeconomic aspects of fiscal policy.
Review of World Economics 2003, Vol. 139 (1)
since 1998, the agreed fiscal stance has been guided by the need to ensure
that the debt-to-GDP ratio is put on a declining path. The well-known
equation for debt dynamics is
d = -x + (r - g ) d ,
fects of the controls has been difficult, since they were imposed after
most of the turbulence of the first part of the Asian crisis was over,
that is after most of the capital that wanted to leave had done so,
and when regional currency values were close to their post-crisis min-
ima. 11
Nonetheless, support for capital controls is often seen as inconsistent
with the Washington Consensus, 12 and a belief in free markets. In dis-
cussing capital controls, I shall assume that countries will in the course
of their development want to liberalize the capital account and integrate
into global capital markets. This view is based in part on the fact that the
most advanced economies all have open capital accounts; it is also based
on the conclusion that the potential benefits of well-phased integration
into the global capital markets - and this includes the benefits obtained
by allowing foreign competition in the financial sector - outweigh the
costs.13
It is necessary to distinguish between controls on outflows and con-
trois on inflows. For controls on capital outflows to succeed, they need
to be quite extensive. As a country develops, these controls are likely to
become both more distorting and less effective. They also cannot prevent
a devaluation if domestic policies are fundamentally inconsistent with
maintenance of the exchange rate.
When a country intends to liberalize capital controls on outflows,
they should preferably be removed gradually, at a time when the exchange
rate is not under pressure, 14 and as the necessary infrastructure - in the
form of strong and efficient domestic financial institutions and markets,
a market-based monetary policy, an effective foreign exchange market,
11 See Kaplan and Rodrik (2001) for a relatively positive appraisal of the Malaysian
controls.
12 The original Washington Consensus list (Williamson 1990) did not include capital
account liberalization, except for foreign direct investment.
13 The argument is developed at greater length in Fischer (1998). The point has been
much disputed, among others by Bhagwati (1998). With regard to empirical evidence
on the benefits of capital account liberalization, I believe we are roughly now where
we were in the 1980s on current account liberalization - that some evidence is com-
ing in, but that it remains highly disputed. Reinhart and Tokatlidis (2002), Chari and
Henry (2002), Bekaert et al. (2002), Galindo et al. (2002), Gourinchas and Jeanne
(2002) provide empirical evidence and discuss whether financial liberalization spurs
growth and through what channels.
14 The removal of controls on outflows sometimes results in a capital inflow, a result
of either foreigners and/or domestic residents bringing capital into the country in light
of the greater assurance that it can be removed when desired.
Fischer: Financial Crises and Reform
and the information base necessary for the markets to operate efficiently
- is being put in place. Unless the country intends to move to a hard
peg, it would be desirable to begin allowing some flexibility of exchange
rates as the controls are gradually eased. Prudential controls that have
a similar effect to some capital controls, for instance limits on the open
foreign exchange positions that domestic institutions can take, should
also be put in place as direct controls are removed.
Some countries have attempted to impose controls on outflows once
a foreign exchange crisis is already under way. This use of controls
has generally been ineffective,is It has also to be considered that the
imposition of controls for this purpose in a crisis is likely to have a longer-
term effect on the country's access to international capital.
Several countries, among them Singapore, the three Asian crisis
countries, and Malaysia, have taken steps to limit the offshore use of
their currencies. In principle, this makes it possible to break the link
between onshore and offshore interest rates, particularly by restricting
the convertibility of the currency for nonresidents - who need access
to the domestic banking system to complete their transactions. ~6 Ishii
et al. (2001) conclude that such restrictions have been more successful
the more comprehensive they have been, and that they could provide
the authorities with a breathing space in which to implement policy
changes. But as with other capital controls, their effectiveness tends to
erode over time. Further, the longer the measures are implemented, and
the stronger they are, the higher the associated costs in terms of the
efficiency of the financial system are likely to be.
