Nothing Special   »   [go: up one dir, main page]

(PDF Download) The Technological Role of Inward Foreign Direct Investment in Central East Europe 1st Edition Johannes Stephan (Auth.) Fulll Chapter

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 41

Download and Read online, DOWNLOAD EBOOK, [PDF EBOOK EPUB ], Ebooks

download, Read Ebook EPUB/KINDE, Download Book Format PDF

The Technological Role of Inward Foreign Direct


Investment in Central East Europe 1st Edition
Johannes Stephan (Auth.)

OR CLICK LINK
https://textbookfull.com/product/the-
technological-role-of-inward-foreign-direct-
investment-in-central-east-europe-1st-edition-
johannes-stephan-auth/

Read with Our Free App Audiobook Free Format PFD EBook, Ebooks dowload PDF
with Andible trial, Real book, online, KINDLE , Download[PDF] and Read and Read
Read book Format PDF Ebook, Dowload online, Read book Format PDF Ebook,
[PDF] and Real ONLINE Dowload [PDF] and Real ONLINE
More products digital (pdf, epub, mobi) instant
download maybe you interests ...

The Globalization of Foreign Investment in Africa The


Role of Europe China and India 1st Edition Adams Bodomo

https://textbookfull.com/product/the-globalization-of-foreign-
investment-in-africa-the-role-of-europe-china-and-india-1st-
edition-adams-bodomo/

Global Regulation of Foreign Direct Investment 1st


Edition Sherif H Seid

https://textbookfull.com/product/global-regulation-of-foreign-
direct-investment-1st-edition-sherif-h-seid/

Foreign Direct Investment in Developing Countries A


Theoretical Evaluation 1st Edition Sarbajit Chaudhuri

https://textbookfull.com/product/foreign-direct-investment-in-
developing-countries-a-theoretical-evaluation-1st-edition-
sarbajit-chaudhuri/

China Trade Foreign Direct Investment and Development


Strategies 1st Edition Yanqing Jiang

https://textbookfull.com/product/china-trade-foreign-direct-
investment-and-development-strategies-1st-edition-yanqing-jiang/
Corporate Links And Foreign Direct Investment In Asia
And The Pacific First Edition. Edition Chen

https://textbookfull.com/product/corporate-links-and-foreign-
direct-investment-in-asia-and-the-pacific-first-edition-edition-
chen/

Foreign Direct Investment in Brazil Post Crisis


Economic Development in Emerging Markets 1st Edition
Mohamed Amal

https://textbookfull.com/product/foreign-direct-investment-in-
brazil-post-crisis-economic-development-in-emerging-markets-1st-
edition-mohamed-amal/

Multinationals As Mutual Invaders Intra Industry Direct


Foreign Investment Asim Erdilek

https://textbookfull.com/product/multinationals-as-mutual-
invaders-intra-industry-direct-foreign-investment-asim-erdilek/

Globalizing Innovation State Institutions and Foreign


Direct Investment in Emerging Economies The MIT Press
1st Edition Egan

https://textbookfull.com/product/globalizing-innovation-state-
institutions-and-foreign-direct-investment-in-emerging-economies-
the-mit-press-1st-edition-egan/

Foreign Direct Investment in the Successor States of


Yugoslavia: A Comparative Economic Geography 25 Years
Later Joel I. Deichmann

https://textbookfull.com/product/foreign-direct-investment-in-
the-successor-states-of-yugoslavia-a-comparative-economic-
geography-25-years-later-joel-i-deichmann/
Studies in Economic Transition

General Editors: Jens Hölscher, Reader in Economics, University of Brighton; and Horst
Tomann, Professor of Economics, Free University Berlin

This series has been established in response to a growing demand for a greater understanding
of the transformation of economic systems. It brings together theoretical and empirical
studies on economic transition and economic development. The post-communist transition
from planned to market economies is one of the main areas of applied theory because in
this field the most dramatic examples of change and economic dynamics can be found. The
series aims to contribute to the understanding of specific major economic changes as well as
to advance the theory of economic development. The implications of economic policy will
be a major point of focus.

