Recent Financial Crises
Recent Financial Crises
Recent Financial Crises
1
2 Recent financial crises
How much have we learned about the nature and the dynamics of these
crises? In particular, are these crises predictable to any appreciable or
practical extent – say, enough to be able to allow us to develop an early
warning system? What are the factors that make economies vulnerable
to financial crises? (Chapter 1 by Klein and Shabbir as well as Chapter 2
by Tinakorn.) Again, can the policy-makers recommend policies that
will soften the impact of, if not eliminate such crises? (Chapter 3 by
Eichengreen.)
Introduction 3
What kinds of specific lessons have we learned, if any, from these episodes?
What kinds of economic, fiscal, monetary and perhaps even political
reforms will be necessary in order to ameliorate the vulnerability of a
country to a financial crisis? In this respect, it is heartening to note that con-
siderable progress has already been made in instituting certain reforms of
the global financial system that have evidently been inspired by the recent
financial crises. Prodded by the IMF and the Bank for International
Settlements (BIS), increasingly countries now report the value of non-
performing loans (NPLs) as a way of monitoring the commercial banking
sector. In addition, there has been a consistent trend towards emphasizing
the importance of maintaining transparency and prudent risk management
by private financial institutions (such as the hedge funds) as well as the
central banks of the respective countries. The latter are now routinely
expected to furnish prompt and regular reports regarding the amount as
well as the disposition of the international reserves they manage. The
occurrences of these recent financial crises have taught us the importance
of continuing to strengthen these trends.
Since the affected countries have mostly recovered, at least economically,
from the recent crises, there is a real danger that, for practical purposes, a
significant complacency may set in. Obviously, we must guard against this
possibility – revisiting the question of the lessons learned and how best to
implement them to minimize recurrence and/or to mitigate the severity of
future crises. The description of one very important way to do just that can
be found in Chapter 3 by Eichengreen.
The next set of issues is often presented under the rubric of ‘cures’ for
financial crises – actually they are the generally recommended reforms
apparently motivated by the experience of financial crises. We will discuss
three such broad categories of the so-called ‘cures’: appropriate exchange
rate policy, capital market reforms and private business governance.
While the various economic indicators have shown sustainable and solid
improvement in the majority of the affected countries, their respective
social indicators are definitely still lagging relative to the pre-crisis trends.
The financial crisis in Asia left a deep mark in terms of social upheaval in
these countries, many of which were unprepared for such an eventuality.
We need to evaluate the income distributional impact in the medium- to
the long-run sense as well as to assess the state of the present and future
adequacy of the social safety nets in emerging economies that may be espe-
cially prone to financial crises (Chapter 1 by Klein and Shabbir). One par-
ticularly important question pertains to the behavior of the real wage rate
6 Recent financial crises
although they reached high growth in unique fashion – China’s has been a
case of growth led now by exports of manufactured goods, while India’s
growth has been fueled by growth of service sector activity (especially in the
information technology [IT], financial and health sectors). While each of
these countries have exhibited impressive rates of GDP growth in recent
years, there are significant financial sector issues such as stock and bond
market reform, greater transparency and better corporate governance that
still need attention. It is clear that going forward, financial sector and
capital market reforms will be necessary for the continued success of these
countries while keeping in mind some of the important ways – political and
structural – in which these countries differ from each other. However, the
important point is that, as the new players on the growth playing field so to
speak, these countries’ reliance on open trade and foreign direct investment
flows makes them vulnerable to financial crises. It is worth watching to see
whether lessons from the recent crises were learned well. During the crisis
period, neighbors and other competitors blamed China for stealing their
export markets. Now they enjoy China’s import appetite. As for India,
advanced countries blame ‘white collar’ unemployment problems on
India’s burgeoning service sector, but should be benefiting from reduced
operating costs in the near future.
The following is a brief guided tour of the contents and the themes
explored in the various chapters in this volume.
Since financial crises can be costly both in economic, as well as, societal
terms, it is only natural to inquire whether such crises are predictable.
Besides providing a brief introduction, this chapter reviews the various
approaches to prediction of currency crises. In this respect, the authors
conclude that while econometric predictive models can be very useful in
identifying various indicators of ‘vulnerability’, such exercises are not
a cure-all. Therefore, exploring the various aspects of the aftermath of a
financial crisis is also quite important. In this regard, the authors focus on
the income distributional consequences of the Asian Financial Crisis of
1997–98 as well as its impact on the poverty alleviation trends in the
affected countries.
Introduction 9
While the above factors may appear to be clouding the horizon for the emerg-
ing economies, Eichengreen stresses that ‘no ill effects are evident yet’
perhaps due to the reforms instituted since the last crisis in 1997–98. He
singles out ten reforms already instituted as noteworthy, namely, lengthening
the maturity structure of emerging economies’ debt, their smaller current
account deficits, larger foreign reserve stockpiles, relatively greater flexibility
Introduction 11
Chapter 5: ‘The Case of the Missing Market: The Bond Market and
Why It Matters for Financial Development’ by Richard J. Herring and
Nathporn Chatusripitak
Over the last decade, there has been an increased interest in analyzing the
role of financial institutions and financial markets in economic growth
and development. However, the main focus has been on equity markets,
and bond markets have been almost entirely overlooked. This chapter by
Herring–Chatusripitak, concentrating particularly on Asian economies,
tries to redress this situation by seeking to explain how the absence of a
well-functioning bond market may adversely affect other markets, savers,
investors and banks, and, in particular, how it may render the economy
more vulnerable to a financial crisis. It concludes with an analysis of recent
financial development in Thailand to illustrate both the problems associ-
ated with the absence of bond markets and the proposed solutions.
The authors assert that absence of well-functioning bond markets can
make an otherwise vibrant economy more vulnerable to a financial crisis (as
was the case in East Asia during the mid-1990s). One major implication of
the absence of a bond market is that the economy lacks a market-determined
term structure of interest rates that accurately reflects the opportunity cost
of funds. This deficiency can make firms under- or over-invest relative to the
societal efficient allocation on whether the firm’s internal rate of discount is
too high or too low (the latter was the case in the early to mid-1990s in East
Asia). Also, lack of ‘true’ term structure will impede accurate pricing of
equity in the stock market as well as pricing of credit risk. Again, in the
Introduction 13
In this chapter, Adams–Shabbir examine the impact of the 1997 East Asian
Financial Crisis on real GDP growth and total factor productivity (TFP)
of the East Asian countries during and after the crisis. Rather than taking
14 Recent financial crises
the more typical approach to analyzing the crisis and its impact in terms of
such factors as financial flows, exchange rate misalignment and contagion,
the authors approach the crisis from a production input/factor productiv-
ity perspective.
In the first place, the authors look at the financial crisis and its impact on
the growth record of East Asian countries, by comparing a number of
growth characteristics pre- and post-crisis. The impact was uneven with
apparently minimal effect on China yet with serious recessionary effect on
the economies of Thailand, South Korea and Indonesia. In general, real
GDP growth rates fell sharply in 1997–98 due to the crisis, and although
the post-crisis period shows renewed growth, it is at substantially lower
growth rates than in the pre-crisis period. Also, post-crisis relative to pre-
crisis, there was a downward trend in labor productivity growth. In add-
ition, compared with the exceptionally high values for the investment/GDP
ratio, there was a sharp drop in this investment share, and post-crisis recov-
ery was of a relatively smaller magnitude. In fact, the downward swing in
investment was not matched by a similar swing in domestic saving, hence
foreign inflows turned to outflows. Finally, though exports recovered in the
post-crisis period, and somewhat offset the lower investment share, the
export growth for this period was also lower than its pre-crisis rate.
The authors then seek to disentangle growth of output into that attrib-
utable to increased inputs and the residual factor, or total factor produc-
tivity. This residual represents the difference between the growth of total
output and the weighted sum of labor and capital input and includes all ele-
ments not taken into account in the computation of growth inputs, includ-
ing technological change, economies of scale, the composition of output,
the role of exports and the cyclical position of the economy. The authors
define unexplained TFP as the change in TFP less the business cycle effect
less the industrial/export effect. Statistics show that total labor and capital
input growth remain lower post-crisis than pre-crisis.
They next undertake a statistical analysis of the factors associated with
the growth of TFP. To measure the effect of the 1997 Financial Crisis on
TFP, during which there were severe declines in production, they perform
regressions linking TFP to a series of dummy variables covering the
1998–2001 periods. They find that declines in production, particularly in
1997 and 1998, have clear impacts on TFP, that the loss in productivity
growth associated with this period was not made up in later years, and that
the coefficient of a time-trend variable was significantly negative. They also
perform regressions linking TFP to other variables such as increasing
exports, share of investment, and industrialization, and find that change in
industrial output and change in exports make significant contributions to
TFP change. Other measured factors, including foreign direct investment,
Introduction 15
Chapter 7: ‘What Really Happened to Thai Wage Rates during the East
Asian Financial Crisis?’ by Jere R. Behrman, Anil B. Deolalikar and
Pranee Tinakorn
and estimate that this aspect of the World Bank methodology by itself
causes a bias of 1.4 percentage points (implying a ‘true’ change of ⫺4.6%
⫺1.4% ⫽ ⫺6.0%). If all of these first three biases were corrected, the World
Bank estimate would change to an increase of 2 percent in Thai real wage
rates during the crisis.
However, more importantly, BDT contend a fourth issue related to the
above World Bank methodology. This issue concerns the World Bank
study’s assumption that no change took place in the composition of wage
recipients between the pre- and post-crisis periods. Instead the BDT study
looks at data for all workers and for subcategories defined by the three
observed characteristics of gender, age and schooling and finds that as a
result of the crisis, wage employment shifted relatively from females to
males, from younger to older workers, and from lower-schooled to higher-
schooled individuals – all shifts from lower to higher real wage categories.
The failure to account for these important compositional changes in World
Bank estimates means that the estimated overall average real wage rate
change is biased upwards. The authors’ best estimate of how much real
hourly wage rates declined due to the crisis is 7.8 percent (due to the
methodology used by BDT, their estimate is free from the first three biases
that the World Bank study had to contend with).
The major conclusion of the study was that the methodology used by the
World Bank presents a misleading picture of what happened to Thai real
wage rates during the Asian Financial Crisis. Although the biases in the
World Bank study are partially offsetting, the severity of the impact of the
crisis on declines in the real wage rate is underestimated by 3.2 percentage
points or about 40 percent (comparing a World Bank estimate of a 4.6
percent decline with this study’s preferred estimate of a 7.8 percent decline).
This study notes that even the decline of 7.8 percent is probably an under-
estimate of the true decline because of the probable compositional changes
that occur because of unobserved characteristics such as ability and moti-
vation. The authors feel that the best solution would be for longitudinal
labor force data to be collected as a matter of routine so that comparisons
could be made for the wage rates for the same individuals over time. If these
longitudinal surveys are not available, then a second-best solution is to
follow the methods in this chapter, in particular controlling for composi-
tional changes with respect to observed characteristics such as gender, age
and schooling.
Besides the above question of computing the ‘true’ magnitude of the
decline in the Thai real wage during the 1997 crisis, the BDT study also
examined the claim that the poorer and more vulnerable suffered most in
the crisis and found some, but limited, support for that claim. Regression
estimates showed that youths fared worse than prime-age adults, but that
Introduction 17
In this chapter, McKinnon puts forth an analysis that concludes that, under
the world dollar standard, a discrete appreciation by a dollar creditor
country of the United States, such as China or Japan, has no predictable
effect on its trade surplus. Currency appreciation by the creditor country
will slow its economic growth and eventually cause deflation but cannot
compensate for a saving–investment imbalance in the United States. Under
a fixed exchange rate, however, differential adjustment in the rate of growth
of money wages will more accurately reflect international differences in
productivity growth. International competitiveness will be better balanced
between high-growth and low-growth economies, as between Japan and the
US from 1950 to 1971 and China and the US from 1994 to 2005, when the
peripheral country’s dollar exchange rate is fixed so that its wage growth
better reflects its higher productivity growth. Also discussed is the qualified
case for China moving toward greater flexibility in the form of a very
narrow band for the yuan/dollar exchange rate, as a way of decentralizing
foreign exchange transacting.
One important implication of the McKinnon hypothesis as articulated
in this chapter is that even if we made some desirable changes in the
yuan/dollar exchange rate, the hope of narrowing the China–US trade
surplus may not materialize since the more important determinant of the
Chinese advantage is its relatively lower wage rate. According to available
data, anecdotal evidence indicates that it may be as high as 20 to 30:1 in
China’s favor compared with about 5 to 10:1 in India’s favor when we
compare India versus China. However, it is interesting to note that China’s
relative advantage in wage competitiveness may already be narrowing and
the dynamic implications of this trend towards the exchange rate and trade
policy vis-à-vis China should be very instructive and important to watch.
In this chapter, the authors Klein, Gao and Tao (KGT), in a pioneering
study, adjust China’s Consumer price index (CPI) to account for the ‘true’
cost of living for 1993–2004, a period that covers the Asian Financial Crisis
period 1997–98.
18 Recent financial crises
冢 冣兺
n n
(pitqit ⫺ pit␥i ) ⫽ i rt ⫺ 兺
j⫽1
pjt␥j ;
i⫽1
i ⫽ 1
↕ ↕ ↕ ↕
expenditure on minimum total total minimum i ⫽ marginal
the i-th category subsistence income subsistence propensity to
expenditure expenditure consume
on the i-th on all categories out of
category supernumerary
income.
stabilizing influence in East Asia during the crisis period. It is evident that
this chapter makes very important contributions methodologically as well
from a policy perspective in the context of the debate on the Asian
Financial Crisis of 1997–98.
NOTE
REFERENCES
1 INTRODUCTION
It is common knowledge that the Asian Financial Crisis refers to the onset
and the aftermath of the currency crashes with attendant sharp declines in
output growth and plummeting stock markets in many of the previously
fast-growing countries in East Asia during 1997–98. Amongst the countries
were particularly hit hard were Thailand, Republic of Korea, Indonesia,
Malaysia and the Philippines (often dubbed the ‘Affected Five’). For this
group of countries, the average decline in the 1997 real GDP growth was
about 10 percent from the trend value in 1996, the currency devaluations
ranged from 30 percent to 80 percent and stock markets declined by as
much as 70 percent, which was the case in Indonesia.
Occurring on the heels of past economic achievements of historic pro-
portions, these severe economic shocks were particularly painful as expect-
ations of an ever-increasing living standard had to be sharply and suddenly
pared down in these countries. After all, during the three decades preced-
ing the crisis, these East Asia countries had enjoyed a period of remarkable
economic growth as well as social sector achievements. The decades leading
up to the crisis had witnessed an average real GDP annual growth rate of
more than 7 percent, a decline in poverty from an incidence of six in ten
to two in ten, income per capita increases of up to ten-fold in Korea and
four-fold in Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand, nearly 100 percent primary
school enrollment, remarkable reductions in infant mortality and increases
in life expectancy. Unfortunately, the Asian Crisis of 1997–98 had suddenly
but surely put all of these past achievements in serious jeopardy. It was
rightly feared that the Asian Crisis will be costly both in economic and soci-
etal terms. However, the majority of the analyses of the costs of this crisis
have focused on its economic or financial aspects while the disruptive social
or societal impact of this episode has been relatively ignored; in fact, one
23
24 Analysis of currency crises
of the three major goals of the present study is to contribute towards rec-
tifying the understanding of this imbalance. The other two goals are to
present a retrospective overview of the nature and efficacy of the econo-
metric predictive models of currency crisis as well as the identification of
the pre- versus post-crisis pattern of macroeconomic indicators of ‘vulner-
ability’ for the ‘Affected Five’ countries in order to note the appropriate
lessons that may be learned.
Three major goals of this chapter are to:
with a pegged exchange rate, and which eventually lead to its collapse. The
canonical model here was presented in Krugman (1979), based on a gov-
ernment that is financing persistent budget deficits through monetization.
This simplest of models suggests that in the period leading up to a specula-
tive attack, one should notice a gradual decline in reserves. It also suggests
that budget deficits and excessive growth in domestic credit may be poten-
tial early warning indicators for speculative attacks. Extensions of the basic
model look at other factors that may force the government to abandon the
peg. For example, expansionary policy may lead directly to a worsening of
the current account through a rise in import demand; the same result may
occur indirectly through a rise in the price of non-tradables and the subse-
quent overvaluation of the real exchange rate.
Thus, the behavior of external sector variables such as the trade balance,
the current account deficit and the real exchange rate may provide some
warning regarding the vulnerability of a country to a speculative attack.
Further, other potentially useful indicators in this respect are possible meas-
ures of the ‘quality of existing debt’, say, the proportion of non-performing
loans of the banking system.
Second-generation models were motivated by episodes such as the
exchange rate mechanism (ERM) crisis in 1992–93, where some of the
countries did not seem to possess the characteristics described in first-
generation models. This led researchers such as Obstfeld (1994) to enrich
existing theories of currency crises. The key element in second-generation
models is recognition that there are both benefits and costs to maintaining
a peg, and that market participants’ beliefs over whether a peg will not hold
or can affect a government’s cost of defending it. The circularity inherent
in second-generation models – that government policy is affected by expect-
ations, and expectations are affected by government policy – leads to the
possibility of multiple equilibria and self-fulfilling crises. These second-
generation models suggest that anything that affects a government’s
decision whether to maintain a peg or not – because of unemployment,
inflation, the amount and composition of debt, financial sector stability
and so on – might contain information on the likelihood of a crisis occur-
ring. Also, evidently, the inflexibility of the ERM system prevented poten-
tially helpful policy actions. This crisis brought to the forefront the
potential for conflict between a member country’s goals and the restrictions
of the system. On the other hand, we saw later in 1997–98, Hong Kong,
with its very strict parity with US dollar, let interest rates go extremely high,
but they had big reserves when attacked by the speculative hedge funds and
could withstand these shocks.
The third generation of currency crisis models focuses on the issue of
contagion, or why the occurrence of a crisis in one country seems to affect
26 Analysis of currency crises
This model further assumes that the Markov chain is of order 1, with tran-
sition probabilities that are time-varying through dependence on observ-
able indicator variables. In Mariano et al. (2002, 2003) there are reports of
results that are based on the following indicator variables:
Further, let
We assume also that the transition probabilities vary over time according
to values of indicator variables in the following manner:
The second part of the model consists of a univariate linear model for yt:
ˆtⴙ1|t ⫽ Pt⫹1 · t | t
T
L() ⫽ 兺log f(yt |Xt,Yt⫺1; )
t⫽1
Asia before and after the financial crisis of 1997–98 31
where
One can then evaluate this at different values of to find the maximum like-
lihood estimate.
The literature that has been inspired by the East Asian Crisis of 1997–98
proffers two competing hypotheses as the possible causes of currency
crisis – the ‘contagion’ hypothesis versus the ‘vulnerability’ hypothesis.7
According to the ‘contagion’ view, the capital flight in Thailand induced
by expectations of an impending devaluation of the bhat relative to the US
dollar (to which it was pegged), had negative informational ‘spillover’
effects that doomed some of the neighbors by casting doubt in the minds
of the investors about otherwise ‘healthy’ economies.
The ‘vulnerability’ hypothesis, on the other hand, maintains that some
economies were inherently vulnerable to a crisis because of relatively long-
term deterioration in economic fundamentals. This predisposed them to
crisis when faced with shocks that may lead to expectation of exchange rate
devaluation.
The above set of rival explanations can be distinguished such that the
‘contagion’ factor is analogous to a ‘trigger’ and ‘vulnerability’ means sus-
ceptibility to a country crisis on fundamental grounds.
Of course, in their respective extreme forms, the contagion and vulner-
ability hypothesis afford significantly different interpretations as well as
policy implications, whereas the vulnerability hypothesis implies that the rel-
ative susceptibility of an economy can be ascertained with the aid of observ-
able indicators. Also, high levels of vulnerability make a crisis inevitable and
any random event could actually provoke it. On the other hand, extreme ver-
sions of the contagion hypothesis deny or certainly minimize the significance
of observable indicators of vulnerability. Most of the literature dealing with
the East Asian Crisis of 1997–98 has taken an intermediate stance.
After all, the pure contagion explanation has had to contend with the
question that if Thailand spread the virus, how did Thailand become
affected in the first place? Evidently, it is hard to escape having to rely on
an explanation that is based on deteriorating fundamentals in Thailand
before 1997. Again contagion theory fails to explain why some countries
such as Singapore, Taiwan and China proved to be resilient to the spread-
ing ‘virus’.
Asia before and after the financial crisis of 1997–98 33
We feel that the intermediate position is the most tenable one and thus
examining the determinants of vulnerability in terms of critical real as well
as financial sector indicators is a very useful exercise. In the analysis that
follows, we examine the pre- as well as post-crisis pattern of certain critical
macroeconomic fundamentals to provide an assessment of the dynamics of
the economies of the ‘Affected Five’ before and after the ‘breakpoint’
marked by the 1997–98 crisis.8
As evident from the data trends in current account deficit, export growth
rate, government budget fiscal balance and other pertinent macroeconomic
variables such as the real exchange rate overvaluation, the ‘Affected Five’
countries (Thailand, Republic of Korea, Indonesia, Malaysia and the
Philippines) were vulnerable before the outbreak of the currency crisis of
the baht on 2 July 1997. The problem is particularly telling if one looks at
the increase in the current account deficit and the slowdown in the export
growth rate. This, accompanied by the fragility of the financial sector, in
particular, the upsurge in the proportion of non-performing loans, con-
tributed greatly to the currency and, more broadly, the financial crisis that
followed. Tables 1.1–1.5 (and the corresponding Figures 1.1–1.5) below
present the pertinent data for the pre- as well as post-crisis period
(1993–2004) and additional comments for each of the ‘Affected Five’ coun-
tries separately.9 On the other hand, Figure 1.6 through Figure 1.11 present
the comparative data for all of the ‘Affected Five’ countries for several
important indicators considered one at a time.
As can be seen from Table 1.1 and Figure 1.1, before 1997, Thailand’s
CA (current account) balance (as a percentage of GDP) had deteriorated
sharply from –5.41 percent in 1994 to –7.89 percent in 1996, while its export
growth had declined precipitously from an average growth of 20.11 percent
during 1993–95 to a decline of –1.91 percent in 1996, and the fiscal balance
(as a percentage of GDP) dropped significantly from 3.01 percent in 1995
to 0.94 percent in 1996. These indicators clearly pointed to Thailand’s
serious vulnerability to a crisis, which, of course, unfolded on 2 July 1997.
In the years following the onset of the crisis in 1997, while Thailand had
started showing definite signs of turnaround in its external sector indicators
as early as 1998 (the CA deficit had turned positive by then), this recovery
was not across the board – in fact, the GDP growth rate registered a steep
decline in 1998. Indeed, it was not until 1999, that a firmer and more broad-
based recovery milestone was reached when, in addition to a sustained CA
surplus, the GDP growth rate turned significantly positive, and both
the growth rates of exports as well as imports were positive. Thus, for all
Table 1.1 Macro indicators: Thailand
Year 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
CA (% of GDP) ⫺4.90 ⫺5.41 ⫺7.88 ⫺7.89 ⫺1.97 12.66 10.17 7.61 5.41 6.06 5.57 4.39
Export Growth* (%) 13.36 22.15 24.82 ⫺1.91 3.76 ⫺6.78 7.42 19.52 ⫺6.92 5.71 18.18 21.56
Import Growth* (%) 12.35 18.44 31.85 0.62 ⫺13.37 ⫺33.75 16.94 31.34 ⫺2.82 4.45 17.35 26.04
Fiscal Balance 1.89 2.69 3.01 0.94 ⫺1.50 ⫺2.79 ⫺3.33 ⫺2.23 ⫺2.40 ⫺1.41 0.40 0.13
(% of GDP)
34
Real GDP Growth (%) 8.99 9.24 5.90 ⫺1.37 ⫺10.51 4.45 4.76 2.14 5.41 7.03 6.17
REER (1996 ⫽100) 90.78 92.28 91.54 100.00 93.71 82.39 85.61 79.56 78.11 82.16 80.49 79.12
Inflation Rate (%) 3.31 5.08 5.79 5.83 5.60 8.08 0.30 1.55 1.66 0.60 1.81 2.77
Notes:
Def.: REER⫽real effective exchange rate index (1996⫽100).
* Based on [{Index(t)/Index (t⫺1)}⫺1]⫻100 where Index value for 1996⫽100.
Source: http://aric.adb.org.
30.00
25.00
20.00
15.00
10.00
Percent
5.00
0.00
35
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
–5.00
–10.00
–15.00
practical purposes, 1999 is the year that marks the onset of the post-crisis
recovery for Thailand even though fiscal balance took a little longer to
recover and started to improve only in 2000.
The Republic of Korea (Table 1.2 and Figure 1.2), in a scenario similar
to Thailand’s, exhibited plenty of pre-crisis signs of vulnerability – its CA
(as a percentage of GDP) turned to a deep deficit in 1996 (–4.41 percent)
from a slight surplus of 0.29 percent in 1993, while its export growth slowed
down significantly from an average of 18.10 percent p. a. during 1993–95
to a relative trickle in 1996 (3.72 percent) and its real GDP growth that
averaged 8.59 percent p. a. for 1994–95, registered at only 6.75 percent in
1996.
While the crisis meant a sharp decline for Korea’s real GDP growth rate
(–6.69 percent in 1998), as a whole, it was relatively the least hampered by
the crisis amongst the group of ‘Affected Five’ countries. In 1999, Korea’s
real GDP growth rate recovered vigorously (10.89 percent), its fiscal deficit
started declining as well, and, in fact, turned to a surplus by 2000, which
has proven sustainable since. Again, following a decline of 2.83 percent in
1998, the export growth rate resumed a positive trend with the exception of
a drop in 2001 on account of the recession in the US, a major importer of
Korean manufactured goods (average export growth of 17.35 percent p. a.
during 1999–2004, excluding 2001, which compares favorably with the
average of 18.10 percent p. a. for the pre-crisis ‘miracle’ years of 1993–95.
The country’s current account balance also turned positive starting in 1998
though this happened primarily because of a relatively much steeper drop
in its trend import growth, which had dropped to –35.50 percent in 1998;
import growth did in fact turn positive by the following year and still the
CA balance stayed positive.
In general, ex post, the trajectory of Korea’s macroeconomic recovery
from the crisis was a ‘V-shaped’ rather than a ‘U-shaped’ one – that is, quick
and sharp rather than dull and drawn out. (See Figure 1.6 in this chapter
for comparative changes in real GDP growth rate for the ‘Affected Five’
countries.)
In addition, in the aftermath of the crisis, Korea has had relatively the
most to show for its efforts to clean up its financial sector both in terms of
the reform of the corporate ownership structure and decreased frequency
of the non-performing loans as a proportion of the total debt of the
banking system (though no statistics have been noted in the tables in this
regard).
Table 1.3 and the corresponding Figure 1.3 look at the case of Indonesia
whose economy, like that of Thailand and Korea, exhibited pre-crisis
increase in external sector imbalance (CA deficit increased from –1.45
percent of GDP to –3.41 percent of GDP). However, unlike the Thai or
Table 1.2 Macro indicators: Republic of Korea
Year 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
CA (% of GDP) 0.29 ⫺0.96 ⫺1.73 ⫺4.41 ⫺1.70 12.58 6.02 2.65 1.93 1.27 1.96 4.05
Export Growth* (%) 7.31 16.75 30.25 3.72 4.97 ⫺2.83 8.59 19.89 ⫺12.67 8.00 19.29 30.97
Import Growth* (%) 2.48 22.13 32.02 11.26 ⫺3.81 ⫺35.50 28.38 34.01 ⫺12.08 7.82 17.55 25.52
Fiscal Balance 0.33 0.26 ⫺1.54 ⫺4.22 ⫺2.71 1.25 1.32 3.80 1.12 0.72
(% of GDP)
37
Real GDP Growth (%) 5.49 8.25 8.92 6.75 5.01 ⫺6.69 10.89 9.33 3.10 6.35 3.10 4.64
REER (1996 ⫽100) 91.93 94.13 95.67 100.00 95.98 79.50 86.89 90.03 87.56 93.71 95.52 97.13
Inflation Rate (%) 4.79 6.27 4.45 4.92 4.44 7.52 0.81 2.26 4.31 2.77 3.51 3.59
Notes:
Def.: REER⫽real effective exchange rate index (1996⫽100).
* Based on [{Index(t)/Index (t⫺1)}⫺1]⫻100 where Index value for 1996⫽100.
Source: http://aric.adb.org.
35.00
30.00
25.00
20.00
15.00
Percent
10.00
5.00
38
0.00
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
–5.00
–10.00
–15.00
Year 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
CA (% of GDP) ⫺1.45 ⫺1.67 ⫺3.34 ⫺3.41 ⫺2.22 4.27 4.11 5.3 4.87 4.3 3.40 1.21
Export Growth* (%) 7.88 9.31 13.39 9.68 7.28 ⫺8.6 ⫺0.37 27.66 ⫺9.34 1.49 6.82 17.24
Import Growth* (%) 3.71 12.95 27.03 5.66 ⫺2.91 ⫺34.41 ⫺11.2 38.06 ⫺7.62 1.06 4.03 42.93
Fiscal Balance 0.61 0.94 2.22 1.16 ⫺0.67 ⫺2.95 ⫺1.15 ⫺1.19 ⫺3.77 ⫺1.76 ⫺1.65 ⫺1.24
(% of GDP)
39
Real GDP Growth (%) 7.54 8.22 7.82 4.7 ⫺13.13 0.79 4.92 3.44 3.66 4.88 5.13
REER (1996⫽100) 93.02 93.63 91.26 100.00 95.46 48.07 68.06 64.19 63.44 77.92 83.39 78.48
Inflation Rate (%) 9.69 8.52 9.43 7.97 6.14 56.15 19.96 3.93 11.54 11.84 6.75 6.08
Notes:
Def.: REER⫽real effective exchange rate index (1996⫽100).
* Based on [{Index(t)/Index (t⫺1)}⫺1]⫻100 where Index value for 1996⫽100.
Source: http://aric.adb.org.
60
50
40
30
Percent
20
10
40
0
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
–10
–20
Year 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
CA (% of GDP) ⫺4.47 ⫺6.05 ⫺9.78 ⫺4.8 ⫺5.18 13.53 15.92 9.14 8.27 7.82 12.82 12.57
Export Growth* (%) 15.72 24.74 25.85 5.93 0.41 ⫺6.75 15.34 16.08 ⫺10.45 5.92 11.60 20.52
Import Growth* (%) 14.32 30.55 31.52 0.1 0.68 ⫺26.14 12.08 25.35 ⫺10.03 7.98 4.84 25.92
Fiscal Balance 0.21 2.26 0.84 0.72 2.35 ⫺1.77 ⫺3.15 ⫺5.75 ⫺5.51 ⫺5.62 ⫺5.30 ⫺4.32
(% of GDP)
42
Real GDP Growth (%) 9.9 9.21 9.83 10.00 7.32 ⫺7.36 6.14 8.55 0.32 4.12 5.42 7.14
REER (1996 ⫽100) 93.42 92.53 93.93 100.00 99.08 81.53 82.33 80.94 87.28 89.49 84.79 78.48
Inflation Rate (%) 3.56 4.94 4.06 3.49 2.67 5.27 2.74 1.52 1.41 1.83 1.09 1.42
Notes:
Def.: REER⫽real effective exchange rate index (1996⫽100).
* Based on [{Index(t)/Index (t⫺1)}⫺1]⫻100 where Index value for 1996⫽100.
Source: http://aric.adb.org.
30
25
20
15
10
Percent
0
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
43
–5
–10
–15
quickly while maintaining a low and stable inflation rate, though fiscal bal-
ances were continuing to worsen well into the 1990s and even early in the
new decade.10
Finally, referring to Table 1.5 and the corresponding Figure 1.5, we turn
to a discussion about the Philippines – a country that had just started to
show promise when the Asian Crisis hit in 1997. In fact, relative to its
ASEAN (Association of Southeast Asian Nations) partners, the Philippines
were relatively more vulnerable – its GDP growth rate had averaged only
about half of what Korea had been able to achieve in the years leading up
to the Asian Crisis; further, for the period, early to mid-1990s, the
Philippines suffered from a current account deficit in the range of 4–5
percent of GDP. The country also had its share of political instabilities and
crises and, collectively, these pre-crisis vulnerabilities made the recovery
period somewhat anemic. Here it is important to note that the ‘Marcos
Regime’, which lasted for almost two decades from 1965–85, had been
replaced by a relatively democratic institution only for about ten years when
the Asian Crisis occurred. Thus, the Philippines were somewhat ‘late
bloomers’ whose ascent to a sustained higher economic stage was signifi-
cantly interrupted by the crisis in 1997. Still the country appears to have
made a sustained, albeit modest-sized, recovery from the crisis. However,
the future prospects of the country would depend on continued political sta-
bility that the country has enjoyed of late, getting the increasing fiscal deficit
under control and continuing to make progress in terms of the financial
sector and governance-related reforms.