Excessive indebtedness of domestic financial and nonfinancial in-
stitutions arises not from capital outflows, but from inflows, especially
short-term inflows. The IMF has cautiously supported the use of market-
based capita 1 inflow controls, Chilean style. These could be helpful for
a country seeking to avoid the difficulties posed for domestic policy by
capital inflows. The typical instance occurs when a country is trying to
reduce inflation using an exchange rate anchor, and for anti-inflationary
purposes needs interest rates higher than those implied by the sum of
the foreign interest rate and the expected rate of currency depreciation.
A tax on capital inflows can help maintain a wedge between the two
17 The Interim Committee agreed in April 1997 that there would be benefits to
amending the Articles of Agreement to make capital account liberalization a purpose
of the Fund, and to extend the Fund's jurisdiction to capital movements.
Fischer: Financial Crises and Reform 11
18 The IMF staff would have preferred weekly data, but some leading central banks
objected. They argued that unless private sector participants were required to provide
information on their positions, the central banks would be at a disadvantage if re-
quired to provide frequent and up-to-date information on their reserves.
19 Many countries do better than this.
12 Review of World Economics 2003, Vol. 139 (1)
Each country would almost certainly have had to allow the exchange rate
to move earlier, well before exhausting their reserves. 2~ It is also possible
that, if this information had been generally available, the political system
in each country would have forced a policy adjustment on the central
bank sooner. 2I
As this discussion suggests, transparency is important not only be-
cause it provides more information to the markets, but even more be-
cause it puts constraints on what policymakers can do. Subsequently the
IMF developed Codes of Good Practices on Transparency in Monetary
and Financial Policies, and on Fiscal Transparency, respectively. These set
out standards against which countries can measure their own practices,
and where necessary, seek to improve them. The Fund helps countries
appraise their practices.
Countries' performance in meeting four standards in other areas
- the Basle Committee's Core Principles for Effective Banking Super-
vision, and standards for securities regulation, insurance supervision,
and payments systems - are assessed as part of the Financial Sector As-
sessment Program (FSAP), a joint effort of the IMF, the World Bank,
and national supervisory agencies. The World Bank is taking the lead in
assessing standards in four other areas: corporate governance (standard
developed by the OECD); accounting (International Accounting Stan-
dards Board, IASB); auditing (International Federation of Accountants);
and insolvency and creditor rights (principles developed by the World
Bank).
Each standard provides a yardstick by which a country can appraise
its performance in the relevant area, and seek to meet international
standards. The key questions then are what are the incentives and ob-
stacles to meeting the standards. The answers depend in part on how
these systems are appraised, how and to whom the information is made
public, what assistance is provided to help countries upgrade their per-
formance, and how investors take country performance in these areas
into account in making their investment decisions. Among the incen-
2o The Mexican case is more complicated, since their reserves dedined in two steps,
first followingthe Colosio assassinationin April and then in November. It is thus not
obvious that adherence to the present reserves template would have produced an ear-
lier exchange rate adjustment.
21 The report of the Nukul Commission on the Thai crisis (The Nation, Bangkok,
March 31, 1998) states that informationon reserves was very tightly held within the
Bank of Thailand.
Fischer: Financial Crises and Reform 13
22 By the end of September 2001, 169 ROSC modules had been completed for 57
countries.
23 One such incentive should have been provided by the fact that to qualify for
the Contingent Credit Line (CCL) facility, a country has to be making satisfactory
progress towards meeting international standards, particularly the SDDS, the Basle
Committee's Core Principles for Effective Banking Supervision, and the Codes on Fis-
cal Transparency, and on Transparency in Monetary and Financial Policies, respec-
tively. However, the CCL has had no takers.