Titles include:

William Bartlett, Sanja Malekovic and Vassilis Monastiriotis (editors)


DECENTRALISATION AND LOCAL DEVELOPMENT IN SOUTH-EAST EUROPE

Tilman Bruk and Hartmut Lehmann (editors)


IN THE GRIP OF TRANSITION
Economic and Social Consequences of Restructuring in Russia and Ukraine

Lucian Cernat
EUROPEANIZATION, VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE IN
CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPE

Bruno Dallago (editor)


TRANSFORMATION AND EUROPEAN INTEGRATION
The Local Dimension

Bruno Dallago and Ichiro Iwasaki (editors)


CORPORATE RESTRUCTURING AND GOVERNANCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES

Hella Engerer
PRIVATIZATION AND ITS LIMITS IN CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPE
Property Rights in Transition

Saul Estrin, Grzegorz W. Kolodko and Milica Uvalic (editors)


TRANSITION AND BEYOND

Daniela Gabor
CENTRAL BANKING AND FINANCIALIZATION
A Romanian Account of How Eastern Europe Became Subprime

Oleh Havrylyshyn
DIVERGENT PATHS IN POST-COMMUNIST TRANSFORMATION
Capitalism for All or Capitalism for the Few?

Iraj Hoshi, Paul J.J. Welfens and Anna Wziatek-Kubiak (editors)


INDUSTRIAL COMPETITIVENESS AND RESTRUCTURING IN ENLARGED EUROPE
How Accession Countries Catch Up and Integrate in the European Union

Björn Jindra
INTERNATIONALISATION THEORY AND TECHNOLOGICAL ACCUMULATION
An Investigation of the Multinational Affiliates in East Germany

Mihaela Keleman and Monika Kostera (editors)


CRITICAL MANAGEMENT RESEARCH IN EASTERN EUROPE
Managing the Transition

David Lane (editor)


THE TRANSFORMATION OF STATE SOCIALISM
System Change, Capitalism, or Something Else?
David Lane and Martin Myant (editors)
VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM IN POST-COMMUNIST COUNTRIES

Jens Lowitzsch
FINANCIAL PARTICIPATION OF EMPLOYEES IN THE EU-27

Sönke Maatsch
CENTRAL AND EAST EUROPEAN MIGRANTS’ CONTRIBUTIONS TO SOCIAL PROTECTION

Enrico Marelli and Marcello Signorelli (editors)


ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STRUCTURAL FEATURES OF TRANSITION

Tomasz Mickiewicz
ECONOMIC TRANSITION IN CENTRAL EUROPE AND THE COMMONWEALTH OF
INDEPENDENT STATES

Tomasz Mickiewicz
ECONOMICS OF INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE, SECOND EDITION
Central and Eastern Europe Revisited

Milan Nikolić
MONETARY POLICY IN TRANSITION
Inflation Nexus Money Supply in Postcommunist Russia

Julie Pellegrin
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF COMPETITIVENESS IN AN ENLARGED EUROPE

Stanislav Poloucek (editor)


REFORMING THE FINANCIAL SECTOR IN CENTRAL EUROPEAN COUNTRIES

Johannes Stephan
THE TECHNOLOGICAL ROLE OF INWARD FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN CENTRAL
EAST EUROPE

Horst Tomann
MONETARY INTEGRATION IN EUROPE

Vera Trappmann
FALLEN HEROES IN GLOBAL CAPITALISM
Workers and the Restructuring of the Polish Steel Industry

Pasquale Tridico
INSTITUTIONS, HUMAN DEVELOPMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN TRANSITION
ECONOMIES

Milica Uvalic
SERBIA’S TRANSITION
Towards a Better Future

Hans van Zon


RUSSIA’S DEVELOPMENT PROBLEM
The Cult of Power

The full list of titles available is on the website:


www.palgrave.com/economics/set.asp

Studies in Economic Transition


Series Standing Order ISBN 978 0–333–73353–0
(outside North America only)
You can receive future titles in this series as they are published by placing a standing order.
Please contact your bookseller or, in case of difficulty, write to us at the address below with
your name and address, the title of the series and the ISBN quoted above.
Customer Services Department, Macmillan Distribution Ltd, Houndmills, Basingstoke,
Hampshire RG21 6XS, England
The Technological Role
of Inward Foreign Direct
Investment in Central East
Europe
Johannes Stephan
Head, Department for Industrial Organisation and Regulation Economics,
Halle Institute for Economic Research, Germany, and Technische Universität
Bergakademie Freiberg, Germany (Habilitation thesis)
© Johannes Stephan 2013
Softcover reprint of the hardcover 1st edition 2013 978-1-137-33375-9
All rights reserved. No reproduction, copy or transmission of this
publication may be made without written permission.
No portion of this publication may be reproduced, copied or transmitted
save with written permission or in accordance with the provisions of the
Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988, or under the terms of any licence
permitting limited copying issued by the Copyright Licensing Agency,
Saffron House, 6–10 Kirby Street, London EC1N 8TS.
Any person who does any unauthorized act in relation to this publication
may be liable to criminal prosecution and civil claims for damages.
The author has asserted his right to be identified as the author of this work
in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988.
First published 2013 by
PALGRAVE MACMILLAN
Palgrave Macmillan in the UK is an imprint of Macmillan Publishers Limited,
registered in England, company number 785998, of Houndmills, Basingstoke,
Hampshire RG21 6XS.
Palgrave Macmillan in the US is a division of St Martin’s Press LLC,
175 Fifth Avenue, New York, NY 10010.
Palgrave Macmillan is the global academic imprint of the above companies
and has companies and representatives throughout the world.
Palgrave® and Macmillan® are registered trademarks in the United States,
the United Kingdom, Europe and other countries.
ISBN 978-1-349-46235-3 ISBN 978-1-137-33376-6 (eBook)
DOI 10.1057/9781137333766
This book is printed on paper suitable for recycling and made from fully
managed and sustained forest sources. Logging, pulping and manufacturing
processes are expected to conform to the environmental regulations of the
country of origin.
A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library.
A catalog record for this book is available from the Library of Congress.
Contents

List of Tables vii


List of Figures ix
Acknowledgements xi
List of Abbreviations xii

1 Introduction 1
1.1 Motivation of the topic 1
1.2 Setting the research agenda: the technological aspect of
the ‘developmental role of inward manufacturing FDI’ 5
1.3 Conceptual framework for the analysis 12
1.4 Empirical evidence of inward FDI into Central East Europe 23
1.5 Structure of the book 32
2 The Database Used in the Empirical Analysis 35
2.1 The development of the IWH FDI Micro Database 36
2.2 The basic population for the IWH FDI Micro
Database 37
2.3 Survey sampling and implementation 39
2.4 Survey representativeness of the two IWH FDI
Micro Database waves 41
2.5 Survey questionnaires 43
3 Foreign Direct Investment Motives and the Match with
Locational Conditions in Central East Europe 45
3.1 Current state of the art in research 46
3.2 The data used for the analysis 49
3.3 Strategic motives of foreign investors investing in
Central East Europe 50
3.4 Summary of main results 65
4 Conditions of Internal Technology Transfer and Spillovers
between Foreign Investors and Foreign Affiliates in Central
East Europe 68
4.1 The current state of the art in research 69
4.2 The ‘role in the network’ and absorptive capacity:
a two-dimensional concept 77
4.3 The data used for the analysis 81

v
vi Contents

4.4 Characterisation of foreign affiliates in CEE within


the two-dimensional concept 83
4.5 Summary of main results 89
5 Central and East European Innovation Systems as
Knowledge Sources for Foreign Affiliates’ Own
Technological Activity in CEE 91
5.1 Internationalisation of technological activity in
transnational corporations 93
5.2 The current state of the art in research 97
5.3 The data used for the analysis and testable hypotheses 112
5.4 The importance of the host innovation system
for foreign affiliates’ own technological activity 116
5.5 Summary of main results 140

6 Foreign Affiliates as Knowledge Source for Host Regional


Innovation Systems in CEE 145
6.1 The current state of the art in research 147
6.2 The data used for the analysis and testable hypotheses 157
6.3 The importance of foreign affiliates for technological
activity in the host innovation system 161
6.4 Summary of main results 175

7 The Role of Intellectual Property Rights for Technology in


FDI into CEE 177
7.1 The current state of the art in research 181
7.2 The data and methods used in the analysis 188
7.3 Hypotheses development and empirical testing 193
7.4 Summary of main results 201
7.5 Annex (complete econometric test results) 203