Incidentally, many of the above observations regarding the pre- versus
post-crisis relative performance of the ‘Affected Five’ countries can also be
visualized in an alternative format as presented in the following set of
Figures 1.6–1.11. Here each figure displays information about a given eco-
nomic indicator across countries rather than across economic indicators for
one country at a time as above. In particular, note that Republic of Korea’s
GDP growth rate was relatively the fastest to recover after the crisis (Figure
1.6) and, relatively speaking, Indonesia had to suffer from the highest rate
of inflation in the aftermath of the crisis (Figure 1.11).
Year 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
CA (% of GDP) ⫺5.54 ⫺4.56 ⫺4.49 ⫺4.77 ⫺5.27 2.36 9.18 8.36 1.84 5.39 1.76 2.37
Export Growth* (%) 15.78 18.53 29.36 17.78 22.8 16.93 18.78 8.69 ⫺15.57 9.51 2.91 9.52
Import Growth* (%) 21.2 21.23 24.38 22.22 10.81 ⫺17.46 3.59 12.26 ⫺4.15 7.17 3.14 8.82
Fiscal Balance ⫺1.48 1.07 0.59 0.29 0.06 ⫺1.88 ⫺3.75 ⫺4.06 ⫺4.0 ⫺5.24 ⫺4.66 ⫺3.86
(% of GDP)
45
Real GDP Growth (%) 2.12 4.39 4.68 5.85 5.19 ⫺0.58 3.4 5.97 2.96 4.43 4.62 6.03
REER (1996⫽100) 81.67 87.55 90.58 100.00 100.6 85.14 91.29 82.47 79.9 82.01 75.47 71.48
Inflation Rate (%) 6.88 8.36 8.03 9.01 5.97 9.7 6.68 4.31 6.12 3.1 3.48 5.98
Notes:
Def.: REER⫽real effective exchange rate index (1996⫽100).
* Based on [{Index(t)/Index (t⫺1)}⫺1]⫻100 where Index value for 1996⫽100.
Source: http://aric.adb.org.
35
30
25
20
15
Percent
10
5
0
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
46
–5
–10
–15
–20
10.00
5.00
Percent
0.00
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
47
–5.00
–10.00
–15.00
Figure 1.6 Relative real GDP growth rates (%) for the Asian ‘Affected Five’
20.00
15.00
10.00
5.00
Percent
0.00
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
48
–5.00
–10.00
–15.00
4.00
2.00
0.00
Percent
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
–2.00
49
–4.00
–6.00
–8.00
30.00
20.00
Percent
Percent
10.00
50
0.00
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
–10.00
–20.00
40.00
30.00
20.00
10.00
Percent
0.00
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
51
–10.00
–20.00
–30.00
–40.00
50
40
Percent
30
52
20
10
0
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
For one, Krugman (1994) asserted that since the high GDP growth
rate of the Asian ‘tigers’ was fueled primarily by ‘Soviet-style’ accumu-
lations of machinery, infrastructure, and other factor inputs rather than
‘efficiency’ gains, these growth rates will ‘slow down’. Also, there were
many other discussions, albeit often of a generic nature, about the
possibility of the appearance of the ‘Mexican Crisis’ of December 1994
and early 1995 in other countries. A somewhat specific case of such analy-
sis is Lau (1995) who noted, in an ex ante sense, that Thailand and
Indonesia were the most likely venues for a Mexican-type financial crisis
to occur.
On the other hand, Inada et al. (2000) is a retrospective simulation exer-
cise that concludes that one factor at the heart of the difficulty in East Asia
was the fact that many of these countries had, to a significant extent,
pegged their currencies to the US dollar, which grew relatively very strong,
and many of these countries, such as Thailand, did not act early enough (as
China did in 1994) to devalue their currencies, which would have averted or
significantly ameliorated the impact of the currency crises. Of course, the
Chinese exchange rate action was not in response to a pending crisis, but
was a move to unify their exchange rate policies in January 1994 and hold
the renminbi-dollar rate at constant par from that time forward. However,
the other East Asian countries failed to react to that move by China and
thus lost export trade share accordingly.11 It is interesting to note that in
this new century, China’s growth has been so rapid and intense that they
have required imports from many partner countries, including East Asian
neighbors, and have contributed to favorable macroeconomic performance
over a wide area.
3.4 Asia in the 21st Century – China and India as the New Players for the
‘New Asian Miracle’
Looking ahead to the future developments in Asia, China and India are
emerging as two increasingly important regional and eventually global eco-
nomic powers. They are relatively the fastest-growing (with respective GDP
growth rates of 8–10 percent for China and 6–7 percent p. a. for India in
the last ten years) with dynamic and open economies, at least with respect
to trade flows. These two countries appear fully poised to be the new players
in the ‘New Asian Miracle’, if we may modify a much-worn label. The
important question from our perspective is: how much are these countries
going to benefit from the lessons learned from the recent financial crises
around the world? No doubt, the open economies of these countries will
make them vulnerable to external shocks. They need to be ready with robust
54 Analysis of currency crises
Theoretically, financial crises are expected to worsen poverty (or slow down
the rate of poverty alleviation) and worsen inequality for a number of
reasons:
Baldacci et al. (2002) examine the relationship between currency crises and
poverty across a number of developing countries during 1960–98.
Compared with a standardized control group that did not suffer any such
crises, the study reports that besides increases in inflation rates ‘by nearly
62 percent relative to the pre-crisis year’ and an increase in unemployment
by 1.1 percent in crisis years relative to pre-crisis years, the inequality
increases as well as poverty worsens in the group of countries that suffer
currency crises. A decline in average income of a country is accompanied
by a more than proportionate decline in income of the lowest and second
lowest quintiles, which worsens income inequality as well as increases inci-
dence of poverty, as households in the lower quintiles are more likely to
have income below the poverty line. Further, government cutbacks in
expenditure on social programs, health and education are associated with
falling incomes of the poorest. In the case of Mexico, the study finds that
the ‘poverty rate spiked to nearly 17 percent of the population in 1996, from
nearly 11 percent in 1994, reversing the gains made in 1992–94’.
Thus, as discussed above, occurrence of financial crisis can be expected
generally to have an impact on the incidence of poverty as well as the
income distribution in the country. In fact, such crises will also have
broader effects on the living standards of the affected countries. We will
discuss these issues in turn mainly for the case of the ‘Affected Five’ coun-
tries of East Asia in the context of the 1997–98 Financial Crisis.
Note: Based on national poverty lines and per capita household income except for
Indonesia (per capita expenditure), Mexico (household income), and Russia (household
expenditure per equivalent adult). Data for Argentina refer to Greater Buenos Aires. nd⫽
no data available.
The available empirical evidence suggests that, in general, inequality rises or,
at best, stays constant during a crisis. As reported in the World Development
Report of 2000–01 (World Bank, 2000), for Latin American countries,
inequality (as measured by the Gini coefficient) increased in 15 of 20 crisis
episodes for which there are data available. For the East Asian countries, on
the other hand, the pattern was somewhat more complex. While during the
crisis year or very soon after it (that is, 1997 or 1998), the Gini coefficient was
virtually unchanged, it often increased (signaling worsening inequality) in
the years following the onset of the crisis. However, in some cases, the Gini
coefficient has dropped as economies have recovered (for instance, Thailand).
Table 1.7 has pre- and post-crisis data for the Gini coefficient (column 1)
for several of the East Asian countries affected by the 1997 crisis – Malaysia,
58 Analysis of currency crises
Note:
The poverty lines in Table 1.7 are set at $2.15 per person per day (in 1993 PPP $) for all
countries. For most countries, 1993 World Bank PPP (purchasing power parity) estimates are
used. The PPP for the Philippines is from the Penn World Tables. Estimates for all countries
except Malaysia are based on surveys of household consumption. The estimates for Malaysia
use income surveys. These poverty estimates differ from those commonly found in national
poverty assessments for two main reasons. First, country assessments use national poverty
lines that differ from the uniform international poverty lines used here. Second, national
poverty lines also typically allow for spatial cost-of-living differentials within countries, but
such adjustments are omitted here to maintain a consistent methodology across countries. For
instance, in the case of Thailand, these differences explain why the above estimates indicate a
small increase in poverty between 1998 and 2000 (in spite of adjusting the CPI by the change
in the national poverty lines over this period), while national poverty line-based estimates
indicate a decline. Also for Thailand, the 2002 estimate is based on a longer consumption
module, which could lead to a small overestimation of consumption relative to 2000.
60 Analysis of currency crises
even a very slight worsening income inequality between 1996 and 1997
meant reversals in poverty alleviation in Malaysia.
Similarly, the mean consumption in Malaysia that had steadily risen
from 195.32 in 1990 to 315.95 in 1997, dropped to 269.00 in 1998 although
it picked up rather smartly soon after that, perhaps, in part, due to the fact
that inequality measures were nearly constant after 1997, the year of the
crisis. If inequality would have worsened significantly after the crisis, it is
very likely that Malaysia’s mean consumption would have stayed depressed
for a considerably longer period of time.
In the Korean case, while income inequality increased after the crisis,
such a trend had been in place even before the crisis. Thus it would appear
that there were structural factors unique to the Korean economy that were
prompting an increasing trend in Gini coefficient values independent of the
1997 crisis. Nevertheless, the data indicate that any such pre-crisis trend
may have been exacerbated as a result of the crisis. Further, in terms of the
status of poverty reduction in Korea, the headcount index has stayed con-
stant at a relatively low level (⬍0.5 percent) since 1990 and the mean con-
sumption series also seems to have been little affected by the incidence of
the 1997 crisis. The most likely reason for this pattern is the fact that in the
Korean case, relatively speaking, the recovery from the crisis was the fastest
of all the affected countries (the ‘V’-shaped pattern of recovery), thus the
previous trends were little disturbed. Korea, in other words, has fared the
best by not suffering any major ill effects of the 1997 crisis in terms of pos-
sible reversals in poverty reduction.
Thailand was the ‘classic’ case where the 1997 crisis led to immediate
reversals in poverty reduction trends. Prior to the crisis, Thailand had been
making remarkable progress in poverty reduction as can be noted from the
fact that, by 1996, the headcount index had dropped to 28.2 from a high of
47.0 in 1990. However, one year after the crisis, the index had jumped
significantly to 34.1 (in 1998) relative to 28.2 in 1996. However, economic
recovery by 2002 meant that the pace of poverty reduction had been
restored. The headcount index was 27.7 in 2002 and, it has, in fact, contin-
ued to drop since then.
The mean consumption pattern in Thailand as of 1990 has followed a
pattern similar to that of the headcount index for the country. The mean
consumption increased from a level of 102.88 in 1990 to a peak of 143.92
in 1996 only to drop precipitously to 121.73 in 1998 on account of the
financial and economic crisis. The previous peak of 1996 was regained only
in 2003 when the mean consumption level rose to 147.03.
Similarly, for Indonesia, the mean consumption had been steadily
increasing before the 1997 crisis (61.58 in 1990 to 86.62 in 1996). However,
this figure tumbled to 66.80 in 1999 compared with its value of 86.62 in
62 Analysis of currency crises
1999, and it took several years of slow recovery to come close to the 1999
level, when in 2003, the mean consumption climbed back to 85.88. Thus,
standard of living, as measured by mean consumption was significantly
adversely affected due to the crisis and it recovered only after almost six
years.
The situation in Indonesia was similar to that of Malaysia. Indonesia
had been making significant gains by way of poverty reduction as head-
count index had dropped from 71.1 percent in 1990 to 50.5 percent in 1996.
However, it jumped back up to 65.1 percent in 1999. It was only several
years later in 2003 that the poverty reduction level attained in 1996 was
regained.
In the case of the Philippines, the trend in poverty reduction witnessed in
terms of a secular trend in lower headcount index values continued unabated
through the 1997 crisis year and after. Similarly, for the Philippines, the mean
consumption continued to show a steady upward trend through the 1990s
and into the early 2000s. In some sense, this result for the Philippines may
appear at odds with the results for similar measures for say, Indonesia or
Malaysia. However, for one, this may be due to the fact that the Philippines
had been a ‘latecomer’ to the economic growth era dubbed ‘The Asian
Miracle’ and thus had ‘less to lose’. For another, IMF- and later, World
Bank-inspired safety net programs and redistributive policies of the
Philippines’ government, may have cushioned the blow even in the face of
worsening income inequality.
a relatively lower rate in the 1980s compared with the earlier decade. Thus,
we can see that financial crisis adversely affect the state of the social indi-
cators of health either by slowing down their progress or even causing an
absolute decline in them.
Similarly, broad indicators of human capital investments such as school
attendance, enrollment and literacy were also adversely affected during
crises. It may also be noted that, in Mexico, the proportion of each graduat-
ing high school class that went on to the next level declined during the 1980s
debt crisis. Also, primary school enrollment dropped too in the 1980s. There
was a similar drop (of almost 1 percent) in 1995 on the eve of the peso crisis.
The adverse impact of financial and macroeconomic crises on human
capital accumulation and health improvements are the channels through
which such crises have secular impact on poverty and potential earnings of
the affected populace, especially the poor who are disproportionately
affected. According to the World Development Report 2000–2001 World
Bank (2000), for Indonesia, the dropout rate in the lowest fourth of income
distributions rose from 1.3 percent in 1997 to 7.5 percent in 1998 among
children aged 7–12 and from 14.2 percent to 25.5 percent among ages
13–19. At the same time, the proportion of poor children not enrolled in
school more than doubled from 4.9 percent to 10.7 percent.
In conclusion, it needs to be emphasized that the social costs of the Asian
Crisis were substantial, and a disproportionate burden fell on the poor or
the ‘near poor’. In each of the ‘Affected Five’ countries, the 1997–98 crisis
led to higher incidence of poverty, and the living standards in general were
adversely affected in these countries. Also, by and large, the income inequi-
ties were often exacerbated on account of the crisis.
The above analysis, in sections 4.1–4.3, clearly implies the kind of public poli-
cies that are needed to ameliorate the situation precipitated by financial crises.
There is an obvious need to provide a better social security net that should be
‘targeted’ to the support groups most affected by the crisis, robust and put in
place well in advance of the crisis. Policy-makers need to take concrete steps
to protect pro-poor public spending in the wake of a financial crisis.
Finally, in an overarching sense, policy-makers should strive to balance
the purely financial aspects of the policy response to a financial crisis
against a meaningful concern for the societal costs of such measures. Thus,
somewhat akin to the now commonplace ‘environmental impact’ study of
any land development or economic growth project, there should be a social
cost impact study of the feasible financial policies. The final choice should
be based on the optimal policy net of its social costs.
Asia before and after the financial crisis of 1997–98 65
5 CONCLUDING REMARKS
Since financial crises can be costly both in economic, as well as, societal
terms, it is only natural to inquire whether such crises are predictable.
Besides providing an overview of the various theories that motivate the
specification of possible early warning systems, this chapter reviewed the
performance of logit/probit as well as more recent Markov-switching
models of currency crisis prediction. In this respect, we would like to con-
clude that while econometric predictive models can be very useful in
identifying various indicators of ‘vulnerability’, such exercises are not a
cure-all.
While formal econometric predictive models of currency crises are very
useful tools, due to limitations related to convergence requirements and
other technical matters, they can be too structured and thus restrict the
scope of the discussion necessary to get a broad sense of the possible deter-
minants of the vulnerabilities of economies to a currency crisis. In this
chapter, we also examined the broad determinants of vulnerability or sus-
ceptibility to crisis of an economy. This enables us to think about the mech-
anisms that may be needed to monitor the economy as well as institute
policies to reduce its susceptibility to a financial crisis.
Finally, it is also very important to explore the aftermath of a financial
crisis. Since the after-effects of such crises are societal and not only eco-
nomic, this chapter focuses on the income distributional consequences of
the Asian Financial Crisis of 1997–98 as well as its impact on the poverty
alleviation trends in the ‘Affected Five’ countries. Amongst the suggested
policy implications is the need to put in place an early warning system and,
at the same time, institute structural reforms to reduce the chances of recur-
rence of financial crises or soften their impact.13 To deal with the societal
aftermath of a crisis, we recommend robust safety nets targeted towards
those in the economy that are most likely to be adversely impacted by a
financial crisis.
NOTES
1. This discussion is based, in a significant fashion, on Shabbir’s earlier joint work reported
in Mariano et al. (2002).
2. See Berg and Pattillo (1999) for a skeptical viewpoint.
3. This discussion is drawn from Shabbir’s earlier joint work reported in Mariano et al.
(2003).
4. Also see, Chauvet and Dong (2004).
5. The significance of these indicators can be motivated analytically, however, in this
chapter, we do not engage in such an exercise.
6. The discussion in this section has drawn on the analysis presented in Warr (2002).
66 Analysis of currency crises
7. For instance, Bhagwati (1998, p. 12) notes ‘[T]he only explanation that accounts for the
massive net capital outflows is panic and herd behaviour: whether of domestic or foreign
nationals’ and Radelet and Sachs (1998, p. 43) infer that the ‘crisis was triggered by dra-
matic swings in creditors’ expectations about the behavior of other creditors, thereby cre-
ating a self-fulfilling – although possibly individually rational – financial panic’. On the
other hand, as Dornbusch (1997, p. 21) notes, ‘vulnerability means that if something
goes wrong, then suddenly a lot goes wrong’. The ‘something’ that causes things to go
wrong can be considered as a trigger, whereas the possibility of ‘suddenly a lot going
wrong’ is conditional on existence of ‘vulnerability’.
8. The list of indicators we have examined is certainly not an exhaustive one. Warr (2002),
in a similar analysis of pre-1997 crisis determinants of vulnerability for Thailand,
Indonesia and Korea, concludes that in these countries there had been a significant
increase in fragility of the banking sector as measured by exposure to interest rate risk
and deteriorating quality of loans (in the absence of data on non-performing loans,
quality was indirectly proxied by an increasing ratio of total loans outstanding for the
banking sector to GDP) as well as currency depreciation risk (measured by the ratio of
foreign liabilities to total loans). Based on evidence provided by indicators such as
‘reserves’/ ‘Volatile’ Capital Inflows, ‘CA/FDI’ and significant real exchange rate appre-
ciation (as proxy of erosion in foreign competitiveness), Warr (2002) also demonstrates
that, in general, these countries had become vulnerable to a currency crisis much before
1997. Ghosh and Ghosh (2003) come to a similar conclusion for ‘deep’ currency crises,
however, see Berg and Pattillo (1999) for a somewhat skeptical viewpoint favoring con-
tagion as the primary explanation.
9. See Barro (2001) for an early attempt at examining the pre- versus post-crisis situa-
tion in the same countries. Also, see Adams and Shabbir, Chapter 6 in this volume, for a
more recent exploration of some analytical aspects of the pre- versus post-crisis com-
parisons.
10. Incidentally, Klein et al., Chapter 4 in the present volume, analyzes the macroeconomic
consequences of the Malaysian capital controls policy more formally by means of a
macroeconometric model and conclude that in the Malaysian case, the capital controls
policy had, on average, beneficial effects in terms of post-crisis stabilization.
11. Interestingly, Warr (2002) maintains that the real exchange rates were overvalued for
Indonesia, Thailand and Korea for reasons independent of China’s exchange rate policy.
12. Some exceptions are Hyun and Lim (2003); Baldacci et al. (2002); Birdsall and Haggard
(2000); Lee (1998) and Shabbir (1998).
13. The authors have discussed several reforms in the Introduction to this volume; add-
itional details about relevant reforms may be noted in Klein (2004).
REFERENCES
Abiad, A.G. (2002), ‘Early Warning Systems for Currency Crises: A Markov
Switching Approach with Applications to Southeast Asia’, PhD dissertation,
Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia.
Alvarez-Plata, Patricia and Mechthild Schrooten (2003), ‘The Argentinean
Currency Crisis: A Markov-Switching Model Estimation’, Discussion Paper,
DIW Berlin.
Baldacci, Emanuele, Luiz de Mello and G. Inchauste (2002), ‘Financial Crises,
Poverty, and Income Distribution’, IMF Working Paper 02/4.
Barro, Robert J. (2001), ‘Economic Growth before and after the Financial Crisis’,
Working Paper 8330, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Berg, A. and C. Pattillo (1999), ‘Predicting Currency Crises: The Indicators Approach
and an Alternative’, Journal of International Money and Finance, 18, 561–86.
Asia before and after the financial crisis of 1997–98 67
Bhagwati, Jagdish (1998), ‘Asian Financial Crisis Debate: Why? How Severe?’,
Paper presented at Managing the Asian Financial Crisis: Lessons and
Challenges Conference, Asian Strategic Leadership Institute and Rating Agency,
Kuala Lumpur, 2–3 November.
Birdsall, Nancy and S. Haggard (2000), After the Crisis: The Social Contract and
the Middle Class in East Asia, Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.
Brunetti, C., R.S. Mariano, C. Scotti and A.H.H. Tan (2003), ‘Markov Switching
GARCH Models of Currency Crises in Southeast Asia’, Working Paper 03-008,
Philadelphia: Penn Institute of Economic Research, University of Pennsylvania.
http://pier.econ.upenn.edu/Archive/03-008.pdf.
Chauvet, M. and F. Dong (2004), ‘Leading Indicators of Country Risk and
Currency Crises: The Asian Experience’, Economic Review, Federal Reserve
Bank of Atlanta,Q1, 25–37.
Demirgüç-Kunt, A. and E. Detragiache (1998), ‘The Determinants of Banking
Crises in Developing and Developed Countries’, IMF Staff Papers, 45 (1), 81–109.
Dornbusch, R. (1997), ‘A Thai–Mexico Primer: Lessons for Outmaneuvering a
Financial Meltdown’, The International Economy, September/October.
Eichengreen, B. and A. Rose (1998), ‘Staying Afloat When the Wind Shifts:
External Factors and Emerging-market Banking Crises’, NBER Working Paper
No. 6370, Cambridge, MA.
Ghosh, S.R. and A.R. Ghosh (2003), ‘Structural Vulnerabilities and Currency
Crises’, IMF Staff Papers, 50 (3).
Hamilton, James B. (1994), Time Series Analysis, Princeton, NJ. Princeton
University Press.
Hyan, Jin K. and B. Lim (2003), ‘Financial Crises and Income Distribution in
Korea’, Working Paper, Korea Development Institute.
Inada, Yoshihisa, Lawrence R. Klein and J. Makino (2000), ‘A Retrospective View
of the Asian Financial Crisis: Special Reference to Exchange Rate Policy’, in L.
Klein and S. Ichimura (eds), Econometric Modeling of China, Singapore: World
Scientific.
Kaminsky, G. and C. Reinhart (1998), ‘Financial Crises in Asia and Latin America:
Then and Now’, American Economic Review, 88, 444–8.
Kaminsky, G. and C. Reinhart (1999), ‘The Twin Crises: The Causes of Banking
and Balance of Payments Problems’, American Economic Review, 89, 473–500.
Kaminsky, G., S. Lizondo and C. Reinhart (1998), ‘Leading Indicators of Currency
Crises’, IMF Staff Papers, 45 (1), 1–48.
Klein, Lawrence R. (2004), ‘Financial Crises in Asia and Development Issues’,
mimeo, Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia.
Krugman, Paul (1979), ‘A Model of Balance of Payments Crises’, Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking, 11, 311–25.
Krugman, Paul (1994), ‘The Myth of Asia’s Miracle’ , Foreign Affairs, November/
December.
Kumar, M., U. Moorthy and W. Perraudin (2003), ‘Predicting Emerging Market
Currency Crashes’, Journal of Empirical Finance, 10, 427–54.
Lau, Lawrence J. (1995), ‘LINK meeting presentation’, Pretoria, South Africa.
Lee, Eddy (1998), The Asian Financial Crisis: The Challenge for Social Policy,
Geneva: International Labour Office.
Mariano, R.S., A.G. Abiad, S. Özmucur, T. Shabbir and A.H.H. Tan (2003),
‘Markov Chains in Predictive Models of Currency Crises – With Applications to
Southeast Asia’, Taiwan Economic Review, 31 (4), December.
68 Analysis of currency crises
Mariano, R.S., B.N. Gultekin, S. Özmucur, T. Shabbir and C.E. Alper (2002),
‘Predictive Models of Economic Financial Crises (Final Report)’, Report sub-
mitted to the Economic Research Forum (ERF) for the Arab countries, Iran and
Turkey for ERF Research Project ERF99-US-4004, mimeo, Department of
Economics, University of Pennsylvania, December.
Mariano, R.S., B.N. Gultekin, S. Özmucur, T. Shabbir and C.E. Alper (2004),
‘Prediction of Currency Crises: Case of Turkey’, Review of Middle East
Economics and Finance, 2 (2).
Martinez-Peria, M.S. (1999), ‘A Regime Switching Approach to Studying
Speculative Attacks: A Focus on European Monetary System Crises’, World
Bank Development Research Group Working Paper 2132, June.
Masson, P. (1998), ‘Contagion: Monsoonal Effects, Spillovers and Jumps between
Multiple Equilibria’, IMF Working Paper 98/142.
Obstfeld, M. (1994), ‘The Logic of Currency Crises’, Cahiers Economiques et
Monetaires, 43, 189–213.
Pérez, J. (2005), ‘Empirical Identification of Currency Crises: Differences and
Similarities between Indicators’, Applied Financial Economics Letters, 1, 41–6.
Radelet, S. and J. Sachs (1998), ‘The East Asian Financial Crisis: Diagnosis,
Remedies, Prospects’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 1–89.
Shabbir, T. (1998), ‘The Social Costs of the Asian Financial Crisis’, mimeo,
Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia.
Warr, Peter (2002), ‘Crisis Vulnerability’, Asian-Pacific Economic Literature, 16 (1),
36–47, May.
World Bank (2000), World Development Report (2000/2001), Attacking Poverty,
New York: Oxford University Press.
2. Indicators and analysis of
vulnerability to currency crisis:
Thailand*
Pranee Tinakorn
1 INTRODUCTION
Thailand was the first of the Asian developing countries to experience the
financial crisis in 1997. The crisis started with a series of currency attacks
during late 1996 and mid-1997, which eventually led to the collapse of
Thailand’s fixed exchange rate system on 2 July 1997. The consequent
severe fall of around 40–108 percent in the baht value (from June 1997
average of 25.75 baht/$ to January 1998 average of 53.71 baht/$ before hov-
ering around 36–45 baht/$ later) led to a tremendous increase in the liabil-
ity side of the balance sheet for a significant number of enterprises that had
borrowed heavily from international markets. Many financial institutions
were faced with both liquidity and insolvency problems. The situation was
aggravated by the contagion effect of currency depreciation that hit other
Asian countries and had a further feedback effect on the Thai economy. In
addition, since the Bank of Thailand (BOT) had used up almost all of the
international reserves through the swap operation to defend the baht value
in vain, resulting in a net reserve of only about 1 billion dollars in July 1997
(see Figure 2.1),1 the country had to turn to the International Monetary
Fund (IMF) for a stand-by credit of 17.2 billion dollars.
The IMF package required the country to cut fiscal expenditure and raise
interest rates mainly to restore international confidence. This in effect dried
up whatever little domestic liquidity there was and the economy inevitably
headed into a deep recession. Thailand’s real GDP in 1998 contracted
by –10.4 percent and the unemployment rate increased more than three
times the rate of 1997.
In fact, even without the IMF austerity package, Thailand had been
heading for an economic downturn anyway as predicted by the composite
leading indicator. Tinakorn (1998) constructs a composite leading economic
indicator for Thailand and finds that the composite leading indicator had
69
70 Analysis of currency crises
Jan-97 Dec-97
45 000.00
40 000.00
35 000.00
30 000.00
(million bank)
25 000.00
20 000.00
15 000.00
0.00
95 l-9
5 96 l-9
6 97 l-9
7 98 l-9
8 99 l-9
9 00 l-0
0 01
n- n- n- n- n- n- n-
Ja Ju Ja Ju Ja Ju Ja Ju Ja Ju Ja Ju Ja
been following a downward trend since early 1996, with a leading time of six
months on average. Although Thailand needed the IMF stand-by credit
badly, the Thai authorities might have negotiated for a less contractionary
package if they had had prior knowledge about the leading indicator of the
economy and where it was heading. Similarly, the IMF might have yielded
to a less contractionary package if they had known that the economic down-
turn in Thailand would have occurred anyway and such downturn would
have helped correct the current account deficits without a strong contrac-
tionary package initially imposed by the IMF.
Although the use of leading indicators as warning signals is widespread
in most developed countries, especially those in the Organisation for
Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), the situation is quite
different for Thailand where many leading indicators were simply not
available and cannot be incorporated into the composite index. It is sug-
gested that the concerned authorities should spend more efforts to gather
the required data and try to improve the performance of the present com-
posite leading indicator so that it can serve as a more reliable warning
signal in the future. In addition to improving and monitoring leading eco-
nomic indicators for the real sector activities, Thailand also needs some
warning signals about the impending crisis in the financial sector and the
balance of payments as well. Kaminsky and Reinhart (1999) found that
Indicators and analysis of vulnerability to currency crisis: Thailand 71
problems in the banking sector typically precede a currency crisis and the
currency crisis deepens the banking crisis. For example, the 1996 abrupt
halt to Thailand’s export growth2 might not have caused such a severe
attack on the baht value if Thailand had not already had troubles in its
financial sector. The high ratios of non-performing loans (NPLs) among
the Thai banks and financial institutions due to the sluggishness in the
property sector must have created fear about their ability to repay debt.
This unsurprisingly leads baht traders and speculators to have growing
doubts about Thailand’s debt servicing capacity and creditworthiness.
While it would be desirable to study leading indicators for both the
banking crisis and currency crisis for Thailand, due to time and data con-
straints this study is focused on analyzing warning signals for the currency
crisis alone.
Since the banking crisis and currency crisis are found to have strong
links, many studies on currency crises also found that overstretched
financial variables provide warning signals to currency crisis. By including
several indicators from the financial sectors in the analysis of currency
crisis, it is hoped that they will provide warning signals not only to currency
crisis but also to financial problems. While most studies on currency crisis
use international cross-section data to look for signals of crisis, this study
will use the time-series data on a monthly basis. Both non-parametric and
parametric analysis will be explored. When a set of leading indicators are
confirmed from statistical analysis, they can be used to assess future vul-
nerability of the Thai economy.
Prior to the Asian currency crisis in the late 1990s, there were basically
two models explaining the onset of currency attacks. They are known as
the first- and second-generation models. The former model focused on the
balance-of-payments problems created mainly through seignorage; the
latter model viewed currency crisis not as a result of bad policy but of a
shift in expectation and the model was called ‘self-fulfilling’. However, the
causes of speculative attacks on Asian currencies, with the Thai currency
being hit first, appeared to be different from those explained in the first- and
second-generation models. Therefore, economists came up with a third-
generation model to explain currency crisis. Kaminsky et al. (1998) pro-
vided a summary of the main explanation of speculative attacks and
72 Analysis of currency crises
the East Asian Crisis, Jeanneau and Micu (2002) found evidence of several
fundamental factors as determinants of international capital flows. Dodd
(2001) pointed out that the ‘carry trade’, whereby foreign exchange for-
wards and swaps were used to hedge as well as speculate on the fixed
exchange rate regimes while profiting from the interest rate differential
between pegged currencies, was the major factor preceding and precipitat-
ing the Thai currency crisis in 1997. If authorities are not mindful of their
activities, derivatives can make the economy more susceptible to financial
crisis because they create conditions for entities to raise risk in relation to
capital and to dodge prudential regulatory safeguards even though they
play the useful role in hedging and risk management.
Krugman (2001) also conjectured about a future ‘fourth-generation’ crisis
model, which may not be a currency crisis model, but may be a more general
financial crisis model in which other asset prices play the major role.
Goldfajn and Valdés Esquivel and Larrain Kaminsky et al. Kruger et al.
(1997) (1998) (1998) (1998)
1. Sample 26 countries 30 countries 20 countries 19 countries
May 1984–May 1997 1975–96 1970–95 1977–93
2. Definition This paper follows 1. The accumulated three- The index of currency market Exchange rate pressure index is
of currency three alternative month real exchange rate turbulence is more than 3 1.5 times standard deviations
crisis procedures as follows: change is 15% or more or standard deviations above the above mean, where the index is
1. Devaluation is a 2. One-month change in mean, where the index is a defined as a weighted average
crisis when it is the real exchange rate is weighted average of monthly of percentage changes in the
larger than higher than 2.54 times percentage changes in nominal exchange rate and
• 1.96 times the country-specific standard exchange rate and monthly the negative of percentage
standard deviation deviation of real monthly percentage changes in gross changes in international
75
Goldfajn and Valdés Esquivel and Larrain Kaminsky et al. Kruger et al.