14 Review of World Economics 2003, Vol. 139 (1)
through the annual Article IV report, along with more frequent interim
interactions with member countries, should contribute to this end. 24
Fund surveillance has improved greatly since 1994. 25 The private dialog
between the management and staffofthe IMF and the officials of a coun-
try can be very frank indeed. Reporting to the Board is also typically very
f r a n k . 26
A key question is whether the Fund should issue public warnings -
a system of yellow and red cards - when it believes a country is heading
for a crisis. In issuing warnings of potential trouble, whether in private
or in public, the IMF has to be mindful of two types of error: the type-1
error of crises that were not predicted; and the type-2 error of a crisis that
was predicted but did not happen. It has particularly to be concerned
that its warnings may be self-justifying - and this is a difficult problem
to deal with, one that member countries tend to emphasize. Members
of the IMF Executive Board often repeat that they do not want the Fund
to become a rating agency. 27
The Fund has rarely issued a clear public warning of an impend-
ing crisis, but does express concerns that make the point. How would
it have done if it had issued public warnings? Of the six major crises
between 1994 and 1999, three were on the Fund's radar screen well
before they happened - Thailand, Russia, and Brazil - and three were
not, despite concerns having been expressed about some weaknesses
in each of the Mexican, Indonesian, and Korean economies. During
the crisis period, I predicted, within official circles, at least one cri-
sis that didn't happen. Type-2 errors of this sort are especially worri-
some. 2s
24 Given the quantity of private sector research on industrialized and emerging mar-
ket countries, the question arises whether the Fund has any advantage in undertaking
surveillance of these countries. Part of the answer should be the quality of the Fund
staff; in addition, Fund staff and management are likely to have a closer dialog with
country officials, and may well have access to better information about policies and
policy intentions.
25 In 1999, a group of experts headed by John Crow, former Governor of the Bank
of Canada, presented a report on Fund surveillance. See External Evaluation of IMF
Surveillance: Report by a Group of Independent Experts, IMF, September 1999.
26 I discuss below how such concerns are reflected in published reports.
27 The Fund publishes each quarter a list of the about 40 countries whose currencies
are usable for Fund lending; since the criterion for being on the list is to have a strong
balance of payments and reserve position, this is a rating, albeit not a very refined one.
28 If Fund warnings were self-justifying, there would not be any type-2 errors.
Fischer: Financial Crises and Reform 15
29 I once took an informalpoll inside the IMF asking for examples of crises averted;
there were more than l expected, even after adjustingfor multiple parentage. I am not
aware of more scientificresults on this issue.
16 Review of World Economics 2003, Vol. 139 (1)
It has sometimes been suggested that the Fund should refuse to lend
to countries that get into a crisis after ignoring warnings. The idea of
providing incentives to heed warnings is attractive, but this punishment
may be too draconian. For not only are some warnings wrong, but also,
in refusing to help a country that is willing to implement the needed
policies, the IMF would be punishing the entire population because of
the actions of a few policymakers who failed to respond to warnings -
and who have probably been fired in the meantime. There is however
a case for developing a procedure in which the terms of lending are
adjusted depending on the country's previous behavior - though there
is a delicate balance to be struck between providing incentives to heed
warnings and providing disincentives to come to the Fund when trouble
looms.
Beyond the standard traditional human intelligence aspects of surveil-
lance, the Fund has invested in the statistical analysis of vulnerability
indicators, as predictors of the probability of a crisis (see IMF 2000 and
Goldstein et al. 2000). Similar exercises are undertaken in the private
sector, and are published. While these efforts are interesting and the
results worth close scrutiny, their forecasting record is not very good;
further, to the extent that any one of these equations fits well and is
used successfully to avert some crises, it may carry the seeds of its own
destruction, in Goodhart's law or Lucas critique fashion (Berg et al.
1999).
The Fund is strengthening the vulnerability analyses it carries out
for internal purposes: these bring together the statistical analyses with
detailed country-by-country reports in seeking to identify countries that
are vulnerable, and to recommend appropriate policy measures. While
it should continue to strive to make surveillance ever better, we need
also to keep reminding ourselves that no early warning system will be
infallible.