8 Conclusions on the Technological Role of FDI into CEE 215


8.1 Conditions for inward FDI in CEE to have a
developmental impact via technology 216
8.2 The research programme – some vital ingredients
into a future research agenda 226

Annexes 233
9.1 The questionnaire for the 2006–2007 wave 233
9.2 The questionnaire for the 2008–2009 wave 244

Notes 256

References 269

Index 293
List of Tables

2.1 Country composition of the IWH FDI Micro Database,


waves 2006–2007 and 2008–2009 40
3.1 Investment motives of foreign investments into CEE,
distinguished by regions of origin 51
3.2 Investment motives, distinguished by the time of entry
of the foreign investor, 1989–2009 52
3.3 Investment motives, distinguished by host economies 55
3.4 Investment motives, distinguished by industry
classifications 56
3.5 Endowment with locational advantages, distinguished by
host economy 58
3.6 Endowment with locational advantages, distinguished by
industry classification 60
3.7 Endowment with locational advantages, distinguished by
strategic motives 62
3.8 Partial correlations between strategic motives and
locational conditions 64
4.1 Shares of foreign affiliates allocated into the four
quadrants of the taxonomy 87
5.1 Strategic investment motives of foreign affiliates,
by country 125
5.2 Pairwise rank correlation between all determinants 133
5.3 Determinants of host scientific institutions assuming an
important role for foreign affiliates’ own technological
activity – the analysis of CEECs 135
5.4 Determinants of host innovation system actors assuming
an important role for foreign affiliates’ own technological
activity – the analysis of CEECs 136
6.1 Pairwise rank correlation between all determinants 168
6.2 Determinants of foreign affiliates assuming an important
role in the technological activity of firms in the host
economy 170
6.3 Determinants of foreign affiliates assuming an important
role in the technological activity of firms in the host
economy 172

vii
viii List of Tables

7.1 Pairwise rank correlation between all determinants 194


7.2 IPR gaps and direct technology transfer embodied in
rather standardised products 196
7.3 IPR gaps and foreign affiliate technological activity 197
7.4 IPR gaps and importance of sources of knowledge and
technology for foreign affiliate technological activity 199
7.5 IPR gaps and technological embeddedness in the local
host economy 201
A1 IPR gaps and direct technology transfer embodied in
rather standardised products: partial correlation and
ordered probit results with tt.mnc 203
A2 IPR gaps and foreign affiliate technological activity:
partial correlation results with sh.R&D and sal.inno 204
A3a IPR gaps and importance of sources of knowledge and
technology for foreign affiliate technological activity:
partial correlation and ordered probit results with own.tech 206
A3b IPR gaps and importance of sources of knowledge and
technology for foreign affiliate technological activity:
partial correlation and ordered probit results with comp.HQ 207
A3c IPR gaps and importance of sources of knowledge and
technology for foreign affiliate technological activity:
partial correlation and ordered probit results with comp.FA 209
A4a IPR gaps and technological embeddedness in the local
host economy: partial correlation and log-OLS results
with comp.sal 210
A4b IPR gaps and technological embeddedness in the local
host economy: partial correlation and log-OLS results
with comp.sup 212
A4c IPR gaps and technological embeddedness in the local
host economy: partial correlation and ordered probit
results with comp.SI 213
8.1 WEF IPR levels of host countries and average sizes of IPR
gaps between home and host countries, by groups of
foreign affiliates according to their host countries 225
List of Figures

1.1 FDI inflow, in % of World FDI inflows 24


1.2 FDI outflow, in % of World FDI inflows 24
1.3 FDI inflow, in % of GDP 25
1.4 FDI outflow, in % of GDP 26
1.5 FDI inflow, in % of Gross Fixed Capital Formation 27
1.6 FDI inflow, in EUR per capita 27
1.7 Inward FDI stock, in EUR mn 28
1.8 FDI-related income outflow (income and its repatriation),
in % of inward FDI stock 29
1.9 Share of FDI inflows in gross fixed capital formation 29
1.10 Inward FDI stock by major home countries in end 2008 30
1.11 Inward FDI stock by economic activity in end 2008 31
1.12 FDI outflow, in 1000 EUR mn per capita 31
1.13 Outward FDI stock, in EUR mn 32
4.1 The conceptual taxonomy and potentials for technology
transfer 80
4.2 Average levels of autonomy in all seven technology-related
business functions of foreign affiliates across countries 84
4.3 Levels of absorptive capacities per host country 85
4.4 Graphical representation of empirical taxonomy 86
5.1 R&D activity of foreign affiliates across countries: share of
research-active foreign affiliates 117
5.2 R&D intensity of foreign affiliates across countries 118
5.3 Innovative activity of foreign affiliates across countries:
share of innovative firms 119
5.4 Innovative activity of foreign affiliates across countries:
intensity of product innovation 120
5.5 Innovative activity of foreign affiliates across countries:
intensity of process innovation 121
5.6 Aggregated share of sales attributable to new or
significantly improved products across countries 122
5.7 Importance of exploiting and augmenting strategies
across countries 124
5.8 Average shares of local supplies and sales of foreign
affiliates across countries 126