(1997) (1998) (1998) (1998)
3. The index of currency
market turbulence is
more than three standard
deviations above mean,
where the index is a
weighted average of
monthly percentage
changes in gross
international reserves
3. Methodology Logit model Probit model with Signals approach Probit model
76
random effect
4. Variables 1. Overvalued real 1. Change in reserve money 1. Real exchange rate. 1. M2/international reserves
found to be exchange rate a percentage of GDP 2. Banking crises 2. Ratio of bank claims on
significant 2. Current account 3. Exports private sector to GDP (a
indicators imbalance 4. Stock prices measure of lending boom)
3. Real exchange rate 5. M2/reserves 3. Real exchange rate
misalignment 6. Output misalignment
4. Foreign exchange reserves 7. Excess M1 balance
5. Terms of trade shock 8. International reserves
6. Poor growth performance 9. M2 multiplier
7. Regional contagion 10. Domestic credit/GDP
11. Real interest rate
12. Terms of trade
13. Real interest differential
Table 2.2 Summary of studies on currency crisis in Thailand
4. Variables found 1. Excessive domestic credit 1. High ratio of short-term 1. Export growth 1. Export growth
to be significant creation foreign debt to 2. Change in real 2. Ratio of M2 to
indicators 2. High ratio of M2 to international reserves exchange rate international
international 2. Large domestic and foreign 3. Terms of trade reserves
reserves interest rate differentials 4. Spread between 3. Percentage
3. Low ratio of international 3. Large current account deficit lending rate and change in
reserves to monthly imports 4. Reversal of portfolio deposit rate credits
4. Large domestic and foreign investment capital inflow (private sector)
interest rate differentials 4. Inflation rate
5. Real (effective) exchange
rate overvaluation
78 Analysis of currency crises
criticized the probit/logit and the signals approaches for possible misclassi-
fication error in the construction of crisis dummy variables. They pointed out
several issues regarding these techniques: the need for a priori dating of crisis
occurrence, the use of arbitrary thresholds and inadequate modeling of the
dynamics in the systems, for example. The Markov-switching model of
exchange rate fluctuations with time-varying transition probabilities was used
as a predictive model of currency crises in their study.
From the summary of previous studies presented in Tables 2.1 and 2.2,
we can see that researchers use either the multivariate logit/probit model or
Indicators and analysis of vulnerability to currency crisis: Thailand 81
the signals approach in analyzing crisis (except for the study by Mariano
et al.). The most commonly used approach seemed to be the estimation of
logit/probit models, and Kaminsky et al. (1998) are the first to use the signals
approach. For this research study, both methodologies are employed. The
sample period is restricted by the availability of monthly data needed for this
study, and covers the period January 1992 to December 2000.5
index in this study will be based on the movements in net reserves and
exchange rates.
An index of currency market turbulence (I) for Thailand was constructed
based on the formula:
I ⫽ ⌬e ⌬R e
e ⫺ R * r
(2.1)
With the above definition, the Thai economy fell within the episode of cur-
rency crisis during January 1997 up to February 1998. This gives us a total
of 14 monthly observations of crisis from our sample of 108 observations
during January 1992 and December 2000. However, for some indicators
their year-on-year changes are used as signals, which means the first 12
months of the sample are lost.
not all of them passed the statistical significance test. The choice of vari-
ables used in this study was dictated not only by economic reasoning but
also by data availability on a monthly basis in Thailand. The set of poten-
tial leading indicators with available monthly observations during our
sample period may be grouped as follows:
It should be pointed out that Thailand does not have monthly GDP data
and the quarterly GDP data go back only to 1993. Since several indica-
tors above should be measured as a ratio to GDP, we need to generate
monthly GDP data from the quarterly data. This is done by making use
of the quarterly relationship between GDP and other variables, which
are themselves available in monthly series. The estimated quarterly rela-
tionship between GDP and exports, indirect taxes, government expendi-
tures and electricity consumption is used to estimate monthly GDP from
the monthly data of these variables. The estimated monthly GDP is
adjusted so as to make the sum of the estimated monthly series equal to
the actual quarterly data. The estimated monthly GDP series are also
used to estimate the demand for money in order to calculate excess real
84 Analysis of currency crises
3.3 Methodology
There are two popular approaches in the analysis of leading indicators for
currency crisis. The parametric approach utilizes the qualitative depend-
ent variable regression models (probit, logit) to identify leading indica-
tors. The non-parametric approach uses the signals analysis proposed by
Kaminsky et al. (1998). This study applied both the signals analysis and
the probit estimates to identify the leading indicators of currency crisis for
Thailand.
The signals analysis starts with the ‘signaling horizon’ of 24 months as
used in Kaminsky et al. (1998) and also performs a test on a 12-month sig-
naling horizon to see if the results are sensitive to the choice of the horizon.
The threshold value for each indicator is scanned between the 10–25 per-
centiles6 of the indicator’s distribution and the ‘optimal’ threshold is the
one that minimizes the adjusted ‘noise-to-signal’ ratio where ‘noise’ and
‘signal’ can be defined in the following matrix.
BⲐ(B ⫹ D)
Adjusted noise᎐to᎐signal ratio ⫽
AⲐ(A ⫹ C)
4 EMPIRICAL RESULTS
Based on the signaling horizon of 24 months and the scan between the
10–25th percentiles, the optimal threshold for each indicator is found and
presented in Table 2.4 together with its adjusted noise-to-signal ratio. A
change of signaling horizon to 12 months is also performed to gauge the
sensitivity of our indicators and the information is presented in Table 2.5. It
can be seen that for most indicators, changing the signaling horizon does not
significantly affect their threshold levels and the adjusted noise-to-signal
Note: * No signals were found between the 10–25th percentiles with the 12-month horizon
for import growth.
ratios, with the exception of import growth M2 money multiplier, real GDP
growth and the ratio of fiscal balance to GDP.
Since the performance of these indicators are indicated by their adjusted
noise-to-signal ratio, Tables 2.6 and 2.7 rank these indicators from low to
high ratios. It can be noticed that the ratio of trade balance to GDP is not
present in these two tables because its effect is already included within the
ratio of current account to GDP. The same goes for the ratio of private short-
term external debt to international reserves, the effect of which is already
included in the ratio of total short-term external debt to international
Indicators and analysis of vulnerability to currency crisis: Thailand 87
Note: The indicators ‘Trade balance/GDP’ and ‘Private short-term external debt/
international reserves’ are excluded from this table as their effect is implicit in ‘Ratio of
current account/GDP’ and ‘Ratio of total short-term external debt/international reserves’
respectively.
reserves. In fact, during the period covered in this study the private short-
term external debt is very close to the total short-term external debt because
the public short-term external debt was insignificantly small in comparison
to that of the private sector. It would be redundant to have duplicate meas-
ures of the same effect.
Comparing the rank and the adjusted noise-to-signal ratio of the indi-
cators in Tables 2.6 and 2.7, we can see that there are a few indicators the
performance of which is rather sensitive to the choice of signaling horizon.
Based on an evaluation of the magnitude change in threshold levels and in
the noise-to-signal ratio, the following two indicators appear to be rather
sensitive to the choice of horizon: import growth and the growth of money
multiplier. For import growth, no signals were found for the 12-month sig-
naling horizon. For growth of the money multiplier, the threshold and the
adjusted noise-to-signal ratio changed from 8.5 and 1.18 for the 24-month
88 Analysis of currency crises
Note: The indicators ‘Trade balance/GDP’ and ‘Private short-term external debt/
international reserves’ are excluded from this table as their effect is implicit in ‘Ratio of
current account/GDP’ and ‘Ratio of total short-term external debt/international reserves’
respectively.
horizon to 9.6 and 0.68 for the 12-month horizon. The changes in thresh-
olds and noise-to-signal ratios of other variables are not so large as to cause
concern.
From the author’s judgment, the following indicators appear to be least
sensitive to the change of signaling horizon:
Figure 2.2 Movement of indicators with negative shocks (threshold from 12-month horizon)
Real GDP growth rate
20
15
10
5
0
–5
–10
–15
–20
Jan-93 Jan-94 Jan-95 Jan-96 Jan-97 Jan-98 Jan-99 Jan-00
92
10
–5
–10
–15
Jan-93 Jan-94 Jan-95 Jan-96 Jan-97 Jan-98 Jan-99 Jan-00
Real exchange rate misalignment (deviation from previous 60-month average)
100
80
60
40
93
20
–20
Jan-93 Jan-94 Jan-95 Jan-96 Jan-97 Jan-98 Jan-99 Jan-00
–20
–30
Jan-93 Jan-94
Jan-94 Jan-95
Jan-95 Jan-96
Jan-96 Jan-97
Jan-97 Jan-98
Jan-98 Jan-99
Jan-99 Jan-00
Jan-00
95
Inflation rate
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
–2
Jan-93 Jan-94 Jan-95 Jan-96 Jan-97 Jan-98 Jan-99 Jan-00
Figure 2.3 Movement of indicators with positive shocks (threshold from 12-month horizon)
Difference
Differencebetween
betweendomestic
domesticand
andforeign
foreigninterest
interestrate
rate(MLR/LIBOR
(MLR/LIBORin
inUS$)
US$)
12
12
10
10
88
66
44
22
00
Jan-93
Jan-93 Jan-94
Jan-94 Jan-95
Jan-95 Jan-96
Jan-96 Jan-97
Jan-97 Jan-98
Jan-98 Jan-99
Jan-99 Jan-00
Jan-00
96
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
–5
–10
–15
–20
Jan-93 Jan-94 Jan-95 Jan-96 Jan-97 Jan-98 Jan-99 Jan-00
present. But during the sample period, the range of the SET index was
between 1528.83 (October 1994) and 214.3 (August 1998) and the rate of
year-on-year decline went up to almost 60 percent for some months.
The terms of trade is the ratio of export price over import price. A
decline in this ratio means imports are relatively more expensive than
exports, which will have a negative impact on the trade and current
account, and ceteris paribus, the balance of payments. In a cross-country
study by Kaminsky and Reinhart (1999), it is found that crises are preceded,
on average, by a deterioration of the terms of trade with an annual decline
that is about 10 percent deeper than those observed in tranquil times before
a balance-of-payments crisis. For the case of Thailand, the threshold of the
annual decline in the terms of trade with the minimum adjusted noise-to-
signal ratio is –8.6 percent, found at the 10th percentile.
Exports account for more than 50 percent of GDP in Thailand.
Therefore its decline has grave implications for the real sector as well as the
position of the current account and the balance of payments. The thresh-
old with the minimum adjusted noise-to-signal ratio is the export growth at
–3.8 percent,7 found at the 20th percentile.
The current account includes the international exchange of both goods
and services and the current account deficit has a negative impact on the
foreign exchange earnings. This variable is measured as a ratio to GDP and
its threshold with minimum adjusted noise-to-signal ratio is found to be
–8.3 percent, at the 15th percentile meaning that current account deficit
that runs in excess of 8.3 percent of GDP is a warning for increased vul-
nerability of the economy.
Both the real GDP growth rate and the ratio of fiscal balance to GDP
are found to be rather sensitive to the choice of signaling horizon. Their
performance improves when the 12-month horizon is used. The threshold
for GDP growth rate is –1.0 percent, at the 25th percentile and that for the
ratio of fiscal balance to GDP is –3.4 percent, at the 19th percentile.
Although the deterioration in these two indicators increases the economy’s
vulnerability, it is also the case that these two indicators tend to deteriorate
after the onset of crisis if the currency crisis evolves into economic crisis.
The evolution of real exchange rate has a significant implication for the
country’s competitiveness. Kaminsky and Reinhart (1999) found that
during the year before the balance-of-payments and banking crises, the real
exchange rate shows evidence of being overvalued. This is also the case for
Thailand. In this study, the real exchange rate is measured in terms of baht
per US dollar adjusted by the ratio of US consumer price index over Thai
consumer price index. Therefore a decline in this variable means an appre-
ciation of the baht, which will have a negative impact on export earnings
and increase the vulnerability of the economy. The misalignment of the real
100 Analysis of currency crises
One way of combining the signals sent out by all the above 11 indicators is
simply by counting the number of individual indicators that have crossed
their threshold in a particular month as in equation (2.2):
n
It(1) ⫽ 兺Stj
j⫽1
(2.2)
However, It(1) does not take into account the fact that each variable has
different forecasting accuracy as depicted by its adjusted noise-to-signal
ratio. For example, the low noise-to-signal ratio of 0.1 of a variable Z con-
tains information that it has more forecasting accuracy than another vari-
able Y with a noise-to-signal ratio of 0.5. Therefore, the composite
indicator should give more weight to the signal sent out by Z than that by
Y. This leads us to a weighted composite indicator based on the adjusted
noise-to-signal ratio of each variable.
n
It(2) ⫽ 兺Stj · w1j
t⫽1
(2.3)
where X is the value of the composite index. It was found that, in general,
the increase in the composite indicator results in higher conditional prob-
ability of crisis. However, there were a few cases where the value of the com-
posite index (X) was high but crisis did not actually occur within 12 months
and vice versa. This can be seen in Figure 2.4 (a), which plots the condi-
tional probability of a crisis, given the value of the composite index. To
obtain a smoother increasing function of probability as the composite
index increases requires some grouping of the composite index. It appears
that a grouping with a range of six (Figure 2.4f) renders a smooth increas-
ing function of probability as the composite index increases. The result of
such grouping is presented in Table 2.8.
Based on the above conditional probability we may look at the value
of the composite index computed from those 11 indicators and predict
that the probability of a crisis in the next 12 months is about 0.61 if the
value exceeds 12. And if the value of the composite index exceeds 18, it is
most likely that a crisis is coming as the conditional probability is equal
to one.
3.01–4.00
6.01–7.00
9.01–10.00
12.01–13.00
15.01–16.00
18.01–19.00
21.01–22.00
24.01–25.00
0.00
0.00–2.00
4.01–6.00
8.01–10.00
12.01–14.00
>16.00
102
3.01–6.00
6.01–9.00
9.01–12.00
12.01–15.00
15.01–18.00
>18
0.00–4.00
4.01–8.00
8.01–12.00
12.01–16.00
>16
(e) Range of composite index = 5 (f) Range of composite index = 6
1.00 1.00
0.90 0.90
0.80 0.80
0.70 0.70
0.60 0.60
0.50 0.50
0.40 0.40
103
0.30 0.30
0.20 0.20
0.10 0.10
0.00 0.00
0.00–5.00
5.01–10.00
10.01–15.00
15.01–20.00
>20
0.00–6.00
6.01–12.00
12.01–18.00
>18
Figure 2.4 Plot of conditional probability of crisis given the value of the composite index
104 Analysis of currency crises
0.00–6.00 49 4 0.08
6.01–12.00 13 6 0.46
12.01–18.00 18 11 0.61
⬎18.00 4 4 1.00
*Quadratic probability score (QPS) ⫽0.266
T
1
Note: * QPS ⫽ T 兺2(Pt ⫺ Rt)2
t⫽1
QPS ranges from 0 to 2, with a score of 0 corresponding to perfect accuracy. See Kaminsky
(1999).
We can use both the signals analysis and the probit estimates to assess the
future vulnerability of Thailand to currency crisis. However, the data
requirements of these two methods are somewhat different. From the
signals approach, we may use the present available data to compute the
index of currency crisis and make use of the conditional probability in
Table 2.8 to assess the likelihood of a crisis within the next 12 months.
Forecasts by the probit estimation, on the other hand, can be made for only
three months ahead since the lags of explanatory variables vary from three
to 12 months. So for the probit estimate, we only check its out-of-sample
predictive performance, given the data for 2001.
Table 2.12 presents the out-of-sample forecast for the probability of
a crisis from probit models during 2001. It can be seen that both models
predicted very low probability of a currency crisis during 2001. There
appeared to be a rise in this probability during the months of July,
September and October but the probability dropped afterwards. Overall,
the probability predicted by probit models was low and there was no cur-
rency crisis in 2001. If we want to assess future vulnerability, then we must
first forecast the values of the indicators in probit models, this is at present
106 Analysis of currency crises
beyond the scope of this report. But we can do it with the signals
approach, given that the signals approach helps predict a crisis within the
next 12 months (from ex post analysis). We can use the available data in
December 2001 to say something about the prospect of a crisis up to
December 2002.
Table 2.13 presents the composite index (I(2)) of 11 variables found to
be leading indicators of a currency crisis for Thailand in this study. The
Indicators and analysis of vulnerability to currency crisis: Thailand 107
composite index for 2001 lies between 1.82 and 7.64 with probability of a
crisis between 0.08 and 0.46. Using 0.5 as a cut-off point, the composite
index implies that a currency crisis is not likely in the next 12 months.
Nevertheless, we should be watchful of these indicators because the terms
of trade have had a negative growth in the past 12 months and export
growth in dollar value has also continuously registered negative growth
below its threshold value of –3.8 percent since July 2001. The fiscal balance
108 Analysis of currency crises
has also been mostly in deficit due to the stimulative fiscal policy. As a con-
sequence, the ratio of fiscal balance to GDP was running below its thresh-
old value in the last four months of 2001. There also remain some
structural problems in the financial and real sectors, and the high and
rapidly rising public debt was a significant cause for concern.
from both the signals analysis and probit estimates conducted in this study
appear quite satisfactory on both theoretical and statistical grounds.
The 1997 crisis in Thailand and its phenomenal spread has spawned a
large body of literature on its analysis and its lessons. This chapter is just a
humble attempt to use the available data in Thailand to study their leading
or signaling nature. The study finds many statistically significant indicators.
It also finds that many important indicators are lacking due to inadequate
collection and dissemination. For example, the data on non-performing
loans are not available before June 1998 and the series are simply not long
enough to establish a reliable statistical pattern. At present, the data col-
lection and dissemination by public authorities have improved a great deal
since the 1997 crisis. Although Thailand joined the IMF Special Data
Dissemination Standard (SDDS) since 1996, it was not until May 2000 that
it could meet the SDDS specifications for coverage, periodicity, timeliness
and advance release calendars. Also the present effort by the National
Economic and Social Development Board to track the short-term move-
ment of the economy by the Current Quarter Model (CQM) should
provide a better opportunity to observe some of the early warning signals.
In hindsight, the fact that there were signals for and high probability of
a currency crisis for the 1997 event indicated that there were some funda-
mental problems with the Thai economy that led speculators to attack the
baht. The fact that the concerned authorities were not mindful of the early
warning signs and decided to defend the baht almost at all costs makes
ordinary citizens shudder. Now with faster reporting of data, greater trans-
parency and improved information and indicators to monitor the economic
conditions, we can hope that monetary authorities will quickly realize an
imminent crisis and put out remedial measures before things get out of
hand.
NOTES
* This chapter is a result of the East Asian Development Network (EADN) research project
in 2002 to evaluate vulnerabilities to economic crises of East Asian countries and to learn
from the 1997–98 economic crisis that severely affected most economies in the region.
Since the project was finished in 2002, the data in this chapter are only up to December
2001. The author thanks Professor Lawrence R. Klein and Professor Tayyeb Shabbir,
both of the University of Pennsylvania, and Dr Chalongphob Sussangkarn of Thailand
Development Research Institute for their valuable comments and Miss Sanpichit
Songpaisan for her research assistance.
1. Ministry of Finance (1998). In the document, it was pointed out that Thailand’s net inter-
national reserves decreased from 33.8 billion dollars in December 1996 to around 1 billion
dollars in July 1997. Such a huge loss was concealed by the swap operation and did not
show up in the gross reserves as can be seen in the plots of Thailand’s gross and net inter-
national reserves in Figure 2.1.
Indicators and analysis of vulnerability to currency crisis: Thailand 113
2. The growth of exports (in millions of US$) during 1994–95 was 21.7 percent and 24.9
percent, respectively. It went down to –1.4 percent in 1996 before picking up to 4.3 percent
in 1997.
3. For instance in Argentina, Chile, Malaysia and Mexico, etc. See Kaminsky and Reinhart
(1999).
4. The year 1997 was chosen just for being a convenient cut-off point. Otherwise, there is a
significant amount of related literature to be reviewed. Interested readers can see a com-
prehensive review of earlier literature in Kaminsky et al. (1998).
5. However, for GDP, there are only quarterly data starting from the first quarter of 1993
and the monthly GDP data have to be estimated from a quarterly relationship of GDP
and other variables.
6. The 10–25th percentile range may appear arbitrary but it may be looked upon as the prob-
ability of rejecting the null hypothesis when it is true, or Type I error. We may regard the
normal or tranquil period as our null hypothesis and take the export growth as our indi-
cator, for example. If we find that 10 percent of the observations post an export growth
below 1 percent, we then regard any export growth below 1 percent as a signal. Such
reading of the indicator may be wrong if the null hypothesis (tranquility) is true.
Therefore, setting the maximum 25th percentile as the upper limit implies that we are
willing to accept one-fourth probability of calling a crisis when it is not true. It is found
in this study that for some indicators the percentile at which the adjusted noise-to-signal
ratio is minimum is far below the 25th percentile. See more details on methodology in
Kaminsky and Reinhart (1999).
7. It is notable that this number is quite different from the threshold of 5.6 found in
Poonpatpibul and Ittisupornrat (2001), who used the same signals approach. Such a
difference cannot be attributed to their using a 24-month horizon because in this study
the threshold from the 24-month horizon for export growth is –6.9.
8. The other two composite indicators considered by Kaminsky (1999) are the following
cases: a) Extreme signals are given more weight than mild signals. b) A time horizon of
eight months is taken into account when adding up signals because not all indicators issue
signals jointly in the same month. See more details in Kaminsky (1999).
9. The criterion for dummy variables in probit estimates is that there must be observations
for which the left-hand-side variable takes both values 0 and 1 in both groups of the
observations for the right-hand-side dummy variable. See Greene (1995, p. 416).
REFERENCES
Goldfajn, Ilan and Rodrigo O. Valdés (1997), ‘Are Currency Crises Predictable?’,
IMF Working Paper WP/97/159, December.
Greene, W.H. (1995), LIMDEP Version 7.0 User’s Manual, Econometric Software,
Inc. New York.
Jeanneau, S. and M. Micu (2002), ‘International Bank Lending to Emerging
Market Countries: Explaining the 1990s Roller Coaster’, BIS Quarterly Review,
March, 52–64.
Kaminsky, G.L. (1999), ‘Currency and Banking Crises: The Early Warnings of
Distress’, IMF Working Paper WP/99/178, December.
Kaminsky, G.L. and C.M. Reinhart (1999), ‘The Twin Crises: The Causes of
Banking and Balance-of-payments Problems’, American Economic Review,
89 (3), June.
Kaminsky, G.L. and C.M. Reinhart (2000), ‘On Crises, Contagion, and Confusion’,
Journal of International Economics, 51, 145–68.
Kaminsky, G.L., S. Lizondo and C.M. Reinhart (1998), ‘Leading Indicators of
Currency Crisis’, IMF Staff Papers, 45 (1), March, 1–48.
Kruger, M., P.N. Osakwe and J. Page (1998), ‘Fundamentals, Contagion and
Currency Crises: An Empirical Analysis’, Bank of Canada Working Paper
WP/97/159, December.
Krugman, P. (1979), ‘A Model of Balance of Payments Crisis’, Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking, 11, August, 311–25.
Krugman, P. (2001), ‘Crises: The Next Generation?’, Paper prepared for the Razin
Conference, Tel Aviv University, March.
Mariano, R.S., A.G. Abiad, B. Gultekin, T. Shabbir and A.H.H. Tan (2002),
‘Markov Chains in Predictive Models of Currency Crises – With Applications to
Southeast Asia’, PIER Working Paper No. 02-013, University of Pennsylvania.
Ministry of Finance (1998), ‘Directions of Monetary and Fiscal Measures to Solve
Economic Problems’, a mimeograph, July (in Thai).
Obstfeld, M. (1996), ‘Model of Currency Crises with Self-fulfilling Features’,
European Economic Review, 40 (3–5), April, 1037–47.
Poonpatpibul, Chaipat and Anotai Ittisupornrat (2001), ‘Early Warning System’,
BOT Working Paper WP/05/2001, June (in Thai).
Tinakorn, Pranee (1998), ‘Analysis of Leading Economic Indicators for Thailand’,
a TDRI research report in the project Short-Term Economic Model and
Forecast, financed by the National Economic and Social Development Board,
September (in Thai).
Indicators and analysis of vulnerability to currency crisis: Thailand 115
APPENDIX 2A
Table 2A.1 Index of currency market turbulence
% % I I⫹ I ⬎I I⫹ I ⬎I
change change 2sd ⫹2sd 1.5sd ⫹1.5sd
% % I I⫹ I ⬎I I⫹ I ⬎I
change change 2sd ⫹2sd 1.5sd ⫹1.5sd
There has been considerable water under the bridge since early 1998 when
then US Treasury Secretary Rubin faced the problem of financial instabil-
ity made so evident by the Asian Crisis. In reality, these efforts long pre-
date Rubin’s speech. Some would trace them to the Mexican Crisis of
1994–95, which then IMF Managing Director Michel Camdessus referred
to as ‘the first financial crisis of the 21st century’ on the grounds that
financial structure and markets had played such a prominent role in its
development.2 Other observers would place the inauguration of this effort
even earlier, perhaps at the time of the 1982 Mexican Crisis, out of which
developed the Brady Plan, or the 1974 Herstatt Crisis that provided the
impetus for the Basel Capital Accord, or even the global financial crisis of
the 1930s that prompted the creation of the Bretton Woods Institutions.
So what makes this an appropriate time for stock taking? As I write, in
the spring of 2005, all the ingredients are in place for a classic emerging
market crisis.3 We have come to the end of a long period when the Federal
Reserve has kept interest rates low.4 Partly in response to the FED’s earlier
policies, spreads on emerging market debt have fallen to very low levels.
Now US policy rates are rising, and rising US rates are a traditional trigger
for financial problems in emerging markets. Market participants see this
coming: we have already seen a significant widening of spreads in the first
half of 2005. And there are growing worries about a disorderly correction
of the US current account deficit. On top of this, oil prices are rising, cre-
ating additional difficulties for emerging markets that are not energy
exporters. The OECD estimates that China and India are two to three times
more intensive in the use of energy than the developed countries and that
an increase of $10 in the cost of a barrel of oil shaves 0.8 percent off China’s
rate of GDP growth.5
Global economic growth of course is entirely dependent on two engines:
the United States and China. This makes the specter of a hard landing in
China as policy-makers attempt to cool down an overheated economy, and
of a dollar crash in the United States if the problem of twin deficits finally
comes home to roost, particularly alarming for emerging markets. The US
is the single most important market for exports of consumer goods by
121
122 Cures and reforms
emerging markets, while China is far and away the most rapidly growing
market for both consumer and producer goods. If either engine begins to
sputter, the result could be very serious problems for emerging markets that
are heavily dependent on exports for both growth and debt sustainability.
And if growth slows simultaneously in both countries, the consequences
could be serious indeed.
Thus, it is striking that this potentially fatal cocktail of rising US inter-
est rates, higher oil prices and growing uncertainty about Chinese policy
has not yet produced serious difficulties. One response to this observation
is ‘just be patient’. Give it more time, and the financial ambulance chasers
among us will eventually acquire a new set of clients. But another response
is that considerable progress has in fact been made in strengthening the
international financial architecture. Reforms of international financial
institutions and markets have strengthened the global financial system,
while significant reforms in emerging market economies themselves have
made these countries more resilient to mounting strains.
There is at least a kernel of truth in this point of view. Specifically,
I would point to ten important reforms that have helped to make the world
a safer financial place. However, these reforms have come at a cost. Each of
them has had unintended consequences that are not entirely salutary from
the point of view of either emerging markets or the international system.
First, emerging markets have grown more cautious since 1994, and espe-
cially since 1997, about cross-border bank borrowing as a way of accessing
external finance. Less reliance on short-term finance, and less reliance on
cross-border bank finance in particular, has reduced an important source
of financial vulnerability. Foreign banks, for their part, have grown more
cautious about cross-border lending, having been reminded of the risks of
international financial intermediation by earlier crises.6 New net flows
through money markets and new bond flotations have also fallen, albeit by
less than cross-border bank lending and less in Asia than Latin America.7
Be that as it may, the point is that emerging markets have taken valuable
steps to lengthen the maturity structure of their debts.8
Second, emerging markets have become more prudent about running
current account deficits. The Institute of International Finance, at latest
report, forecasts that emerging Asia will run a current account surplus of
$113 billion in 2005, down only slightly from its surplus of $120 billion in
2004.9 Latin America as a whole is running a balanced current account. Of
the principal Latin countries, only Ecuador has a noticeable deficit. But
elsewhere the notorious problem of current account reversals – what
happens when funding for the flow deficit suddenly dries up – has been very
considerably ameliorated. The one place where this is not the case is emerg-
ing Europe – that is, in countries like Hungary, Romania and Turkey.10
The next financial crisis 123
hence the credibility of its commitments. Clearly, while there has been
progress in the direction of greater transparency and openness, there is still
an accountability problem.
This brings me to the agenda for the future. What key reforms remain
incomplete? What are the most important tasks going forward? How can
we continue to strengthen the international financial system while mini-
mizing corollary damage to emerging markets?
The first item on my list, while the least exciting, is at the same time the
most important. It is more business as usual. I mean redoubling efforts to
strengthen banking systems, enhance shareholder rights, improve the
effectiveness of corporate governance and heighten the transparency and
efficiency of financial markets. This effort to improve the structure, regula-
tion and efficiency of financial markets, first and foremost at the national
level, has been the touchstone of recent efforts to strengthen the interna-
tional financial architecture. There has been progress, but much remains to
be done. While this observation is commonplace, it is no less important for
that fact.
The second item is to create a credit culture in emerging markets. When
cheap credit becomes available, it flows in large amounts into the property
market and other speculative investments, with too little attention to the
decline in credit quality that occurs with the pursuit of higher risk projects.
More investment means faster growth, at least temporarily, which attracts
more foreign investors impressed by the improvement in economic perfor-
mance. The result is self-reinforcing, procyclical and dangerously unstable
dynamics.
The solution to this problem is to price credit risk more efficiently. Doing
so is the job of bond markets.21 The implication is that emerging markets
need better bond markets. Developing them will have a number of corol-
lary benefits, including reducing dependence on bank finance and limiting
currency and maturity mismatches. While I have doubts about the efficacy
of some fashionable initiatives in this area – the Asian Bond Fund, for
example – I nonetheless regard the objective, domestic bond market devel-
opment, as a high priority.22
The third priority item should be to move to still more flexible exchange
rates as a way of discouraging procyclical capital flows and permitting the
authorities to provide better tailoring of credit conditions to meet local
needs. China is the current poster boy for this argument, but it is only the
latest example of a country that would benefit from a more flexible rate.23
Emerging markets as a class would benefit from greater exchange rate
flexibility and less fear of floating. Getting there will require putting in place
the prerequisites for flexible inflation targeting – an independent central
bank, sound fiscal policies and market-determined interest rates – in
The next financial crisis 127
countries where they do not already exist. It will require moving away from
outdated commitments to export-led growth in countries like Taiwan and
South Korea where the export sector is no longer the exclusive locus of
learning effects and productivity spillovers, and where educating and retain-
ing knowledge workers will require a better balance of investment between
traded and non-traded goods sectors.24 In Latin America, it will require
measures to reduce liability dollarization and to help countries acquire the
capacity to borrow abroad in local currency.
This brings me to the fourth priority, namely measures to address the
inability of emerging markets to borrow abroad in their own currencies.
The evidence is overwhelming that institutional and policy reform at the
national level, by themselves, will not solve this problem anytime soon.25
Stronger policies and institutions help to solve many problems, to be sure,
but not obviously this one. Chile has admirably strong policies and institu-
tions, but it still cannot borrow abroad in its own currency. This suggests
that the problem resides at least in part in the structure of international
financial markets. International investors reap limited diversification
benefits from adding a variety of currencies to their portfolios while incur-
ring significant transactions costs from managing positions in relatively
small, illiquid markets. The smaller a country, the greater the difficulty it
has in getting its currency added to the global portfolio.26
Part of the solution is for the World Bank and regional development
banks to borrow and lend in these currencies. Their AAA credit rating
permits them to do so with relative ease. The issuance of World Bank debt
denominated in pesos will supply the high-quality benchmark asset that
investors need in order to price riskier credits. It will increase the installed
base of local currency denominated securities. It will enhance market liq-
uidity. In turn, this will make positions in assets denominated in these cur-
rencies more attractive to international investors. From this point of view,
the decision of the Asian Development Bank to issue in Chinese yuan, Thai
baht and Indian rupees is an important step. So was the decision of the
Inter-American Development Bank to include a local currency conversion
clause in a $300 million loan to Mexico in May of 2005. These are valuable
precedents; the World Bank and other regional development banks need to
respond in kind.
