Administration Unraveled
Administration Unraveled
Administration Unraveled
ISBN 9781937520373
Published by First Edition Design eBook Publishing
November 2011
www.firsteditiondesignpublishing.com
ALL RIGHTS RESERVED, including the right of reproduction in whole or in part in any form, except for brief
quotes used specifically within critical articles and reviews.
Disclosure due to the media format of this book, the Appendix has been omitted. For full content of the book,
please refer to the PRINT version or charts are available via the URL provided at end of book for viewing.
WEBERS BUREAUCRACY
Max Webers ideal, legal, monocratic type of Bureaucracy is a supplementary component of
the Unified General Theory. It emerges naturally, rationally and unavoidably in the application of
The Unified Pattern of Administration to develop an enterprise.
MASLOWS HIERARCHY OF HUMAN NEEDS
Abraham Maslows theory of motivation is a supplementary component of The Unified
General Theory. It emerges naturally, rationally and unavoidably in the application of The
Unified Pattern of Administration to develop an enterprise.
-AppendixIMPLICATIONS
A list of some of the more apparent implications that can be deduced from the propositions
of the Unified General Theory of Administration.
-AppendixDISPLAYS
Figure 1The Principles of Administration Logical Square
Figure 2The Principles of Organization and Coordination Logical Square
Figure 3The Principles of Command and Control Logical Square
Figure 4Urwicks Pattern of Administration
Figure 5Urwicks Elements of Administration
Figure 6The Unified Pattern of Administration
Chapter One - THE GENESIS OF THE UNIFIED GENERAL THEORY
For the last hundred or so years thousands of books, technical papers and periodicals
about administration have accumulated. This is knowledge that could be useful to those
concerned with administration if they just knew what was there, where it is and they had the
motivation, time and opportunity to look for it. Very few that need it ever have the opportunity to
access more than the tiniest bit of it. There was a time in my career when I needed some of this
administration knowledge but didnt know if it existed or where to find it if it did exist.
My need for administration knowledge developed early in a 31-year management career
with a large industrial enterprise. Early in those years events occurred that were confusing or
puzzling or frustrating or sometimes even seemed irrational. Policies believed to be rational and
necessary would accomplish their intended purpose but would also cause collateral damage that
was detrimental to the organization. Here are a few very brief illustrative examples.
There was a standard cost system in which actual costs were compared to standard
budgets and the variances evaluated as a measure of performance. It was obvious that the
standards were too generous because good performances were being routinely achieved with
little or no special effort. It was apparent that production costs could be significantly reduced and
profits increased by tightening these standard budgets. A program to accomplish this offered cash
awards to management for developing and installing improved practices that reduced costs
accompanied by progressively tightened standard budgets. The awards were generous and
management entered into the program with zeal. Eventually appropriate standards were achieved
but they were not recognized as such. The standards continued to be tightened but the
accompanying changes that were supposed to reduce costs frequently did not do so. The end
result was standard costs that became as much too tight as they were once too loose creating an
apparent decline in performance. The organization was actually performing effectively but was
perceived as ineffective.
Organizations can internalize counterproductively in their own worst interest. They can
become so attached to internal procedures and controls that they lose sight of the harmful effects
that can result when dedication to procedure supercedes dedication to the objectives for which
the procedure was developed. Management and non-management personnel were observed
who day after day and year after year performed their work competently and dependably but with
benign apathy. Sometimes even arising out of this apathy to intense activity to perpetuate an
undesirable status quo apparently unaware of its adverse effect upon the operation and its
personnel.
Internalization can also reach beyond internal counterproductively and become an external
threat. Manufacturing units had monthly shipping directives of specific orders to be shipped that
month. Occasionally it would become apparent that some of the orders would not ship on time. To
meet the shipping directive, orders that were promised for the following month but could be
shipped in the current month would be pulled into the current month to replace those that were
promised but would not be ready for shipment. Customers who expected delivery of their orders
as promised had based their business plans and operations upon that promise but received
instead a disappointing broken delivery notice. Other customers were asked to accept unplanned
for early deliveries that they didnt want or need. Eventually, customers turned to more reliable
suppliers resulting in a progressive decay in market participation.
Sales representatives make promises to customers to get orders that the producing unit
subsequently rejects because it cant fulfill the promises made. This will adversely affect sales
performance, so the sales unit persuades the executives that the order is very important and is
just too good to lose. The producing unit is directed to accept the order, give it special attention
and work it in somehow. Months later, the special order ships on time because of executive
mandated special attention, but other orders that were preempted in the process ship late. The
producing unit is penalized with a poor shipping performance and other customers are burdened
with late shipments.
Over the years, these and other counterproductive events in great variety continued to
occur. There had to be some sort of rationale within which these dysfunctional events could at
least be understood and possibly be corrected. A personal off-the-job effort searching for these
rationales ended with my acceptance of a career advancing invitation to be sponsored for a
course of study leading to a Sc.D. in Metallurgical Engineering. Ironically, this event initiated a
long and very different path that has led, serendipitously, to the result that the personal research
effort it interrupted had been seeking. The Sc.D. program was entered with much enthusiasm but
out of economic necessity working in the steel mill also continued. By the end of the first semester
it was apparent that this arrangement wasnt going to succeed despite the attraction for the
subject. The disconcerting events in the workplace continued to be a distraction and a source of
subject. The disconcerting events in the workplace continued to be a distraction and a source of
frustration. They couldnt be ignored because they often added burdensome complications to
work responsibilities. With more regret than realized at the time, my participation in the Sc.D.
Program was terminated and my personal efforts were redirected back to the search for rationales
but this time with a more formal and intense procedure.
Since the troubling events were occurring in business situations and the way that the
people conducted their business affairs, it seemed reasonable that Business Administration
should be a resource for answers. An MBA evening program was entered and eventually
abandoned. By the end of the first year it had become apparent that it would not be the source of
answers for the concerns of this pursuit. Just as Metallurgical Engineering basically taught the
mechanics of Metallurgy, Business Administration basically taught the mechanics of Business.
Since these troubling events dealt with people, perhaps psychology could be the source
where the answers could be found. This time, instead of engaging in a course of psychological
study, time and effort were devoted to reviewing the psychological course content and the
publications available in the Psychological Department library. Psychological books and
periodicals were reviewed. The table of contents and some of the chapters and articles were
scanned or read to assess what they offered. It eventually became apparent that psychology
would not be the source for the answers.
Dr. Alfred Berger, my sponsor for the Metallurgical Sc.D. program, was supportive of this
search for the right place to study and was aware of these disappointments. He made a crucial
suggestion that Dr. Brinkloe, an Industrial Engineering Professor, should be consulted. Dr.