Transparency: At the time of the Mexican crisis, the IMF published
very little about its programs, its policy deliberations, and its surveillance
activities - except for the World Economic Outlook and the International
Capital Markets Report. If the Board agreed to support a program, an
announcement of the amounts involved would be made. Program docu-
ments were not published; nor were Article IV reports.
Now the great majority of IMF members publish their Article IV
conclusions (in the Public Information Notices (PINs)) and, more im-
portant, most agree to the publication of the Article IV reports them-
Fischer: Financial Crises and Reform 17
selves. 3~Most borrowers release the Letters of Intent that describe their
IMF-supported programs. In addition, since the start of 2001, countries
have been allowed to publish the staff reports on programs, and about
half have been published since then. Staff papers on general policy is-
sues are almost all published, sometimes also in preliminary form to
solicit public comment. In addition, an Independent Evaluation Office,
reporting to the Board, has been established and is beginning to operate.
All this marks a revolution in transparency, and a revolution within
the Fund. At the time the changes were being debated within the Fund,
some Board members feared that greater transparency would inhibit the
frankness of the policy dialog between the Fund and its members, and
the frankness of reporting to the Board. The objection was a serious
one, even if it sometimes came from members with whom the policy
dialog was not particularly frank. It was dealt with in part by allowing
members to request the removal of market-sensitive information from
reports that were later to be published. 31 On balance I do not believe
the fears have turned out to be valid, though from time to time in
clearing a report, I was mindful of the fact that the report would be
made public.
The main argument for transparency put forward a few years ago
was that it helps make markets more efficient. That it does, despite the
difficulties skeptical markets frequently create for member countries
and for the Fund. But transparency has many other benefits. As already
mentioned, it improves policy, because policymakers operating in the
light of day cannot do some of the things they can do in the dark of
secrecy. It also improves the quality of the Fund's work, for Fund staff
and management are bound to be even more careful to get it right when
subject to s c r u t i n y - and here the Independent Evaluation Office will
also make an important difference.
But transparency does even more than that, in two regards. First,
it promotes interactions with the outside world, for as the Fund puts
information out, it has also to interact with the outside, listening to what
outsiders are saying, and taking information in. This happens in a variety
of ways: the posting of papers for comment on the web; the setting up of
30 Publication rates of Article IV's are highest for the advanced countries, Central and
Eastern Europe, and Western Hemisphere members.
31 All changes made between Board presentation and publication of a report have to
be reported in complete detail to the Board - this serves as a safeguard against changes
that do not meet the market-sensitivity test.
18 Review of World Economics 2003, Vol. 139 (1)
32 The report of the Meltzer Commission (the International Financial Institution Ad-
visory Committee) is available at <http:/lwww.house.gov/jec/imf/ifiac.htm>.
Fischer: Financial Crises and Reform 19
would not make sense, even if the country's overall policies had been
good at the time the line of credit was negotiated, for macroeconomic
conditions are almost bound to have changed at the time the country
needs to draw on its line of credit. Further, while there should be in-
centives for prequalification, I do not believe the Fund should refuse to
lend to nonprequalifying crisis countries - provided such countries are
willing to adjust their policies to deal with the crisis. The discussion here
parallels the discussion about the suggestion that the Fund not lend to
countries that ignore warnings provided by the Fund - and we should
note also that the Meltzer Commission's systemic risk contingency is
one that discriminates against smaller countries.
Nonetheless, the notion of prequalifying for lending is an important
one, which is embodied in the conditions for the Contingent Credit Line
(CCL) facility. The basic idea is straightforward: the IMF offers a precau-
tionary line of credit to countries that have demonstrably sound policies,
but which nonetheless believe they may be vulnerable to contagion from
crises elsewhere. In effect, it allows countries that have met certain pre-
conditions to augment - at low cost - the foreign exchange reserves they
can draw on in a crisis. The knowledge that these resources are available
may in itself deter a speculative attack. By offering qualifying countries
a seal of approval for their policies, it should also reduce contagion, by
giving less reason for investors and creditors to pull their money out
because of crises elsewhere.