The fifth and final priority should be to address governance problems at
the Bretton Woods Institutions. Admittedly, it is easier to advocate reform
of IMF governance than to specify exactly what steps should be taken.
(If nothing else, this is a salutary reminder to high-income countries urging
developing economies to strengthen corporate governance that moving
from statements of high policy to implementation is easier said than
done.) Clearly, recommendations for the reform of IMF governance should
128 Cures and reforms
100 000 Special Drawing Rights, on which basis both its contribution and
ability to draw resources are calibrated, while quotas are calculated on the
basis of a complicated set of formulas that in practice place substantial
weight on country size and current account volatility. Quotas have been
increased in the course of 11 reviews in order to reflect better the growth of
countries and their balances of payments, but without also increasing basic
votes. Consequently, the share of basic votes has fallen from 11 percent in
1945 and 14 percent in 1955, by which time additional members had been
admitted, to only 2 percent today. Increasing the share of basic votes would
go some way toward restoring the principle of universality and enhance the
representation of the poor countries that are frequently the subject of IMF
programs. In addition, using GDP at purchasing power parity rather than
GDP at market exchange rate prices in quota calculations would enhance
the voice of rapidly growing countries like those of Asia that are chroni-
cally under-represented in the Fund.
I would also favor appointing a single executive director for the
European Union. Rationalizing Europe’s board representation in this way
will free up chairs on the Executive Board for under-represented countries.
The majority of EU members have a single currency. Hence, there is no
more possibility of balance-of-payments problems among them than there
is scope for balance-of-payments problems between US states. If a financial
crisis develops in an EU member state, the bailout, for better or worse, will
be extended by its partners in the European Union and not by the IMF. In
addition, the Fund should rely more heavily on the International Monetary
and Financial Committee for defining the objectives and strategies of the
institution (including meetings of IMFC heads of state, which can substi-
tute for G7/8 summits). This will be possible insofar as the composition of
the IMFC becomes more representative as quotas and constituencies are
adjusted.
It should also be possible to strengthen the frankness of staff surveillance
by creating a presumption that staff studies written for Article IV consul-
tations will be published. Staff performance assessments could be revised
to give greater weight to ability to make independent, candid judgments,
and a presumption could be established that reports of the IMF’s own
Independent Evaluation Office would be published. By further enhancing
transparency, these steps will strengthen the accountability of the institu-
tion. They will enhance the efficiency of IMF governance by limiting
doubts that political pressures, both internal to the Fund and from national
sources, are unduly influencing staff assessments. They will reassure those
who worry that, in the absence of adequate transparency and accountabil-
ity, a handful of advanced economies have disproportionate influence in
the Fund as a result of their personal, political and intellectual connections.
130 Cures and reforms
current account deficits to develop and that are financing them mostly or
entirely with portfolio capital inflows. Specifically, I mean Hungary,
Romania and Turkey, which have current account deficits in the order of 6
to 8 percent of GDP at the time of writing. These countries are widely
regarded as ‘convergence plays’, the assumption that their interest rates will
come down to Western European levels as a result of their recent or immi-
nent accession to the European Union and the consequent ‘Europeanization’
of their policies.29 But if capital flows turn around, growth will slow, budget
deficits will widen and the stability of financial systems will be undermined.
Again, this will sound alarmingly familiar to those who recall the Asian
Crisis. Some say that this time is different – that, unlike previous episodes,
rising US policy rates and tightening global credit conditions will not pre-
cipitate a crisis in emerging markets. I am not so sure.
NOTES
12. Fear of floating, as this phenomenon is labeled by Calvo and Reinhart (2000), is still a
problem, in other words.
13. First-generation crises as modeled by Krugman (1979) and Flood and Garber (1984) are
crises where a deterioration in domestic policies leads to a speculative attack that col-
lapses the exchange rate ex post. This is in contrast with second-generation models where
the speculative attack on the exchange rate leads to the deterioration of domestic poli-
cies that validates the attack ex post (for example, Obstfeld, 1986). I claim the credit – or
the blame – for coining this terminology (in Eichengreen et al., 1995).
14. See Eichengreen and Park (2002).
15. At least so far as we can tell, given that information on the still largely unregulated hedge
fund industry is thin on the ground.
16. See for example Cady (2004); Christofides et al., (2003); Gelos and Wei (2002); and
Glennerster and Shin (2003).
17. See Tong (2004).
18. See IMF (2004).
19. See Fischer (2001).
20. Many of the same questions apply to the World Bank.
21. See Xie (2004) for a more elaborate discussion of this point. Banks, in contrast, tend to
be too easily influenced by their customers – and the government – and in any case they
operate in the less transparent, more information-impacted segments of the economy.
22. See Eichengreen (2004a) for some of these doubts.
23. Eichengreen (2004b) elaborates this argument. Currently, when the Chinese authorities
attempt to clamp down on the provision of bank credit to reduce property market spec-
ulation and the danger of overheating, capital simply flows in from abroad and enters
the property market through non-bank channels. This is the classic ‘trilemma’ of not
being able to have an independent monetary policy when the exchange rate is pegged and
the capital account is increasingly porous (whether the authorities like it or not). A more
flexible exchange rate would go a considerable way toward squaring this circle.
24. That is to say, more investment in universities and housing.
25. For evidence on this see Eichengreen and Hausmann (2005).
26. For evidence, see Eichengreen et al. (2003).
27. This is the scenario in Goldstein (2005).
28. Which might not in fact be two independent events.
29. Hungary became a member of the EU in 2004. Romania will join at the beginning of
2007 while Turkey’s (presumably lengthy) accession negotiations are underway.
REFERENCES
Cady, John (2004), ‘Does SDDS Subscription Reduce Borrowing Costs for
Emerging Market Economies’, IMF Working Paper No. 04/58, April,
www.imf.org.
Calvo, Guillermo and Carmen Reinhart (2000), ‘Fear of Floating’, Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 117, 379–408.
Camdessus, Michel (1995), ‘Drawing Lessons from the Mexican Crisis: Preventing
and Resolving Financial Crises – the Role of the IMF’, Address at the 25th
Washington Conference of the Council of the Americas, Washington, DC,
22 May, www.imf.org.
Christofides, Charis, Christian Mulder and Andrew Tiffin (2003), ‘The Link
between Adherence to International Standards of Good Practice, Foreign
Exchange Spreads, and Ratings’, IMF Working Paper No. 03/74.
Eichengreen, Barry (2004a), ‘The Unintended Consequences of the Asian Bond
Fund’, unpublished manuscript, University of California, Berkeley.
The next financial crisis 133
1 INTRODUCTION
134
Capital controls, financial crises and cures: Malaysia 135
commodities are rubber, saw logs, palm oil, kernel oil, cocoa, crude oil, tin
and natural gas. Industrial production indexes for major manufacturing
sub-categories are also estimated in the model. There are five private invest-
ment categories, namely, agriculture, manufacturing, mining, construction
and other.
There is a very detailed section on the export component of the balance
of payments. The capital account is also treated as endogenous. Both
foreign direct investment and portfolio investment are treated endogenously
in the model. Interest rates, exchange rates and equity prices are explained
within the model.
Because of the public sector’s significance, the model has a detailed
public sector block. Public revenues are determined within the model, using
the appropriate base for the revenue being considered. Current expend-
itures are also treated as endogenous. Development expenditures are
treated as exogenous. Non-financial public enterprises, state and local gov-
ernments’ accounts are also studied in detail. The financial sector is also
treated in detail. Monetary base and money supply are determined by the
net claims of the government, net claims of the private sector, and net
claims of the external sector. Money demand equations are estimated,
assuming equilibrium in the money market. Banking sector balance sheets
are treated in detail.
The in-sample forecasting performance of the model is assessed through
static and dynamic simulations of the model over the period 1990–2001. The
one-period simulation indicates that the major macroeconomic variables
can be predicted within reasonable error margins (in terms of mean absolute
percentage error or MAPE): GDP with 6 percent, private consumption with
5.1 percent, total investment with 5.2 percent, and prices (CPI and the
implicit GDP deflator) with 1.5 percent and 3 percent, respectively. For
the unemployment rate and the interest rate, the relevant performance indi-
cator is either mean absolute error (MAE) or root mean square error
(RMSE). The mean absolute errors are 124 basis points for the unemploy-
ment rate. These errors are rather low when compared with those from other
models; the model is relatively successful in tracking historical values.
The model was solved (dynamic solution) for the 1997–2005 period for a
baseline solution. The scenario of ‘no capital controls’ was the alternative
(simulation). In the model, there is a capital control dummy that is equal to
1 in 1994, 1998 and 1999, and 0 for other years.1 This dummy variable is set
to 0 (no controls) for the period 1997–2005 to obtain the alternative
Capital controls, financial crises and cures: Malaysia 139
solution. The difference (or the percentage difference) between the simula-
tion and the baseline were calculated to see the possible effects of the ‘no
capital controls’ policy. The results are obtained for all endogenous vari-
ables, but for brevity, results for only selected variables are provided here.
The real GDP would have been 0.08 percent higher in 1998 without con-
trols (Figure 4.1). This effect turns to negative 0.01 percent in 1999, nega-
tive 0.12 percent in 2000 and 0.02 percent in 2001. The overall effect is
negative, indicating that GDP would have been lower without capital con-
trols. The GDP deflator would have been 0.04 percent higher in 1998, and
0.03 percent higher in 1999. The percentage differences are negative, but
quite small in magnitude, after 1999. The overall effect is positive, indicat-
ing that GDP deflator would have been higher without capital controls.
The real exports of goods and services would have been 0.15 percent
higher in 1998 without controls (Figure 4.1). This effect turns to negative
0.01 percent in 1999, negative 0.22 percent in 2000, and 0.02 percent in
2001. The overall effect is negative, indicating that real exports of goods
and services would have been lower without capital controls. The real
imports of goods and services would have been 0.10 percent higher in 1998
without controls. This effect turns to negative 0.01 percent in 1999, nega-
tive 0.12 percent in 2000, and 0.02 percent in 2001. The overall effect is
negative, indicating that real imports of goods and services would have
been lower without capital controls.
The real private consumption expenditures would have been 0.08 percent
higher in 1998 without controls. This effect turns to negative 0.01 percent
in 1999, negative 0.11 percent in 2000 and 0.01 percent in 2001. The overall
effect is negative, indicating that real private consumption expenditures
would have been lower without capital controls. The real private fixed
investment would have been 0.23 percent higher in 1998 without controls.
This effect turns to negative 0.01 percent in 1999, negative 0.28 percent in
2000 and 0.02 percent in 2001. The overall effect is negative, indicating
that real private fixed investment would have been lower without capital
controls.
The real government consumption expenditures would have been 0.028
percent lower in 1998, and 0.022 percent lower in 1999 without controls.
This effect turns to 0.02 percent in 2001, 0.005 percent in 2001 and 0.01
percent in 2002. The overall effect is negative, indicating that real govern-
ment consumption expenditures would have been lower without capital
controls. The real government fixed investment would have been 0.010
percent lower in 1998, and 0.008 percent lower in 1999 without controls.
This effect turns to 0.006 percent in 2001, 0.002 percent in 2002. The overall
effect is negative, indicating that real government fixed investment would
have been lower without capital controls.
Percentage Deviation [(Simulation–Baseline)/Baseline*100]
Real
RealGDP
GDP GDP Deflator
0.12
0.12 0.04
0.08
0.08 0.03
0.04
0.04 0.02
0.00
0.00 0.01
–0.04
–0.04 0.00
–0.08
–0.08 –0.01
–0.12
–0.12 –0.02
–0.16
–0.16 –0.03
97
97 98
98 99
99 00
00 01
01 02
02 03
03 04
04 05
05 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05
140
Real
RealExports
ExportsofofGoods
Goodsand
andServices
Services Real Imports of Goods and Services
0.2
0.2 0.12
0.08
0.1
0.1
0.04
0.0
0.0 0.00
–0.1
–0.1 –0.04
–0.08
–0.2
–0.2
–0.12
–0.3
–0.3 –0.16
97
97 98
98 99
99 00
00 01
01 02
02 03
03 04
04 05
05 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05
Private Consumption Private Fixed Investment
0.12 0.3
0.08 0.2
0.04 0.1
0.00 0.0
–0.04 –0.1
–0.08 –0.2
–0.12 –0.3
97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05
141
0.01 0.004
0.00 0.000
–0.01 –0.004
–0.02 –0.008
–0.03 –0.012
97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05
Figure 4.1 Effects of capital controls on real indicators and the GDP deflator
142 Cures and reforms
The government’s total tax revenues would have been 0.08 percent higher
in 1998, and 0.10 percent higher in 1999 without controls (Figure 4.2). This
effect turns to negative 0.08 percent in 2000, and negative 0.12 percent in
2001. The overall effect is a small negative, indicating that government tax
revenues would have been lower without capital controls. Similar results are
obtained for total revenues of the government. The federal budget balance
would have been about 50 million ringgits higher both in 1998 in 1999
without controls. This effect turns to negative 60 million in 2000, and nega-
tive 80 million in 2001. The overall effect is negative, indicating that federal
government budget balance would have been lower without capital con-
trols. The federal government debt would have been 40 million ringgits
lower in 1998, 90 million lower in 1999 and 40 million lower in 2000 without
controls. This effect turns to 30 million in 2001, and remains in the neigh-
borhood of 10 million until 2005. The overall effect is negative, indicating
that federal government debt would have been lower without capital con-
trols. It should be noted that this is largely driven by domestic debt.
The effect of capital controls on net private capital flows is of special
interest. The net effect on long-term private capital flows is negative, but
very small in magnitude (Figure 4.3). The effect on the short-term capital
flows is also small in magnitude and negative. The net private short-term
capital flows would have been 200 million higher in 1999. The figure turns
to be negative 300 in 2000, and negative 280 in 2001, and positive 400 in
2002. The net effect is very small, especially when these are compared with
the effects on the current account and the balance of payments. There is a
significant effect on the current account, and hence the basic balance and
the overall balance of payments. The balance of payments could have been
2500 million lower in 1998 and 2800 million lower in 1999. The effects are
much smaller in following years. The corresponding figures for the basic
balance were 2600 million in 1998 and 3200 million in 1999. The major
determinant of the change in the basic balance is the change in the current
account balance.
The initial effect on interest rates would have been higher in 1998, but
generally smaller in 1999 and 2000 if there were no capital controls (Figure
4.4). The overall effect on interest rates and exchange rates is quite small.
However, since the model is an annual one it is not possible to study another
interesting question, namely the volatility of interest rates, and stock prices
as done by Edison and Reinhart (2000).
All in all, temporary controls of capital flows in Malaysia achieved
intended goals of keeping inflation under control, and resuming growth
without much distortion in foreign exchange and financial markets. A coor-
dinated stabilization policy was the key to a successful outcome.
Tax Revenue (percentage Total Government Revenue (percentage
deviation) deviation)
0.12 0.10
0.08
0.04 0.05
0.00
0.00
–0.04
–0.08
–0.05
–0.12
–0.16 –0.10
95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05
143
40 20
20 0
million ringgits
million ringgits
0 –20
–20 –40
–40 –60
–60 –80
–80 –100
95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05
Figure 4.2 Effects of capital controls on government revenues, balance and debt
Deviation (Simulation-Baseline)
Net
NetPrivate
PrivateLong-term
Long-termCapital
Capital Net Private Short-term Capital
8080 500
400
4040
300
million ringgits
million ringgits
million ringgits
00 200
100
–40
–40
0
–80
–80 –100
–200
–120
–120
–300
–160
–160 –400
9797 9898 9999 0000 0101 0202 0303 0404 0505 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05
144
Balance
BalanceofofPayments,
Payments,Overall
OverallBalance
Balance Balance of Payments, Basic Balance
500
500 400
00 0
–400
–500
–500
million ringgits
million ringgits
million ringgits
–800
–1000
–1000 –1200
–1500
–1500 –1600
–2000
–2000
–2000
–2400
–2500
–2500 –2800
–3000
–3000 –3200
9797 9898 9999 0000 0101 0202 0303 0404 0505 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05
Percentage points
Percentage points
0.000 0.0000
–0.0004
–0.001
–0.0008
–0.002 –0.0012
–0.0016
–0.003
–0.0020
–0.004 –0.0024
97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05
145
0.02 0.2
Percentage points
0.01 0.1
0.00 0.0
–0.01 –0.1
–0.02 –0.2
–0.03 –0.3
97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05
Figure 4.4 Effects of capital controls on interest rates and exchange rates
146 Cures and reforms
5 CONCLUSION
NOTES
* The views expressed in this chapter are those of the authors and do not necessarily rep-
resent those of the Central Bank of Malaysia.
1. Using a dummy variable indicates the existence of controls, but not the intensity of con-
trols. There are attempts to measure the intensity to alleviate the limitation of using a
dummy variable. See Edison and Warnock (2002).
REFERENCES
Calvo, G. (1998), ‘Capital Flows and Capital Market Crises: The Simple Economics
of Sudden Stops’, Journal of Applied Economics, 1 (1), 35–54.
Edison, H.J. and C.M. Reinhart (2000), ‘Capital Controls During Financial Crises:
The Case of Malaysia and Thailand’, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System International Finance Discussion Papers No. 662, Washington, DC,
March (mimeo).
Edison, H.J. and F.E. Warnock (2002), ‘A Simple Measure of the Intensity of Capital
Controls’, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System International
Finance Discussion Papers No. 708, Washington, DC, October (mimeo).
Edison, H.J., M. Klein, L. Ricci and T. Slok (2002), ‘Capital Account Liberalization
and Economic Performance: A Review of Literature’, IMF Working Paper
02/120, Washington, DC.
Capital controls, financial crises and cures: Malaysia 147
1 INTRODUCTION
Over the last decade, interest in the role of finance in economic growth has
revived. Building from the pioneering work of Goldsmith (1965) and the
insights of Shaw (1973) and McKinnon (1973), the more recent work exam-
ines the role of financial institutions and financial markets in corporate
governance and the consequent implications for economic growth and
development. Levine (1997) and Stulz (2000) have provided excellent
reviews of this literature and Allen and Gale (2000) have extended it by
developing a framework for comparing bank-based financial systems with
market-based financial systems.1 Although the literature addresses ‘capital
markets’, on closer inspection the main focus is really equity markets. Bond
markets are almost completely overlooked.2
Although the omission of the bond market is not defended in the litera-
ture, one could argue that it does little violence to reality. As Table 5.1
shows, in most emerging economies in Asia, bond markets are very small
relative to the banking system or equity markets.3 Moreover, the most strik-
ing theoretical results flow from a comparison of debt contracts with equity
contracts and at a high level of abstraction bank lending can proxy for all
debt. In any event, data are much more readily available for equity markets
and the banking system than for bond markets, even in the United States.
In contrast to the academic literature, however, policy-makers have
become increasingly concerned about the absence of broad, deep, resilient
bond markets in Asia. The World Bank (Dalla et al., 1995, p. 8) has pub-
lished a study of emerging Asian bond markets urging that Asian economies
‘accelerate development of domestic . . . bond markets’, and has launched
another major study aimed at helping countries develop more efficient bond
markets. Along with Malaysia, Hong Kong has led the way. Hong Kong has
succeeded in fostering development of an active fixed-income market in
148
The case of the missing market 149
Table 5.1 The size of bond versus equity and loan markets (as a
percentage of GDP, average 1990–97)
exchange fund bills and notes even though the government has not run
significant deficits (Sheng, 1994 and Yam, 1997). In 1998, the Asia-Pacific
Economic Cooperation (APEC 1999) formed a study group to identify best
practices and promote the development of Asian bond markets. Much of
this official concern stems from the perception that the absence of bond
markets made several Asian economies more vulnerable to financial crisis.
The Governor of the Bank of Thailand (Sonakul, 2000) reflected this view
when he observed, ‘If I [could] turn back the clock and have a wish [list] . . .
high in its ranking would be a well-functioning Thai baht bond market’. (In
the concluding section we will discuss not only Thailand’s efforts to nurture
a bond market, but also the broader initiatives of the Executives’ Meeting of
East Asia-Pacific Central Banks [EMEAP].)
In this chapter, we consider why bond markets are so underdeveloped
relative to equity markets and the banking sector. In addition, we investi-
gate what the absence of a well-functioning bond market may imply for
savings, the quality and quantity of investment and for risk management.
Our analysis leads us to conclude that the absence of a bond market may
render an economy less efficient and significantly more vulnerable to
financial crisis.
If a government wishes to enhance efficiency and financial stability by
nurturing the development of a bond market, what are the appropriate
policy remedies? We review the key requirements for developing a broad,
150 Cures and reforms
deep, resilient bond market and conclude with an analysis of recent financial
development in Thailand, which is broadly representative of the wide range
of countries that have highly developed equity markets and a large banking
sector, but until very recently, only the most rudimentary bond market.
The impact of the financial sector on the real economy is subtle and
complex. What distinguishes financial institutions from other firms is the
relatively small share of real assets on their balance sheets. Thus, the direct
impact of financial institutions on the real economy is relatively minor.
Nonetheless, the indirect impact of financial markets and institutions on
economic performance is extraordinarily important. The financial sector
mobilizes savings and allocates credit across space and time. It provides not
only payment services, but more importantly products that enable firms
and households to cope with economic uncertainties by hedging, pooling,
sharing and pricing risks. An efficient financial sector reduces the cost and
risk of producing and trading goods and services and thus makes an
important contribution to raising standards of living.
The structure of financial flows can be captured in flow of funds analy-
sis, a useful analytical tool for tracing the flow of funds through an
economy. This device has been used for evaluating the interaction between
the financial and real aspects of the economy for nearly half a century
(Copeland, 1955 and Goldsmith, 1965, 1985). The basic building block is
a statement of the sources and uses of resources for each economic unit
over some period of time, usually a year.
Our analysis of the relationship between the financial sector and eco-
nomic performance will proceed in stages. In the first stage, we consider
how an economy would perform without a financial sector in order to
provide a clear benchmark for comparison. The second stage introduces
direct financial claims in an environment with severe information asym-
metries. The third stage considers financial intermediaries that transform
the direct obligations of investors into indirect obligations of financial
intermediaries that have attributes that savers prefer. The fourth stage intro-
duces the government sector and the international sector.
Table 5.2 Sources and uses of funds for the household sector
Table 5.3 The flow of funds matrix for an economy without a financial
sector
Table 5.4 The flow of funds matrix for an economy with private placement
of direct claims
Flows of U S U S U S U S U S U S
Real
Income
Savings 87 43 10 140
Real Assets 7 2 131 140
Financial
Flows
Equity 60 31 91 91 91
Fixed 20 10 30 30 30
Income
Instruments
Indirect
Financial
Assets
Financial
Instruments
Issued
by Foreign
Residents
Totals 87 87 43 43 131 131 261 261
three respects: (1) firms hold most of the real assets; (2) households hold direct
financial claims on firms in lieu of most of their previous holdings of real
assets; and (3) household savings have increased by (an arbitrary) ten units to
reflect the enhanced level of income that could be gained from reallocating
real assets to more productive uses. Generally, the higher an economy’s per
capita income, the higher the ratio of financial assets to real assets.
What makes this reallocation of resources possible? What induces house-
holds to exchange real assets for direct financial claims on firms? The simple
answer is that the direct financial claims that firms offer, promise more
attractive rates of return than households could expect to earn from invest-
ing in real assets themselves. In short, they shift from real investment to the
purchase of financial claims because they expect it to be profitable to do so.
But this superficial answer ignores several important obstacles that must be
overcome in order to induce savers to give up real assets in exchange for
direct financial claims.
The case of the missing market 155
Table 5.5 The flow of funds matrix for an economy with private placement
and financial institutions
Flow of U S U S U S U S U S U S
Real
Income
Savings 145 12 5 0 162
Real Assets 12 148 2 162 0
Financial
Flows
Equity 10 34 28 4 38 38
Fixed 25 7 105 87 112 112
Income
Instruments
Indirect 105 3 108 108 108
Financial
Instruments
Financial
Instruments
Issued by
Foreign
Residents
Totals 152 152 151 151 117 117 418 418
base for the money supply. It also issues direct claims to finance its own
spending when desired government expenditures for purchases of goods
and services and the redistribution of income exceed current tax revenues.
Table 5.6 shows the flow of funds matrix that incorporates the government
sector. The government is shown with a deficit of 33 units that causes a cor-
responding reduction in net savings for the economy. Some economists argue
that current deficits lead to a one-for-one increase in household savings in
anticipation of higher future tax burdens (Barro, 1974). Other economists
regard this view as too extreme in light of the empirical evidence (Hausman
and Poterba, 1987). Table 5.6 depicts a case in which households make a
partial response to the government deficit: household savings rise from 145
units to 150 units. The government issues 45 units of financial liabilities to
fund its current and capital expenditures as well as its subsidies to favored
private sector borrowers. In our example, real sector investment declines in
spite of subsidies from the government to the private sector. Total real sector
Table 5.6 The flow of funds matrix for a closed economy with a
government sector
Flows of U S U S U S U S U S U S
Real
Income
Savings 150 12 5 33 33 167
Real Assets 7 118 2 7 134 0
Financial
Flows
Equity 10 34 28 4 38 38
Fixed 30 10 77 97 5 45 132 132
Income
Instruments
Indirect 113 5 118 118 118
Financial
Assets
Financial
Instruments
Issued by
Foreign
Residents
Totals 160 160 101 101 127 127 45 45 423 423
assets decline from 162 units in Table 5.5 to 134 units in Table 5.6, indicative
of the ‘crowding out’ of private sector investment by government funding
demands.
Second, to complete the flow of funds, we add the international sector. As
national economies have become increasingly interdependent, cross-border
financial transactions of all kinds have become commonplace. Opening a
country to trade in financial assets offers advantages similar to those that we
observed in introducing financial instruments in the primitive economy.
World savings may be allocated more efficiently so that national income in
all countries is increased. International specialization on the basis of com-
parative advantage in financial services, like international specialization in
production, is likely to enhance efficiency. Competition from foreign insti-
tutions also stimulates innovations to cut costs and expand the range of
products. Moreover, the broader range of financial instruments available
enhances the scope for diversification to reduce country-specific risks.
Table 5.7 shows the complete flow of funds matrix. In this example the
national economy is running a current account deficit of 28 units. This
deficit is financed by net financial inflows that provide both debt and equity
Flows of U S U S U S U S U S U S
Real
Income
Savings 155 33 28 33 183
Real Assets 7 134 2 7 150 0
Financial
Flows
Equity 13 41 28 5 5 46 46
Fixed 27 10 98 81 5 45 40 153 153
Income
Instruments
Indirect 116 5 136 15 136 136
Financial
Assets
Financial 2 30 32 32 32
Instruments
Issued by
Foreign
Residents
Totals 165 165 139 139 141 141 45 45 60 60 550 550
162 Cures and reforms
The economy that we have sketched in the preceding section has a banking
system, but only a rudimentary capital market. The absence of an adequate
financial infrastructure meant that direct claims tended to be allocated
through extended families rather than through arm’s-length transactions in
the marketplace. Most corporate borrowing was in the form of bank loans.
The underdevelopment of capital markets in this economy limits risk-
pooling and risk-sharing opportunities for both households and firms. It
also robs the economy of a crucial source of information that helps coord-
inate decentralized decisions throughout the economy. Interest rates and
equity prices should be used by households in allocating income between
consumption and savings and in allocating their stock of wealth. And firms
should rely on financial markets for information about which investment
projects to select and how such projects should be financed (Merton, 1989).
Efficient financial markets help to allocate, transfer and deploy economic
resources across time and space in an uncertain environment (Merton,
1990). Without efficient financial markets, these functions are likely to be
performed less well and living standards will be lower than they might oth-
erwise have been.
The infrastructure to support a corporate bond market includes an
appropriate legal framework including reliable enforcement of bankruptcy
and foreclosure laws, strong accounting and disclosure standards, and
efficient and reliable clearing and settlement arrangements. It is also useful
to have a community of bond analysts and ratings agencies who can help
investors evaluate bonds. And, as we will emphasize in section 4, it is essen-
tial to develop a broad, deep, resilient secondary market.
In order for potential investors to be willing to accept a claim on future
cash flows for the repayment of principal and interest, they must be
confident that their rights to collect the promised debt payments are well
defined and enforceable. La Porta et al. (1998) have identified six measures
of creditor rights that are shown in Table 5.8a for countries in Table 5.1
along with a measure of contract enforceability. The measures focus on
The case of the missing market 163
pending the resolution of the reorganization process, and 0 otherwise. Source: Bankruptcy and Reorganization Laws and LaPorta et al. (1998).
Creditor rights: An index aggregating different creditor rights. The index is formed by adding 1 when: (1) the country imposes restrictions such as
creditors’ consent or minimum dividends to file for reorganization; (2) secured creditors are able to gain possession of their security once the
reorganization petition has been approved (no automatic stay); (3) secured creditors are ranked first in the distribution of the proceeds that result
from the disposition of the assets of a bankrupt firm; and (4) the debtor does not retain the administration of its property pending the resolution of
the reorganization. The index ranges from 0 to 4. Source: Bankruptcy and Reorganization Laws and LaPorta et al. (1998).
Legal reserves required to continue operation: It is the minimum percentage of total share capital mandated by Corporate Law to avoid the
dissolution of an existing firm. It takes a value of 0 for countries without such restrictions. Source: Company Law or Commercial Code and
LaPorta et al. (1998).
166 Cures and reforms
3.1 Why Equity Markets May Exist Where Bond Markets Fail to Thrive
What are the main obstacles to developing an efficient bond market? Why,
in environments with weak financial infrastructures, which discourage all
external finance to some extent, do equity markets appear to flourish rela-
tive to bond markets? Part of the answer is inherent in the difference
between debt and equity contracts. Debt claims promise repayment of prin-
cipal and interest, while equity claims promise payment of a pro rata share
of profits and usually convey a proportionate vote in important corporate
governance matters.
168 Cures and reforms
match the maturity of their liabilities. And consequently, the insurance they
provide against future contingencies will be more costly.
Source: IMF International Financial Statistics, IMF World Economic Outlook Database,
Bank for International Settlements.
174 Cures and reforms
Without competition from the bond market, the banking sector will be
larger than it would otherwise be. Banks will have more deposits at lower
cost because their customers will have very few other alternative fixed-
income investments and they will have more corporate loans because their
borrowers will have few other sources of debt financing. If the banking
market were highly competitive, the distortions from bank dominance of
debt finance might be relatively slight, but in most countries without a bond
market the banking system is highly concentrated. The deposit rate is not
likely to reflect the true opportunity cost of funds for the economy because
of cartel pricing in some countries and because in most countries, banks
benefit from access to an implicit, if not an explicit safety net. The percep-
tion that claims on the bank will receive some degree of protection from the
government, means that depositors will not be an effective source of discip-
line on bank risk-taking.
It is generally argued that bank monitoring of a borrower is superior to
monitoring by bondholders because bank lenders have lower costs of col-
lective action and can renegotiate a loan contract at lower cost in the event
that the borrower cannot meet the original repayment schedule. This may
be true in general, but recent experience has shown that if a bank is weakly
capitalized so that it cannot take a write-down in a loan renegotiation
without violating capital adequacy standards, the bank may let the bor-
rower continue negative present value projects by funding these activities to
avoid declaration of default (Herring, 1989). In this circumstance, mon-
itoring by bondholders may be preferable since they will have no motive to
sustain uneconomic activity.
The absence of a bond market precludes banks from issuing bonds,
which might reduce their exposure to liquidity risk and provide another
source of market discipline.10 The virtual absence of market discipline from
debt markets places a heavier burden on bank supervisors to curb risk-
taking. Like their counterparts in the industrialized world, however, bank
The case of the missing market 175
An economy that relies exclusively on banks for debt financing faces several
major costs. First is the loss of information that is contained in market-
determined interest rates. This impedes the development of derivatives
176 Cures and reforms
The first major bond market to develop is usually the market in government
obligations. In many countries, the government has the largest stock of
issues outstanding. In general, it is easier for bond traders to price govern-
ment issues where credit risk is not an important consideration.
Government bond prices can then serve as a basis for pricing the issues of
other borrowers who are subject to credit risk.
In most countries, governments issue debt to fund the gap between tax
receipts and current expenditures, and sometimes to finance some extraor-
dinary current expenditure. (See Table 5.10 that shows government bor-
rowing and government borrowing relative to borrowing by other issuers in
the eight Asian emerging economies and the four industrialized countries.)