Brinckloe evidenced a genuine interest in these concerns and after several discussions he
suggested that the Graduate School of Public and International Affairs (GSPIA) should be
explored. The procedure used for Psychology was repeated at GSPIA. The class offerings and
the GSPIA library were thoroughly assessed. GSPIA offered courses with unusual titles such as
Diplomacy, Negotiation, Bureaucracy, Power etc. Books about bureaucracy, administration and
organization were reviewed that addressed subject matter dealing with people and organizations
from a different perspective. The GSPIA faculty suggested that the Public Administration
curriculum offered the most potential for what they perceived as the nature of my concerns. A
formal request for entry into the Ph.D. in Public Administration program was submitted. The
request took almost a year to process because I did not fit the appropriate candidate profile for this
program. Eventually, acceptance as an unusual but acceptable candidate was granted. The
purpose of briefly relating these trials and tribulations is to illustrate just how difficult, expensive
and time consuming it can be for someone to muddle their way to the discovery of extraordinary
sources of administration knowledge like GSPIA and why not many do so.
By the end of the 1st trimester, the very small GSPIA library had become a gold mine of
administration knowledge. By the end of 3 trimesters I had accumulated a sizeable collection of
random, unconnected nuggets of administration knowledge. These did not readily coalesce into a
rationale nor did they present an apparent context for understanding. They were just isolated
pieces of information that I was certain were part of the big puzzle but did not know how to put
them together. I thought that these were unusual finds so it became a standard procedure to
purchase a copy of the source document or, if unavailable, to make copies if possible or if
necessary make extensive notes. Fortunately, at this time, an article by Dr. Edward Litchfield
surfaced that specifically addressed this issue. In essence, Dr. Litchfield stated that there is a lot
of excellent knowledge about administration widely distributed throughout several disciplines. He
believed that most of the value and contribution to our understanding of organizations and
administration are yet to be revealed because the information has not been assembled and
correlated into a comprehensive totality of any kind. He then made the case for a General Theory
of Administration to serve as a framework for assembling this knowledge into a coherent whole.
No one had yet done so and he speculated that until someone did much of the real value of all of
this knowledge would remain obscure or hidden and unavailable. I decided to respond to Dr.
Litchfields call and try to develop a way to assemble administration knowledge into a coherent
whole or as he called it, A General Theory of Administration. I also viewed it as a good subject of
choice for the Ph.D. dissertation.
This formal pursuit at GSPIA ended four trimesters through the six trimester in-residence
part of the Ph.D. program. Several major unforeseeable events in both my personal and
professional lives converged simultaneously necessitating my reluctant withdrawal from the
GSPIA Ph.D. program with virtually no prospects for subsequent reentry. Now, more than 30
years later, the quest is nearly finished. During those intervening years, as time allowed, I
continued working to develop the General Theory drawing primarily from experience and the
large volume of administration information nuggets accumulated while at GSPIA. This effort
became an avocation and the scope of the effort gradually broadened and eventually expanded
into the development of a Unified General Theory of Administration. The term Unified was added
to recognize that some of the components of the theory were adopted from the Administration field
to recognize that some of the components of the theory were adopted from the Administration field
and that other parts were adopted from the fields of Sociology and Psychology. The Unified
General Theory of Administration also provides the context within which rationales for the
dysfunctional events described earlier can be understood.
The Unified General Theory of Administration has its roots in, and surprisingly derives
most of its substance from, the often vilified classical school of administration study that began
late in the 1890s and reached its peak of activity between 1935 and 1950. Organizations have
been around for centuries but a concerted interest in studying them did not begin until the turn of
the century. In Germany, Max Weber studied and published his work on social and economic
organization in the late 1890s and early 1900s. His relevant work was translated into English in
1947. Henri Fayols work on industrial management was published in French in 1916 and was
available in England but was not published in the United States until 1949. Lyndall Urwick, in
England, published his assembly and arrangement of administration principles in 1943. In the
United States, Abraham Maslow published his work on human motivation in 1943, Ralph Currier
Davis published his work on the fundamentals of top management in 1951 and in 1962 Robert
Presthus published his analysis and theory of human accommodation in bureaucracy. By 1962
the components that are assembled into The Unified General Theory of Administration had
already become part of the huge accumulation of administration knowledge.
The Unified General Theory of Administration is the product of my original work
synthesized with work adopted from these classical school scholars to form the Unified Pattern of
Administration that is the composite core component of the Unified General Theory. This
composite core also includes melded, supplemental work adopted from 6 additional scholars and
is augmented with edifying commentary adopted from another group of 11 scholars.
The liberal use of quotations was chosen as the most functional method of adopting and
embedding the work of these referenced scholars. The preference, to the greatest possible extent,
was to use their exact words without change or embellishment. For the most part, what these
scholars had to say was said well, and in my judgment, nothing could be gained by tampering
with their expression of their work. In almost every instance, it was the way that they said what
they said that captured my attention in the first place and motivated me to excerpt them verbatim
into my body of research. I have chosen to use the quotes from these scholars to express what I
want to convey in lieu of unethically paraphrasing the content and presenting it in my own words. I
have endeavored to be meticulously careful not to adopt and present the work of others as my
own. There was, occasionally, a need to paraphrase a few excerpts to facilitate brevity. In those
instances I have credited the originator of the central thought or idea. There are also a few
segments where I have extracted sentences and short paragraphs out of context and synthesized
them into a paragraph to enhance understanding by excluding the intervening case examples
and supporting commentary, arguments and references that the original authors used to validate
their positions. Most of the time it was possible to credit these sources as well. If there was a
dominant source for the text, the surname of that source is identified with [brackets]. Text that is
not referenced or credited is mine. However, this work was accumulated and developed over
more than 30 years and there is always the possibility that a connection to an old reference has
faded in memory or has been lost. All things considered, I could not have developed The Unified
General Theory of Administration without the many years of thinking, study and explanation of
administration and related phenomena by those scholars whose work has become a part of it.
I have chosen to liberally paragraph the text and to use italics, underlines and bold print to
highlight words and phrases to enhance comprehension and make the text less formal and easier
to read. The reader is asked to tolerate these and other format idiosyncrasies. They are
deliberate, functional and none are committed out of ignorance of the rules of formal writing form.
The case is also presented without the overburden of added arguments to persuade you for its
acceptance. I believe that the case as presented should persuade on its own merit and either be
obvious or become obvious upon reflection. The overall proposition is that the Unified General
Theory of Administration is novel, natural, rational and unavoidable.
The following is a functionally annotated, bibliographic listing of the scholars mentioned
above whose work was adopted and assembled into the Unified General Theory of
Administration.
