Unit 7
Unit 7
Unit 7
Objectives
After going through this unit, you should be able to: familiarise with the concepts and rules relevant for production decision analysis; understand the economics of production; understand the set of conditions required for efficient production.
Introduction to Microbes
Structure
7.1 7.2 7.3 7.4 7.5 7.6 7.7 7.8 7.9 Introduction Production Function Production Function with one Variable Input Production Function with two Variable Inputs The Optimal Combination of Inputs Returns to Scale Summary Self-Assessment Questions Further Readings
7.1 INTRODUCTION
Production process involves the transformation of inputs into output. The inputs could be land, labour, capital, entrepreneurship etc. and the output could be goods or services. In a production process managers take four types of decisions: (a) whether to produce or not, (b) how much output to produce, (c) what input combination to use, and (d) what type of technology to use. This Unit deals with the analysis of managers decision rules concerning (c) and (d) above. The analysis of the other two decisions will be covered in Units 8 and Unit 9 of this block. In this unit, we shall begin with a general discussion of the concept of production function. The analysis of this unit mainly focuses on the firms that produce a single product. Analysis on decisions related to multiproduct firms is also given briefly. The nature of production when there is only one variable input is taken up first. We then move on to the problem of finding optimum combination of inputs for producing a particular level of output when there are two or more variable inputs. You will learn various functional forms of production frequently used by economists and their empirical estimation in Unit 10. The unit concludes with the production decisions in case of product mix of multiproduct firms.
In general, we can represent the production function for a firm as: Q = f (x1, x2, .,xn) Where Q is the maximum quantity of output, x1, x2, .,xn are the quantities of various inputs, and f stands for functional relationship between inputs and output. For the sake of clarity, let us restrict our attention to only one product produced using either one input or two inputs. If there are only two inputs, capital (K) and labour (L), we write the production function as: Q = f (L, K) This function defines the maximum rate of output (Q) obtainable for a given rate of capital and labour input. It may be noted here that outputs may be tangible like computers, television sets, etc., or it may be intangible like education, medical care, etc. Similarly, the inputs may be other than capital and labour. Also, the principles discussed in this unit apply to situations with more than two inputs as well.
under consideration. The time period will vary depending on the circumstances. Although any input may be varied no matter how short the time interval, the cost involved in augmenting the amount of certain inputs is enormous; so as to make quick variation impractical. Such inputs are classified as fixed and include plant and equipment of the firm. On the other hand, a variable input is one whose amount can be changed during the relevant period. For example, in the construction business the number of workers can be increased or decreased on short notice. Many builder firms employ workers on a daily wage basis and frequent change in the number of workers is made depending upon the need. The amount of milk that goes in the production of butter can be altered quickly and easily and is thus classified as a variable input in the production process. Whether or not an input is fixed or variable depends upon the time period involved. The longer the length of the time period under consideration, the more likely it is that the input will be variable and not fixed. Economists find it convenient to distinguish between the short run and the long run. The short run is defined to be that period of time when some of the firms inputs are fixed. Since it is most difficult to change plant and equipment among all inputs, the short run is generally accepted as the time interval over which the firms plant and equipment remain fixed. In contrast, the long run is that period over which all the firms inputs are variable. In other words, the firm has the flexibility to adjust or change its environment. Production processes of firms generally permit a variation in the proportion in which inputs are used. In the long run, input proportions can be varied considerably. For example, at Maruti Udyog Limited, an automobile dye can be made on conventional machine tools with more labour and less expensive equipment, or it can be made on numerically controlled machine tools with less labour and more expensive equipment i.e. the amount of labour and amount of equipment used can be varied. Later in this unit, this aspect is considered in more detail. On the other hand, there are very few production processes in which inputs have to be combined in fixed proportions. Consider, Ranbaxy or Smith-Kline-Beecham or any other pharmaceutical firm. In order to produce a drug, the firm may have to use a fixed amount of aspirin per 10 gm of the drug. Even in this case a certain (although small) amount of variation in the proportion of aspirin may be permissible. If, on the other hand, no flexibility in the ratio of inputs is possible, the technology is described as fixed proportion type. We refer to this extreme case later in this unit, but as should be apparent, it is extremely rare in practice. Activity 1 1. What is a production function? How does a long run production function differ from a short run production function? ...................................................................................................................... ...................................................................................................................... ...................................................................................................................... ...................................................................................................................... ...................................................................................................................... 2. When can we say that a firm is: (a) technically efficient, (b) economically efficient? Is it necessary that a technically efficient firm is also economically efficient? ...................................................................................................................... ......................................................................................................................