The adoption of the CCL marked an important departure from the
Fund's traditional lending activities. Rather than waiting to pick up the
pieces after an accident has happened, the intent behind the introduction
of the CCL was to use the Fund's lending capacity for crisis prevention,
as well as crisis resolution. This obviously creates a risk of moral hazard.
Countries have an incentive - in theory at least - to run weaker poiicies if
they have an extra financial cushion in place. Perhaps more importantly,
investors have an incentive to lend to countries with weaker policies if
they believe that the presence of the credit line increases the chances that
they will be repaid if things go wrong.
To counter this problem, the CCL was aimed explicitly at members
with first-class policies, who would face a potential loss of access to
international capital markets because of contagion rather than domestic
policy weaknesses. But we do not live in a Manichaean world in which
we can divide countries neatly between the righteous and the ungodly.
So "first-class" should not be taken to mean "perfect." The eligibility
20 Review of World Economics 2003, Vol. 139 (1)
criteria are demanding, but not so much so that they would disqualify
any country that might benefit from signing up. 33
Unfortunately, the CCL has not been adopted by any country, and
as time goes by, it seems less likely that it will be adopted. In part this
was because of a Groucho Marx-like concern that no country that was
eligible would want to join the club. It is not clear whether a further
reformulation of the facility would lead to its use, but as of now it
seems that this important attempt to make the Fund's financial resources
available for crisis prevention has failed.
33 The key conditions are (i) at the time the credit line is agreed, the country is not
expected to need to borrow from the Fund; (ii) the country's economy is in good
shape, and it is making progress towards meeting relevant international standards; and
(iii) the country must enjoy constructive relations with its private creditors, and he
taking appropriate steps to limit its external vulnerability.
Fischer: Financial Crises and Reform 21
34 Financial Stability Forum, Report of the Working Group on Highly Leveraged Institu-
tions, Basle, 2000.
22 Review of World Economics 2003, Vol. 139 (1)
35 The question of the optimal size of the IMF and of individual programs could be
analyzed using a cost-benefit analysis, in which at the margin the benefit to the global
economy of an extra dollar provided to the IMF is equal to its marginal cost. There
are of course formidable difficulties in quantifying the benefit to the global economy,
including the need to weight the gains to different groups in the global system.
36 A great deal lies behind this sentence: in particular, if optimal IMF operations can
sustainably (in the stochastic equilibrium of the system) reduce the variability of out-
put in emerging market economies, then the real risks facing investors are those in the
equilibrium in which the IMF is acting optimally.
Fischer: FinancialCrises and Reform 23
erwise moral hazard will lead investors to make decisions based on beliefs
about extraordinary rescue packages rather than a careful appraisal of
the real value of the investment. And if that happens, a successful rescue
could contain the seeds of a future crisis.
Some emphasize fairness as much as efficiency, arguing that investors
should not be bailed out by loans financed by advanced country taxpay-
ers. In fact, IMF crisis loans have always been repaid 37 - often early -
and the industrialized country taxpayers do not bear a burden. 3s Rather
the loans are repaid by the taxpayers of the borrowing country - and
accordingly many argue that investors are being bailed out by imposing
a burden on domestic residents. To clinch this argument, it would be
necessary to spell out what the alternative course of action for the cri-
sis country would have been. There would surely have been substantial
costs associated with any other course of action, such as defaulting on
the debt.