THE 6 PRIMARY SCHOLARS:
LITCHFIELD, EDWARD H.adopted basis for a General Theory of Administration Notes
on a General Theory of Administration
1956 Administrative Science Quarterly, (June) Ithaca: Cornell University
DAVIS, RALPH CURRIERadopted basis for the Governing component 1951 The
Fundamentals of Top Management New York: Harper and Brothers
URWICK, LYNDALLadopted central core component 1943 The Elements of
Administration New York: Harper & Brothers
Administration New York: Harper & Brothers
WEBER, MAXadopted supplementary core component Legitimate Authority and
Bureaucracy
1976 Organization Theory ed. D. S. Pugh London: Cox and Wyman Ltd
1947 Extracted from: Max Weber: The Theory of Social and Economic Organizations.
Translated and edited by A. M. Henderson and Talcott Parsons New York: Oxford University
Press
MASLOW, ABRAHAM H.adopted supplementary core component A Theory of Human
Motivation
1963 Readings in Managerial Psychology eds. Harold J. Leavitt and Louis R. Pondy
Chicago: The University Press 1943 Abridged from: The Psychological Review L)1943),
370 396
PRESTHUS, ROBERTadopted complementary core component
1962 The Organizational Society: An Analysis and a Theory New York: Random House
This section summarizes Lyndall Urwicks synthesis of his work with the work of other
scholars into logical relationships. If Henri Fayol had not documented his principles of
administration; If Louis F. Anderson had not identified the logical relationships among principles,
processes and effects; If Mooney and Reilly had not organized their principles of organization in
accordance with Andersons logical relationships;
Its doubtful that Lyndall Urwick would have developed and organized his principles of
administration and I would not have developed the Unified General Theory of Administration.
In the 1940s Lyndall Urwick, a British consultant, was an exponent of the traditional
classical approach to administration. Urwick concentrated less on building an entire philosophy of
administration and more on collecting the basic ideas of earlier writers into an eclectic summary
of classical concepts. He tediously compared the frameworks of Fayol, Taylor, Mooney and
Reiley, and others and found a remarkable consistency in their conclusions. (Massie, 1968: 413)
There are principles which can be arrived at inductively from the study of human
experience of organization, which should govern arrangements for human association of
any kind. These principles can be studied as a technical question, irrespective of the
purpose of the enterprise, the personnel composing it, or any constitutional, political, or social
theory underlying its creation. They are concerned with the method of subdividing and
allocating to individuals all the various activities, duties, and responsibilities essential to the
purpose contemplated, the correlation of these activities and the continuous control of the work of
the individuals so as to secure the most economical and most effective realization of
purpose. (Urwick, 1937: 49)
Urwicks work was published in 1943 in a book titled, The Elements of Administration.
This brief discussion of the Elements of Administration is based on five lectures delivered under
the auspices of the London branch of the Institute of Industrial Administration at the Polytechnic,
London, in May and June, 1942. The main point underlying this series of lectures is that it
focuses in a logical scheme various Principles of Administration formulated by different
authorities. The fact that such Principles worked out by persons of different nationalities, widely
varying experience and, in the majority of the cases, no knowledge of each others work were
susceptible to such logical arrangement, is in itself highly significant. (Urwick, 1943: 7)
Urwicks research and analysis identified 27 administrative principles. He adopted 17
principles from the work of Henri Fayol, 1 key principle from the works of F. W. Taylor and Mary
Parker Follett and 9 principles from the work of Mooney and Reiley. Mooney and Reiley had
arranged their 9 principles dealing with Organization and Coordination into a Logical Square
discipline that follows the order of the basic logical laws as revealed in Louis
F. Andersons Das Logische, seine Gesetze und Categorien.
The most distinguished American authors who have written on the theory of organization,
Mr. J.C. Mooney, President of the General Motors Export Corporation, and Mr. A.C. Reiley,
adopted a logical scheme from a German author, Louis F. Anderson. This scheme postulated:
First that every principle has its process and effect, and
Second, that if these have been correctly identified, the process and effect will, in their turn,
be found to have, each of them, a principle, process and effect. Thus completing a logical square
of nine items. (Urwick, 1943: 17)
Urwick adopted Mooney and Reileys Logical Square arrangement of Organization and
Coordination principles along with Andersons logical scheme and created a sequence of 3
Logical Squares, 1 primary and 2 subordinate each comprised of 9 principles for a total of 27.
Urwick developed a primary Logical Square, The Principles of Administration, Figure [1] (pg 102).
It is comprised of 8 of the 17 principles that he adopted from the work of Henri Fayol plus the 1
key principle he attributed to the work of Frederick W. Taylor and Mary Parker Follett. Mooney and
Reileys Organization and Coordination Logical Square, Figure [2] (pg 103) is the 2nd in the
sequence. It is subordinate to the 3 principles that comprise the 2nd line of Urwicks primary
Logical Square. Urwick developed the Command and Control Logical Square, Figure [3] (pg
104). It is 3rd in the sequence and is subordinate to the 3 principles comprising the 3rd line of his
primary Logical Square.
The Principles of Administration
Urwicks Development of the Primary Logical Square
Henri Fayol was a famous French industrialist. For 30 years he was Managing Director of
one of the largest coal and iron combines in the country. When he took it over it was on the verge
of bankruptcy. When he retired it was brilliantly successful, with an exceptionally strong balance
sheet. Towards the end of his life he tried to reduce to a logical form, the principles on which his
sheet. Towards the end of his life he tried to reduce to a logical form, the principles on which his
success as an administrator had been built up. He always insisted that the success had nothing
difficult or unusual about it. It followed simply and logically from strict adherence to
principle.(Urwick, 1943: 15,16)
Fayol analyzed the operations which occur in business into 6 main groups; technical,
commercial, financial, security, accounting and administrative operations. Thus, he regarded
Administration merely as one of a group of major functions. Administration, regarded in this way,
he wrote, must not be confused with government. To govern is to conduct an undertaking towards
its objective by seeking to make the best possible use of all the resources at its disposal; it is, in
fact, to ensure the smooth working of the 6 essential functions. Administration is only one of these
functions. (Urwick, 1943: 16)
Fayol broke down this key function of Administration into 5 main aspects:
to planto organizeto commandto coordinateto control.
But the word he used, prevoyance, which has been translated to plan, really covers 2
functions. He wrote prevoir [literally, to foresee] as used here means both to foretell the future and
to prepare for it. In other words, the one term meant both Forecasting and Planning. These 6
aspects of Administration fall into main groups related as to process and effect. That is to say:
Forecasting [process] leads to a Plan [effect]Organization [process] has as its object Coordination
[effect]Command [process] issues in Control [effect]. (Urwick, 1943: 16)
Fayols analysis was simply concerned with aspects of Administration with operations.