Production Function
Two other important concepts are the average product (AP) and the marginal product (MP) of an input. The AP of an input is the TP divided by the amount of input used to produce this amount of output. Thus AP is the output-input ratio for each level of variable input usage. The MP of an input is the addition to TP resulting from the addition of one unit of input, when the amounts of other inputs are constant. In our example of machine parts production process, the AP of labour is the TP divided by the number of workers. APL = Q/L
As shown in Table 7.1, the APL first rises, reaches maximum at 19, and then declines thereafter. Similarly, the MP of labour is the additional output attributable to using one additional worker with use of other input (service of five machine tools) fixed. MP L = W Q/W L Where W means the change in. For example, from Table 7.1 for MP4 (marginal product of 4th worker) WQ = 7654 = 22 and WL = 43 =1. Therefore, MP4 = (22/1) = 22. Note that although the MP first increases with addition of workers, it declines later and for the addition of 8th worker it becomes negative (4).
Figure 7.1: Relationship between TP, MP, and AP curves and the three stages of production
Production Function
100 90
Thousands of Machine Parts
z y
TP
80 70 60
x
50 40 30 20 10 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
Stage I Stage II Stage III
26 24 22 20 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 -2 -4
AP MP
4.5
The graphical presentation of total, average, and marginal products for our example of machine parts production process is shown in Figure 7.1.
Three things should be noted concerning the law of diminishing marginal returns. 1. This law is an empirical generalization, not a deduction from physical or biological laws. 2. It is assumed that technology remains fixed. The law of diminishing marginal returns cannot predict the effect of an additional unit of input when technology is allowed to change. 3. It is assumed that there is at least one input whose quantity is being held constant (fixed). In other words, the law of diminishing marginal returns does not apply to cases where all inputs are variable.
Production Function
Stages of Production
Based on the behaviour of MP and AP, economists have classified production into three stages: Stage 1: MP > 0, AP rising. Thus, MP > AP. Stage 2: MP > 0, but AP is falling. MP < AP but TP is increasing (because MP > 0). Stage 3: MP < 0. In this case TP is falling. These results are illustrated in Figure 7.1. No profit-maximising producer would produce in stages I or III. In stage I, by adding one more unit of labour, the producer can increase the AP of all units. Thus, it would be unwise on the part of the producer to stop the production in this stage. As for stage III, it does not pay the producer to be in this region because by reducing the labour input the total output can be increased and the cost of a unit of labour can be saved. Thus, the economically meaningful range is given by stage II. In Figure 7.1 at the point of inflection (x), we saw earlier that MP is maximised. At point y, since AP is maximized, we have AP = MP. At point z, TP reaches a maximum. Thus, MP = 0 at this point. If the variable input is free then the optimum level of output is at point z where TP is maximized. However, in practice no input will be freely available. The producer has to pay a price for it. Suppose the producer pays Rs. 200 per worker per day and the price of a unit of output (say one apple) is Rs. 10. In this case the producer will keep on hiring additional workers as long as (price of a unit of output) * (marginal product of labour) > (price of a unit of labour) That is, marginal revenue of product (MRP) of labour > PL On a similar analogy, (price of a unit of output) * (marginal product of capital) > (price of a unit of capital) That is, marginal revenue of product (MRP) of capital > PK The left side denotes the increase in revenue and the right side denotes the increase in the cost of adding one more unit of labour. As long as the increment to revenues exceeds the increment to costs, the profit of the producer will increase. As we increase the units of labour, we see that MP diminishes. We assume that the prices of inputs and output do not change. In this case, as MP declines, revenues will start falling, and a point will come when the increase in revenue equals the increase in cost. At this point the producer will stop adding more units of input. With further addition, since MP
declines, the additional revenues would be less than the additional costs, and the profit of the producer would decline. Thus, profit maximization implies that a producer with no control over prices will increase the use of an input until Value of marginal product (MP) = Price of a unit of variable input Activity 2 1. Fill in the blanks of the following Table: Capital 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 8 9 Labour 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 15 11 1 2 12 14 2 2 1 TP 0 2 5 3 3 2 3 4 APL MP L
2. State clearly the relation between APL and MPL. ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... 3. Why is the marginal product of labour likely to increase and then decline in the short run? ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... 4. Faced with constantly changing conditions, why would a firm ever keep any factors fixed? What determines whether a factor is fixed or variable? ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... 5. Suppose a chair manufacturer is producing in the short run where equipment is fixed. The manufacturer knows that as the number of labourers used in the production process increases from 1 to 7, the number of chairs produced changes as follows: 10, 17, 22, 25, 26, 25, and 23. 8
Calculate the marginal and average product of labour for this production function. Does this production function exhibit increasing returns to labour or decreasing returns to labour or both? Explain. Explain intuitively what might cause the marginal product of labour to become negative?