For aH three reasons - particularly because it does not have and
should not have enough money to do otherwise - the IMF has to be
concerned with private sector involvement in the resolution of financial
crises. However, the issue has to be approached carefully, lest proposed
solutions increase the frequency of crises. For instance, the formalization
of a requirement that the banks, or any other set of creditors, always be
forced to share in the financing of IMF programs, would be destabilizing
for the international system. If such a condition were insisted on, the
creditors would have a greater incentive to rush for the exits at the
mere hint of a crisis. This is a real dilemma, one that suggests the need
for a differentiated approach to involving the private sector, one that
depends on the circumstances of each country: sometimes a formal
approach may be necessary, as in Korea at Christmas in 1997; at other
times, as in t h e case of Brazil in March 1999, when the commercial
banks voluntarily agreed to maintain their lines of credit, less formal
discussions could serve better; when financing needs are small, there may
not be a need to approach the creditors; and in extreme and infrequent
cases, an involuntary restructuring of the debt may be necessary.
37 A few countries (among them Sudan, Democratic Republic of the Congo, Liberia)
are in arrears to the IMF, but these are not countries that suffered capital account
crises - rather they sufferedfrom conflict and civil wars.
38 I leave aside here the issue of whether the subsidy implicit in lending to crisis
countries at IMF rates is a burden on the providers of funds.
24 Review of World Economics 2003, Vol. 139 (1)
39See the Annex for a full statement of the relevant paragraphs. I am grateful to
Mark Allen of the IMF for allowing me to draw on material he has provided.
Fischer: Financial Crises and Reform 25
40 Part of the decline in interbank lines was a result of a decline in demand by Turk-
ish banks.
26 Review of World Economics 2003, Vol. 139 (1)
been had it done what seemed best for it, acting alone, which was to
attempt to withdraw its funds. Bank regulators have been much less
enthusiastic about exerting such pressure in recent years, for they see
a conflict between their regulatory role and their pressuring the banks to
maintain portfolio positions against their will. Some industrial country
regulators argued that it was up to the authorities in the crisis country to
persuade the banks to hold their lines. But typically the crisis country has
very little leverage in this situation. It is similarly difficult for the IMF to
exert any leverage if the industrial country regulators are not also doing
so. The key issue is whether by exerting pressure the industrial country
regulators are indeed helping the banks reach a better equilibrium - and
a judgment on that issue should be made case by case.
The third difficulty is in the notion of voluntary market-based re-
structurings of the debt. To a first approximation, a purely voluntary
market-based restructuring cannot reduce the present value of a coun-
try's debt, for the country will simply be trading the debt up and down
the term structure. 41 Thus not much should be expected from purely
voluntary debt restructurings, though changes in the profile of debt
payments - for instance pushing them out into later years - could be
useful if the country has a temporary liquidity problem. The country
could achieve a reduction in the debt burden by reducing the seniority
and thus the value of existing claims in some way. And perhaps it could
achieve some reduction in the debt burden by enhancing some new
claims with the aid of financing or guarantees from the official sector,
where the reduction in the value of the debt will be approximately equal
to the reduction in the present value of interest payments implied by
the substitution of lower interest official debt for higher interest market
debt.
The fourth, most profound, difficulty occurs in the "extreme cases
where the member may have to resort to a temporary payments sus-
pension or standstill pending action by its creditors to support the
restoration of viability." The problem is that we have no accepted frame-
work in which a country in extremis can impose a payments suspension or
standstill pending agreement with its creditors to support the restoration
of viability - and that accordingly any country contemplating a standstill
faces enormous uncertainties about what will happen to the economy if it
41 The present value of the debt could change as a result of changes in the term struc-
ture of interest.
Fischer: Financial Crises and Reform 27
42 NationaI bankruptcy laws should apply to private sector debtors who carmot make
payments; if debtors can pay in local currency, the stay could permit a delay in con-
verting these payments into foreign currency.
43 It is often argued that Article VtlI-2b of the IMF Articles of Agreement could serve
as the basis for international approval of a payments standstill imposed by a member
of the Fund. However, this judgment is not shared by the IMF's lawyers, who point
out that Article VlII-2b applies to exchange controls on exchange contracts, not to
payments on debt contracts.