But elsewhere he lists, somewhat empirically, 16 Administrative Duties. The 2nd of his
Administrative Duties provides a very sound principle on which to base Forecasting, that is,
Appropriateness; see that the human and material organization are suitable. His 14th
Administrative Duty equally provides a principle on which to base Planning, that is Order; ensure
material and human order. (Urwick, 1943: 17)
Thus the Logical Square is completed with the exception of the principle underlying the
whole process of Administration. And here it is not unduly straining probability to imagine that
Fayol himself would have inserted Investigation. Certainly to students of scientific management,
the idea of research into facts as the basis of all activity is fundamental. And every writer of note
on the subject is at one on the point. For instance, Mary Parker Follett, in the last lecture that she
delivered in public before her death wrote, I have given four principles of organization. The
underpinning of these is information based on research. F. W. Taylor, when he first attempted to
reduce his practice to generalizations, put first of the new duties devolving on management that,
They develop a science for each element of a mans work that replaces the old rule of thumb
method. Both sides must recognize as essential the substitution of exact scientific Investigation
and knowledge for the old individual judgment or opinion. (Urwick, 1943: 17, 18)
These 3 principles; Investigation, Forecasting and Planning, each with its corresponding
principle, process and effect, make up the perfect Logical Square summarizing the main aspects
of Administration. The underlying principle on which the whole art rests is Investigation. It enters
into process with Forecasting and the effect is Planning. Forecasting has its own principle,
namely, Appropriateness. It enters into process with Organization, since the first thing you do
when you look ahead is to try to provide the means, human and material, to meet the future
situation which you foresee. Its effect is Coordination. Finally, Planning finds its underlying
principle in Order. Order enters into process with Command, and the effect is Control. This
arrangement of the material is shown in tabular form in Figure [1] (pg 102). (Urwick, 1943: 18)
The Unified Pattern of Administration, Figure [6] (pg 107), is a 2 part functional flowchart. It
depicts the Logical Square relationships and designated actions of Urwicks 3 Logical Squares of
27 Administrative Process principles coupled with 5 additional Governing principles that were
alluded to but not specified by Urwick. The following describes the 4 actions that occur among the
principles.
All curved vertical lines have an arrow and represent the action enters into process with.
A straight vertical line with an arrow represents the action takes effect in.
A straight vertical line without an arrow represents the action result in.
All 90 degree angle lines have arrows and represent the action finds its underlying
principle in.
It is worth the effort to refer to Figure [6], while reading through this section.
The Unified Pattern of Administration has 2 parts, Governing, and Administrative Process.
Urwick, with a quote from Fayol in the header section of the Administration Logical Square (pg
102), recognized Administration and Governing as different and separate functions.
Administration must not be confused with government. To govern is to conduct an undertaking
towards its objective by seeking to make the best possible use of all the resources at its disposal.
To this Urwick added: The general objective and broad policy of any undertaking are therefore
given before administration starts.
GOVERNING
Governing is the 1st of 2 parts that comprise the Unified Pattern of Administration.
Governing is the result of Governing Authority. It is subordinated under Governing Authority and
finds its underlying principle in Governing Objectives that enter into process with Administration
and result in Administrative Process, the 2nd of the 2 parts.
Governing Authority has overall control of the enterprise. It could be the owners, a Board of
Directors, Board of Regents, Joint Chiefs of Staff, Board of Governors, an individual; or whatever
is appropriate for the type of enterprise which could be industrial, commercial, civil, educational,
military, hospital, etc. Governing Authority provides the oversight to direct the enterprise seeking
to obtain the best possible use of all of the resources at its disposal. Governing Authority finds its
underlying principle in Governing Objectives that encompass the purpose, objectives and general
policies of the enterprise.
Ralph C. Davis, a Professor of Business Organization at Ohio State University, was one of
the chief representatives of the classical approach to administration. Professor Davis focused his
work on business organizations. He recognized that the Governing Objectives of a business
should be balanced to service both internal business objectives and external objectives relative
to the public interest and to the total environment in which the business must function and survive.
The Unified General Theory of Administration adopts Professor Daviss views but expands
their scope to include all types of enterprise such as industrial, commercial, civil, educational,
military, hospital, etc. Consequently in the quotes adopted from his work that follow, the term
business has been replaced with the general term enterprise.
Enterprise objectives may be any of the values that the enterprise is required or expected
to acquire, create, preserve, or distribute. They may be tangible or intangible. Enterprise
objectives may be broken down into three general classes: primary, collateral, and secondary.
(Davis, 1951: 10)
primary objectivesThe economic values provided by the enterprise are necessarily the
primary objectives of the enterprise. The primary mission of an enterprise is to supply the public
with whatever goods and/or services it desires at the proper time and place, in the required
amounts having the desired qualities, and at a price that the public is willing to pay. (Davis, 1951:
10)
collateral objectivesThese are the values that an enterprise is expected to supply
without detrimental sacrifice of the primary objectives. Collateral objectives includes chiefly
those personal and social objectives that are affected by the operations of the enterprise.
Personal collateral objectives are values that individuals and groups within the enterprise seek
to acquire and distribute among themselves. The term includes good wages for operative
employees, good salaries for management employees, good dividends for investors, and other
such values, both tangible and intangible. Social collateral objectives are those broad, general
values that are deemed necessary to the wellbeing of society that can be affected by enterprise
activity. These would include the interests of broader groups such as, political, religious or social
groups. Enterprise activity should also be conducted with due regard for them. Collateral
groups. Enterprise activity should also be conducted with due regard for them. Collateral
objectives should also include the interests of other groups such as dealers, suppliers, and
bankers, when they are associated with the particular enterprise. Collateral objectives rank with
but after primary objectives. (Davis, 1951: 10, 11)
secondary objectivesSecondary objectives include those values that are needed by the
enterprise for the accomplishment of its primary and collateral objectives with the required
economy and effectiveness. These values are not necessarily secondary in importance. They are
secondary in incidence of service. They rank, therefore, after primary and collateral objectives.
(Davis, 1951: 11)
A key secondary objective is the necessary and important service of maintaining working
conditions including physical facilities in accordance with established standards. The purpose of
maintenance standards is chiefly for reasonable assurance that the enterprise will have good
physical conditions of work because effective and economical accomplishment of enterprise work
depends on such conditions. Accomplishment of the immediate objectives of maintenance work
does not directly satisfy the needs of either the customer or the employee. It contributes indirectly
to their satisfaction, however. Maintenance is a staff service in most enterprises. It is a function of
staff to provide the enterprise with the service values it needs for the satisfactory accomplishment
of its objectives. Secondary objectives become more and more the objectives of staff departments
with continued enterprise growth. Their accomplishment frequently presents difficult internal
problems for management. [Davis]
Policies are basically statements of principles and rules that are set up as guides and
constraints for administrative thought and action. The principle purpose of policy is to enable
Administration to relate enterprise work to its objectives. Policies govern decisions based on
previously approved plans concerning what should be done, how it should be done, who should
do it, where it should take place and similar questions. They guide the coordination of action
after it has been initiated. Consequently policies are a fundamental consideration in planning,
organizing, and controlling enterprise activities. (Davis, 1951: 13)
Enterprise organization in a modern industrial society is inevitably charged with a public
interest. An enterprise should conduct its activities in conformity with accepted standards of
proper conduct for political as well as moral reasons. The larger the enterprise, the more this
becomes necessary. Standards of conduct are criteria of the extent to which a given enterprise is
compatible with the public interest. They condition our relations with customers, employees,
investors, and others. Acceptance tends to be based on the system of values that is currently in
effect in the society. Hence standards of business conduct tend to be relative like any ethical
criteria. They may be established by custom, law, court decisions, administrative rulings of
governmental agencies, voluntary codes of trade associations, or other means. The
contributions of ethical standards of business conduct are fundamental. There is accordingly a
universal need for them in legitimate business activities. (Davis, 1951: 9, 11, 12, 130)
Objectives must be given a primary position in any discussion of Administration. Governing
Objectives should be established before entering the Administrative Process. The Administrative
Process guides the implementation or analysis of an enterprise from principle to principle. The
choices made from the options available for each principle should be guided by Governing
Objectives. Governing Authority establishes Governing Objectives to define the purpose of the
enterprise, establish its broad policies and set enterprise objectives. Governing Objectives should
provide Administration with the functional degrees of freedom and constraints and with the ethical
standards within which it will operate in pursuing the purposes and general interests of the
enterprise.