Production Function
..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... 6. Why a profit-maximising producer would produce in stage-II and not in stage-I or III? Explain. ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... ..................................................................................................................... .....................................................................................................................
Production Isoquants
In Greek the word iso means equal or same. A production isoquant (equal output curve) is the locus of all those combinations of two inputs which yields a given level of output. With two variable inputs, capital and labour, the isoquant gives the different combinations of capital and labour, that produces the same level of output. For example, 5 units of output can be produced using either 15 units of capital (K) or 2 units of labour (L) or K=10 and L=3 or K=5 and L=5 or K=3 and L=7. These four combinations of capital and labour are four points on the isoquant associated with 5 units of output as shown in Figure 7.2. And if we assume that capital and labour are continuously divisible, there would be many more combinations on this isoquant. Now let us assume that capital, labour, and output are continuously divisible in order to set forth the typically assumed characteristics of isoquants. Figure 7.3 illustrates three such isoquants. Isoquant I shows all the combinations of capital and labour that will produce 10 units of output. According to this isoquant, it is possible to obtain this output if K0 units of capital and L0 units of
Figure 7.2: Production Isoquant: This iisoquant shows various combinations of capital and labour inputs that can produce 5 units of output.
Capital Input
22 20 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11
Q=5
Labour Input Figure 7.3: Isoquant Map: These isoquants shows various combinations of capital and labour inputs that can produce 10, 15, and 20 units of output.
Capital Input
K2
K1 K0 L2 L1 L0
Q3 = 20 Q2 = 15 Q1 = 10 Labour Input
10
labour inputs are used. Alternately, this output can also be obtained if K1 units of capital and L1 units of labour inputs or K2 units of capital and L2 units of labour are used. Similarly, isoquant II shows the various combinations of capital and labour that can be used to produce 15 units of output. Isoquant III shows all combinations that can produce 20 units of output. Each capitallabour combination can be on only one isoquant. That is, isoquants cannot intersect. These isoquants are only three of an infinite number of isoquants that could be drawn. A group of isoquants is called an isoquant map. In an isoquant map, all isoquants lying above and to the right of a given isoquant indicate higher levels of output. Thus, in Figure 7.3 isoquant II indicates a higher level of output than isoquant I, and isoquant III indicates a higher level of output than isoquant II.
In general, isoquants are determined in the following way. First, a rate of output, say Q0, is specified. Hence the production function can be written as Q0 = f (K,L) Those combinations of K and L that satisfy this equation define the isoquant for output rate Q0. Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution As we have seen above, generally there are a number of ways (combinations of inputs) that a particular output can be produced. The rate, at which one input can be substituted for another input, if output remains constant, is called the marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS). It is defined in case of two inputs, capital and labour, as the amount of capital that can be replaced by an extra unit of labour, without affecting total output.
= K L
Production Function
MRTSL
for K
It is customary to define the MRTS as a positive number, since WK/WL, the slope of the isoquant, is negative. Over the relevant range of production the MRTS diminishes. That is, more and more labour is substituted for capital while holding output constant, the absolute value of WK/WL decreases. For example, let us assume that 10 pairs of shoes can be produced using either 8 units of capital and 2 units of labour or 4 units each of capital and of labour or 2 units of capital and 8 units of labour. From Figure 7.4 the MRTS of labour for capital between points a and b is equal to WK/WL = (48) / (42) = 4/2 = 2 or | 2 |. Between points b and c, the MRTS is equal to 2/4 = or | |. The MRTS has decreased because capital and labour are not perfect substitutes for each other. Therefore, as more of labour is added, less of capital can be used (in exchange for another unit of labour) while keeping the output level constant.
Figure 7.4: Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution
10
8
Capital Input
6
b
0 0 2 4 6 8 10
Labour Input
There is a simple relationship between MRTS of labour for capital and the marginal product MPK and MPL of capital and labour respectively. Since along an isoquant, the level of output remains the same, if WL units of labour are substituted for WK units of capital, the increase in output due to WL units of
11
labour (namely, WL * MPL) should match the decrease in output due to a decrease of WK units of capital (namely, WK * MPK). In other words, along an isoquant, W L * MP L = W K * MP k which is equal to
K L = MPL MPK
However, as we have seen earlier WK/WL is equal to MRTSL for K, and hence, we get the following expression for MRTS of L for K as the ratio of the corresponding marginal products.