The US bond market took flight after the issuance of Liberty Bonds to
finance US participation in World War I. Rajan and Zingales (1999) note
The case of the missing market 177
Source: IMF International Financial Statistics, IMF World Economic Outlook Database,
Bank for International Settlements.
that people who would otherwise not buy a financial security, bought these
bonds for patriotic reasons. The favorable experience investors had with
these bonds left them willing to invest in securities issued by corporations.
This gave liquidity to the corporate securities market and made possible the
significant expansion of these markets during the 1920s.
Does this mean that fiscally conservative governments that do not run
deficits cannot nurture a robust bond market? Hong Kong has shown that
this need not be true. After all, it is gross debt that matters for the develop-
ment of the market, not the net debtor position of the government. Hong
Kong developed a benchmark yield curve in Hong Kong dollars through
issues of exchange fund bills and notes, the proceeds of which are used pri-
marily to invest in international markets, not to fund government spending.
If the government’s objective is the nurture of a robust bond market,
then it should aim at establishing a benchmark yield curve that can serve as
the risk-free rate for the pricing of other securities. This means committing
to a program of regular issues at the appropriate maturities – usually three
months, six months, one year, three years, five years and ultimately ten
years. It must be recognized at the outset that the goal of developing a
178 Cures and reforms
robust bond market may conflict with the goal of minimizing the cost of
government borrowing.11
The design of government securities should be as simple as possible
without complicated covenants and the design should be consistent across
the maturities that comprise the benchmark yield curve. This will facilitate
pricing of the risk-free rate without the complication of special features
such as sinking funds, call options or other features.
It is crucial that the interest rate on government bonds be market-
determined, not administratively determined. If the government attempts
to manipulate the bond market to reduce the cost of government borrow-
ing, important information will be lost, which may lead to distortions in the
allocation of capital. This means that the government should not require
certain institutions to hold its debt or devise special tax treatment of gov-
ernment debt that differs from that for other securities. Here again there is
a natural tension between the objectives of nurturing the development of a
robust bond market and minimizing the cost of government borrowing.
Generally, the price discovery process is enhanced by combining com-
petitive auctions of new issues with issuance through a set of primary
dealers who act as underwriters. It is useful to invite foreign firms to become
primary dealers on the same basis as domestic firms. This is likely to speed
the adoption of world-class best practices in the local bond market and
enhance the access of domestic borrowers to longer-term foreign sources
of funds. Primary dealers should be required to make markets in the issues
by continuously quoting a bid-asked spread and standing ready to buy or
sell at the stated rates.
Although the government will find a natural constituency for its longer-
term issues in the portfolios of institutions with longer-term liabilities, such
placements will not facilitate the development of a liquid secondary market
because these institutions are likely to buy and hold bonds until they
mature. Thus, it is important to attract other investors who will have a
trading orientation. Mutual funds, for example, should be encouraged to
enter the market.
maturity so that they need not be marked to market. This discouraged sec-
ondary market trading and meant that the interest rate did not necessarily
reflect the true opportunity cost of funds.
Third, tax laws impeded the development of the secondary market. Until
1995, Thailand imposed a stamp duty on transfers of bond ownership.
Although the rate was low, approximately 0.1 percent of the value of the
bond,15 it was a powerful deterrent to secondary market trading.
Fourth, a weak legal infrastructure created doubts about creditor rights
in the event of default. Although Thailand ranked relatively well in terms
of creditor rights (see Table 5.8a), it ranked poorly in terms of judicial
effectiveness. Thailand has made a concerted effort to improve its legal
infrastructure, but survey data from a sample of local law firms and bank-
ruptcy judges in each country, reported in Doing Business in 2004 (World
Bank, 2004) show that Thailand appears to lag behind six other middle
income countries in two important respects. Table 5.12 provides data for
four Asian countries and three other middle income countries, all of which
have recently undertaken structural reforms. Based on the specified bank-
ruptcy scenario, the time to go through insolvency in Thailand (2.6 years)
is exceeded only by Indonesia (6.0 years) and Argentina (2.8 years).
Moreover, the costs of going through insolvency in Thailand (38 percent of
the bankruptcy estate) are markedly higher than in the six other countries.
Fifth, weak accounting and disclosure standards impeded the evaluation
of credit risk and made it difficult for external investors to value risky debt.
Table 5.8c shows that accounting standards in Thailand ranked below
average among the eight Asian emerging economies. Again, there have been
recent efforts to correct this weakness. Based on a study funded by the
Asian Development Bank, Thailand launched its first credit rating agency,
Weak legal infrastructure
Weak accounting standards
Captive market
Underdevelopment
of
Tax and stamp duty SECONDARY MARKET
Limited disclosure
Figure 5.1 Thailand’s structural problems and consequences for the development of the bond market
The case of the missing market 183
South
Thailand Korea Malaysia Indonesia Turkey Mexico Argentina
Time to Go 2.6 1.47 2.2 6.0 1.8 2.0 2.8
Through
Insolvency
(years)
Cost to Go 38 4 18 18 8 18 18
Through
Insolvency
(% estate)
Absolute 67 100 100 67 67 33 67
Priority
Preserved
Efficient 1 1 0 0 0 1 0
Outcome
Achieved
Goals-of- 62 91 52 35 51 61 43
Insolvency
Index
Court- 33 67 33 100 67 67 67
Powers
Index
Source and notes: Doing Business in 2004, Understanding Regulation (World Bank, 2004).
Based on responses to a questionnaire filled out by local law firms and bankruptcy judges
specifying the details of the insolvency in which the business runs a hotel in downtown real
estate, its only asset. The business is assumed to default on principal and interest 2 January,
2003. The measure for preservation of absolute priority is on a scale of 100. A score of 100
means that secured creditors are paid before labor, tax claims and shareholders. A score of 67
means that secured creditors get paid second. The efficient outcome measure takes on the
value 1 if the insolvency process results in either foreclosure or liquidation with a going-
concern sale or in a successful rehabilitation with new management. A 0 indicates the efficient
outcome was not achieved. The Goals-of-Insolvency Index goes from 0 to 100 and is the
simple average of the time of insolvency and cost of insolvency (each rescaled from 0 to 100)
and the observance of absolute priority. The Court-Powers Index is a measure of the degree to
which the court drives insolvency proceedings and is the average of three indicators: whether
the court appoints and replaces the insolvency administrator with no restrictions imposed by
law, whether the reports of the administrator are accessible only to the court and not the
creditors, and whether the court decides on the adoption of the rehabilitation plan. The index
is scaled from 0 to 100, with higher values indicating more court involvement. South Korea,
Malaysia and Indonesia are included because they experienced crises more or less
simultaneously with Thailand. Argentina, Mexico and Turkey are included because they are
middle income countries that have also undertaken structural reforms.
184 Cures and reforms
Note: Profit is defined as earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation and amortization
(EBITDA). Leverage is debt over equity.
Notes and sources: Includes financial institution bonds. 1996, end of year data. The
banking sector includes monetary authorities, deposit money banks, and other banking
institutions for which data are available (including institutions that do not accept
transferable deposits but do incur such liabilities as time and savings deposits). Examples of
other banking institutions include savings and mortgage loan institutions and building and
loan associations. The data are as reported on line 32d in the IMF International Financial
Statistics (IFS). GDP is the gross domestic product as reported on line 99b in the IFS. GCF
is the gross fixed capital formation as reported on line 93e in the IFS. Corporate debt
securities are debt securities that were issued in domestic currency by residents of the
country indicated, including short-term paper (for example, commercial paper).
180
160
140
Turnover (in %)
120
100
80
188
60
40
20
0
1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
each maturity interval. And, instead of raising revenue through taxing bond
transactions, which discourages trading, the government must remove
stamp taxes. Indeed, the Asian Policy Forum proposal even contemplated
positive tax incentives.
More recently, along with ten22 other Asian central banks, the Thai
Central Bank formed the Executives’ Meeting of East Asia-Pacific Central
Banks (EMEAP) to consider ways to overcome the limitations inherent in
the small size of most of the existing national markets and to work toward
greater integration of these markets to form a regional market. This group
established an Asian Bond Fund 1 (ABF 1) on 2 June, 2003 to invest about
$1 billion in reserve assets in Asian bonds. On 16 December, 2004, a second
fund was launched to invest in the local currency bonds of eight EMEAP
members including Thailand. ABF 2 allocated about $2 billion to a Pan-
Asia Bond Index Fund and a Fund of Bond Funds. ABF 2 is designed to
encourage investment by public investors outside the EMEAP region and
by private sector investors both in Asia and from around the world in local
currency bonds of the EMEAP group.23 The Thai government has also
opened its market to issuance of local currency-denominated bonds by
international financial institutions and borrowers from several other coun-
tries to further encourage the cross-border supply and trading of bonds.
The success of these efforts can be seen in the growth of bond markets
in Asia. Relative to the pre-crisis situation, Table 5.16 shows that six of the
Table 5.16 The size of bond markets (as a % of GDP, average 1990–97
versus 2003)
Asian economies (the exception being the Philippines) have made substan-
tial progress in developing their bond markets. The Thai bond market is
more than four times larger, relative to GDP, than before the crisis.
As the Thai example has shown, bond markets do matter for financial
development. Certainly, an economy can grow rapidly without an active
bond market. But the cost is an increased vulnerability to a financial crisis
and a loss of information to guide savings and investment decisions. Heavy
reliance on banks means a correspondingly heavy exposure to banking
crises. And the consequence can be catastrophic for the real economy. But
the example of Thailand also shows that it may be possible to rebuild the
financial system with an expanded role for the bond market.
NOTES
8. Note that when the principal owners are the managers of the firm, the usual arguments
about the disciplinary role of debt in constraining agency problems between the owner
principal and manager agents do not apply.
9. Technically, it is not essential that the term structure be default risk-free. It is necessary,
however, that the benchmark bonds that price the term structure share the same risk of
default. In most markets, government issues, which are approximately default risk-free
in domestic currency terms, provide the benchmarks for estimating the term structure of
interest rates.
10. See, for example, the recent proposal by the Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee
to require that all internationally active banks be required to issue subordinated debt
(Calomiris et al., 2000).
11. The US, for example, is currently reducing the effective maturity of its outstanding
debt. Because the US has a highly developed bond market with abundant issues by
government-sponsored enterprises that serve as close substitutes for government debt, it
may be able to reduce gross debt without undermining the efficiency of the bond market.
This would not be a wise policy in an emerging market, however.
12. When Citibank introduced the Certificate of Deposit, it was careful to make
arrangements with dealers to establish active secondary markets in which CDs could be
traded.
13. Publicly traded corporations issue letter stock frequently in making acquisitions or
raising capital when the time and cost of registering the new stock with the SEC
(Securities and Exchange Commission) would make the transaction impractical. Even
though such stock cannot be sold to the public on the open market, it may be sold in
private transactions under certain circumstances. Such transactions must be reported to
the SEC where they become a matter of public record Pratt (1989, p. 240).
14. Fernando and Herring (2002) have shown how liquidity depends on the diversity of
market participants and provide evidence from a natural experiment in which the sec-
ondary market for perpetual floating rate notes collapsed and prices fell from 15 to 30
percent even though the credit standing of the issuers had not changed.
15. Emery (1997).
16. In 1999, the Securities and Exchange Commission passed a resolution requiring private
placement debt of more than 100 million baht to be rated.
17. Retained earnings, of course, financed the remainder of the change in gross fixed capital
formation.
18. Thailand: Economic Monitor, World Bank Thailand Office (2003), p. 33, Table 8.
19. CLSA Asia-Pacific Markets is a provider of brokerage and investment banking services,
headquartered in Hong Kong.
20. Thailand: Economic Monitor, World Bank Thailand Office (2003), p. 34.
21. See also Yoshitomi and Shirai (2001) for an extensive discussion of many of the issues
that underlie the proposals.
22. The other nine include the Reserve Bank of Australia, People’s Bank of China, Hong
Kong Monetary Authority, Bank of Indonesia, Bank of Japan, Bank of Korea, Bank
Negara Malaysia, Reserve Bank of New Zealand, Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas, and the
Monetary Authority of Singapore.
23. For additional discussion, see Asia Bond Monitor, April 2005, Asian Development Bank.
REFERENCES
Alba, Pedro, Stijn Claessens and Simeon Djankov (1998), ‘Thailand’s Corporate
Financing and Governance Structures: Impact on Firms’ Competitiveness’,
Paper for the World Bank Conference on Thailand’s Dynamic Economic
Recovery and Competitiveness.
192 Cures and reforms
1 INTRODUCTION
Almost ten years have passed since the East Asian Financial Crisis so
rudely interrupted the rapid expansion of the East Asian economies. Most
scholars have sought to evaluate the crisis phenomenon and its impact in
terms of financial flows, international exchange exposure, contagion, etc.
All of these factors seem to have had some relevance (Corsetti et al., 1998a
and 1998b; Radelet and Sachs, 1998). Comparatively, little analysis has
been devoted to the crisis from a production input/factor productivity per-
spective. Such a view has important implications for the growth prospects
of the East Asian countries.
In this chapter, we will consider the East Asian Crisis from the perspec-
tive of macroeconomic performance, its impact on investment, growth and
productivity. First, we discuss the East Asian growth process and its rela-
tionship to underlying growth forces. Then, we look at developments from
an empirical perspective, computing total factor productivity and testing
various explanations for it. Finally, we will speculate about the long-run
implications for future development in East Asia.
197
198 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
use rather than increased Total Factor Productivity (TFP).2 By and large,
the later empirical work suggests that while a large share of the growth in
the region is attributable to growth of inputs, there remains substantial
room for productivity catch-up (Timmer and Szirmai, 1997; Lau, 1998).
The growth accounting papers have used the traditional production func-
tion approach and then have attempted to explain the unexplained residual
in terms of a number of general and country-specific variables. Some of
these variables relate to the quality of inputs, for example, mean years of
schooling acquired by labor, but others relate to macroeconomic issues like
the exchange rate and the government budget deficit. Interestingly, these
studies have not taken into account the impact of the business cycle, despite
the fact that business fluctuations are known to be an important variable in
explaining short-term variations in productivity in the industrial countries.3
Being aware of the sometimes heated debate that can involve the concept
of total factor productivity (TFP), we would like to note that we intend to
use the TFP concept non-judgmentally, that is, only as a mechanical way for
summarizing growth that is not directly the result of increased factor inputs
and not associate any one specific interpretation to this residual. Then we
will try to explain computed TFP in terms of variables that relate to the
speed of growth, industrialization and exports. An important aspect of our
explanation will be the impact of the fluctuation in real output that was
associated with the 1997 financial crisis. We stress that an emphasis on real
output and productivity does not necessarily contradict the linkages
between the rate and patterns of development and international financial
considerations like capital flows, exchange rates, competitiveness and expec-
tations that lie behind traditional explanations of the East Asian Crisis.
As is well known, the rapid development of East Asia was interrupted in the
late 1990s by the East Asian Financial Crisis, introducing a sharp reversal
in output growth and investment throughout the region. The impact was
uneven with little apparent influence on China but with serious recessionary
effect on the domestic economies of some countries, particularly Thailand,
South Korea and Indonesia. Rapid growth of exports, in part, a result of
financial crisis-induced exchange rate readjustments and a gradual return to
higher rates of investment (though not as a share of GDP) have enabled
most East Asian countries to resume their rapid growth in recent years.
Let us start by looking here at the East Asian growth record (Figure 6.1).
The 1997 and 1998 period shows a severe interruption of real growth at the
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
% per year
0.0
1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
200
–5.0
–10.0
–15.0
Table 6.1 Growth of real GDP, pre- and post-crisis (% per year)
time of the East Asian Financial Crisis for all the East Asian countries
except China. We show the relevant averages in Table 6.1 for the pre-crisis
period, for the time of the financial crisis – 1997, 1998 and 1999 – and for
a post-crisis period. Before the crisis, the growth rates are extraordinarily
high in all the countries except the late-blooming Philippines, ranging from
6.8 percent in Taipei to 12.1 percent in China. The crisis-induced down-
swing is clearly apparent in 1997–98 particularly in Indonesia, Thailand,
Malaysia and South Korea. The period 1998–99 is a time that marks the
start of the recovery. The post-crisis period shows renewed growth but, with
the exception of the Philippines, at substantially lower growth rates than in
the pre-crisis period.
Now let us examine labor productivity which provides a simple way to
measure improvements in a nation’s productive power. Figure 6.2 and
Table 6.2 show the movement of labor productivity in East Asia. For most
countries, except China, the rate of productivity growth shows fluctuations,
in relation particularly to the 1997–98 crisis. There appears to be a down-
ward trend, with growth in the post-crisis period substantially lower than
in the years that preceded the crisis.
The 1997–98 crisis is dominated by a huge swing in the share of fixed
investment in GDP (Table 6.3, Figure 6.3). Before the crisis, gross fixed
capital formation had risen to high levels relative to GDP, between 30 and
40 percent, in all the East Asian countries, except Thailand and the
15.0
10.0
5.0
0.0
% per year
1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
–5.0
202
–10.0
–15.0
–20.0
Pre-crisis Post-crisis
Period Period
1987–91 1991–96 1997 1998 1999 2000–03 Difference*
China, People’s 2.8 11.1 7.6 6.6 6.1 7.2 ⫺3.9
Rep. of
Hong Kong, 5.6 3.1 2.1 ⫺3.7 3.7 3.0 0.0
China
Korea, 5.4 4.8 2.9 ⫺0.8 7.7 3.4 ⫺1.4
Rep. of
Indonesia 5.3 5.2 5.0 ⫺15.8 ⫺0.5 3.5 ⫺1.8
Malaysia 4.7 5.5 5.3 ⫺7.7 3.4 1.7 ⫺3.7
Philippines 1.7 ⫺0.2 3.6 ⫺1.9 5.2 0.8 0.9
Singapore 4.7 6.5 3.9 ⫺3.1 6.0 0.7 ⫺5.8
Thailand 7.8 7.4 ⫺4.3 ⫺7.4 4.6 2.8 ⫺4.6
Taipei 6.6 5.4 5.5 3.3 4.4 2.1 ⫺3.3
Pre-crisis Post-crisis
1986–90 1991–96 1997 1998 1999–2003 Difference*
China, People’s 36.3 39.3 38.2 37.7 39.4 0.1
Rep. of
Hong Kong, 26.7 30.3 34.5 29.2 25.1 ⫺5.2
China
Korea, 30.4 31.3 31.8 16.8 15.4 ⫺15.9
Rep. of
Indonesia 32.4 37.6 36.0 25.0 29.6 ⫺8.0
Malaysia 27.5 39.8 43.0 26.7 23.8 ⫺16.0
Philippines 19.4 22.7 24.8 20.3 19.7 ⫺3.0
Singapore 36.1 35.1 39.2 32.3 24.7 ⫺10.4
Thailand 21.7 24.8 24.2 24.9 19.6 ⫺5.2
Taipei, China 32.6 41.2 33.7 20.4 23.3 ⫺17.9
45.0
40.0
35.0
30.0
% per year
25.0
20.0
15.0
204
10.0
5.0
0.0
86
87
88
89
90
91
92
93
94
95
96
97
98
99
00
01
02
03
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
China, People’s Rep. of Indonesia Taipei
Malaysia Philippines
Thailand Korea, Rep. of
Table 6.4 Growth of capital stock:** pre- and post-crisis (% per year)
Pre-crisis Post-crisis
1986–91 1991–96 1997 1998 1999 1999–2003 Difference*
China, People’s 9.30 9.60 10.10 9.40 9.00 8.80 ⫺0.90
Rep. of
Hong Kong, 4.70 5.50 7.00 7.60 5.90 3.80 ⫺1.80
China
Korea, 7.30 9.20 12.10 9.90 5.40 5.90 ⫺3.30
Rep. of
Indonesia 3.00 6.90 8.70 8.70 3.40 2.50 ⫺4.40
Malaysia 5.70 11.50 12.80 12.20 3.80 3.80 ⫺7.80
Philippines 2.30 3.00 4.20 4.80 3.30 3.30 0.30
Singapore 7.40 8.20 10.70 10.70 8.30 5.80 ⫺2.30
Thailand 8.70 10.70 10.10 5.90 0.70 0.80 ⫺9.90
Taipei 2.70 5.50 5.70 6.20 6.40 4.60 ⫺0.90
Notes:
* (1991–96) minus (1999–2003).
** Computed from investment, an initial capital output ratio of 3 and an assumed
depreciation rate of 0.05 per year.
35.0
30.0
25.0
20.0
% per year
15.0
10.0
5.0
206
0.0
1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
–5.0
–10.0
–15.0
40.0
30.0
% per year
20.0
10.0
207
0.0
1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
–10.0
–20.0
China, People’s Rep. of Indonesia Korea, Rep. of
Malaysia Philippines Thailand
Taipei
Pre-crisis Post-crisis
1986–91 1991–95 1996 1997 1998 1999 1999–2003 Difference*
China 18.4 21.8 17.9 20.9 0.5 6.1 22.9 1.1
Hong Kong 23.0 15.2 4.0 4.1 ⫺7.5 0.1 6.9 ⫺8.4
Indonesia 14.5 11.8 9.8 7.1 ⫺8.6 ⫺0.4 10.7 ⫺1.0
Korea 16.6 16.4 4.6 4.8 ⫺7.9 8.2 8.3 ⫺8.1
Malaysia 19.8 21.1 6.1 0.9 ⫺6.9 15.1 9.5 ⫺11.5
Philippines 13.2 18.6 18.3 22.8 16.9 20.3 5.1 ⫺13.5
Singapore 21.7 19.2 5.9 0.2 ⫺12.3 4.4 6.6 ⫺12.6
Thailand 26.8 18.8 ⫺2.5 3.3 ⫺5.3 7.3 8.8 ⫺10.1
Taiwan 14.3 10.2 3.8 5.3 ⫺9.4 10.0 5.4 ⫺4.8
major contributing factors to the onset of the 1997 crisis (Adams, 1998).
The recovery of exports after devaluation provided an important offset to
the lower investment share in the post-crisis period, but export growth in
the post-crisis period has been lower than before the crisis. China is, again,
a glaring exception. The importance of exports here is that export produc-
tion is hypothesized to contribute to the growth of productivity.
In view of the complex interactions between the various forces to which the
East Asian Crisis can be attributed, it is helpful to look at the phenomenon
from the perspective of the underlying forces influencing the production
potential of the region’s economies. For this purpose, we take an input/total
factor productivity view of the developments. Growth of output can be dis-
entangled into that attributable to increased inputs and the residual factor,
often termed ‘total factor productivity’. (Denison, 1974; Solow, 1956).
Following Solow, the residual represents the difference between the growth
of total output and a weighted sum of growth in labor and capital inputs:
12.0
10.0
% per year
8.0
6.0
4.0
210
2.0
0.0
1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
Figure 6.6 Growth of East Asian inputs of labor and capital (% per year, wk ⫽ 0.6 and wk ⫽ 0.4)
Investment, growth and productivity during the East Asian Financial Crisis 211
Table 6.6 Growth of capital and labor inputs in East Asia: pre-crisis and
post-crisis (% per year assuming wk ⫽ 0.4 and wl ⫽ 0.6)
Pre-crisis Post-crisis
1987–91 1991–96 1997 1998 1999 1999–2003 Difference*
China, People’s 6.1 4.5 4.8 4.5 4.2 4.1 ⫺0.3
Rep. of
Hong Kong, 2.1 3.5 4.5 2.3 2.1 2.0 ⫺1.5
China
Korea, 4.6 5.0 5.9 0.4 3.2 3.7 ⫺1.3
Rep. of
Indonesia 2.3 4.2 3.3 5.1 2.2 1.3 ⫺2.8
Malaysia 4.1 7.1 6.3 5.1 3.2 3.2 ⫺3.9
Philippines 2.1 3.4 2.7 2.7 0.3 3.3 ⫺0.1
Singapore 5.2 4.9 7.1 5.6 3.9 3.6 ⫺1.4
Thailand 4.7 4.7 5.8 0.5 0.2 1.5 ⫺3.2
Taipei, China 1.9 3.1 3.0 3.2 3.2 2.1 ⫺0.9
continues to grow during the first years of the financial crisis (note the esti-
mates in Table 6.4) but output declines. Similarly, procyclical variation of
labor productivity is well-known – employers delay hiring during the
upswing and postpone layoffs during the downswing, producing cyclical
variations in labor productivity over the cycle. In the post-crisis period,
TFP growth is considerably lower than in pre-crisis China, Singapore and
Taipei, but not in the other East Asian countries. In China, this may reflect
statistical changes towards a ‘norm’, given the astonishingly high rate
recorded earlier. In Taipei and Singapore, the decline in TFP growth may
be a result of the fact that these countries are approaching the technologi-
cal frontier in their high-tech industries.
10.0
5.0
% per year
0.0
1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
–5.0
212
–10.0
–15.0
–20.0
Table 6.7 Total factor productivity growth in East Asia: pre-crisis and
post-crisis (% per year assuming wk ⫽ 0.4 and wl ⫽ 0.6)
Pre-crisis Post-crisis
1987–91 1991–96 1997 1998 1999 1999–2003 Difference*
China, People’s 1.9 7.6 4.1 3.4 2.9 4.1 ⫺3.5
Rep. of
Hong Kong, 4.5 1.8 0.5 ⫺7.2 1.3 1.9 0.1
China
Korea, 4.5 2.0 ⫺1.2 ⫺7.2 6.2 1.9 ⫺0.1
Rep. of
Indonesia 5.2 3.4 1.4 ⫺18.2 ⫺1.4 2.9 ⫺0.5
Malaysia 4.4 2.5 1.0 ⫺12.5 3.0 1.3 ⫺1.2
Philippines 1.9 0.1 2.5 ⫺3.3 3.1 0.8 0.7
Singapore 4.1 4.4 1.4 ⫺6.5 3.0 ⫺0.8 ⫺5.2
Thailand 6.3 3.4 ⫺7.1 ⫺11.0 4.2 3.3 ⫺0.1
Taipei, China 6.4 3.8 3.7 1.3 2.2 0.5 ⫺3.3
above that might affect TFP, either by moving businesses away from the his-
torical production path, such as in the financial crisis or shifts into new
industries, or that might move the productivity path such as technical
change incorporated in investment.
The 1997 financial crisis is the sharpest and most pervasive business
fluctuation episode that affected the East Asian countries during the past two
decades. As we have noted, there were severe declines in real output in most
East Asian countries in 1997–98. We have examined the effect of these events
on productivity using regressions linking TFP to a series of dummy variables
covering the 1997–2001 period (Table 6.8). The significant coefficients for
1997 and 1998, amounting to 1 percent in 1997 (largely the effect on
Thailand) and 9 percent for 1998, show that declines in production have clear
impacts on TFP, probably through underutilization of capital and labor.
Note that these effects are in addition to effects related to use of less labor
and slower growth of capital that have been incorporated into inputs.
A closely related question is whether the impact of the crisis was sym-
metrical, in the sense that the loss in productivity suffered in 1997–98 was
made up at a later point. That does not appear to be the case. With refer-
ence to Equation 2, the regression showing dummies for 1997, 1998 and
214 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
Equation 1
Coefficient Standard error Significance
Dependent variable
% change TFP
Independent variables
Dummy 1997 ⫺2.516 1.155 Significant
Dummy 1998 ⫺10.022 1.155 Significant
Dummy 1999 ⫺0.474 1.155 Non-significant
Constant 3.213 0.298
Adjusted R2 0.343
Equation 2
Dependent variable
% change TFP
Independent variables
Dummy 1997 ⫺3.096 1.136 Significant
Dummy 1998 ⫺10.602 1.136 Significant
Dummy 1999 ⫺1.055 1.136 Non-significant
Dummy 2000–03 ⫺2.031 0.640 Significant
Constant 3.793 0.343
Adjusted R2 0.385
Equation 3
Dependent variable
% change TFP
Independent variables
Time ⫺0.313 0.113 Significant
Dummy 1997 ⫺1.371 1.274 Marginal
Dummy 1998 ⫺8.563 1.333 Significant
Dummy 1999 1.297 1.399 Non-significant
Dummy 2000–03 1.105 1.294 Non-significant
Constant 5.518 0.707
Adjusted R2 0.416
Equation 4
Coefficient Standard error Significance
Dependent variable
% change TFP
Independent variables
China dummy 0.501 1.037 Non-significant
Dummy 1997 ⫺1.109 0.871 Marginal
Dummy 1998 ⫺4.169 1.066 Significant
Dummy 2000–03 ⫺0.282 0.575 Non-significant
Income pc. ppp basis ⫺2.735E⫺06 3.500E⫺05 Non-significant
Industry share ⫺0.035 0.032 Marginal
Change of ind. share ⫺1.426 0.254 Significant
FDI/employment 2.163E⫺05 3.382E⫺05 Non-significant
Investment/GDP ⫺0.055 0.035 Marginal
% change exports 5.895 2.076 Significant
% change industrial output 49.774 5.729 Significant
Constant 1.870 1.805
Adjusted R2 0.683
Investment change has already been taken into account as an input, prior
to the computation of the residual productivity change and it does not yield
a significant result in the form of investment as a share of GDP. Notable
are the results for industry as a share of GDP. The effects of the industry
share variable are negative, though with only marginal significance. This
suggests, that countries that already have a high level of industrialization
are less likely to show technical change-based productivity change. More
puzzling, however, is the result for change in the share of industry, since
here also there is a negative coefficient and it is statistically significant.
Given the level of industrial development, an increase in the share of indus-
try appears to have a negative impact on TFP. Again, this may reflect the
lessened potential for productivity change as high income countries shift
further resources into industry. On the other hand, the income per capita
variable does not show significant effects.
We also hypothesized that foreign direct investment would influence
changes in TFP. It is difficult, however, to measure FDI across the East
Asian countries since some, like Taipei, show negative values for FDI, while
others benefit from positive values. In any case, we were not able to show a
significant positive effect, though that may have been incorporated into the
significant effect of export growth, many of which are produced by firms
benefiting at some stage from foreign investment or management. The
dummy variable for 1998 is significantly negative, the dummy for 1997 is
only marginally significant. The dummy for China and the dummy for
2000–03 did not show significant effects.
The variables that showed statistically significant effects were combined
into the regression shown in Table 6.10 and the differences between actual
and predicted values are shown for the pre- and post-crisis periods in
Table 6.11. Much of the variation in TFP can be explained in terms of
growth of industrial output and exports (adjusted R-squared of 0.67) that
appear to be associated with high TFP growth in the East Asian countries.
Presumably, the resources employed in the new industries have a higher
level of productivity than that prevailing elsewhere in the economy, causing
TFP to increase with industrial and export growth.
The unexplained element of TFP growth (difference between actual TFP
growth and the estimated value) can be said to indicate pure technical
progress as well as interactions and possible increasing returns to scale. It
is relatively small, accounting for less than a third of the variance of calcu-
lated TFP and a much smaller share of the total variance of productivity,
for most countries throughout the entire estimation period. This is in
accord with the results noted in earlier growth accounting studies. While
there is no comprehensive evidence of a change in unexplained TFP
growth, some countries are clearly doing better recently in this respect than
Investment, growth and productivity during the East Asian Financial Crisis 217
Equation 5
Coefficient Standard error Significance
Dependent variable
% change TFP
Independent variables
Dummy 1997 ⫺1.237 0.828 Marginally significant
Dummy 1998 ⫺4.123 0.957 Significant
% change exports ($) ⫺6.458 1.945 Significant
% change industrial output 45.783 4.819 Significant
Change in industrial share ⫺1.379 0.234 Significant
Constant ⫺0.833 0.405
Adjusted R2 0.674
Table 6.11 Difference between actual and estimated TFP, pre-crisis and
post-crisis
Pre-crisis Post-crisis
1987–91* 1992–96* 1997 1998 1999 2000–03 Difference*
China, 0.2 1.9 0.9 4.4 0.1 ⫺0.1 ⫺1.9
Rep. of
Hong Kong, 1.5 0.9 1.8 0.2 1.0 1.5 0.5
China
Korea, 0.2 ⫺1.3 ⫺1.5 1.8 2.3 ⫺0.6 0.7
Rep. of
Indonesia 1.6 ⫺0.4 1.0 ⫺6.7 ⫺1.5 1.3 1.8
Malaysia 0.1 ⫺2.2 ⫺0.1 ⫺4.0 0.7 ⫺0.5 1.7
Philippines 0.0 ⫺1.8 0.8 0.8 1.2 ⫺0.9 1.0
Singapore ⫺0.7 ⫺0.1 ⫺0.4 ⫺0.3 0.5 ⫺1.8 ⫺1.7
Thailand 0.3 ⫺0.4 ⫺4.8 ⫺1.1 2.8 1.5 1.9
Taipei 2.2 0.8 2.3 4.8 0.0 ⫺0.2 ⫺1.0
Note: * Omitting outlier values for 1990 (China) and 1995 (Korea) (2000–03) minus
(1992–96).
others. China shows almost zero unexplained TFP since the mid-1990s,
meaning that all of its growth reflects either an increase in inputs or is
closely associated with the expansion of industrial production and exports.