THE ADMINISTRATIVE PROCESS
Governing Objectives enter into process with Administration and result in Administrative
Process. Administrative Process is the 2nd part of the Unified Pattern of Administration (pg 107) It
depicts a logical flow chart of Urwicks 27 Logical Square principles that are subordinated under
Administration. The principles of Administrative Process establish the organization and the staff
required to implement the Governing Objectives.
The Administrative Process begins with Investigation. Investigation is the underlying
principle on which the whole art of Administration rests. Investigation or research is the basis for
prediction and is the principle that precedes the process of Forecasting. Investigation deals with
making a detailed research inquiry or systematic inquiry into an examination of facts. [Urwick] The
purpose of Investigation is to identify and estimate the full scope and variety of the economic
requirements for the fulfillment of the Governing Objectives. The first thing to be done
administratively when you look ahead is to define and set up the general structure of the
enterprise with reference to its objectives, its means of operation and its future course as
determined by Planning. It is to give form to the whole and to every detail its place. [Fayol]
Investigation enters into process with Forecasting and takes effect in Planning.
Investigation enters into process with Forecasting and takes effect in Planning.
Governing Objectives are executed through Administrative Process that divides into 2
branches via its 2nd principle Forecasting and its 3rd principle Planning.
The Coordinative Branch of Structure and Task Principles is subordinated under
Forecasting.
The General Interest Branch of Staffing and Behavior Principles is subordinated under
Planning.
Forecasting should be in terms that correspond with the realities of the situation, i.e. with
the general objective and broad policy of the undertaking. Forecasting has its principle, process
and effect. The underlying principle is Appropriateness that enters into process with Organization
resulting in Coordination. Appropriateness deals with the suitability of the Organization for its
intended purpose. [Urwick] See that the human and material Organization are suitable for the
objectives, resources and needs of the enterprise. [Fayol]
The first point to remember is the position of Organization in the general scheme of
Administration. It is the way by which Forecasting enters into process. That is to say, it is not an
end in itself, it is a means to an end. Forecasting itself postulates an a priori decision of the main
objectives and general policies of the enterprise. Moreover, Forecasting cannot take effect in
Planning unless a great deal of detailed precision has been used in defining the Governing
Objectives. This applies also to Organization and to every part of any Organization. The
Organization should only exist in order to carry out some specific purpose implicit in the Forecast
and the Plan. Every piece of it should make a definite and authorized contribution to that purpose.
Otherwise there is no reason for its existence. (Urwick, 1943: 42)
Forecasting deals with the way in which the Organization structure is designed and
assembled. In good engineering practice, design must come first. Similarly in good social practice
design should come first. The effort to work out principles of Organization structure first and
separately from the Staffing problems which arise from them, is worthwhile. Logically it is
inconceivable that any individual should be appointed to a position without a clear idea of the
responsibilities and relationships attached to it and the standard of performance that is expected.
Unless jobs are clearly put together along lines of functional specialization it is impossible to train
new men to succeed to positions as the incumbents are promoted, resign, or retire. It is important
to think consciously and technically about Organization and to lay out structure first and not think
about Staffing until structure has been determined. [Urwick]
The characteristics contained in the ideal type correspond, more or less, to actual features
of existing organizations. With the aim of maximum efficiency, these characteristics are linked to
one another by a system of control based on rational rules that try to regulate the whole
organizational structure and process on the basis of technical knowledge. Authority is
legitimized by a belief in the correctness of the rules. The loyalty of the bureaucrat is oriented to
an impersonal order, to a superior position, not to the person who holds it. The decisive criterion
is whether or not the authority relations have a precise and impersonal character as a result of the
elaboration of rational rules. In order to rationalize and make an administrative machine efficient,
one has to control and guide administrative behavior by strict rational rules thus limiting individual
initiative to a minimum. (Mouzelis, 1969: 38, 39, 40, 41)
Many criticisms of Webers concept of Bureaucracy are rather irrelevant, as they make the
assumption that the ideal type has the same logical status as a simple classificatory type, or as an
empirical model. For example, the ideal type has been criticized for not focusing on other crucial
aspects of organizational reality such as informal organization and dysfunctional consequences.
To such criticism, Weber could reply that it was not his intention to construct a model of
Bureaucracy that would, as much as possible, approximate the real world. Rather, he tried to
identify the administrative characteristics typical of a certain kind of organization. The only way
to make a valid criticism of Webers concept of Bureaucracy is to consider it as what it was meant
to be, an ideal type, and to analyze it on this level. Webers construct was meant to be an
analytic tool contributing directly to the explanation and interpretation of social phenomena. It
was not meant by Weber to be simply an extreme type. Weber does not consider the ideal type
as a theoretical model, that is as a set of interconnected hypotheses which can be validated or
rejected by empirical research The ideal construction must be objectively possible. It must also
make sense to us, give us the feeling of consistency and plausibility. It is this kind of intuitive
understanding, of empathetic knowledge which plays a great role in the construction and
comprehension of the ideal type. In the case of Bureaucracy, it is the meaning of rationality,
grasped in the above intuitive manner, which links together the various ideal characteristics and
which gives consistency and logic to the whole construct. (Mouzelis, 1969: 43, 44, 45, 46)
An ideally rational organization, in the Weberian sense, is an organization performing its
tasks with maximum efficiency. Thus the selection and exaggeration of the various empirical
elements and their interconnections were established in such a way, that a perfectly efficient
organization would result if ever such an extreme type could exist in reality. In other terms,
Weber attached the attribute of rationality to the combination of empirical elements that he
incorporated into his ideal type. This evaluative assumption is not a hypothesis to be checked by
further research. It is simply the meaning of Bureaucracy that results when this type of
organization is imagined in isolation from all alien elements that, in the real world, distort its
ideal rationality. The issue at this point is to what extent it is possible to construct a conceptual
model of a perfectly rational organization. The model would be constructed by specifying in detail
and without previous research, the combination of characteristics that should, if ever realized,
give the maximum degree of efficiency. Or in other words, to what extent is it possible, assuming
the members of an organization to be acting in the most efficient way in the accomplishment of
their tasks, to find out by the imagination only what the characteristics of such an organization
should look like?(Mouzelis, 1969: 46, 47)
For Weber the ideal type is a conceptual tool which helps us to understand better social
phenomena, by analyzing the discrepancy between their ideal form and their concrete state. In
our case the problem should be to compare the ideal type of Bureaucracy with a real
administration, find out the differences, and try to explain them. Even if a conceptual construction
of an ideal Bureaucracy was possible, in order to make the comparison, we ought to know
something about concrete Bureaucracy. But to do this, we have to use a non-ideal model, that is a
model which attempts to describe, explain and approach, as much as possible, the real situation.