MRTS L for K = MPL MPK
There are vast differences among inputs in how readily they can be substituted for one another. For example, in some extreme production process, one input can perfectly be substituted for another; whereas in some other extreme production process no substitution is possible. On the other hand, in most of the production processes what we see is imperfect substitution of inputs. These three general shapes that an isoquant might have are shown in Figure 7.5. In panel I, the isoquants are right angles implying that the two inputs a and b must be used in fixed proportion and they are not at all substitutable. For instance, there is no substitution possible between the tyres and a battery in an automobile production process. The MRTS in all such cases would, therefore, be zero. The other extreme case would be where the inputs a and b are perfect substitutes as shown in panel II. The isoquants in this category will be a straight line with constant slope or MRTS. A good example of this type
Figure 7.5: Three General Types of Shapes of Isoquants
Input b
Q2 Q1 Input a Panel I
Input b p
Q2 Q1 Input a Panel II
Input b
Q2 Q1 Input a
12
Panel III
would be natural gas and fuel oil, which are close substitutes in energy production. The most common situation is presented in panel III. The inputs are imperfect substitutes in this case and the rate at which input a can be given up in return for one more unit of input b keeping the output constant diminishes as the amount of input b increases.
Production Function
Capital Input
Labour Input
13
Thus, the decision is to minimize cost subject to an output constraint or maximize the output subject to a cost constraint. We will now discuss these two fundamental principles. Before doing this we will introduce the concept isocost, which shows all combinations of inputs that can be used for a given cost.
Isocost Lines
Recall that a universally accepted objective of any firm is to maximise profit. If the firm maximises profit, it will necessarily minimise cost for producing a given level of output or maximise output for a given level of cost. Suppose there are 2 inputs: capital (K) and labour (L) that are variable in the relevant time period. What combination of (K,L) should the firm choose in order to maximise output for a given level of cost? If there are 2 inputs, K,L, then given the price of capital (Pk) and the price of labour (PL), it is possible to determine the alternative combinations of (K,L) that can be purchased for a given level of expenditure. Suppose C is total expenditure, then C= PL* L + Pk* K This linear function can be plotted on a graph.
Figure 7.7: Isocost line K C/Pk A P N ISOCOST
B O C/PL L
If only capital is purchased, then the maximum amount that can be bought is C/Pk shown by point A in figure 7.7. If only labour is purchased, then the maximum amount of labour that can be purchased is C/PL shown by point B in the figure. The 2 points A and B can be joined by a straight line. This straight line is called the isocost line or equal cost line. It shows the alternative combinations of (K,L) that can be purchased for the given expenditure level C. Any point to the right and above the isocost is not attainable as it involves a level of expenditure greater than C and any point to the left and below the isocost such as P is attainable, although it implies the firm is spending less than C. You should verify that the slope of the isocost is1 EXAMPLE : Consider the following data: PL = 10, Pk = 20 Total Expenditure = 200. Let us first plot the various combinations of K and L that are possible. We
K L C P
k
C P
L
L k
14
1 The nagative sign is due to the fact that the slope of the isocost is negative.
consider only the case when the firm spends the entire budget of 200. The alternative combinations are shown in the figure (7.8).
Production Function
K 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 O 2 4 6 8 C 10 12 14 16 18 20 B L A
The slope of this isocost is . What will happen if labour becomes more expensive say PL increases to 20? Obviously with the same budget the firm can now purchase lesser units of labour. The isocost still meets the Yaxis at point A (because the price of capital is unchanged), but shifts inwards in the direction of the arrow to meet the X-axis at point C. The slope therefore changes to 1. You should work out the effect on the isocost curve on the following: (i) decrease in the price of labour (ii) increase in the price of capital (iii) decrease in the price of capital (iv) increase in the firms budget with no change in the price of labour and capital [Hint: The slope of the isocost will not change in this case]
Alternatively, consider the problem of maximising output subject to a given cost amount. You should satisfy yourself that among all possible output levels, the maximum amount will be represented by the isoquant that is tangent to the relevant isocost line. Suppose the budget of the firm increases to the amount shown by the higher of the two isocost lines in Figure 7.9, point Q or 100 units of output is the maximum attainable given the new cost constraint in Figure 7.9.