Of course, one possible explanation of this phenomenon may lie in the fact
that China has proven, in a systemic or institutional sense, to be a much
sought-after destination for foreign direct investment and the resulting
218 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
relatively large FDI inflows may have reduced China’s imperative to worry
about ways to improve productivity per se. Again, while the financial crisis
had significant negative impacts on productivity growth, there is little evi-
dence to suggest that the unexplained component of productivity growth is
structurally different in the post-crisis period than in earlier years; it is
lower in Taiwan and Singapore, where it may reflect the increasing difficulty
of these relatively advanced countries in catching up with advanced tech-
nology. It is also lower in China, where it may reflect statistical problems,
but it is higher in Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand.
6 CONCLUDING REMARKS
The object of this study was to examine the effect of the East Asian Crisis
on the growth of productivity change in East Asia. Our approach has been
one based on measurement of inputs and explanation of total factor pro-
ductivity (TFP), associating it with the cyclical impact of the financial crisis
and growth in industrial production and exports. These considerations had
statistically significant explanatory power. The coefficient estimates for
other measured factors, including FDI and investment, did not show up
statistically significant in the regressions.
As has also been shown by earlier empirical work, our calculations
suggest that rapid growth in East Asia depends greatly on the expansion of
inputs of labor and capital. Productivity growth also appears to be closely
related to expansion of industrial production and exports and to vary con-
siderably with cycles in business activity. A relatively small share of TFP
remains unexplained and that may be associated with increasing returns
and technological change.
The impact of the financial crisis is clearly apparent in 1997 and 1998.
The loss in productivity growth associated with this period is not made up
in later years. In the post-crisis years, investment is lower as a share of GDP
and growth of total inputs is slower, except in the Philippines, than before
the crisis. Moreover, in China, Singapore and Taipei, TFP is substantially
lower in the post-crisis than in the pre-crisis period. In these countries, this
reduction is also apparent in the unexplained part of TFP, though in other
parts of East Asia, the unexplained part of TFP is somewhat higher post-
crisis than before. Lower growth of unexplained TFP in the most advanced
countries, Taipei and Singapore, suggests that they are finding it increas-
ingly difficult to shift their production functions to take advantage of new
technology. The reduced unexplained TFP element in China, which reflects
a downward trend from an extraordinarily high pre-crisis rate of unex-
plained productivity growth, calls for further study.
Investment, growth and productivity during the East Asian Financial Crisis 219
NOTES
REFERENCES
Adams, F.G. (1998), ‘The East Asian Development Ladder: Virtuous Circles and
Linkages in East Asian Economic Development’, in F.G. Adams and
S. Ichimura, (eds), East Asian Development, Westport, CN: Praeger, pp. 3–18.
Akamatsu, K. (1961), ‘A Theory of Unbalanced Growth in the World Economy’,
Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 86, 195–213.
Akamatsu, K. (1962), ‘Historical Pattern of Economic Growth in Developing
Countries’, The Developing Economies, 1, 3–25.
Collins, Susan M. and Barry P. Bosworth (1996), ‘Economic Growth in East Asia:
Accumulation Versus Assimilation’ Brookings Papers, Washington: Brookings
Institution, http://www.brookings.edu/=views/articles/collins/19960828.htm.
Corsetti, G., P. Pesenti and N. Roubini (1998a), ‘What Caused the Asian Currency
and Financial Crisis? Part I: A Macroeconomic Overview’, NBER Working
Paper, W 6833, Cambridge, MA: NBER.
Corsetti, G., P. Pesenti and N. Roubini (1998b), ‘What Caused the Asian Currency
and Financial Crisis? Part II: The Policy Debate’, NBER Working Paper, W 6834,
Cambridge, MA: NBER.
Crafts, Nicholas (1999), ‘East Asian Growth Before and After the Crisis’, IMF Staff
Papers, 46 (2) 139–66.
Denison, Edward F. (1974), Accounting for United States Economic Growth,
1929–1969, Washington: Brookings.
Herrick, Bruce and Charles P. Kindleberger (1983), Economic Development,
New York: McGraw-Hill.
220 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
1 INTRODUCTION
221
222 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
uses a methodology that other analysts have used as well for other studies
of the Thai experience and of the experience of other countries (for
example, Betcherman and Islam, 2000; also see Fallon and Lucas, 2000;
Horton and Mazumdar, 1999; Mahmoud and Aryah, 1999). In this
approach, the percentage change in the number of employed workers
between the pre- and post-crisis period2 is subtracted from the percentage
change in aggregate real wage earnings between the pre- and post-crisis
period to obtain the percentage change in the real wage rate due to the
crisis. Using this methodology, the World Bank estimates that the Thai real
wage rate fell by 4.6 percent and Betcherman and Islam estimate that real
wages fell by –1.1 percent in Malaysia, –9.3 percent in Korea and –41.0
percent in Indonesia (Table 7.1). But we argue that the methodology used
in these and other studies is subject to at least four possibly important lim-
itations:
Country % Change In
Employment Real wages Real wage labor GDP
earnings
Indonesia 2.7 (⫺20) ⫺41.0 (299) ⫺38.3 (280) ⫺13.7
South Korea ⫺5.3 (91) ⫺9.3 (160) ⫺14.6 (252) ⫺5.8
Malaysia ⫺2.7 (36) ⫺1.1 (15) ⫺3.8 (51) ⫺7.5
Thailand ⫺3.0 (30) ⫺4.6 (46) ⫺7.6 (76) ⫺10.0
Sources: World Bank (2000, Table 1). Figures for Thailand calculated from Labor Force
Survey data, and represent data for the first and third quarters of 1998. Figures for other
countries obtained from Betcherman and Islam (2000), and refer to the full 1998 year.
What really happened to Thai wage rates? 223
While these may seem to be dry technical points, they may make a consid-
erable difference in our understanding of the answer to the important
empirical question of what did happen to real wage rates and what the
implications are for policy.
We demonstrate that, indeed, in the Thai case, these four methodologi-
cal aspects of the approach used by the World Bank and others each make
differences in estimates of what happened to real wage rates. These
differences are particularly large in the Thai case for the second and the
fourth of these methodological limitations, resulting in absolute biases in
measured real wage declines of 5.5 and 9.8 percentage points, respectively.
In the particular case of Thailand, these biases are partially offsetting.
Even so, we estimate that for the combination of these four reasons, the
World Bank (2000) overestimates the decline in real wage rates by about 40
percent. Our preferred estimate, using the same data and, except for these
four aspects of methodology, the same assumptions as the World Bank is
that the Thai aggregate real wage rate declined by 7.8 percent due to the
crisis.
In our judgment, these individual biases and their combined impact on
the estimated decline in real wage rates due to the crisis are NOT small
differences that should be relegated to a footnote in a country evaluation of
the impact of the crisis. Such differences might significantly affect how ana-
lysts think about the impact of the crisis and what policy responses seem
appropriate. Therefore, we claim that how one calculates the real wage rate
is important in the Thai case, and quite possibly in other cases.
Finally, the method that we use to obtain our preferred estimates also
permits us to investigate the frequent claim that the more vulnerable and
poorer members of the work force suffered the largest real wage declines in
the crisis: females, those with less schooling, and the young and the old. Our
examination of this question suggests that the usual characterization is par-
tially, but only partially, correct. Those who had limited schooling and the
young did experience relative declines in real wage rates. But so did those
with university schooling. And females and older wage earners experienced
relative increases in their real wages in comparison with others.
This chapter is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the previous
studies on what happened to aggregate Thai real wage rates due to the crisis,
with emphasis on World Bank (2000) because that is the most prominent
study and the one that is clearest about the procedures followed to obtain
the estimates. Section 3 presents estimates of the extent of the four biases
noted above in World Bank (2000) estimates for the Thai case, presents our
preferred estimates of the change in aggregate real wage rates due to the
financial crisis, and presents our estimates of what happened to real wage
rates for some of the more vulnerable workers. Section 4 concludes.
224 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
Studies by other authors on the impact of the crisis on Thai labor markets
have suggested – and in most cases stated explicitly – that wage rates fell
considerably in the immediate aftermath of the crisis, though in some cases
there is some ambiguity about whether wage rates or wage earnings are
being discussed. We begin by summarizing the results of World Bank
(2000) because, as noted, that is the most visible and the clearest on the
methodology used among the available studies. We then summarize more
briefly five other studies.
As noted in the introduction, the World Bank (2000) estimates that the Thai
real wage rate fell by 4.6 percent due to the crisis by subtracting the per-
centage change in the number of employed workers between the pre- and
post-crisis period from the percentage change in aggregate real wage earn-
ings between the pre- and post-crisis period. The pre-crisis period that is
used is the average over three Labor Force Survey (LFS) rounds prior to the
crisis (that is, the first and third quarters of 1996 and the first quarter of
1997). The post-crisis period that is used is the average over three survey
rounds after the initiation of the crisis (that is, the first and third quarters
of 1998 and the first quarter of 1999). Both periods cover five quarters, or
1.25 years, ending about six months before and starting about six months
after, respectively, the July 1997 date that is often referred to as the start of
the crisis period. For comparability, both are for the same duration and
both include the same combination of seasonal peak and slack LFSs.
Monthly wage earnings were calculated from wages reported for other
reporting periods (for example, hourly, daily, weekly) by multiplying by
standard factors that assume full-time work.3 Then other monetary
benefits were added and the resulting total monthly wage earnings were
deflated by the consumer price index (CPI) to obtain the total real monthly
wage earnings.
We summarize here more briefly several other studies. They all are based
on pre- and post-crisis comparisons with LFS data and they all convey the
impression that the empirical evidence suggests that Thai real wage rates
What really happened to Thai wage rates? 225
declined due to the crisis. But they present a range of estimates, refer to
somewhat different periods and in most cases are not very clear about their
procedures. So it is not possible to determine why they differ in some
respects from the World Bank (2000) estimates, nor whether they are
subject to some or all of the same biases.
We have questions, as we note above, about four aspects of the World Bank
(2000) estimates of real wage rate decline of 4.6 percent due to the crisis. In
this section we first consider each of these four aspects in turn and what
they imply for the estimated change in real wages. We then consider what
our estimates imply for what happened to the real wage rates for selected
‘more vulnerable’ groups.
3.1 Possible Biases in the World Bank (2000) Procedure and Our
Preferred Estimates of Aggregate Thai Real Wage Rate Changes
due to Crisis
The essence of the World Bank procedure about which we have questions
can be summarized as follows. The World Bank calculates the change in
real wage rates between the pre- and post-crisis periods as:
where Wmw is the real wage rate (with the superscript ‘w’ referring to the
World Bank 2000 estimate), Ym is the total real wage earnings based on all
wage earners (⫽ ⌺Yi, where i is summed over all wage recipients), Nm is the
total number of employees, and the subscript ‘m’ denotes means). Relation
(7.1) is consistent with the real wage rate being defined in each period as:
where Hm is the average hours worked per pay period by wage recipients, E
is the number of wage recipients in each period and ‘a’ is the ratio between
the number of wage recipients in each period E and the total number of
employees in that period N, and both Hm and a are assumed to be constant
across periods.
We argue that the best available estimate is to calculate for each period
the average wage rate for individuals who are observably the same as:5
where Wi is the real hourly wage rate for the i-th wage recipient that is cal-
culated by dividing real wage earnings Yi for each wage recipient by the
hours worked per pay period Hi for each wage recipient. We then calculate
the percentage change in Wm between the pre- and the post-crisis periods.
What really happened to Thai wage rates? 227
Before we turn to why we think that our procedure is preferable and the
empirical importance of each of the four differences between what we argue
is the preferred procedure and the procedure that the World Bank utilized,
we wish to emphasize that we are not disagreeing with a number of other
important aspects of the World Bank estimates – the definition of the pre-
and post-crisis periods, the use of the LFS and of particular rounds of the
LFS, the deflation procedure, the definition of real wage compensation, the
definition of wage recipients, the definition of who is employed – so we are
following exactly the same procedures as the World Bank with regard to all
these aspects of the estimates. Therefore, the differences on which we focus
below are NOT due to other differences in the calculations.
3.1.3 Average of wage rates across wage recipients with these individuals
weighted proportional to their hours worked
A more subtle difference between our preferred approach and that of the
World Bank is how individuals are weighted when wages or wage rates are
summed across individuals in relation (7.2) versus relation (7.3). The World
Bank effectively weights wage recipients proportionately to their hours
228 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
38 38
36 36
34 34
In 1994 baht per hour
32 32
30 30
28 28
26 26
24 24
22 22
20 20
18 18
88 3
88 1
89 3
89 1
90 3
90 1
91 3
91 1
92 3
92 1
93 3
93 1
94 3
94 1
95 3
95 1
96 3
96 1
97 3
97 1
98 3
98 1
99 3
99 1
3
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
19 -Q
-Q
87
19
Note: No first round was conducted by the NSO in 1990 causing a gap in the plotted
section.
before leaving wage employment because they were less productive regard-
ing observed characteristics such as schooling or unobserved characteris-
tics such as innate ability and motivation. If so, it is possible that mean
wage rates for those in wage employment in the post-crisis period increased,
even though the post-crisis wage rates for those who maintained wage
employment through both periods hardly changed or even declined.
Table 7.2 summarizes relevant data for all workers and for subcategories
defined by three characteristics of workers that are observed in the data and
that are not likely to change (or at least not change much) due to labor
market conditions: gender, age and schooling.8 The first column gives the
average wage rate for the indicated subgroup as a percentage of the national
average wage rate for the pre-crisis period. These data permit the charac-
terization of which types of workers received relatively high wage rates
before the crisis. The next two columns include the percentage changes
between the pre- and the post-crisis periods for wage employment and
hours worked in wage employment.
Examination of this table suggests that wage employment shifted rela-
tively from females to males, from younger to older workers, and from
lower-schooled to higher-schooled individuals. Each of these three
shifts was from lower to higher real wage rate categories.9 This suggests that
230 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
compositional changes may have been important and, because they involved
a shift from much lower wage rate categories to higher wage rate categories,
the failure to account for them in the World Bank estimates mean that the
estimated overall average real wage rate change is biased upwards.
Therefore, we obtain estimates that permit the control for changes in the
composition of wage recipients with respect to age, gender and schooling.
We estimate a ln real hourly wage rate equation, pooling individual data
from all six quarters covering the pre- and post-crisis periods. By construc-
tion, this approach does not have any of the first three problems in the
World Bank estimates that are discussed above. All coefficients of the wage
equation are allowed to vary across the pre- and post-crisis periods. Using
this equation, the actual change in real hourly ln wages (which would be the
percentage change in real hourly wages between the pre- and post-crisis
periods) can be decomposed into changes that might have occurred in the
absence of any compositional changes in wage employment and changes
What really happened to Thai wage rates? 231
Note: See Appendix 7A, Table 7A.1 for the estimates of the underlying ln wage equation.
change in the share of employees who were wage workers and of no change
in hours worked partially offset the biases due to the compositional shift
and the weighting by hours worked instead of by wage recipients. But even
with this serendipitous partial canceling of different biases, the estimate as
presented in World Bank (2000) understates by about 40 percent the real
wage rate decline that we obtain in our preferred estimate.
In summary, thus, our best estimate of how much real hourly wage rates
would have declined had there been no change in the composition of wage
recipients is 7.8 percent. Of course if the composition changed in terms of
unobserved variables, such as ability and motivation, in the same way that
it changed in terms of observable variables, such as schooling, as is sug-
gested by some micro empirical estimates for other countries, the true
decline for the same individuals controlling also for these unobserved
factors would have been greater than 7.8 percent.
3.2 Who Fared Relatively Poorly in Terms of Real Wage Rate Changes?
Many have claimed that the poorer and more vulnerable workers – females,
low-schooled, the young and the old – suffered most in the crisis (for
example, Horton and Mazumdar, 1999; Kittiprapas, 1999; Kittiprapas and
Intaravitak, 2000; Knowles et al., 1999; Pongsapich and Brimble, 1999;
Sussangkarn et al., 1999). The compositional shifts in wage employment
described near the end of section 3.1 are generally consistent with that
claim. But that does not necessarily mean that the poorer and most vul-
nerable suffered the largest relative real wage rate declines.
Table 7.4 presents some evidence on this question with reference to
gender, age and schooling. The first column gives the percentage change
between the pre- and post-crisis periods in real wage rates. The second and
third columns give regression estimates from the pooled data described for
the decomposition in section 3.1 (and presented in Appendix 7A, Table
7A.1) for the interaction between the post-crisis dummy variable and
gender, age and schooling (all relative, again, to males younger than 20 with
less than complete primary schooling). Column 2 includes coefficient esti-
mates for all of these characteristics; column 3 includes only those charac-
teristics that have statistically significant coefficient estimates at least at the
10 percent level in column 2.
The percentage changes in real hourly wage compensation rates in the
first column of Table 7.4 suggest that some of the groups that are often
characterized as ‘more vulnerable’ did fare relatively badly in terms of wage
rate changes. In particular, youth fared worse than prime-age adults. On the
other hand, some of the groups usually characterized as more vulnerable
fared relatively well: those with primary or less schooling (as well as those
What really happened to Thai wage rates? 233
Table 7.4 Percentage changes in real wage rates and coefficient estimates
for interactions between crisis dummy variable and different
groups in pooled real wage regression
Notes: * Calculations from the LFS data tapes. Changes are defined between the period
before the crisis (first quarter of 1996, third quarter of 1996 and first quarter of 1997) to a
comparable period after the initiation of the crises (first quarter of 1998, third quarter of
1998, first quarter of 1999). Real hourly wage rate includes cash wages plus monetary
benefits, adjusted for the CPI, per hours worked. The second and third columns are from
regressions 2 and 3 in Appendix 7A, Table 7A.1. * implies significantly non-zero at least at
the 10 percent level. B means that included in reference group in bottom row.
with vocational schooling) had smaller declines than those with secondary
or university schooling, females had larger increases than males, and older
adults had much larger increases than any other age group. The first
column gives the gross associations without controlling for other charac-
teristics. The second and third columns give the changes for various groups
with multivariate controls for other changes. These multivariate estimates
again suggest that some of the more vulnerable groups fared relatively
poorly. Based on column 3, males under 20 years of age with less than
primary schooling had significant declines of 13.3 percent in wage rates.
234 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
But females had significantly greater increases than males by 3.0 percent-
age points and older adults had significantly and substantially greater
increases than any other age group. The only other significant effect is that
those with university schooling had declines that were 5.5 percentage points
greater than the declines experienced by the reference group (those with less
than completed primary school).
3 CONCLUSIONS
partially offsetting, the severity of the impact of the crisis on declines in the
real wage rate is underestimated by 3.2 percentage points or by over 40
percent even if the added problem of unobservables is ignored. In order to
understand the impact of such crises and to inform policy-makers and
other interested parties, it is important that the informational basis and the
methodologies for estimating real wage rate changes are improved.
The best solution would be for longitudinal labor force data to be col-
lected as a matter of routine so that comparisons could be made of the
wage rates for the same individuals over time, thereby controlling for all
individual unobserved as well as observed characteristics. Such data are
collected in Labor Force Surveys for some developing countries (for
example, Brazil has a rolling panel), but not many. Until such longitudinal
surveys are available in other cases, a second-best solution is to follow the
methods in this chapter, particularly with regard to controlling for compo-
sitional changes with respect to observed characteristics such as age, gender
and schooling. An added by-product of such an approach is estimates of
the extent to which different groups identified by such characteristics fared
relatively poorly – which in the present case gives some, but limited, support
to the widely-held understanding that the more vulnerable fared worse –
and, in fact, females and older adults fared relatively well, while highly edu-
cated individuals fared relatively poorly.
NOTES
* This chapter builds upon work in Behrman et al. (2000) that was prepared for the World
Bank by the Thailand Development Research Institute (TDRI). The authors alone – and
not TDRI nor the World Bank – are responsible for all interpretations in this chapter.
The authors thank Dr Worawan Chandoevwit and Mr Rangsiman Kingkaew for
research and computational assistance on this project.
1. In 1997 speculation on currency devaluation intensified, official foreign reserves were
rapidly depleted, the currency was subsequently allowed to float and devalued consider-
ably, and over half of the finance companies were closed. The annual growth rate in real
GDP per capita declined to –2.3 percent in 1997 and to –11.4 percent for 1998 from
4.8 percent for 1996 and from an average of 7.2 percent for 1990–95. Real GDP per capita
relative to the underlying secular growth trend for the 1990s fell (from the peak in 1996)
by 5.2 percent in 1997, 20.2 percent in 1998, and 20.5 percent in 1999 (based on the data
for the 1990s as presented in Behrman and Tinakorn, 2000, Table 8; these estimates focus
on how much real GDP per capita differs from the secular trend each year, and, because
this secular trend is positive, incorporate the secular growth not realized in addition to
any decline in measured real GDP per capita; see also Kakwani and Pothong, 1998).
2. To avoid long and perhaps awkward terminology, the ‘post-crisis period’ is used here and
throughout this study to refer to what is really the ‘post-initiation-of-the-crisis period’
and not the period subsequent to the recovery from the crisis. That is, comparisons are
made between average real wage rates for three labor force surveys prior to the initiation
of the crisis in mid-1997 and for three labor force surveys subsequent to the initiation of
the crisis in mid-1997 (see section 2.1 below).
236 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
3. Specifically, hourly wages were multiplied by 208 work hours per month, daily wages
were multiplied by 26 days per month, and weekly wages were multiplied by 4.2 weeks
per month.
4. The source is given as ILO (1999), ‘Country Employment Policy Review for Thailand’.
Given that inflation was positive (5.6 percent in 1997 and 8.1 percent in 1998 according
to the CPI based on data from the Bank of Thailand, see Behrman et al. (2000, Table 2),
it is not clear how the real drop in percentage terms can be less than, rather than greater
than, the nominal drop in percentage terms.
5. As is standard in the literature, this procedure is using the average real wage per hour for
each wage recipient rather than the marginal real wage rate per hour. The latter concep-
tually is preferable at least for some uses, but it is not clear how to calculate the marginal
real wage rate per hour with information that is generally available in Labor Force
Surveys.
6. The 1997 third-quarter real wage rate was strikingly high: 23.5 percent above the post-
crisis average and 38.2 percent above the pre-crisis average. It should be emphasized,
however, that if there is some anomaly for the 1997 third-quarter report, that does not
affect our, nor the World Bank’s (2000), pre–post comparisons because that period is not
used for these comparisons.
7. The real wage rates declined between rounds within the post-crisis period: by 14.1
percent from 1997-Q3 to 1998-Q1, by 2.8 percent from 1998-Q1 to 1998-Q3, and by 7.7
percent from 1998-Q3 to 1999-Q1.
8. Schooling may be affected a little by labor market conditions for those near the margin
of ending their schooling, but not much for older individuals in the prime working age
ranges. We do not include in this table characteristics such as location, migration status,
work status and occupation because these are likely to be affected by current and recent
labor market conditions.
9. The third column indicates a further shift in average hours worked per worker in wage
employment by schooling levels that reinforces this tendency, though no such shift in
hours worked per wage worker by gender and a small partially offsetting shift in hours
worked per wage worker by age groups. This shift in hours worked does not affect the
estimate of the change in real wage rates if each wage recipient is weighted equally as we
argue is preferable. But it affects the estimate if wage recipients are weighted by hours
worked as in World Bank (2000).
10. This type of decomposition is different in some basic respects from the racial and gender
decompositions of wage differentials along the lines pioneered by Oaxaca (1973) and
Blinder (1973) and subsequently extended and refined by others such as Jones (1983),
Cotton (1988) and Neumark (1988). In the Oaxaca–Blinder tradition, for example, the
comparison is between two exclusive groups at the same point of time (not two overlap-
ping groups in different time periods as in our case) and it makes a difference whether
the estimates for one group or the other is used as the base for making the decomposi-
tion. Not only does the decomposition change depending on which estimates are used,
but in the counterfactual in which ‘discrimination’ was changed, the relevant coefficients
might change. In the present case we are merely describing the changes from the pre-
crisis to the post-crisis periods, not attempting to indicate what would happen with
movement in the opposite direction or with some counterfactual. Our procedure is
equivalent, of course, to estimating separate ln real wage rate relations for the pre- and
post-crisis period and comparing the coefficient estimates.
11. On the other hand, had real wage rates for every population subgroup remained
unchanged during the crisis, the observed average wage rate would still have shown an
increase of 9.7 percent. Most of this increase (8.2 out of 9.7, or 85 percent) would have
occurred because of a shift in wage employment from lower-schooled to university-
educated individuals (who typically earn substantially more). The difference between the
increase of 9.7 percent (with only real wage rates unchanged) and the decline of 7.8
percent (with only the composition changed) is basically the same as the 2.0 percent
increase with no concern about composition and with the other three adjustments in
place.
What really happened to Thai wage rates? 237
REFERENCES
Behrman, Jere R. and Pranee Tinakorn (2000), ‘The Surprisingly Limited Impact
of the Thai Crisis on Labor, Including on Many Allegedly “More Vulnerable”
Workers’, Indian Journal of Labour Economics, 43 (3) (October), 513–44.
Behrman, Jere R., Anil B. Deolalikar and Pranee Tinakorn with Worawan
Chandoevwit (2000), The Effects of the Thai Economic Crisis and of Thai Labor
Market Policies on Labor Market Outcomes, Bangkok: Thailand Development
Research Institute.
Betcherman, G. and R. Islam (2000), ‘East Asian Labor Markets and the Crisis:
Impacts, Responses, and Lessons’, Synthesis paper prepared for the World
Bank/ILO/Japanese Ministry of Labor/Japan Institute of Labor seminar on The
Economic Crisis, Employment, and the Labor Market in East and South-East
Asia, Tokyo, February.
Blinder, Alan (1973), ‘Wage Discrimination: Reduced Form and Structural
Estimates’, Journal of Human Resources, 8 (Fall), 436–55.
Cotton, Jeremiah (1988), ‘On the Decomposition of Wage Differentials’, The
Review of Economics and Statistics, 70 (2), 236–43.
Fallon, Peter R. and Robert E.B. Lucas (2000), ‘The Impact of Financial Crises on
Labor Markets, Household Incomes and Poverty: A Review of the Evidence’,
Discussion Paper Number 103, Boston: Boston University, Institute for Economic
Development.
Horton, S. and D. Mazumdar (1999), ‘Vulnerable Groups and the Labor Market:
The Aftermath of the Asian Financial Crisis’, Paper prepared for the World
Bank/ILO/Japanese Ministry of Labor/Japan Institute of Labor Seminar on
Economic Crisis, Employment, and the Labor Market in East and South-east
Asia, Tokyo, November.
Jones, F.L. (1983), ‘On Decomposing the Wage Gap: A Critical Comment on
Blinder’s Method’, Journal of Human Resources, 18 (1), 126–30.
Kakwani, N. (1998), ‘Impact of Economic Crisis on Employment, Unemployment
and Real Income’, Bangkok: National Economic and Social Development
Board, mimeo.
Kakwani, N. and Jaroenjit Pothong (1998), ‘Impact of Economic Crisis on the
Standard of Living in Thailand’, Indicators of Well-Being and Policy Analysis, 2
(4) (October), 1–20.
Kittiprapas, Sauwalak (1999), ‘Social Impacts of Thai Economic Crisis’, in
Chalongphob Sussangkarn, Frank Flatters and Sauwalak Kittiprapas (eds),
Social Impacts of the Asian Economic Crisis in Thailand, Indonesia, Malaysia and
the Philippines, Bangkok: Thailand Development Research Institute.
Kittiprapas, Sauwalak and Chedtha Intaravitak (2000), ‘Social Responses to
Economic Crisis: Some Evidence during 1997–99 of Thai Crisis’, Bangkok:
Thailand Development Research Institute, mimeo.
Knowles, James C., Ernesto M. Pernia and Mary Racelis (1999), ‘Social
Consequences of the Financial Crisis in Asia: The Deeper Crisis’, Manila: Asian
Development Bank, mimeo.
Mahmoud, Moazam and Gosah Aryah (1999), ‘An Appraisal of the Labor Market
in the Context of the Macro Economy: Growth, Crisis and Competitiveness’,
Country paper prepared for the World Bank/ILO/Japanese Ministry of
Labor/Japan Institute of Labor seminar on The Economic Crisis, Employment,
and the Labor Market in East and South-East Asia, Tokyo, 13–15 October.
238 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
Table 7A.1 Estimated real hourly ln wage functions, using pooled data for six quarters (1Q96, 3Q96, 1Q97, 1Q98,
3Q98 and 1Q99)
Whether aged 24–49 years 0.374 50.3 0.354 36.2 0.350 12.6 0.642 0.677
Whether aged 50 years and over 0.571 47.7 0.498 30.1 0.495 15.3 0.095 0.099
Dummy for post-crisis period ⫺0.078 ⫺18.6 ⫺0.146 ⫺6.2 ⫺0.133 ⫺5.9 0 1
Crisis ⫻ Female 0.030 3.5 0.030 1.9
Crisis ⫻ Primary schooling 0.027 1.4
Crisis ⫻ Secondary schooling 0.006 0.3
Crisis ⫻ Vocational education 0.025 1.0
Crisis ⫻ University education ⫺0.033 ⫺1.7 ⫺0.055 ⫺8.5
Crisis ⫻ 20–24 years ⫺0.010 ⫺0.6
Crisis ⫻ 24–49 years 0.046 3.1 0.055 9.6
Crisis ⫻ 50 years and over 0.153 6.4 0.161 17.7
Intercept 2.372 198.6 2.403 144.7 2.397 316.1
Mean of dependent variable 3.269 3.289
R-square 0.505 0.506 0.506
F-statistic 8179 4371 17 570
Number of observations 223 484 223 484 223 484
8. Exchange rate or wage changes in
international adjustment? Japan and
China versus the United States
Ronald I. McKinnon1
Seldom have the pages of the financial press in Europe and America been
so full of grave editorializing on the need for a major depreciation of the
dollar to correct the ‘unsustainable’ current account and trade deficits of
the United States. Much of this international moralizing directs the high-
growth East Asian countries to stop pegging their currencies to the dollar –
or, in China’s case, to allow a large appreciation of the renminbi before
moving to unrestricted floating. The critics’ message has two facets.
First, in order to reduce East Asia’s large trade surpluses and thereby
reduce America’s even larger trade deficit, US and European critics suggest
that Asian governments should let their currencies appreciate discretely
against the dollar. For example, Fred Bergsten, Morris Goldstein, Nicholas
Lardy and Michael Mussa from the Institute for International Economics
(IIE) in Washington DC, all suggest that an immediate 20 to 25 percent
appreciation of the renminbi is warranted (Bergsten et al., 2005). However,
they provide no suitable conceptual model – let alone econometric evi-
dence – that this would significantly reduce China’s trade surplus with the
United States.
Second, because of the very high ongoing productivity growth in some
East Asian countries (notably China) relative to that in the United States
and Europe, critics contend that subsequent continual appreciation of the
renminbi (couched in terms of making its exchange rate more flexible) may
also be required to balance fairly international competitiveness. And many
outside critics see ‘smooth’ ongoing upward adjustments in the renminbi to
be best obtained by China’s government eventually allowing its currency to
float freely – instead of intervening heavily to hold it down as is now the case.
In this chapter, I contend that these critics are wrong in both respects.
Their ‘conventional wisdom’ is based on faulty, although unfortunately
widely accepted, theorizing that fails to come to grips with how the inter-
national dollar standard works.
240
Exchange rate or wage changes in international adjustment? 241
At least some of the critics of Asian countries’ pegging to the dollar would
agree that low saving in the United States, rather than misaligned exchange
rates, is the root cause of the trade imbalance. However, suppose a country
with very high productivity growth such as China trades with countries
with much lower productivity growth. In the new millennium, Japan and
Europe have overall trade surpluses, and the United States has an overall
trade deficit. But all of these more mature industrial countries have much
lower productivity growth than China’s. Isn’t exchange rate flexibility with
ongoing appreciation of the renminbi more or less necessary to balance
international competitiveness by offsetting the productivity differential
between China and its slower growing trading partners? Indeed, because of
foreign unease, China has promised that the yuan/dollar exchange rate will
become more flexible in the future.