One should construct a realistic model, learn something about actual efficiency or inefficiency of
real organizations and then try, on the basis of this knowledge to speculate on the hypothetical
form of an entirely rational model. Thus one does not need an ideal type in order to understand
realty, but rather one needs some knowledge of reality in order to construct an ideal model (at
least in the study of Bureaucracy). Weber uses the ideal type of Bureaucracy as a tool for
comparison with real situations. In this context the ideal type helps to isolate the factors on which
the comparison becomes critical. (Mouzelis, 1969: 48, 49)
The following is a list of features describing Webers ideal legal monocratic type of
Bureaucracy from Amatai Etzionis book Modern Organizations. Etzioni condensed these
features from the book, MAX WEBER: The Theory of Social and Economic Organization, a
translation of Webers Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft by A. M. Henderson and Talcott Parsons
translation of Webers Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft by A. M. Henderson and Talcott Parsons
published in the United States in 1947.
Weber spelled out in considerable detail the features of the bureaucratic structure. They
all specify what makes a highly rational structure.
A continuous organization of official functions bound by rules. Rational organization is the
antithesis of ad hoc, temporary, unstable relations; hence the stress on continuity. Rules save
effort by obviating the need for deriving a new solution for every problem and case; they facilitate
standardization and equality in the treatment of many cases. These advantages are impossible if
each client is treated as a unique case, as an individual.
A specific sphere of competence. This involves a sphere of obligations to perform
functions that have been marked off as part of a systematic division of labor; the provision of the
incumbent with the necessary authority to carry out these functions; and that the necessary means
of compulsion are clearly defined and their use is subject to definite conditions. Thus a systematic
division of labor rights and power is essential for rational organization. Not only must each
participant know his job and have the means to carry it out, which includes first of all the ability to
command others, but he also must know the limits of his job, rights, and power so as not to
overstep the boundaries between his role and those of others and thus undermine the whole
structure.
The organization of offices follows the principle of hierarchy; that is, each lower office is
under the control and supervision of a higher one. In this way no office is left uncontrolled.
Compliance cannot be left to chance, it has to be systematically checked and reinforced.
The rules, which regulate the conduct of an office, may be technical rules or norms. In both
cases, if their application is to be fully rational specialized training is necessary. It is thus normally
true that only a person who has demonstrated an adequate technical training is qualified to be a
member of the administrative staff. Weber thought that the root of the authority of the bureaucrat is
his knowledge and his training. Not that these replace legitimation, but his command of technical
skill and knowledge is the basis on which legitimation is granted to him.
It is a matter of principle that the members of the administrative staff should be completely
separated from ownership of the means of production or administration. There exists, furthermore,
in principal, complete separation of the property belonging to the organization, which is controlled
within the spheres of the office, and of the personal property of the official. This segregation of the
bureaucrats personal residence from the organization keeps the officials bureaucratic status
from being infringed by the demands of his non-organizational statuses.
In order to enhance this organizational freedom, the resources of the organization have to
be free of any outside control and any incumbent cannot monopolize the position. They have to
be free to be allocated and reallocated according to the needs of the organization. A complete
absence of appropriation of his official position by the incumbent is required.
Administrative acts, decisions, and rules are formulated and recorded in writing. Most
observers might view this requirement as less essential or basic to rational organization than the
preceding ones, and many will point to the irrationality of keeping excessive records, files, and the
like, often referred to as red tape. Weber, however, stressed the need to maintain a systematic
interpretation of norms and enforcement of rules, which cannot be maintained through oral
communication.
Weber pointed out that officials should be compensated by salaries and not receive
payments from clients to ensure that their primary orientation be to the organization, to its norms
and representatives. Moreover, by promoting officials systematically, thus channeling their
ambitions by providing them with careers, and by rewarding those loyal to it, the corporation
would reinforce this commitment.
Underlying the whole analysis is a set of principles that follows from the central
organizational problem as Weber saw it. The high rationality of the bureaucratic structure is
fragile; it needs to be constantly protected against external pressures to safeguard the autonomy
required if it is to be kept closely geared to its goals and not others.
The rules Weber specified are concerned with relationships between bureaucrats, i.e.,
those who make up the administrative body of the organizational hierarchy and structure. But,
Weber indicated organizations have non-bureaucratic heads. Although the bureaucrats follow the
rules, the head sets them; although the administrative body serves the organizations goals, the
head decides which goals are to be served; although the bureaucrats are appointed, he is often
elected or inherits his position. Presidents, cabinets, boards of trustees, and kings are typical non-
bureaucratic heads of bureaucratic organizations. These organizational heads fulfill an
important function in helping to maintain the emotional and in this sense, non-rational
commitment to rationality. {Etzioni, 1964: 53,54)
The following is Webers discourse on his ideal legal monocratic type of Bureaucracy. It is
adopted directly from the above mentioned book, MAX WEBER: The Theory of Social and
Economic Organization.
Economic Organization.
Experience tends universally to show that the purely bureaucratic type of administrative
organization, that is, the monocratic variety of Bureaucracy is, from a purely technical point of
view, capable of attaining the highest degree of efficiency and is in this sense, formally the most
rational known means of carrying out imperative control over human beings. It is superior to any
other form in precision, in stability, in the stringency of its discipline, and in its reliability. It thus
makes possible a particularly high degree of calculability of results for the heads of the
organization and for those acting in relation to it. It is finally superior both in intensive efficiency
and in the scope of its operation, and is formally capable of application to all kinds of
administrative tasks.
The development of the modern form of the organization of corporate groups in all fields is
nothing less than identical with the development and continual spread of bureaucratic
administration. This is true of church and state, of armies, political parties, economic enterprises,
and organizations to promote all kinds of causes, private associations, clubs, and many others. Its
development is, to take the most striking case, the most crucial phenomenon of the modern
western state. However many forms there may be which do not appear to fit this pattern, such as
collegial representative bodies, parliamentary committees, soviets, honorary officers, lay judges,
and what not, and however much people may complain about the evils of bureaucracy, it would
be sheer illusion to think for a moment that continuous administrative work can be carried out in
any field except by means of officials working in offices. The whole pattern of everyday life is cut
to fit this framework. For bureaucratic administration is, other things being equal, always, from a
formal, technical point of view, the most rational type. For the needs of mass administration today,
it is completely indispensable. The choice is only that between Bureaucracy and dilettantism in
the field of administration.