Figure 7.9: Optimal combination of inputs
Capital Input
K A
K1 Z
Q B L1 Labour Input
150 100 50 L
Regardless of the production objective, efficient production requires that the isoquant be tangent to the isocost function. If the problem is to maximise output, subject to a cost constraint or to minimise cost for a given level of output, the same efficiency condition holds true in both situations. Intuitively, if it is possible to substitute one input for another to keep output constant while reducing total cost, the firm is not using the least cost combination of inputs. In such a situation, the firm should substitute one input for another. For example, if an extra rupee spent on capital generates more output than an extra rupee spent on labour, then more capital and less labour should be employed. At point Q in Figure 7.9, the marginal product of capital per rupee spent on capital is equal to the marginal product of labour per rupee spent on labour. Mathematically this can be shown as
MPL PL MPK PK
Or equivalently,
MPL MPK PL PK
21
Whenever the 2 sides of the above equation are not equal, there are
Recall that MPL is the slope of the isoquant and it is also the MRTS while
PL PK
MPK
is the slope of the isocost line. Since for optimum, the isocost must be tangent to the isoquant, the result follows. Many text books denote PL which is the price of labour as w or the wage rate and Pk which is the price of capital as r or the rental. The equilibrium condition can thus also be written as
MP L
w r
16
MP K
possibilities that input substitutions will reduce costs. Let us work with numbers. Suppose PL = 10, Pk = 20, MPL = 50 and MPk = 40. Thus, we have 50 > 40 10 20 This cannot be an efficient input combination, because the firm is getting more output per rupee spent on labour than on capital. If one unit of capital is sold to obtain 2 units of labour (Pk = 20, PL = 10), net increase in output will be 602. Thus the substitution of labour for capital would result in a net increase in output at no additional cost. The inefficient combination corresponds to a point such as A in Figure 7.9. At that point two much capital is employed. The firm, in order to maxmise profits will move down the isocost line by substituting labour for capital until it reaches point Q. Conversely, at a point such as B in figure 7.9 the reverse is true - there is too much labour and the inequality
MPL PL MPK PK
Production Function
will hold
This means that the firm generates more output per rupee spent on capital than from rupees spent on labour. Thus a profit maximising firm should substitute capital for labour. Suppose the firm was operating at point B in Figure 7.9. If the problem is to minimise cost for a given level of output (B is on the isoquant that corresponds to 50 units of output), the firm should move from B to Z along the 50-unit isoquant thereby reducing cost, while maintaining output at 50. Alternatively, if the firm wants to maximise output for given cost, it should more from B to Q, where the isocost is tangent to the 100-unit isoquant. In this case output will increase from 50 to 100 at no additional cost. Thus both the following decisions: (a) the input combination that yields the maximum level of output with a given level of expenditure, and (b) the input combination that leads to the lowest cost of producing a given level of output are satisfied at point Q in Figure 7.9. You should be satisfied that this is indeed the case. The isocost-isoquant framework described above lends itself to various applications. It demonstrates, simply and elegantly, when relative prices of inputs change, managers will respond by substituting the input that has become relatively less expensive for the input that has become relatively more expensive. On average, we know that compared to developed countries like the US, UK, Japan and Germany, labour in India is less expensive. It is not surprising therefore to find production techniques that on average, use more labour per unit of capital in India than in the developed world. For example, in construction activity you see around you in your city, inexpensive workers do the job that in developed countries is performed by machines.
2 Since the MPL = 50, 2 units of labour produce 100 units, while reducing capital by 1 unit decreases output by 40 units (MPk = 40). Therefore, net increase is 60 units. This, of course, assumes that MPL and MPk remain constant in the relevant range. We know that as more labour is employed in place of capital, MPL will decline and MPK will increase (this follows from the law of diminishing returns) and thus equation (1) will be satisfied.
17
One application of the isocost-isoquant framework frequently cited is the response of industry to the rapidly rising prices of energy products in the 1970s. (Remember the oil price shock of 1973 and again of 1979). Most prices of petrol and petroleum products increased across the world, and as our analysis suggests, firms responded by conserving energy by substituting other inputs for energy. Activity 3 1. Draw an isoquant map using the information available in the following Table. Isoquant-I L 2 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 K 11 8 5 3 2.3 1.8 1.6 1.8 Isoquant-II L 4 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 K 13 10 7 5 4.2 3.5 3.2 3.5 Isoquant-III L 6 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 K 15 12 9 7 6.2 5.5 5.3 5.5
Capital Input
Labour Input
1a)
Which one of the isoquants provides you with highest level of output and why? ................................................................................................................ ................................................................................................................ ................................................................................................................ ................................................................................................................ ................................................................................................................