As long as the American price level remains stable, more flexibility in the
central exchange rate of 8.28 yuan per dollar is neither necessary nor desir-
able for balancing international competitiveness with China’s neighbors in
the long run. International adjustment occurs by money wages naturally
growing faster in the country with higher productivity growth. But this
mechanism of differential wage adjustment, with more rapid wage growth in
China than the United States, only works well when enterprises and workers
in China are confident that the central rate will remain fixed indefinitely, and
China’s inflation remains more or less aligned with that in the United States.
Then Chinese employers in the rapidly growing tradables sectors, largely
manufacturing, will vigorously bid for workers subject to the constraint of
having to remain internationally competitive at the fixed nominal exchange
rate. Money wages, particularly for the increasingly skilled workers, then rise
in line with the high-productivity growth. Similar wage growth than spreads
out through the rest of the economy, including non-tradable services.
In the 1950s and 1960s under the Bretton Woods system of fixed dollar
exchange rates, how differential wage growth became the principal mode of
international adjustment was first articulated for high-growth Scandinavia
when the Swedish, Norwegian and Danish currencies were all pegged to the
244 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
dollar. But very high productivity growth in post-war Japan relative to the
United States, when the yen/dollar rate was also convincingly fixed, pro-
vides an equally striking example of what is now known as the
‘Scandinavian Model’ of wage adjustment (Lindbeck, 1979).
When the yen was fixed at 360 to the dollar from 1950 to 1971, the import-
ance of relative wage adjustment between Japan and the United States was
pronounced. Table 8.1 gives the summary statistics for this remarkable era
of very high Japanese growth in comparison to those of the wealthier, and
consequently more slowly growing, United States. From 1950 to 1971,
Japan’s annual growth in real output was 9.45 percent while industrial
production grew an even more astonishing 14.56 percent per year.
Unsurprisingly, the annual growth in Japanese labor productivity of 8.92
percent was far in excess of the 2.55 percent in the United States. However,
the balancing item was that average money wages grew at a robust rate of
10 percent per year in Japan and only 4.5 percent in the US. Figure 8.1
shows the dramatic rise of Japanese money wages relative to American
wages under the Bretton Woods system of fixed dollar exchange rates.
Table 8.1 Key economic indicators for Japan and the United States,
1950–71 (average annual percentage change)
Notes:
a1952–71.
b1953–71.
c1951–71.
600
500
Index
400
245
300
200
100
195019511952195319541955 1956195719581959196019611962196319641965196619671968196919701971
Figure 8.1 Nominal manufacturing wage growth for US and Japan: 1950–71 (base year 1950 ⫽ 100)
246 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
Keeping the yen at 360 per dollar effectively anchored Japan’s price level
for tradable goods. In the 1950s and 1960s, the Japanese wholesale price
index (WPI) rose less than 1 percent per year whereas the American WPI
rose a bit more than 1 percent (Table 8.1). Because the bulk of world trade
was invoiced in dollars, fixing an exchange rate to the dollar was (is) a
stronger anchor for the price level than the size of Japanese bilateral trade
with the United States would suggest.
Employers in Japan’s manufacturing export sector, with its extremely
high growth in labor productivity, then bid vigorously for both skilled and
unskilled workers subject to remaining internationally competitive at the
fixed exchange rate. Wages rose rapidly in manufacturing so that workers
received the main fruits from the productivity growth there. But then, as in
the Scandinavian Model, these high wage settlements spread into the rest
of the economy, such as in non-tradable services, where productivity
growth was much lower. The result was that, within Japan, the price of ser-
vices rose relative to goods prices. For 1950–71, Table 8.1 shows that Japan’s
CPI, which includes services as well as goods, began to increase much faster
at 5 percent per year than its WPI, which contains only goods. But Japan’s
international competitiveness in its high-growth tradables sector remained
balanced with the United States.
In Japan’s bygone high-growth era, fashioning a purely domestic mone-
tary anchor would have been more difficult. As in China today, restrictions
on domestic interest rates proliferated; and the rate of growth in narrow
money was high and unpredictable – more than 16 percent per year from
1950 to 1971 as Japanese households rebuilt their financial assets after the
war. Thus having the Bank of Japan simply key on the dollar exchange rate
was the most convenient instrument for stabilizing Japan’s tradable goods
price level while promoting high growth in money wages.
By the end of the 1960s, however, American monetary policy became too
inflationary. The loss of America’s foreign competitiveness was too great
for the Bretton Woods system of fixed dollar exchange parities to survive.
President Nixon had to choose between disinflating at home and thus main-
taining the fixed rate system, or forcing a devaluation of the dollar against
other major currencies while continuing to inflate. He chose to devalue in
August 1971, and the United States suffered the great inflation of the 1970s.
Unlike Japan, China has kept its exchange rate stable since 1994 – and did
not have the earlier misfortune of being pushed into a deflationary slump
from an appreciating currency. Table 8.2 provides the key summary stat-
istics comparing China to the United States. From 1994 through 2003,
money wages in manufacturing increased by about 13 percent in China and
by just 3 percent in the United States. This ten percentage-point wage-
growth differential approximately reflected the differential growth of labor
productivity: about 12.3 percent in China5 versus 2.7 percent in the United
States since 1994. Under the fixed yuan/dollar exchange rate, the appropri-
ate wage-adjustment mechanism for balancing international competitive-
ness seems to be alive and well.
Figure 8.3 shows China’s dramatically higher growth in money wages in
manufacturing relative to the United States over the past decade. Within
China, Figure 8.4 shows that wages in all sectors were rising fast – with wage
growth in manufacturing about the median for the economy as a whole.
20 380
Wage differential
Inflation differential
15 Yen/dollar
300
10
220
Yen/dollar
Percent
5
248
140
0
50
53
56
59
62
65
68
71
74
77
80
83
86
89
92
95
98
01
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
60
–5
–10 –20
Note: Positive values indicate higher inflation and higher wage increases in Japan.
Figure 8.2 Inflation and wage differential between Japan and US, and yen/dollar rate, 1950 to 2004
Exchange rate or wage changes in international adjustment? 249
Table 8.2 Key economic indicators for China and the United States,
1994–2003 (average annual percentage change)
Notes:
a Ex-factory price index.
b 2003 data on manufacturing wages are projected from overall average wages from
1997–2003.
c 1994–2002.
d 1994–2001. Zhang and Tan (2004).
e 1994–2002. R. Fernholz (2004).
Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics CD-ROM, Nov. 2004, unless otherwise
noted. Chinese CPI, manufacturing wage data, labor productivity data, real income data
and wholesale price data are from China Statistical Yearbook, 2004. Labor productivity data
for the US are obtained from the index for the non-farm business sector as reported by the
Bureau of Labor Statistics. The China labor productivity data refer only to the industrial
sector.
Much of this reflects the upgrading of skills and greater work experience
of the labor force. True, at the margin, the wages of unskilled migrant
workers may be lagging – and many of these seem to be absorbed into con-
struction activities where average wages show the slowest rate of growth in
Figure 8.4.
China’s exchange rate stabilization in 1994 followed a major depreciation
of the renminbi associated with the unification of the official exchange
rate at the much higher ‘free-market’ swap rate. Figure 8.5 shows that the
official rate jumped from 5.5 to 8.7 yuan per dollar. Because much of
China’s trade – particularly in manufacturing – had been transacted at the
higher swap rate, this jump in the official rate overstates the effective deval-
uation. Nevertheless, because of a temporary burst of domestic inflation
from 1993 to 1996 as shown in Figures 8.5 and 8.6, the ‘real’ devaluation was
negligible. But the nominal devaluation certainly exacerbated the inflation.
By 1996, the renminbi had appreciated slightly to 8.28 to the dollar where it
remained until 2005. Chinese price inflation then settled down after 1996
and seems have converged close to the American level. In 2004, China’s CPI
350
China
USA
300
250
Index
250
200
150
100
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
Source: IMF: IFS; Chinese manufacturing wage data are obtained from China Statistical Yearbook, 2004.
Figure 8.3 Nominal manufacturing wage growth for US and China, 1994–2003 (base year 1994 ⫽ 100)
300
280
260
240
Farm
Mine
220
Mfg
Index
200 ElecGas
Const
251
180 Trans
Retail
160 SocServ
140
120
100
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
Figure 8.4 China: nominal wages across different sectors, 1994–2002 (base year 1994 ⫽ 100)
30 10
25 Yuan/USD Exchange
Rate 9
(RHS)
20
8
15
Percent
10 7
CPI Inflation Differential:
China–US
252
(LHS)
5
6
0
1993M1 1994M1 1995M1 1996M1 1997M1 1998M1 1999M1 2000M1 2001M1 2002M1 2003M1 2004M1
5
–5
–10 4
Note: M1 ⫽ January.
Source: EIU.
130
125
USA CPI
China WPI
115
253
USA WPI
110
105
100
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
Source: IMF: IFS; Chinese ex-factory price data are obtained from China Statistical Yearbook, 2004.
rose 3.8 percent while that in the United States rose 3.3 percent. The fixed
rate regime served China as a nominal anchor for its price level much like
the fixed yen/dollar rate served Japan in the 1950s and 1960s.
One might argue that, in 2004, inflation was too high in both China and
the United States. But under the international dollar standard, only the
center country can exercise monetary policy independently. Thus the onus
is on the United States to disinflate. Fortunately, in 2005 and 2006, the
Federal Reserve was committed to steadily increasing short-term interest
rates back to more normal levels after its unprecedented monetary easing
(low federal funds rates) in 2003 and 2004. Thus, inflation should calm
down in both countries. China should have less trouble with inflows of ‘hot’
money, and even less trouble if outside commentators and government
officials stop talking about the ‘need’ to appreciate the RMB.
More generally for the increasingly integrated East Asian economies,
China’s fix at 8.28 yuan per dollar became the key to intra East Asian
exchange stability in the new millennium. All the others more or less peg to
the dollar and thus to each other. If this fixed rate system continues, adjust-
ment in relative wage growth in the other East Asian economies becomes
the main vehicle for balancing international competitiveness.
In the context of the old Scandinavian model of wage adjustment,
Table 8.3 below compares the 1950–71 Japanese and 1994–2005 Chinese
experiences under fixed dollar exchange rates (the first row) with the post-
1971 Japanese experience with a floating and erratically appreciating yen
(the second row).
Under a fixed dollar exchange rate, the system converges to relative pur-
chasing power parity (PPP): the rate of inflation in tradables in the peripheral
country converges to that in the center country. Subject to the fixed exchange
rate constraint, wage bargaining is determinate in the sense that employers
bid up money wages to reflect fully the growth of labor productivity in the
rapidly growing export sector. International competitiveness is balanced.
Under a floating rate that moves randomly or is hectored into appreciat-
ing as with the Japanese yen from 1971 to 1995, bargaining over money
Partly responding to foreign pressure but also because China could benefit
from a more open foreign exchange market with decentralized transacting,
it is important to pin down what the Chinese government should mean by
greater foreign exchange ‘flexibility’. This involves both the pace of liber-
alizing and rationalizing of capital controls (relaxing administrative con-
straints on foreign exchange transacting) and the optimal degree of
flexibility in the exchange rate itself. Let us discuss each in turn.
In one respect China has been, and remains, very open to foreign capital
flows. Inward foreign direct investment (FDI) at over US$40 billion per
year since 2000 has been higher than China’s multilateral trade surplus of
about 3 percent of GDP. FDI has been an important vehicle for introduc-
ing the modern technology underlying China’s rapid industrial transfor-
mation. It has also been a major contributor to the build up of China’s
256 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
liquid dollar assets, both held privately and increasingly as official exchange
reserves – about US$660 billion as of March 2005. And outward FDI may
be beginning in a significant way, as with Lenovo’s purchase of IBM’s PC
division in 2005, and with large numbers of less publicized investments in
African infrastructure projects.
However, there are two distortions in official Chinese policy that unduly
amplify the financial magnitudes of inward FDI. First, the tax treatment
of foreigners investing in China, particularly in special economic zones, is
still more favorable than that accorded domestic investment – although
much equalization has occurred. While entirely rational at the beginning of
China’s opening to international trade in the 1980s, such favoritism for
foreign FDI is now counterproductive for encouraging domestic entrepre-
neurship. The second distortion is to limit foreign firms borrowing from
domestic Chinese banks to help fund their operations in China. China
wants and needs foreign technical expertise, but with its high domestic
saving, it does not need foreign finance. Thus allowing foreign firms to
borrow domestically would reduce unwanted financial inflows.
In foreign trade more generally, China has followed, and is following, the
optimal order of (gradual) economic liberalization (McKinnon, 1993). In
the mid-1990s, China consolidated its exchange rate system and achieved
full current account convertibility for the renminbi in the sense of satisfy-
ing the IMF’s Article VIII. In the new millennium, China is rapidly satis-
fying its WTO obligations by eliminating quota restrictions and drastically
cutting tariffs. On capital account, it has liberalized relatively illiquid
FDI flows before eliminating restrictions on shorter-term and more liquid
financial flows. All this is according to what is now received textbook
theory.
But this last stage, that of liberalizing liquid international financial flows,
which can all too easily become ‘hot’ money, is best done very carefully in
conjunction with an appropriate regulatory framework – or not at all. The
most important principle is to contain (latent) moral hazard in financial
institutions, implicitly or explicitly insured by the Chinese government, by
limiting their ability to assume risk. In particular, undue foreign exchange
exposure in banks and other financial institutions can imperil both them-
selves and the economy. And foreign financial institutions should always be
subject to the same stringent regulatory constraints as domestic ones.
What is the best way to proceed with this delicate last stage in the liberal-
ization process? One way is to assign foreign exchange trading exclusively
to authorized banks that must keep their exposure in any foreign currency
against renminbi within well defined limits. The State Administration
for Foreign Exchange (SAFE) would then continuously monitor the net
foreign exchange positions of these authorized banks relative to their
Exchange rate or wage changes in international adjustment? 257
NOTES
1. I would like to thank Hong Qiao and Ricardo Fernholz of Stanford University, and
Gunther Schnabl of the University of Tubingen, for their great help in preparing this
chapter.
2. In dollar debtor countries facing the threat of having their currencies depreciate
against the dollar, the negative wealth effect tends to reinforce the relative price effect
of an actual devaluation. Their trade balances could improve sharply from devaluation
as domestic consumption (and imports) slumps even as their now cheaper exports
expand into world markets. This was the case for Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia,
Philippines and Thailand after the great Asian Crisis of 1997–98. Their current
accounts went from being sharply negative before the crisis to positive immediately
afterwards.
3. In a provocative paper, Ben Bernanke (2005) argues that the problem is more one of excess
saving in other countries, particularly in Asia, than a saving deficiency in the United
States. Either way, however, this international saving imbalance cannot be corrected by
exchange rate changes.
4. As discussed in detail in Chapter 4 of McKinnon and Ohno (1997).
5. This estimate of productivity growth is not official, and was taken from Zhang and Tan
(2004). In both countries, how best to measure labor productivity growth is controversial.
Estimates for China can vary.
6. I am greatly indebted to Ms Hong Qiao for pointing out this interesting parallel between
a negative foreign exchange risk premium in domestic interest rates and in bargaining over
growth in domestic money wages.
REFERENCES
Bergsten, C. Fred, and the Institute for International Economics (2005), The
United States and the World Economy, Institute for International Economics,
Washington DC.
Bernanke, Ben (2005), ‘The Global Saving Glut and the US Current Account
Deficit’, At the Sandridge Lecture, Virginia Association of Economics,
Richmond, Virginia, 10 March.
Exchange rate or wage changes in international adjustment? 259
INTRODUCTION
Much discussion has taken place during the past two or three years con-
cerning China’s growth rate, often dealing with the appraisal of statistical
reliability and possible bias in the published figures. This discussion
has taken place during a period when many people have seen for them-
selves the unfolding of a Chinese expansion that has been almost unbe-
lievable in the speed, scope and depth of movement of the largest
economy in the world, measured in terms of population. Most of the
scholarly discussion and publication has dealt with the unbelievable
numerical size and speed of the expansion, drawing the frequent conclu-
sion that the magnitudes are overstated.1 However, that is not the
appraisal that comes from some of the authors of this chapter, who used
quite different methods of measurement that seem to validate the impres-
sions formed by the non- (economic) professional visitors who have actu-
ally experienced what has been taking place since 1978, especially on a
year-after-year basis, so that the evolution of new developments are
clearly exposed and China’s stabilizing role in the crisis of 1997–98 is
properly understood.
The main purpose of this chapter is to examine a crucial part of the issue
at hand by concentrating on a neglected important part, namely, the rate of
price level change, that is, the inflation rate that is needed to convert the
nominal direct measures of GDP to real GDP. When it is claimed that
China’s GDP has roughly quadrupled between 1980 and 2000 or that the
national growth rate since reform in 1978 has been about 9 percent, the
statements implicitly mean GDP adjusted for inflation. There has been rela-
tively little attention paid to the evaluation of the price deflator used to
convert nominal into real values. In this chapter, we are going to argue that
260
Adjustment to China’s CPI-based inflation rate 261
the magnitude of inflation has been overstated, because it does not take
account of quality change or lifestyle change, in a broader sense.
It should be noted at the outset that the United States went through a
period of significant change in the measurement of the economy’s rate of
inflation when some leading economic officials and scholars decided that
the major price indexes for the US overstated the magnitudes. This was
undertaken by the Boskin Committee, who examined such things as
product quality, new products, place of purchase and other lifestyle fea-
tures.2 They concluded that the prevailing price indexes overstated US
inflation by approximately as much as one full percentage point and that
about half a point was due to quality improvement alone.
Without using the Boskin Committee’s methods of analysis, which are
not easily transferable to China because of unavailability of comparable
data, we are going to estimate an adjustment to China’s CPI by quite
different methods and determine how to estimate the real growth rate
of GDP.
The approach that we are using for China is through estimation of the
‘true’ economic cost of living index. During World War II, some British
economists challenged the government’s allowances for civilians, because
the officials did not allow for enforced substitution of rationed for unra-
tioned goods, thus lowering the quality of the available market basket.
Following that debate, one of the authors of this chapter helped to produce
a research paper in 1947 to show how one might specify an equation system
that could be estimated from available data. This system is known as the
linear expenditure system (LES).3
The relevance of the LES in the present context is that it provides a
readily computable equation system that can be determined from Chinese
data, and the formula for the ‘true’ cost of living for China for the period
under dispute can be calculated to see how much the inflation rate might
be lowered (and the growth rate correspondingly increased) for the
economy as a whole. It should be borne in mind that the US potential
growth rate, which used to be considered to be roughly 3 percent was
raised to 4 percent or more by the work of the Boskin Committee. If the
US can claim a higher rate of expansion by revising the price index, why
not make a similar revision for China? It is quite evident that the Chinese
economy has gone through a much faster and larger change in lifestyle
since 1978 than has the US economy. The diet is better; clothing is
immensely better; transportation is superior in many ways; retailing is
better; services are better; tourism is far better; and so on and so on. Given
these changes in living conditions, the economic goal for all progressive
societies, surely one should try to take these changes into account when
evaluating economic growth.
262 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
The LES equations are not unique, but just any comprehensive demand
system is not suitable – it should have some economic-theoretical proper-
ties. Of course it need not be linear, but this property can be tested. The the-
oretical basis for the LES is that it satisfies the following properties from
consumer theory:
n n
(pitqit ⫺ pit␥i ) ⫽ i (rt ⫺ 兺pjt␥j);兺
j⫽1 i
i ⫽ 1
⫽1
expenditure on the minimum total total minimum i ⫽marginal
i-the category subsistence income subsistence propensity to
expenditure expenditure consume
on the i-th on all out of
category categories supernumerary
income
1400
1200
800
600
400
264
200
0
1239.35 1359.87 1718.63 2041.67 1453.88 1985.88 3626.66 4905.77
Income (yuan p. a.)
Food Clothing
Household Facilities, Articles and Services Medicine and Medical Services
Transport, Post and Communication Services Education, Cultural and Recreation Services
Residence Miscellaneous Commodities and Services
Poor Lowest Low Lower Middle Middle Upper Middle High Highest
Income (yuan p. a) 1239.35 1359.87 1718.63 2041.67 1453.88 1985.88 3626.66 4905.77
Expenditure (yuan p. a) 1183.15 1261.36 1528.68 1770.17 2055.72 2404.13 2810.32 3533.49
Food 700.33 744.58 869.27 957.57 1064.65 1169.40 1284.57 1464.65
Clothing 127.01 142.50 195.79 246.43 303.32 367.20 418.16 492.62
Household Facilities, 60.00 66.51 94.42 120.06 163.10 220.27 314.16 446.75
Articles and Services
265
Medicine and Medical 36.02 36.05 41.92 50.09 53.59 61.52 74.58 100.34
Services
Transport, Post and 24.18 28.34 35.69 51.04 68.72 99.60 127.27 212.16
Communication Services
Education, Cultural and 101.43 113.29 136.40 158.43 182.91 221.37 256.21 356.23
Recreation Services
Residence 92.88 93.28 103.74 119.33 132.98 150.50 187.61 240.87
Miscellaneous Commodities 34.69 36.81 51.45 67.21 86.45 114.26 147.76 219.88
and Services
4500
4000
Expenditure (yuan p. a.)
3500
3000
2500
2000
1500
1000
500
266
0
4759.10 5153.91 6221.44 7064.18 4812.34 6275.38 11061.31 13834.27
Income (yuan p. a.)
Food Clothing
Household Facilities, Articles and Services Medicine and Medical Services
Transport, Post and Communication Services Education, Cultural and Recreation Services
Residence Miscellaneous Commodities and Services
Poor Lowest Low Lower Middle Middle Upper Middle High Highest
Size of family (persons) 3.84 3.79 3.62 3.46 3.31 3.16 3.05 2.82
Income (yuan p.a.) 4759.10 5153.91 6221.44 7064.18 4812.34 6275.38 11 061.31 13 834.27
Expenditure (yuan p.a.) 4543.30 4780.55 5533.82 6124.79 6804.43 7597.05 8571.48 9964.44
Food 2689.27 2821.96 3146.76 3313.19 3523.99 3695.30 3917.94 4130.31
Clothing 487.72 540.08 708.76 852.65 1003.99 1160.35 1275.39 1389.19
Household Facilities, 230.40 252.07 341.80 415.41 539.86 696.05 958.19 1259.84
267
2000
1000
500
268
0
1566.33 1734.57 2238.37 2721.15 3303.66 4079.07 5007.24 6837.81
Income (yuan p. a.)
Food Clothing
Household Facilities, Articles and Services Medicine and Medical Services
Transport, Post and Communication Services Education, Cultural and Recreation Services
Residence Miscellaneous Commodities and Services
Poor Lowest Low Lower Middle Middle Upper Middle High Highest
Income (yuan/p. a.) 1566.33 1734.57 2238.37 2721.15 3303.66 4079.07 5007.24 6837.81
Expenditure (yuan/p. a.) 1512.70 1644.56 2028.80 2351.56 2798.12 3252.70 3880.91 4799.83
Food 932.90 1005.76 1169.37 1305.41 1431.04 1563.81 1727.97 1921.61
Clothing 144.79 167.99 235.54 309.39 390.89 477.17 569.08 682.33
Household Facilities, 69.30 78.39 115.58 154.31 230.21 299.94 429.43 628.72
Articles and Services
269
Medicine and Medical 52.68 53.82 60.30 67.39 78.89 96.97 109.40 138.48
Services
Transport, Post and 31.80 39.60 63.00 83.15 121.98 161.78 227.7 319.40
Communication Services
Education, Cultural and 120.07 130.80 174.16 187.47 244.29 288.61 346.62 479.11
Recreation Services
Residence 116.18 121.54 143.23 161.58 183.24 211.41 259.70 335.98
Miscellaneous Commodities 44.99 46.65 67.62 82.85 117.58 153.01 210.95 294.21
and Services
6000
5000
3000
2000
1000
270
0
5920.73 6452.60 7990.98 92 24.70 10 836.00 12 889.86 15 071.79 19 214.25
Income (yuan p. a.)
Food Clothing
Household Facilities, Articles and Services Medicine and Medical Services
Transport, Post and Communication Services Education, Cultural and Recreation Services
Residence Miscellaneous Commodities and Services
Poor Lowest Low Lower Middle Middle Upper Middle High Highest
Size of family (persons) 3.78 3.72 3.57 3.39 3.28 3.16 3.01 2.81
Income (yuan p. a.) 5920.73 6452.60 7990.98 9224.70 10 836.00 12 889.86 15 071.79 19 214.25
Expenditure (yuan p. a.) 5718.01 6117.76 7242.82 7971.79 9177.83 10 278.53 11 681.54 13 487.52
Food 3526.36 3741.43 4174.65 4425.34 4693.81 4941.64 5201.19 5399.72
Clothing 547.31 624.92 840.88 1048.83 1282.12 1507.86 1712.93 1917.35
Household Facilities, 261.95 291.61 412.62 523.11 755.09 947.81 1292.58 1766.70
271
4000
3500
2500
2000
1500
1000
272
500
0
2063.95 2527.68 3833.01 5209.18 7061.37 9437.99 12555.07 20208.43
Income (yuan p. a.)
Food Clothing
Household Facilities, Articles and Services Medicine and Medical Services
Transport, Post and Communication Services Education, Cultural and Recreation Services
Residence Miscellaneous Commodities and Services
Poor Lowest Low Lower Middle Middle Upper Middle High Highest
Income (yuan p. a.) 2063.95 2527.68 3833.01 5209.18 7061.37 9437.99 12 555.07 20 208.43
Expenditure (yuan p. a.) 2079.52 2387.91 3259.59 4205.97 5452.94 6939.95 8919.94 13 040.69
Food 988.19 1127.41 1457.87 1772.88 2140.34 2596.95 3171.36 4100.79
Clothing 152.38 193.09 309.49 438.38 571.19 737.20 866.38 1103.16
Household Facilities, 71.49 86.69 144.67 226.42 331.54 460.99 645.72 1014.63
Articles and Services
273
Medicine and Medical 150.74 164.63 225.67 286.56 382.83 510.15 657.33 933.10
Services
Transport, Post and 126.34 157.64 257.63 367.72 505.78 718.92 991.17 1731.09
Communication Services
Education, Cultural and 280.53 317.57 425.33 576.71 797.52 1046.46 1373.85 2148.56
Recreation Services
Residence 261.45 282.74 355.12 421.90 563.31 643.15 906.67 1485.72
Miscellaneous Commodities 48.40 58.14 83.81 115.40 160.43 226.13 307.46 523.64
and Services
12000
8000
6000
4000
2000
274
0
7203.19 8669.94 12802.25 16669.38 21466.56 27464.55 34903.09 54158.59
Income (yuan p. a.)
Food Clothing
Household Facilities, Articles and Services Medicine and Medical Services
Transport, Post and Communication Services Education, Cultural and Recreation Services
Residence Miscellaneous Commodities and Services
Poor Lowest Low Lower Middle Middle Upper Middle High Highest
Size of family (persons) 3.49 3.43 3.34 3.2 3.04 2.91 2.78 2.68
Income (yuan p. a.) 7203.19 8669.94 12 802.25 16 669.38 21 466.56 27 464.55 34 903.09 54 158.59
Expenditure (yuan p. a.) 7257.52 8190.53 10 887.03 13 459.10 16 576.94 20 195.25 24 797.43 34 949.05
Food 3448.78 3867.02 4869.29 5673.22 6506.63 7557.12 8816.38 10 990.12
Clothing 531.81 662.30 1033.70 1402.82 1736.42 2145.25 2408.54 2956.47
Household Facilities, 249.50 297.35 483.20 724.54 1007.88 1341.48 1795.10 2719.21
275
1400
1000
800
600
400
276
200
0
1551.79 2288.34 3025.17 4075.60 7567.22
Income (yuan p. a.)
Food Clothing
Household Facilities, Articles and Services Medicine and Medical Services
Transport, Post and Communication Services Education, Cultural and Recreation Services
Residence Miscellaneous Commodities and Services
1400
1000
800
600
400
277
200
0
1551.79 2288.34 3025.17 4075.60 7567.22
Income (yuan p. a.)
Food Clothing
Household Facilities, Articles and Services Medicine and Medical Services
Transport, Post and Communication Services Education, Cultural and Recreation Services
Residence Miscellaneous Commodities and Services
Urban Rural
Per capita Household Per capita Household
Cost of living 4.55 4.56 3.96 3.42
CPI 5.47 5.47 5.13 5.13
r94
C ⌸
i⫽1
pi ⫺
i94 兺␥i pi94
i⫽1
r93 ⫽ 8 8
C ⌸ p ⫺ 兺 ␥i pi93
i
i93
i⫽1 i⫽1
CPI at 5.47 percent to be almost two percentage points higher than that of
the ‘true’ cost of living at 3.51 percent per capita and 3.52 percent family,
1993–2002, using the Engel curve for 2002 but re-basing the associated cost
of living index to 1993 (the initialization point for valuing the constant of
integration). These results are shown in Figures 9.9–9.14 and Tables
9.12–9.18. The larger spread for this validation-checking calculation would
imply a larger spread in the real growth rate of consumption.
Our procedures for estimating a bias in the consumer price index for
China lack some data series that would be needed in order to make a
definitive estimate of the increment to China’s economic growth rate, but
we can see that persistent overestimates of the price deflator for consump-
tion is indicated by our various approximations. We come to the conclusion
that one or two percentage points should be added to the growth rate.
Table 9.12 Cost of living and official CPI (urban, per capita, initialized at
1993, Engel curve at 2002)
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Average
Growth
Rate
CPI 1.00 1.25 1.46 1.59 1.64 1.63 1.61 1.62 1.63 1.61 5.47%
‘True’ 1.00 1.20 1.35 1.45 1.47 1.44 1.39 1.37 1.38 1.36 3.51%
cost of
living
1.70
1.60
1.50
Price index
1.40
1.30
1.20
1.10
CPI ‘True’ cost of living
1.00
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
Figure 9.9 Cost of living and official CPI (urban, per capita, initialized at
1993, Engel curve at 2002)
284 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
Table 9.13 Cost of living and official CPI (urban, family, initialized at
1993, Engel curve at 2002)
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Average
Growth
Rate
CPI 1.00 1.25 1.46 1.59 1.64 1.63 1.61 1.62 1.63 1.61 5.47%
‘True’ 1.00 1.20 1.35 1.44 1.46 1.44 1.39 1.37 1.38 1.36 3.52%
cost of
living
1.70
1.60
1.50
Price index
1.40
1.30
1.20
CPI ‘True’ cost of living
1.10
1.00
1993199419951996199719981999200020012002
Figure 9.10 Cost of living and official CPI (urban, family, initialized at
1993, Engel curve at 2002)
The linear expenditure system (LES) is, without doubt, a very special case
and, as Samuelson pointed out in 1947, not a general case of linearity,
such as in a first-order Taylor approximation. Yet the linear expenditure
system is not linear in unknown parameters nor in individual prices,
quantities, and income (total expenditures). Linearity depends on how the
non-stochastic specification is transformed and how stochastic properties
Adjustment to China’s CPI-based inflation rate 285
Table 9.14 Cost of living and official CPI (rural, per capita, initialized at
1993, Engel curve at 2002)
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Average
Growth
Rate
CPI 1.00 1.23 1.45 1.56 1.60 1.59 1.56 1.56 1.57 1.57 5.13%
‘True’ 1.00 1.20 1.37 1.46 1.49 1.47 1.43 1.41 1.42 1.42 3.96%
cost of
living
1.70
1.60
1.50
Price index
1.40
1.30
1.20
CPI ‘True’ cost of living
1.10
1.00
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
Figure 9.11 Cost of living and official CPI (rural, per capita, initialized at
1993, Engel curve at 2002)
Table 9.15 Cost of living and official CPI (rural, family, initialized at
1993, Engel curve at 2002)
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Average
Growth
Rate
CPI 1.00 1.23 1.45 1.56 1.60 1.59 1.56 1.56 1.57 1.57 5.13%
‘True’ 1.00 1.16 1.28 1.36 1.40 1.38 1.36 1.35 1.36 1.35 3.42%
cost of
living
1.70
1.60
1.50
Price index
1.40
1.30
1.20
1.10
1.00
93
95
97
99
01
19
19
19
19
20
Figure 9.12 Cost of living and official CPI (rural, family, initialized at
1993, Engel curve at 2002)
interesting application of LES. They started this analysis with the provoca-
tive question, ‘Are tastes the same the world round?’ This question is akin,
but not identical, to our preoccupation with measuring price changes in the
context of a constant level of utility over time. Their within-sample variation
comes from variability from country to country, while ours comes from vari-
ability from time period to time period within a given country – China. In
the Summers–Heston–Kravis study, expenditures (or consumption volumes,
in an aggregate sense) vary from country to country because incomes and
prices vary, while tastes are assumed to be fixed. They show that LES can be
written in three ways: (1) the dependent variable being expenditures, (2) the
dependent variable being quantity consumed, (3) the dependent variable
being budget share. They chose two forms (2) and (3), while we chose (1) for
our analysis. They used four demand categories (Food, Clothing, Shelter, All
others), while we chose eight demand categories.