The primary source of the superiority of bureaucratic administration lies in the role of
technical knowledge, which, through the development of modern technology and business
methods in the production of goods, has become completely indispensable. In this respect, it
makes no difference whether the economic system is organized on a capitalistic or a socialistic
basis. Indeed, if in the latter case a comparable level of technical efficiency were to be achieved,
it would mean a tremendous increase in the importance of specialized Bureaucracy.
When those subject to bureaucratic control seek to escape the influence of the existing
bureaucratic apparatus, this is normally possible only by creating an organization of their own
which is equally subject to the process of bureaucratization. Similarly, the existing bureaucratic
apparatus is driven to continue functioning by the most powerful interests which are material and
objective, but also ideal in character. Without it, a society like our own, with a separation of
officials, employees, and workers from ownership of the means of administration, dependent on
discipline and on technical training, could no longer function. Even in case of revolution by force
or of occupation by an enemy, the bureaucratic machinery will normally continue to function just
as it has for the previous legal government.
Though by no means alone, the capitalistic system has undeniably played a major role in
the development of Bureaucracy. Indeed, without it capitalistic production could not continue and
any rational type of socialism would have simply to take it over and increase its importance. Its
development, largely under capitalistic auspices, has created an urgent need for stable, strict,
intensive, and calculable administration. Only by reversion in every fieldpolitical, religious,
economic, etc.to small scale organization would it be possible to any considerable extent to
escape its influence. On the one hand, capitalism in its modern stages of development strongly
tends to foster the development of Bureaucracy, though both capitalism and Bureaucracy have
risen from many different historical sources. Conversely, capitalism is the most rational economic
basis for bureaucratic administration and enables it to develop in the most rational form especially
because, from a fiscal point of view, it supplies the necessary money resources.
Bureaucratic administration means fundamentally the exercise of control on the basis of
knowledge. This is the feature of it, which makes it specifically rational. This consists on the one
hand in technical knowledge which, by itself, is sufficient to ensure it a position of extraordinary
power. But in addition to this, bureaucratic organizations, or the holders of power who make use
of them, have the tendency to increase their power still further by the knowledge growing out of
experience in the service. For they acquire through the conduct of office a special knowledge of
facts and have available a store of documentary material peculiar to themselves. Bureaucracy is
superior in knowledge, including both technical knowledge and knowledge of the concrete fact
within its own sphere of interest, which is usually confined to the interests of a private business
and capitalistic enterprise. (Weber, 1947: 337339)
SUMMARYBureaucracy
It is far more fruitful to speak of a degree of bureaucratization rather than of Bureaucracy or
non-Bureaucracy in an absolute sense. Bureaucracy is actually a characteristic possessed to a
non-Bureaucracy in an absolute sense. Bureaucracy is actually a characteristic possessed to a
greater or lesser extent by all formal Organizations. (Scott, 1967: 249)
There are almost as many formulations of the essential characteristics of Bureaucracy as
there are writers on the subject. Nevertheless, the area of agreement on the structural and
organizational features that are central is substantial. The pivotal structural characteristics can be
reduced to three: (1) hierarchy, (2) division or specialization of labor and (3) qualification or
competence. The pivotal organizational features that are central are a body of rules governing the
behavior of members, a system of records, a system of procedures for dealing with work
situations, and size sufficient at least to assure a network of secondary group relationships. The
variations come mostly in the way these aspects are expressed and in the divergence that comes
when behavioral traits are added. (Heady, 1966: 20)
The ideal type of Bureaucracy is a tool of comparison for developing, analyzing and
evaluating the Organization design of an enterprise. The purpose of the comparison is to locate
where, how, and by how much the real Organization will fall short of the impossible to achieve
efficiency levels of the ideal type of Bureaucracy. These then can receive special attention and,
where possible, alternative or supplemental actions to counteract or neutralize these control
shortfalls could be implemented to improve control over the general interest of the enterprise.
Organization is a discrete entity with characteristics and Bureaucracy is a variable
characteristic of Organization. Bureaucracy has objective existence in Organization and is not
merely an idea. The usual and normal goal of an Organization is to be the most efficient and
effective possible. The closer that an Organization approximates a Weber ideal type monocratic
Bureaucracy the greater will be the probability that it can approach that most efficient and effective
goal. Bureaucracy does not have a separate existence but is latent in The Unified Pattern of
Administration. It develops and takes form naturally, rationally and unavoidably through the
design and operation of an Organization.
Humans, like Organizations, are discrete units. They are entities with characteristics.
Humans man the Organizations and bring with them, among their many characteristics, Maslows
Hierarchy of Human Needs that is a latent, supplementary, psychological component of The
Unified General Theory of Administration. It is discussed in the next section.
Chapter Six - MASLOWS HIERARCHY OF HUMAN NEEDS A PSYCHOLOGICAL
COMPONENT
Physiological Needs
Man is a wanting animal. As soon as one of his needs is satisfied, another appears in its
place. This process is unending. It continues from birth to death. Mans needs are organized in a
series of levels, a hierarchy of importance. At the lowest level, but preeminent in importance when
they are thwarted, are his physiological needs. Man lives for bread alone, when there is no bread.
Unless the circumstances are unusual, his needs for love, for status, for recognition are
inoperative when his stomach has been empty for a while. But when he eats regularly and
adequately, hunger ceases to be an important need. The sated man has hunger only in the sense
that a full bottle has emptiness. The same is true of the other physiological needs of manfor
rest, exercise, shelter, protection from the elements. A satisfied need is not a motivator of
behavior! This is a fact of profound significance. It is a fact that is regularly ignored in the
conventional approach to the management of people. One example will make my point.
Consider your own need for air: Except as you are deprived of it, it has no appreciable motivation
effect upon your behavior. (McGregor, 1964: 271)
Safety Needs
When the physiological needs are reasonably satisfied, needs at the next higher level
begin to dominate mans behavior, to motivate him. These are called safety needs. They are
needs for protection against danger, threat, and deprivation. Some people mistakenly refer to
these as needs for security. However, unless man is in a dependent relationship where he fears
arbitrary deprivation, he does not demand security. The need is for the fairest possible break.
When he is confident of this, he is more than willing to take risks. But when he feels threatened or
dependent, his greatest need is for guarantees, for protection, for security.
The fact needs little emphasis that since every industrial employee is in a dependent
relationship, safety needs may assume considerable importance. Arbitrary management actions,
relationship, safety needs may assume considerable importance. Arbitrary management actions,
behavior which arouses uncertainty with respect to continued employment or which reflects
favoritism or discrimination, unpredictable administration of policythese can be powerful
motivators of the safety needs in the employment relationship at every level from worker to vice-
president. (McGregor, 1964: 271, 272)
Unlike the lower needs, these are rarely satisfied; man seeks indefinitely for more
satisfaction of these needs once they have become important to him. But they do not appear in
any significant way until physiological, safety and social needs are all reasonably satisfied.