Fischer: Financial Crises and Reform 29
44 This proposal led to an Alphonse and Gaston act in which emerging country bond
issuers announced they would be willing to follow industrialized countries in includ-
ing such clauses, while the industrialized countries generally explained that they had
no need for them. In 2000, the United Kingdom did include such a clause in a euro
issue, in the hope that other countries would follow.
45 The strong opposition to the initial (1996) proposal for CACs became less persua-
sive when it was realized that such clauses already existed in so-called British trust-
deed bonds, and that no one had noticed. Subsequent empirical research by Eichen-
green and Mody (2000) suggested that the inclusion of such clauses reduces spreads
for high-quality borrowers and raises them for less sound borrowers - an appealing
result, though one that is the subject of ongoing research.
30 Review o f World Economics 2003, Vol. 139 (1)
restructure their debt obligations. I doubt this will happen, for the issuers
have generally fought vigorously to avoid defaults. If there is a hazard
in the adoption of CACs, it is that the official sector will become too
quick to urge restructurings as an alternative to IMF lending. There is
a balance to be struck, and it is important that the IMF not step back
from the provision of financial resources to countries facing a liquidity
crisis.
than two years after imposing them - did that. 46 Emerging market
country policymakers must have thought it useful to remain within the
international financial system despite the problems that had caused for
them.
Is there any way of establishing that the international capital markets
are inefficient? As we know from the literature on the stock market, it is
difficult to prove empirically that asset prices fluctuate excessively. 47 But
let me mention a few pieces of evidence.
Larry Summers has argued that there is an inconsistency between
the pricing of emerging market bonds and the frequency of defaults:
46 TO be sure, several countries did impose measures seeking to control or close access
to offshore markets in their currency.
47 It may be even more difficult to establish excess variability if there are multiple
equilibria. Presumably the test o f efficiency would then have seek to establish whether
the system was in a good or a bad equilibrium at any given time. There have been sev-
eral crises during which I was convinced we were in a multiple equilibrium situation,
in which the government's policies would be fully viable if spreads were lower - the
good equilibrium - but that the policies were not viable at actual spreads - the bad
equilibrium. But I do n o t know h o w to establish that was the case.
Fischer: Financial Crises and Reform 31
But we should also remember that the overall flow of resources to the
developing countries is highly variable, and that we are once again in
a period in which gross flows are extremely low, and net flows are almost
certainly negative.
In 1997 there was much talk about there being no need for the
IFIs because the private markets were doing the job of financing the
developing countries. That was never true for the smaller less developed
countries, but the variability of private sector flows makes clear the need
for the official sector to try to offset some of the fluctuations in private
flOWS. 50
5 Concluding Comments
Paul Volcker remarked during the debate over the international financial
architecture that the proposals for reform were more like interior deco-
rating than architecture. The proposals discussed in this lecture indeed
lack the grandeur of the vision of the global economy that the wartime
generation put in place, and the issues are less important for the behavior
of the international system than those on the agenda of international
monetary reform in the 1970s. But they are critical for the emerging
market countries, and that is reason enough to treat them as matters of
the highest priority.
Those who favor a more thoroughgoing reform of the system -
including Paul Volcker - focus on the exchange rate system among the
major currencies. There is no question that such fluctuations have been
disruptive, and that changes in the yen-dollar rate contributed to the
Asian crisis - given the peg of the Asian currencies to the U.S. dollar. But
for now and the foreseeable future there is no prospect of changing the
flexible exchange rate system among the major currencies.
Would emerging market countries be better off giving up their cur-
rencies and dollarizing or euro'izing? I believe that will ultimately hap-
pen, but that for a long time, most emerging market countries will and
should continue to allow exchange rate flexibility. Had exchange rates
been flexible, most of the famous crises of the last decade would either
not have happened, or would not have taken the form they did. That is
50 The argument that IMF lending creates moral hazard implies that spreads are on
average too low. That point does not jump out of the data.