Adjustment to China’s CPI-based inflation rate 287
Table 9.16 Cost of living and official CPI (urban, per capita, initialized
at 1993, Engel curve at 1993)
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Average
Growth
Rate
CPI 1.00 1.25 1.46 1.59 1.64 1.63 1.61 1.62 1.63 1.61 5.47%
‘True’ 1.00 1.25 1.46 1.58 1.60 1.57 1.52 1.50 1.50 1.49 4.55%
cost of
living
1.70
1.60
1.50
1.40
Price index
1.30
1.20
1.10
1.00
0.90 CPI ‘True’ cost of living
0.80
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
Figure 9.13 Cost of living and official CPI (urban, per capita, initialized
at 1993, Engel curve at 1993)
Table 9.17 Cost of living and official CPI (urban, family, initialized at
1993, Engel curve at 1993)
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Average
Growth
Rate
CPI 1.00 1.25 1.46 1.59 1.64 1.63 1.61 1.62 1.63 1.61 5.47%
‘True’ 1.00 1.25 1.46 1.58 1.60 1.57 1.52 1.51 1.50 1.49 4.56%
cost of
living
1.70
1.60
1.50
1.40
Price index
1.30
1.20
1.10
1.00
0.90 CPI ‘True’ cost of living
0.80
93
94
95
96
97
98
99
00
01
02
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
Figure 9.14 Cost of living and official CPI (urban, family, initialized at
1993, Engel curve at 1993)
family budget data samples. The other parameters are then estimated,
given the minimum subsistence amounts, from the regression of supernu-
merary expenditure for each category on supernumerary income, which is
taken to be total expenditure, serving as a proxy for long-run income. It
seems reasonable to assume that the first set of parameter estimates does
not depend on the second set, which uses time series of macro concepts –
supernumerary expenditure, by categories of goods and services, in rela-
tion to total supernumerary income, from time series estimation. This is
a linear estimator, given the estimates of minimum essential expenditure,
on average, in the different groupings, over time periods in our sample of
family budget data.
A remarkable property of the Summers–Heston–Kravis estimates is that
the LES fits the data of the consumption estimate and their associated price
indexes on a cross-country sample. An interesting application of the ana-
Adjustment to China’s CPI-based inflation rate 289
Table 9.18 Urban consumption expenditure (1993 price, 100 million yuan)
Geary-Khamis LES
Malawi 4.76 4.49
Kenya 6.09 6.67
India 5.86 6.51
Pakistan 7.81 8.31
Sri Lanka 8.75 10.50
Zambia 7.25 7.46
Thailand 12.79 11.52
Philippines 12.14 14.09
Korea 18.69 17.95
Malaysia 17.14 18.33
Colombia 22.21 22.23
Jamaica 23.92 26.70
Syria 23.66 23.22
Brazil 22.21 22.82
Romania 26.00 27.89
Mexico 33.66 37.04
Yugoslavia 31.78 34.68
Iran 24.64 25.12
Uruguay 39.92 36.83
Ireland 43.70 44.38
Hungary 42.81 44.09
Poland 39.63 40.12
Italy 49.05 53.19
Spain 57.70 58.90
UK 61.03 62.70
Japan 55.34 55.96
Austria 72.01 74.95
Netherlands 66.11 68.35
Belgium 71.90 73.99
France 71.58 74.37
Luxembourg 71.69 77.71
Denmark 75.48 74.16
Germany 72.98 74.98
US 100.00 100.00
Adjustment to China’s CPI-based inflation rate 291
close to telling us about quality of life. We, however, did not want such a
concentrated measure and looked for a variety of indicators, thus spread-
ing the risk of poor judgment.
In a series of research papers, Nagar and Basu, have made cross-country
estimates using the method of principal components to construct an index
of human development.6 Nagar and Basu recommend the construction of
an index in which each principal component (which is a linear combination
of indicators) is weighted by its eigenvalues.
Following the path laid out by Nagar and Basu, but using the time
dimension in a time series sample for China rather than country designa-
tion in a cross-country sample Suleyman Özmucur and Lawrence Klein
estimated five principal components from five variables:
These data were prepared (1980–2000), separately, for USA and China,
interpolating values for specific years in which quantitative reports were not
published and the results showed growth of the weighted aggregates to be
0.33 percent for USA and 0.53 percent for China.
For comparison without cost of living price deflators for China (and the
USA for comparison) leads us to conclude that this source of variation shows
that quality improvement grew about 60 percent (20 percentage points) faster
in China than in the USA. This is about growth and not about levels.
There are some very important indicators for China that have not yet been
investigated. For the USA, however, some of these indicators have been
taken about as high as country performance could go. For example, illiter-
acy, in a practical sense, has been banished in the USA. Professor Teh-wei
Hu of the University of California School of Public Health has suggested
that we expand our list by adding data on access to tap water and public san-
itation facilities for insight into improvement of China’s quality of life.
In this chapter, we estimate the contributions of the following additional
variables to China’s principal component analysis: SO2 Emissions; Urban
Access to Tap Water; Urban Garbage Disposal; Urban Excrement and
Urine Disposal (tons per capita), and Graduates of Higher Educational
Institutions (per 1000 people). These variables are all measured for urban
China. In the case of the USA, they are not necessarily relevant. They are
year after year already at virtual saturation levels in the USA. So we have
made an analysis of China alone, to be compared with the previous values
Adjustment to China’s CPI-based inflation rate 293
for China, to see how much improvement, in an overall sense, has been
taking place between the two countries.
We have, however, introduced a particular variable, namely SO2 Emissions.
The variable CO2 Emissions, in an earlier study, measured possible environ-
mental deterioration, but not directly a cause of individual human health
problems; rather a cause of atmospheric conditions that could cause prob-
lems to existing cities or towns. CO2 Emissions are generally associated with
such problems as global warming, which could eventually cause human
suffering. SO2 Emissions are more likely to have direct effects on the health of
exposed people so we have experimented with the use of this variable for
China, either with or without simultaneous consideration of a CO2 variable.
Below, we list ten indicators, including the original five variables used in
the paper with Suleyman Özmucur (Klein and Özmucur, 2003):
These are indicators of urban lifestyle change since data are not available
for rural persons and areas.
The sample covers 1980–2002. In Table 9.20, we show the end results for
annual growth, for an index computed as a ten-element weighted average,
which grows from 100 in 1980 to 115.47 in 2002. The 22-year increase com-
puted from
115.47 ⫽ 100.00 (1 ⫹ r) 22
r ⫽ 0.65596%
This growth rate is nearly double that for the USA, 1980–2000. Thus the
adjustment to China’s growth rate could be as high as 1 percent or more,
because the quality adjustment for the USA case has been estimated at 0.32
in a confidence interval of –0.1 to 0.8 percentage points.
294 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
NOTES
REFERENCES
Advisory Committee to Study the CPI (1996), Final Report of the Advisory
Committee to Study the Consumer Price Index, Chairman Michael J. Boskin,
Washington, DC, Government Printing Office. http://www.ssa.gov/history/
reports/boskinrpt.html.
Geary, R.C. (1950), ‘A Note on a Constant-utility Index of the Cost of Living’,
Review of Economic Studies, 18, 65–6.
Klein, L.R. and S. Özmucur (2002/03), ‘The Estimation of China’s Growth Rate’,
Journal of Economic and Social Measurement, 28, 187–202.
Klein, L.R. and H. Rubin (1947/48), ‘A Constant-utility Index of the Cost of
Living’, Review of Economic Studies, 15, 84–7.
Klein, L.R. and S. Özmucur (2003), ‘Estimates of Changes in Chinese Lifestyle’,
unpublished research paper, University of Pennsylvania.
Nagar, A.L. and Sudip Ranjan Basu (1999), ‘Weighting Socio-economic Indicators
of Human Development (A Latent Variable Approach)’, National Institute of
Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi.
Samuelson, P.A. (1947/48), ‘Some Implications of “Linearity” ’, Review of
Economic Studies, 15, 88–90.
Stone, Richard (1954), ‘Linear Expenditure Systems and Demand Analysis: An
Application to the Pattern of British Demand’, Economic Journal, 64, 511–27,
September.
Summers, Robert, Alan Heston and Irving Kravis (1982), ‘Interspatial Demand
Analysis’, World Product and Income, Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University
Press, Ch. 9, p. 374.
10. Estimating China’s core
inflation rate*
Deming Wu
1 INTRODUCTION
The objective of this chapter is to measure the core inflation rate in China
between 1997 and 2002. An accurate and timely measurement of inflation
is a critical prerequisite for successful monetary policies. The conventional
price indices, however, may not accurately capture the underlying inflation
from a monetary policy point of view. Taking the consumer price index
(CPI) as an example, it measures inflation as experienced by consumers in
their day-to-day living expenses. However, the inflation from the con-
sumers’ perspectives may be different from the underlying inflation that
concerns monetary policy-makers for reasons discussed below.
First, the prices of certain goods, such as agricultural products and oil,
depend on factors such as weather and OPEC’s oil production and pricing
decisions, which are beyond the control of the central bank. Monetary
policy as a response to inflation or deflation due to these kinds of price
changes may be ineffective.
Second, some goods and services have very volatile prices whose move-
ments typically reverse direction quickly. It is inappropriate for monetary
policy to respond to these short-run fluctuations since it typically takes
between 12 and 18 months, based on the US experience, for a monetary
policy to begin to affect inflation significantly.
Third, some price changes are due to changes in the policy environment,
such as those in the tax and tariff rates, or due to the increased competition
in the distribution sector as a result of price reforms and trade liberaliza-
tion. It is not necessary to respond to these one-time changes as if they are
persistent.
Inflation as measured by the consumer price index is the sum of these
different kinds of price changes. However, not all movements in the general
price level are equally important from a monetary policy point of view.
Instead, the central bank should focus on the underlying, or the core inflation,
that is, the portion of inflation that can be affected through monetary policy.
296
Estimating China’s core inflation rate 297
In this chapter, the core inflation is defined as the portion of inflation that
depends on monetary policy. This definition is based on the rationale that
not all movements in the general price level are due to changes in monetary
policy. Therefore, the central bank should focus on the part it can poten-
tially control. Based on this rationale, the core inflation rate is measured by
excluding agricultural products and energy, whose prices cannot be easily
controlled by the central bank.
It should be noted that there are different interpretations of core
inflation, which typically lead to different approaches to the measurement
of the core inflation rate (Wynne, 1999). One interpretation, proposed by
Okun (1970) and Flemming (1976), is that the observed inflation can be
decomposed into two components: the general price change and the rela-
tive price change due to supply-side shocks. Core inflation can be thought
of as the general price change that reflects the monetary policy. Therefore,
the measurement of the core inflation rate is to remove the relative price
changes from the observed inflation.
298 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
market basket from 1994 to 2000 are different from those after January
2001. Table 10.1 and Table 10.2 list the categories in the CPI basket before
and after 2001 respectively. The weights for calculating the consumer
price index are determined according to the composition of the con-
sumption expenditures of more than 90 000 urban and rural households.
Table 10.3 and Table 10.4 report the composition of per capita consump-
tion expenditures for urban and rural households respectively from 1997
to 2001.
As can be seen from these tables, in China, food-related costs comprise
more than 40 percent of the per capita consumption expenditures. As a
result, the weight for food-related costs in the CPI was above 40 percent
before 2001. Because of this, the majority of the fluctuation in CPI was due
to fluctuations of food prices. Changes in food prices in China depend on
natural factors, such as the weather and the government restrictions on
Item 1997 (%) 1998 (%) 1999 (%) 2000 (%) 2001 (%)
Total living expenditures 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00
1. Food 46.41 44.48 41.86 39.18 37.94
1.1 Grain 5.69 5.24 4.67 3.77 3.54
1.2 Meat, Poultry and 10.98 9.96 8.85 8.23 7.79
Related Products
1.3 Eggs 1.76 1.55 1.42 1.13 1.07
1.4 Aquatic Products 3.37 3.29 3.12 2.87 2.86
1.5 Milk and Dairy 0.99 1.11 1.22 1.37 1.51
Products
2. Clothing 12.45 11.10 10.45 10.01 10.05
2.1 Garments 7.84 7.18 6.94 6.75 6.86
3. Household Facilities, 7.57 8.24 8.57 8.79 8.27
Articles and Services
3.1 Durable Consumer 4.14 4.65 5.01 5.18 4.72
Goods
4. Medicine and 4.29 4.74 5.32 6.36 6.47
Medical Services
5. Transportation, Post and 5.56 5.94 6.73 7.90 8.61
Communication Services
5.1 Transportation 2.66 2.65 2.96 3.25 3.31
5.2 Communication 2.90 3.29 3.76 4.66 5.30
6. Recreation, Education 10.71 11.53 12.28 12.56 13.00
and Cultural Services
6.1 Durable Consumer Goods 2.69 2.91 2.93 2.94 2.62
for Recreational Use
6.2 Education 5.68 6.35 7.00 7.28 8.07
6.3 Recreation 2.35 2.27 2.35 2.34 2.30
7. Residence 8.57 9.43 9.84 10.01 10.32
7.1 Housing 3.55 3.99 4.24 4.03 4.09
7.2 Water, Electricity, 5.02 5.43 5.59 5.98 6.23
Fuel and Others
8. Miscellaneous 4.44 4.55 4.96 5.17 5.35
Commodities and Services
8.1 Personal Consumption 3.51 3.62 4.01 4.21 4.40
8.2 Other Commodities 0.43 0.41 0.43 0.41 0.41
8.3 Other Services 0.50 0.52 0.51 0.55 0.54
food imports. Because these factors are beyond the central bank’s control,
in order to construct a measurement of the core inflation rate that is more
relevant from the central bank’s perspective, we need to exclude food prices
from CPI, as shown in Figure 10.1.
Estimating China’s core inflation rate 301
Item 1997 (%) 1998 (%) 1999 (%) 2000 (%) 2001 (%)
Total living expenditure 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00
Food 55.05 53.43 52.56 49.13 47.71
Clothing 6.77 6.17 5.83 5.75 5.67
Household Facilities, 5.28 5.15 5.22 4.52 4.42
Articles and Services
Medicines and Medical 3.86 4.28 4.44 5.24 5.55
Services
Transportation, Post and 3.33 3.82 4.36 5.58 6.32
Telecommunication
Services
Cultural, Educational and 9.16 10.02 10.67 11.18 11.06
Recreational Articles
and Services
Residence 14.42 15.07 14.75 15.47 16.03
Other Commodities 2.12 2.07 2.18 3.14 3.24
and Services
The core CPI inflation rate is defined as the CPI inflation rate excluding food
and energy. In China’s CPI basket, there is no explicit category for energy.
There is a subcategory of ‘Water, Electricity and Fuel’ under the major cate-
gory of ‘Residences’. The weight for ‘Residence’ in the CPI is about 10 percent;
the weight for ‘Water, Electricity and Fuel’ is about 5 percent of the total CPI
calculation. Because of the lack of published data for the price index of the
‘Water, Fuel and Electricity’ subcategory in the CPI, I use the price index of
the ‘Fuel’ subcategory under the RPI (retail price index) basket as a proxy.
I also have to estimate the weight by using the composition of per capita
expenditure for urban and rural households. The expenditure shares of this
category for urban households were 5.02 percent in 1997 and 6.23 percent
in 2001; the expenditure share of this category for rural households was not
available. It can be imputed by assuming the ratio of this category to its
parent category is the same as that of the expenditure of urban households.
In the research, I used the expenditure share for urban households as the
approximation for this weight.
302 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
The inflation rate of core CPI is calculated using the following equations:
Table 10.5 and Figure 10.2 report the overall CPI inflation, the inflation
of the food price index, the calculated CPI inflation excluding food, and the
CPI inflation excluding food and energy from 1980 to 2003. As can be seen
from the data, for 1998 and 1999, the overall CPI inflation rate was nega-
tive, but this was due to the large decline of food prices. If food prices were
excluded from the basket, the core CPI inflation rate would have been
positive in 1998 and 1999. For the year 2002, even after excluding food
prices, the core CPI inflation rate was still negative. This indicates that the
CPI decline in 2002 was likely to have been caused by factors other than
food prices.
In Table 10.6 and Figure 10.3 I report the decomposition of the monthly
CPI inflation rate between 1994 and 2004. I am taking advantage of the
availability of monthly data because the annual data are somewhat mis-
leading in that they are averages of the monthly data; so that the monthly
positive and negative changes offset each other. As can be seen from Table
10.6 and Figure 10.3 the inflation rate of core CPI had been mostly posi-
tive until February 2002.
The decline of the consumer price index in 2002 was likely due to the
effects of China’s accession into the WTO and the reduction of the tariff
rate in 2002. According to the WTO rules, and the commitments China
made, China lowered the tariff rates of 5300 items in 2002, accounting for
73 percent of the total tariff items. The average overall tariff rate was cut
down from 15.3 percent to 12 percent; the average tariff rate of industrial
products was lowered to 11.6 percent; the average tariff rate of agricultural
products, excluding aquatic products, was lowered to 15.8 percent; the
average tariff rate of aquatic products was lowered to 14.3 percent. Lower
tariff rates caused a large price reduction in imported goods, adding to the
downward pressure on domestic price levels. The large increase of imported
goods has also intensified the competition between imported and domestic-
ally produced goods. Domestic enterprises had to reduce their prices and
costs in order to preserve their market shares.
The slowdown of economic growth in 2001 might also have con-
tributed to the downward pressure on prices in 2002. Price changes
35.0
30.0
25.0
20.0
15.0
Percent
10.0
303
5.0
0.0
80
81
82
83
84
85
86
87
88
89
90
91
92
93
94
95
96
97
98
99
00
01
02
03
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
–5.0
–10.0
Year
CPI Inflation, all items CPI Inflation, all items less food CPI inflation, food
typically lag the GDP from half one year to one year. The GDP growth
rates for the four quarters in 2001 were 8.1 percent, 7.8 percent, 7.0
percent, and 6.6 percent consecutively, declining quarter by quarter.
This slowdown was reflected in price movement in 2002. In addition,
there was a substantial decline of ex-factor prices and the purchase price
of raw materials in 2001, which had a strong lagged influence on
retail prices in 2002. Finally, the decline of stock prices in 2002
might have also contributed to the decline in the price of investment and
consumer goods.
40.0
35.0
30.0
25.0
20.0
Percent
15.0
305
10.0
5.0
0.0
0
3
8
0
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
–5.0
–10.0
Year
CPI Inflation, all items CPI inflation, all items less food and energy CPI inflation, food CPI inflation, energy
Figure 10.2 CPI Inflation, all items less food and energy, 1980–2003
306 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
Using the monthly retail price index (RPI) by category, I estimate the core
rate of inflation as measured by the RPI by excluding the food and fuel cat-
egories. Because of the lack of published data for the weights of categories
in the RPI baskets, I regress the overall RPI against the indices of subcat-
egories to estimate the weights. To resolve the multicollinearity problem of
highly intercorrelated indices of subcategories, I have to remove some cat-
egories from the right-hand side in order to get plausible estimated results.
Table 10.7 reports the estimated weights of the major categories in the RPI
basket for different periods. Using the estimated weights for the period
between 04/1994 and 05/2003, Table 10.8 reports the decomposition of the
inflation rate of the RPI by excluding food and energy.
As can be seen from Figures 10.3 and 10.4, one striking difference
between the decomposition of RPI and that of CPI is that the inflation rate
of RPI excluding food and energy has been consistently negative since
October 1997. One possible explanation for the decline of the retail price
index is the increased competition in the distribution sector, which has
squeezed the gross margins of the wholesalers and retailers, and thus has
put downward pressure on retail prices (Wu, 2004).
20.0
15.0
10.0
Percent
5.0
310
0.0
97 97 97 97 98 98 98 98 99 99 99 99 00 00 00 00 01 01 01 01 02 02 02 02 03 03 03 03 04 04
n- pr- ul- ct- an- pr- ul- ct- an- pr- ul- ct- an- pr- ul- ct- an- pr- ul- ct- an- pr- ul- ct- an- pr- ul- ct- an- pr-
Ja A J O J A J O J A J O J A J O J A J O J A J O J A J O J A
–5.0
–10.0
Month
CPI inflation, all items CPI inflation, all item less food and energy CPI inflation, food CPI inflation, energy
basket is small, the indirect impact of oil price on domestic price levels
could be large because energy cost accounts for a significant portion of
the production cost in every industrial sector. Therefore, the simple index
accounting approach used in the previous sections may underestimate the
impact of petroleum price changes. In light of this limitation, I construct
an input–output price model to estimate both the direct and indirect
impact of changes in petroleum prices on the price levels.
Here, a1, j, a2, j, . . . , an, j are the input–output coefficients, and vj is the share
of valued-added in commodity j.
Now assume sector n is the petroleum industry. Suppose the price of
petroleum changes by p⬘n , the direct impact of petroleum price changes on
the price of commodity j is
That is,
Here, we use the lower-case p⬘j to represent the percentage of price changes.
However, because prices of other inputs also change as a result of the
change in petroleum prices, we need to consider both the direct and the
indirect effects, therefore, we have
20
15
10
Percent
5
315
0
96 96 96 96 97 97 97 97 98 98 98 98 99 99 99 99 00 00 00 00 01 01 01 01 02 02 02 02
n- pr- ul- ct- an- pr- ul- ct- an- pr- ul- ct- an- pr- ul- ct- an- pr- ul- ct- an- pr- ul- ct- an- pr- ul- ct-
Ja A J O J A J O J A J O J A J O J A J O J A J O J A J O
–5
–10
Month
RPI inflation, all items RPI inflation, all items less food and fuel RPI inflation, food RPI inflation, fuel
Because there are similar equations for other sectors, we can write this
total system in matrix notation to obtain
Here we have
冢 冣
a1,1 ... an ⫺1,1
ATn⫺1 ⫽ (10.10)
...
...
..
.
a1,n ⫺1 ... an ⫺1,n ⫺1
and
冢 冣
an, 1
an, 2
An ⫽ (10.11)
...
an, n ⫺1
and
冢 冣
p1
p2
p⫽ (10.12)
...
pn ⫺1
Table 10.10 The world market price of crude oil and China’s average
tariff rate
between the oil price changes and the price changes in the final market, this
14 percent decline in oil prices could have contributed to 0.82 percent
decline of the consumer price index in 2002.
t ⫹1 ⫽ Tt ⫹ t (10.14)
t ⫽ CPI inflation
gt ⫽ Real GDP growth
ˇ
core
t ⫽ Core CPI inflation
yt ⫽
冤冥
t
gt
冤冥
t
gt
core
t
t ⫽
⌬t
⌬gt
⌬core
t
Where ⌬ xt ⫽ xt ⫺ xt⫺1.
The observation equation is defined as
冤冥
t
gt
yt ⫽ 冤 冥 冤
t
gt
⫽
10 0 0 0 0
01 0 0 0 0 冥 core
t
⌬t
⌬gt
⌬core
t
t ⫽ t⫺1 ⫹ ⌬t
gt ⫽ gt⫺1 ⫹ ⌬gt
core
t ⫽ core core
t⫺1 ⫹ ⌬ t
⌬ t ⫽ ␣1 (t⫺1 ⫺ core
t⫺1 ) ⫹ 1 ⌬t⫺1 ⫹ 2 ⌬gt⫺1 ⫹ 3 ⌬t⫺1 ⫹ 1t
core
⌬ core
t ⫽ 7 ⌬core
t⫺1 ⫹ 3t
Or
冤 冥冤 冥冤 冥冤 冥
t 1 0 0 1 0 0 t⫺1 0
gt 0 1 0 0 1 0 gt⫺1 0
core
t 0 0 1 0 0 1 core
t⫺1 0
t ⫽ ⫽
⌬t ␣1 0 ⫺ ␣1 1 2 3 ⌬t⫺1 1t
⌬gt 0 0 0 4 5 6 ⌬gt⫺1 2t
⌬t core 0 0 0 0 0 7 ⌬core
t⫺1 2t
Table 10.11 reports the estimation results; Table 10.12 reports the esti-
mated core CPI inflation; Figure 10.5 plots the estimated core CPI inflation
along with the overall CPI inflation. It can be seen from the chart that the
core CPI inflation rates were all positive over the estimation interval.
It should be noted that the estimated core inflation rates based on
this model are very sensitive to the initial conditions used in the estima-
tion. For example, the estimated results for sample period 1980–2002 are
significantly different from the estimated results for sample period
1978–2002. It is likely that there are multiple time series that are cointe-
grated with the headline inflation. As a result, the initial conditions will
determine which time series get picked. As the core inflation is defined as
Notes:
Method: Maximum likelihood (Marquardt).
Date: 04/25/04 Time: 11:04.
Sample: 1980:1 2002:4.
Included observations: 92.
322 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
Table 10.12 CPI inflation and estimated core inflation using Kalman filter,
1980–2002
7 CONCLUSION
In this chapter, I have shown that although the overall CPI inflation rate
was negative in the years 1998 and 1999, the core CPI inflation rate after
excluding the price of food was positive in these two years. The core CPI
inflation rate for 2002 was negative after excluding the food prices. This
indicates that the CPI decline in 2002 might have been caused by factors
other than food prices. It was highly likely that the decline of the consumer
price index in 2002 was due to the effects of China’s accession into the WTO
and the reduction of the tariff rate in 2002. According to the WTO rules
and the commitments China made, China lowered the tariff rates of 5300
items in 2002, accounting for 73 percent of the total tariff items. The overall
tariff level was cut from 15.3 percent to 12 percent.
I have also decomposed the inflation rate of the RPI, and have found that
a striking difference between the movement of the RPI and the CPI is that
the inflation rate of the RPI, excluding food and energy, has been consis-
tently negative since November 1997. A potential explanation (Wu, 2004)
is that the increased competition in the distribution sector squeezed the
gross margins of the distributors, hence adding to the downward pressure
on retail prices.
30.00
25.00
20.00
15.00
Percent
10.00
325
5.00
0.00
:1 :4 :3 :2 :1 :4 :3 :2 :1 :4 :3 :2 :1 :4 :3 :2 :1 :4 :3 :2 :1 :4 :3 :2 :1 :4 :3 :2 :1 :4 :3
80 80 81 82 83 83 84 85 86 86 87 88 89 89 90 91 92 92 93 94 95 95 96 97 98 98 99 00 01 01 02
19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 20 20 20 20
–5.00
Quarter
Figure 10.5 CPI inflation and estimated core inflation by Kalman filter, 1980–2002
326 Analytical issues pertaining to the recent crises
NOTE
* The views expressed in this chapter are those of the author, and do not necessarily reflect
those of the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency. This chapter is based on Chapter 2
of my doctoral dissertation at Stanford University. I am grateful to Professor Lawrence
Lau, Professor Ronald McKinnon and Professor Takeshi Amemiya for their invaluable
guidance.
REFERENCES
Bernanke, Ben (2002), ‘Deflation – Making Sure “It” Doesn’t Happen Here’,
Speech by Ben S. Bernanke, Member of the Board of Governors of the US
Federal Reserve System, before the National Economists Club, Washington, DC,
21 November.
Bjornland, H.C. (2000), ‘Identifying Domestic and Imported Core Inflation’, IMF
Working Paper.
De Long, Bradford J. (1999), ‘Should We Fear Deflation?’, Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, 1, 225–41.
Eckstein, O. (1981), Core Inflation, Engelwood Cliffs, N.J: Prentice-Hall.
Erceg, Christopher, Jon Faust, Luca Guerrieri, Carter Hemphill, Linda Kole,
Jennifer Roush, John Rogers, Nathan Sheets and Jonathan Wright (2002),
‘Preventing Deflation: Lessons from Japan’s Experience in the 1990s’,
International Finance Discussion Paper, Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System.
Flemming, J. (1976), Inflation, Oxford University Press.
IMF (2003), ‘Deflation: Determinants, Risks, and Policy Options – Findings of an
Interdepartmental Task Force’, IMF working paper.
Krugman, Paul R. (1999a), ‘Can Deflation Be Prevented?’, Krugman website,
http://web.mit.edu/krugman/www/.
Krugman, Paul R. (1999b), ‘Deflationary Spirals’, Krugman website, http://web.
mit.edu/krugman/www/.
Krugman, Paul R. (2003), ‘Fear of a Quagmire’, New York Times, 24 May,
Section A, Page 15, Column 5.
Lau, Lawrence J. (2003), ‘The World Economy and Deflation’, working paper pre-
sented at the Fifth Meeting of the International Advisory Council of the China
Development Bank, Beijing, 7 November 2003, Stanford University.
Lee, Jong Wong, Sang Don Lee and Ki-Ho Kim (2003), ‘New Approach to
Estimation of the Core Inflation’, Journal of the Korean Economy, 4 (2), 315–43.
Leontief, Wassily (1986), ‘Input–output Economics’, 2nd Edition, Oxford
University Press.
Marques, C.R., P.D. Nerves and A.G. Da Silva (2002), ‘Why Should Central Banks
Avoid the Use of the Underlying Inflation Indicator’, Economics Letters, 75,
17–23.
Melvin, James R. (1979), ‘Short-run Price Effects of the Corporation Income Tax
and Implications for International Trade’, The American Economic Review,
69 (5), 765–74.
National Bureau of Statistics of China (1999), ‘Input–output Table of China’,
China Statistics Press, China, Beijing.
Estimating China’s core inflation rate 327
329
330 Index
75–6, 81, 82–3, 84, 99, 101, 104, Leontief, Wassily 311
105, 134 letter stocks 179
Kane, Edward J. 163, 166, 167 leverage 124, 172, 175, 184
Kaplan, E. 136 Levine, Ross 148
Kenya, domestic consumption 290 liberalization
Khatdhate, Deena 148 capital account 11, 135–7
Kim, Ki-Ho 298, 319 capital markets 4–5
Kindleberger, Charles P. 197 China 256–7
Kittiprapas, Sauwalak 225, 232, 233 Liberty Bonds, US 176–7
Klein, Lawrence R. 1–20, 23–65, lifestyle change 19, 261, 263, 291–5
134–46, 260–95 Lindbeck, Assar 244
Klein, M. 146 linear expenditure system (LES)
Knowles, James C. 232 262–84
Kojima, K. 198 comments on 284–91
Kole, Linda 297 overview 18–19, 260–61
Kondury, Kali 148 liquid secondary markets 178–80
Kravis, Irving 285–6, 287, 288–9, 291 liquidity shocks 175
Kruger, M. 73, 75–6 literature, real wage declines 224–5
Krugman, Paul 25, 53, 72, 73, 134, living standards, impacts of financial
198, 297 crises 62–4
Kumar, M. 26 Lizondo, S. 9, 71, 73–6, 81, 82–3, 84
loan contracts 159
La Porta, Rafael 162, 163, 166 logit model 26–8, 73, 75–6, 80–81, 84
Labor Force Surveys (LFSs) 224–5 London Interbank Offered Rate
labor inputs 208–11 (LIBOR) 85–9, 96, 98–100
labor market conditions 55 Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio 162, 163,
labor market, Thailand 221 166
labor productivity Lucas, Robert E.B. 222
Asia 201, 202, 203 Luxembourg, domestic consumption
China/US 249 290
Japan/US 244
Lang, Larry H.P. 156, 184 M1 85–9, 97, 98–100
Lardy, Nicholas 240 M2 9, 29, 73, 85–9, 94, 97, 98–100, 104,
Larrain, Felipe 73, 75–6 106, 107, 110, 111, 136–7
Latin America macroeconometric model, Malaysia
current accounts 122 main characteristics 137–8
exchange rates 123, 127 overview 11–12, 134–5
fiscal discipline 123–4 simulations 138–45
income inequality/poverty 57 macroeconomic indicators 24
living standards 62–3, 64 Indonesia 36, 39–41
Lau, Lawrence J. 53, 199, 297 Korea 36, 37–8, 44
leading-indicator approach 26–8 Malaysia 41–4
Thailand 69–70, 80–84, 108–9, 111 overview 12
Leblang, D. 135 Philippines 44, 45–6
Lee, Jong Wong 298, 319 Thailand 33–6
Lee, Sang Don 298, 319 macroeconomic performance 135–7
legal frameworks, bond markets 162–3 Mahmood, Moazam 222, 225
legal infrastructure, Thailand 181 Makino, J. 53
lending rate, Thailand 85–9, 96, 98–100 Malawi, domestic consumption
Lenovo 256 290
338 Index