ix
x List of Figures

5.9 Average levels of autonomy in three technology-related


business functions of foreign affiliates across countries 127
5.10 Age and size of foreign affiliates across countries 128
5.11 Averages of levels of importance of host innovation
system actors for foreign affiliates’ technological activity 129
6.1 Average (short-term) cost curves o f domestic firms in a
situation of entry of foreign-owned competitors 150
6.2 Importance of foreign affiliates for technological activity
in the host innovation system 161
6.3 Averages of product and process innovation intensities
in comparison to competitors (inno), by host country 164
6.4 Importance of embodied technology received from the
foreign investors’ networks, by host country 165
6.5 Technological quality of the host innovation system from
the perspective of foreign affiliates, by host country 166
7.1 IPR indicators in Europe, East and West 179
7.2 Observed IPR gaps between host and home countries
(IPR.gap) of the IWH FDI Micro Database of 2006–2007 190
Acknowledgements

I would like to thank all my colleagues who are involved with common
research ventures around the IWH FDI Micro Database and the EU
projects. Particular thanks go out to the distinguished researchers
Wladimir Andreff, Horst Brezinski, Rolf Hasse, and Paul J. J. Welfens
for their constructive comments and testimonies provided during my
habilitation project. Many other colleagues have provided important
comments on the work presented here – my gratitude goes out to all of
them.
The publishers and I wish to acknowledge the premission given for
the reproduction of copyright material from ‘Does Local Technology
matter for Foreign Investors in Central and Eastern Europe? – Evidence
from the IWH FDI Micro Database’ which was published in the
Special Issue of the Journal of East West Business on Market Entry and
Operational Strategies of MNEs in Transition and Emerging Economies,
15/3&4, pp. 210–47 © Taylor & Francis 2009.

xi
List of Abbreviations

CATI computer assisted telephone interviews


CEE Central East Europe
CEECs Central East European Countries
CEFTA Central European Free Trade Agreement
CMEA Council for Mutual Economic Assistance
EU European Union
FA foreign affiliate of an FDI project
FDI foreign direct investment
HRSTO Human Resources in Science and Technology Occupation
IB international business (literature, theory)
ICT information and communication technology
IPA investment promotion agencies
IPR intellectual property rights
ISCO International Standard Classification of Occupations
IWH Halle Institute for Economic Research
MNC multinational company
MNE multinational enterprise
NACE Statistical Classification of Economic Activities in the
European Community
NIS National Innovation Systems
NUTS Nomenclature of Statistical Territorial Units in Europe
OLI Ownership, Localisation, and Internalisation Advantages
(Dunning’s concept)
OLS ordinary least squares
OPT outward processing trade
ROR Raumordnungsregion
R&D research and development
TFP total factor productivity
TNC trans-national corporation
TRIPS trade-related aspects of intellectual property rights
USA United States of America
WTO World Trade Organization

xii
1
Introduction

This book intends to assess the role that inward foreign direct
investment (FDI) can have on the technological development of the
recipient economy, in particular where the recipient country is in the
process of economic catching up. This focus positions the analysis in
the book between the body of literature testing the existence of
economic effects of inward FDI on the one hand, and the management
literature concerned with strategies of multinational enterprises in host
regions with lower levels of economic development, possibly transition
economies, on the other.
The book starts out with a fairly comprehensive introduction that not
only discusses the motivation of the topic and the analytical implica-
tions that emerge from this focus for empirical analysis, but also provides
some of the characterisation of the countries at hand and the issue of
FDI itself.