The typical industrial organization offers few opportunities for the satisfaction of these
egoistic needs to people at lower levels in the hierarchy. The conventional methods of organizing
work, particularly in mass production industries, give little heed to these aspects of human
motivation. If the practices of scientific management were deliberately calculated to thwart these
needs, which of course they are not, they could hardly accomplish this purpose better than they
do. (McGregor, 1964: 272, 273)
SelfFulfillment Needs
Finally, a capstone, as it were, on the hierarchy of mans needs. There are what we may
call the needs for self-fulfillment. These are the needs for realizing ones own potentialities, for
continued self-development, for being creative in the broadest sense of that term. (McGregor,
1964: 273)
It is clear that the conditions of modern life give only limited opportunity for these relatively
weak needs to obtain expression. The deprivation most people experience with respect to other
lower level needs diverts their energies into the struggle to satisfy those needs, and the needs for
self-fulfillment remain dormant. (McGregor, 1964: 273)
The several subsections that follow were extracted from Maslows previously identified
paper. They fill the gaps and expand and enhance important aspects of Maslows Hierarchy of
Human Needs that McGregor cautioned that he had, of necessity, overgeneralized or bypassed.
Advancement to the next higher level usually occurred within the first 5 years of
incumbency. After 5 years at a level, advancements were rare and unusual. Promotions were
arithmetically infinitesimal from the 4th level to the 5th and highest-level plant position of General
Superintendent and from there on to the hierarchy of corporate executive positions.
At most of the three Superintendent levels there was an Assistant Superintendent position
that in addition to its essential functional utility, also facilitated the short tenure mobility of Upward
Mobile individuals. These Assistant Superintendent positions were usually occupied by near end-
Mobile individuals. These Assistant Superintendent positions were usually occupied by near end-
of-career individuals but they were also used for relatively short periods as career development
positions for Upward Mobile individuals.
Consider the bleak prospects of the 1st level Foremen. 90% of them spend their entire
management career at that 1st level. Most spend those years at the same plant, in the same
department, and usually on the same job. This also applies to the un-promoted 2nd level General
Foremen and 3rd level Department Superintendents. Indeed, an individual was fortunate to rise
even one level, and was truly blessed to rise two levels in the formal management hierarchy. This
distribution of opportunity is representative of all large, mature organizations. Normally, it would
take at least twenty years to become a General Superintendent, but it did not always work that
way. The tenure at successively higher management levels got shorter with each promotion for
those very few who would eventually reach the top plant and the higher corporate executive
levels, thus allowing career time for the rise to and through the corporate executive positions.
These select individuals were obvious en-route and were commonly viewed and referred to as
being on the fast-track.
The conditions and results in this example generally and variably are representative of all
mature hierarchical enterprises. There is not much room at the top in any of them. It is very
simply a case of time based, arithmetical, hierarchical convergence.
The example deals with management personnel in a hierarchical management role
structure. Management included operating, technical and administrative personnel variably
comprising 10% to 15% of the plants total personnel. The prospects for progressive hierarchical
success with increasing opportunities for workplace satisfaction are minimal at best for most of
the management personnel but are even less so for the remaining 85% to 90% of non-
management personnel. Non-management career paths for most are nonexistent. For some, there
is a very limited range of mobility into better-compensated non-management jobs. These are
usually achieved through attrition; by seniority or a formal bidding process, an arbitrary award, or
by pre-established skill progression from apprentice to journeyman. Although there are a few
exceptions, the best non-management compensation did not match that of 1st level management.
There is little job satisfaction for non-management personnel beyond Maslows physiological
level or for some, as was the case with this industry, the safety level if they work in a unionized
industry. Most of the nations non-management workforce does not. Both non-management and
management personnel have to make adjustments in their working lives to accommodate for the
almost nonexistent opportunities to find sources of satisfaction in the workplace for their higher
level Maslow Hierarchy of Human Needs. This adjustment is occasionally but very slightly eased
for some through mock mobility that is achieved by upgrading position titles. Janitors are titled
custodians; reporters titled journalists; clerks titled administrators; secretaries titled executive
assistants; salesmen titled sales executives; large banks create innumerable vice-president titles;
executive support staffs are given assistant-to-the titles; etc. The described circumstances are
ubiquitous in mature hierarchical organizations. They occur there naturally, rationally and
unavoidably.
It is possible to suggest a reasoned numerical estimate of the proportional distribution
among the three modal types. At least 90% of all management and non-management personnel
in a mature hierarchically structured enterprise can be classified as actively Indifferent, at least
57% can be classified as actively Ambivalent and at least 12% classified as active Upward
Mobiles. The residual 1% is a mix of individuals in the process of modal type transition and those
with dysfunctional personalities such as, malcontents, individuals in denial, etc.
Very few Upward Mobile individuals remain active Upward Mobiles throughout their
career. Some Upward Mobile individuals must arithmetically top-out at every low, middle and top
management level where they eventually transition to Indifferent.
A few Ambivalent individuals will make the transition to Upward Mobility and a few will
eventually accept their lack of mobility and transition to Indifferent.
Indifference is the typical pattern of accommodation for the majority of organization
personnel. The Indifferents make up virtually all of the great mass of non-management employees
and most of the management employees from foreman to vice-president. The Indifferents are
those who have come to terms with their work environment by withdrawal and by a redirection of
their interests toward off-the-job satisfactions. (Presthus, 1962: 205208)
At least 90% of the personnel of a mature enterprise will naturally, rationally and
unavoidably eventually transition to Indifference.
Chapter Eight - THE UNIFIED GENERAL THEORY OF ADMINISTRATION
IN GOVERNING:
It is implied that a Governing Authority (Board of Directors, Owner etc.) is responsible for
the enterprise and should exert control of the General Interest of the enterprise through Governing
Objectives to assure conformity with its General Interest and with accepted standards of proper
business conduct, customs, conventions and societies legal degrees of freedom and constraints
such as laws, statutes, ordinances, regulations etc.
It is implied that members of the Governing Authority should be functional and operative
and not just ceremonial.
It is implied that members of the Governing Authority must have the capability to
appropriately contribute to determining and guiding the General Interest of the enterprise.
It is implied that members of the Governing Authority should not simultaneously serve as
members of Administration. They are mutually exclusive responsibilities and accountabilities.
It is implied that Administration should always serve at the pleasure of the Governing
Authority.
It is implied that Governing Objectives should precisely define the General Interest of an
enterprise and empower Administration with the appropriate degrees of freedom and constraint
for their implementation.
It is implied that Governing Objectives are also the means through which Governing
Authority should regulate and audit the compliance of Administration and Management with the
General Interest of the enterprise.
It is implied that ethical standards of business conduct should be specifically established
through Governing Objectives.
It is implied that profit should not be the only Governing Objective of an enterprise.
It is implied that organization size should be no larger than necessary to implement its
Governing Objectives.