Fischer: Financial Crises and Reform 33
why the shift to flexible rates among the emerging market countries is the
most important change in the international financial architecture dur-
ing the past decade, which should greatly reduce the frequency of crises.
But as we see in Brazil at present, the adoption of a flexible exchange rate
regime does not prevent all external crises, for debt-sustainability crises
will still occur.
What else needs to be done? All the measures we have discussed
to prevent crises by strengthening individual economies - including
lower debt-to-GDP ratios - will contribute to the better performance of
those economies and the international system. So will lessons learned
by the IMF from the recent crises. So too should better supervision
by industrial country regulators over the financial institutions active
in international markets, and more provision of information by those
institutions.
The major unresolved issue is the framework for private sector in-
volvement. Sometimes countries, like companies, need either a pause
in their debt servicing (in a liquidity crisis) or a permanent reduction
in the burden of debt servicing (in a solvency crisis). The international
financial system will not work well unless the imposition of a standstill
or debt reduction is extremely costly to a country, and very rare. But that
cost is currently too high.
The introduction of collective action clauses in bond agreements
will help reduce the costs of restructuring when that is necessary. But the
balance between creditors and debtors could also be tilted by changing
the legal framework for standstills and debt restructurings. What would
happen to the international capital markets if the rules could be changed
in this way? The initial reaction is to think that flows would decline, and
spreads would rise. But there is another, more likely, possibility: that
with more room for more orderly resolution of crises, and less risk of
extreme crises, flows would soon rise and spreads would decline as the
stability of emerging market economies grows.
What should we expect? Measures already in place or under way
will increase the stability of the international capital markets, and as
normalcy returns to the global economy, should also lead to greater flows
to countries that are managing themselves well. Work on developing
a better legal framework for standstills and sovereign debt restructuring
should get under way, but will take time to complete and longer to agree.
If the apparent improvements in the ability of the international capital
markets to discriminate among countries continues, thereby helping
34 Review of World Economics 2003, Vol. 139 (1)
Annex
21. The Committee endorses the report by the Managing Director on the in-
volvement of the private sector in crisis prevention and management. It wel-
comes the progress on developing a framework for involving private creditors
in the resolution of crises. The Committee notes that this approach strikes
a balance between the clarity needed to guide market expectations and the op-
erational flexibility, anchored in clear principles, needed to allow the most ef-
fective response in each case. The Committee notes that Fund resources are
limited and that extraordinary access should be exceptional; further, neither
creditors nor debtors should expect to be protected from adverse outcomes by
official action.
22. The Committee agrees that the operational framework for private sector
involvement must rely as much as possible on market-oriented solutions and
voluntary approaches. The approach adopted by the international community
should be based on the IMF's assessment of a country's underlying payment
capacity and prospects of regaining market access. In some cases, the combi-
nation of catalytic official financing and policy adjustment should allow the
country to regain full market access quickly. The Committee agrees that re-
liance on the catalytic approach at high levels of access presumes substantial
justification, both in terms of its likely effectiveness and of the risks of alter-
native approaches. In other cases, emphasis should be placed on encouraging
voluntary approaches, as needed, to overcome creditor coordination problems.
In yet other cases, the early restoration of full market access on terms consis-
tent with medium-term external sustainability may be judged to be unrealis-
tic, and a broader spectrum of actions by private creditors, including com-
prehensive debt restructuring, may be warranted to provide for an adequately
financed program and a viable medium-term payments profile. This includes
the possibility that, in certain extreme cases, a temporary payments suspen-
sion or standstill may be unavoidable. The Fund should continue to be pre-
pared to provide financial support to a member's adjustment program despite
arrears to private creditors, provided the country is seeking to work coopera-
tively and in good faith with its private creditors and is meeting other program
Fischer: Financial Crises and Reform 35
References