1.1 Motivation of the topic

When the ‘historical experiment’ of central state planning collapsed


in Central East Europe (CEE), it was widely assumed that the formerly
socialist countries would be able to swiftly catch up with the West
(Lipton and Sachs, 1990; Herr and Westphal, 1991; Sachs, 1992). The
Washington consensus (Williamson, 1989, 1993; for critique, see for
example Stiglitz, 2002; Rodrik, 2006) explored a path of comprehen-
sive liberalisation of all internal and external spheres of the economy
and assumed that entrepreneurial activity,1 having been subdued for
so long, would now thrive in the new pro-economic and competitive
environment. Alas, history took a different path: the ‘lost decades’ of
socialist planning had produced technological stagnation and had dried

1
2 The Technological Role of Foreign Direct Investment

out individual entrepreneurial behaviour (because it was not regarded as


a core competence (see Åslund, 2002, p. 283), and would also have run
counter to the constituting criterion of the economic plan, resulting in
a shortage economy unable to satisfy demand to a very large extent. The
liberalisation of the thenceforth ‘transition countries’ was therefore in
need of external help (to overcome the technology gap and to supply
demand) – yet help in terms of development aid would have been
inconceivable in the light of the large amounts that would have been
necessary: the financial ‘transfers’ invested into the East German new
Länder are an impressive case in point. Rather, foreign private economic
activity had to be the main engine of the transition process and of the
process of catching up at least during the first years. This is the role that
FDI assumed.
FDI was assigned a pivotal role in the catching-up process of the Central
East European countries (CEECs). The list of objectives to which FDI
can contribute to at times of systemic transition includes the following,
perhaps most prominent, points:2

● Alleviating capital shortage: even if doubtful in the medium term


(credit gives rise to capital in a monetary economy), this assertion
may possibly be acceptable in the case of CEE due to an environment
of insufficient trust in the financial spheres around currencies that
are newly establishing themselves in terms of international convert-
ibility and acceptance as legal tender.
● Supply of technology: the socialist countries existed in economic
autarky from the West within their own integration area of the
Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (CMEA), which was both
self-inflicted (or governed by the Soviet Union) and at the same time
forced upon them by the West, exemplified in the CoCom-list (see for
example van Brabant, 1980/2012). They were consequently delinked
from the kind of technical advance so characteristic of the develop-
ment processes in the West since World War II. Those had been broad
in the sense of emanating from all sorts of industries and fields of
science, were driven to a large extent by private risk-bearing economic
activity, and have been – to a large extent, and by consequence – in
coherence with demand by the users of new technology.
● Privatisation: who else should have (i) the necessary capital or ability
to raise capital to foot the bill of desperately needed recapitalisa-
tion and restructuring, and (ii) the management skills, knowledge,
and expertise to make the transforming economic entities in those
countries internationally competitive?
Introduction 3

● Competition: central planning consistently excluded and necessarily


had to exclude competition from economic activity. It was foreign
trade liberalisation and inward FDI which was to assume the role of
enforcing competition on (formerly) state-owned monopolies.

Those four points can be directly deducted from the dichotomy in


the world during the socialist era: in economic terms, the distinction
between the two worlds, East and West, is best harnessed by characterisa-
tion of the constituting criteria of the two systems (see for example Riese,
1991, 1992): whilst the West was governed by competitive and (more or
less) free markets that incentivised private economic activity, the East
was governed by an overarching economic plan that transcended into
nearly all aspects of economic activity. Consequently, economic activity
was public and did not involve (or involved to only a very small extent)
privately organised economic activities.3 In the West, the coherence of
the economic sphere was based on competition4 and money. In the East,
it was administrative planning. The western world generated an envi-
ronment conducive to intensified economic foreign integration by way
of private foreign investment, private foreign trade and the cross-border
migration of labour; the conditions for those were framed in bilateral
and multilateral institutions such as the work of the then GATT and the
institution of international (reserve-)currency regimes, the International
Monetary Fund. The ‘communist bloc’, on the other hand, planned,
controlled, and executed external economic relationships through the
political administration such as the CMEA (see, for example, Brezinski,
1978), thereby not allowing the emergence of private internationalising
activities (private exporting and importing, outward or inward FDI with
internationally owned property rights, international licensing or fran-
chising etc.). Indeed, foreign ownership during socialist times rested by
default with the country hosting the property – no other legal arrange-
ment would have been consistent with the system of economic planning.
Where new firms were established involving cross-country ownership,
international production agreements in intergovernmental contracts
guaranteeing ‘inter-country socialist ownership’ had to align the respec-
tive economic plans of respective participants to preserve consistency of
the economic plans (see Brezinski, 1978, p. 172–3).5
Despite the obvious role that FDI could potentially play in the
transition process, the countries in CEE were in reality regarded as unat-
tractive locations for FDI in the early years, due to fears of a return to
communism and the significant political risks in some of the countries
(for example, the civil war in the former Yugoslavia, the uncertainties
4 The Technological Role of Foreign Direct Investment