18
1b)
Take any one of the isoquants and compute MRTSLK. What do you observe about computed MRTS? Explain the observed trend. Isoquant.......... L K MRTSLK
Production Function
2. The marginal product of labour in the production of computer chips is 50 chips per hour. The marginal rate of technical substitution of hours of labour for hours of machine-capital is . What is the marginal product of capital? ...................................................................................................................... ...................................................................................................................... ...................................................................................................................... ...................................................................................................................... ...................................................................................................................... 3. What would the isoquants look like if all inputs were nearly perfect substitutes in a production process? What if there was near-zero substitutability between inputs? ...................................................................................................................... ...................................................................................................................... ...................................................................................................................... ...................................................................................................................... ......................................................................................................................
19
K C B A 50 C Panel A CRS: OA = AB = BC L
C 150 100 C Panel B IRS: OA > AB > BC Increasing Returns to Scale A 50 L B 150 100
Z 150
In unit 9 we will examine returns to scale from the point of view of cost and also advance reasons for increasing and decreasing returns to scale. For the moment consider the following example. A box with dimensions 4*4*4 has a capacity of 64 times a box with dimensions 1*1*1, even though the former uses only 16 times more wood than the smaller box.3 Isoquants can also be used to depict returns to scale (Figure 7.10) Panel A shows constant returns to scale. Three isoquants with output levels 50,100 and 150 are drawn. In the figure, successive isoquants are equidistant from one another along the ray 0Z. Panel B shows increasing returns to scale, where the distance between 2 isoquants becomes less and less i.e. in order to double output from 50 to 100, input increase is less than double. The explanation for panel C, which exhibits decreasing returns to scale, is analogous. There is no universal answer to which industries will show what kind of returns to scale. Some industries like public utilities (Telecom and Electricity generation) show increasing returns over large ranges of output, whereas other industries exhibit constant or even decreasing returns to scale over the relevant output range. Therefore, whether an industry has constant, increasing or decreasing returns to scale is largely an empirical issue.
3
20
Volume of box : 4 1
* 4 * 4 = 64 * 1 * 1 = 1
Area of box :
4 1
* 4 * 6 = 96 * 1 * 6 = 6
7.7 SUMMARY
A production function specifies the maximum output that can be produced with a given set of inputs. In order to achieve maximum profits the production manager has to use optimum input-output combination for a given cost. In this unit, we have shown how a production manager minimizes the cost for a given output in order to maximize the profit. Also, we have shown how to maximize the output at a given level of cost. The law of diminishing marginal returns states that as equal increments of variable input are added to fixed input, a point will eventually be reached where corresponding increments to output begin to decline. We have also seen the relations between the marginal product, average product, and total product. There are three stages of production. Stage I is characterized by MP>0 and MP>AP. Stage II is characterized by MP>0 and MP<AP. Stage III is characterized by MP<0. The economically meaningful range is Stage II. The production manager maximizes the profit at a point where the value of marginal product equals the price of the output. A production isoquant consists of all the combinations of two inputs that will yield the same maximum output. The marginal rate of technical substitution is WK/WL, holding output constant. The law of diminishing marginal rate of substitution implies the rate at which one input can be substituted for another input, if output remains constant. An isocost line consists of all the combinations of inputs which have the same total cost. The absolute slope of the isocost line is the input price ratio. Returns to scale, a long run concept, involves the effect on output of changing all inputs by same proportion and in the same direction.
Production Function
2. The marginal product of labour is known to be greater than the average product of labour at a given level of employment. Is the average product increasing or decreasing? Explain. 3. Explain the law of diminishing marginal returns and provide an example of the phenomenon. 4. Explain why a profit maximising firm using only one variable input will produce in stage-II. 5. Explain why an AP curve and the corresponding MP curve must intersect at the maximum point on the AP curve. 21
6. Explain why MP is greater than (less than) AP when AP is rising (falling). 7. Suppose a firm is currently using 500 labourers and 325 units of capital to produce its product. The wage rate is Rs. 25, and price of capital is Rs. 130. The last labourer adds 25 units of total output, while the last unit of capital adds 65 units to total output. Is the manager of this firm making the optimal input choice? Why or why not? If not, what should the manager do?
22