souring the break-up of Czechoslovakia, the despotized political regime


in the early years of the Slovak Republic, and the non-transparent situa-
tion in Romania). When privatisation programmes in the CEE countries
started, they flooded the markets with institutionalised productive
capital to such an extent and in such a short period of time that prices
and values of to-be-privatised firms fell sharply (in Germany to symbolic
amounts, and even at times effectively negative due to guarantees and
state aid). It was to a large extent foreign capital that took advantage of
this (for an early account of the relationship of FDI and privatisation in
CEE, see Welfens and Jasinski, 1994, Chapter D). Once the worst tran-
sitional recession was overcome in the early 1990s and the economies
started on their process of catching up with Western European levels of
GDP per capita, CEECs became more interesting targets for FDI. This was
spurred not only by mass privatisation, but also by the expectation that
these countries would swiftly integrate their already industrialised and
now liberalised economies into the European economic area and hence
offer profit rates in excess of risk premia. The hope amongst CEECs was
that they would not only receive the capital needed to restructure their
industries but also that they would get access to modern western knowl-
edge and technology. Most of the CEECs adopted FDI policies based on
attracting as much FDI as possible without any concern about the quality
of investors (Rugaff, 2008). Over time and with rising stocks of produc-
tive capital and levels of economic development, wages also increased.
Where wage increases surpass productivity growth,6 the (unit labour)
cost advantages in CEECs melt away; yet now, two decades after the
transition process started, CEECs are still offering sizeable unit labour
cost advantages in comparison to the West.7 Where unit labour costs
are converging to western levels, strategic motives tend to shift towards
building industrial and service networks with the local host economies,
reaping localisation advantages beyond motives of pure efficiency.
Today, it is the technology-intensive networks that can be expected to
be particularly competitive not only as FDI projects, but also as drivers
of international competitiveness for the foreign investor in the home
country. An increasing number of foreign affiliates in CEECs assume
the character of ‘developmental subsidiaries’, build capacities of tech-
nological development, and become active drivers of knowledge and
technology in their own right.
This is the empirical starting point of this analysis. The starting
point unveils the overarching research question guiding the anal-
ysis: under what conditions can inward manufacturing FDI serve
as a panacea for transition and catch-up development in CEE?
Introduction 5

This analysis cannot, of course, answer that ambiguous question to a


satisfactory extent, yet it contributes some important insights that
should help generate answers.

1.2 Setting the research agenda: the technological


aspect of the ‘developmental role of inward
manufacturing FDI’

This overarching question forms part of a wider research agenda on the


developmental role of FDI in general. The agenda has been evolving
for many decades in the bodies of literature on economic development,
international economics and, to a lesser extent, in the international
business literature. This has produced ‘conventional wisdoms’ that
over time have adapted to new empirical trends and research results
generated by more powerful methods and firm-specific data. Three sets
of ‘conventional wisdom’ are summarised in a volume edited by two
Washington institutions: the Institute for International Economics and
the Center for Global Development (Moran et al., 2005, p. 2):

● The ‘Washington consensus’ enthusiasm is shared mostly by multi-


national investors and business lobby groups. It holds that FDI always
has a positive effect on the host economy, hence countries should
attract as much inward FDI as possible.
● Academic scepticism however prevails over the relationship between
inward FDI and economic development. It may well be that the
effects of FDI will not yield beyond the effects of any other domestic
investment.
● ‘Dirigisme resurrected’ describes a contemporary tendency by
policy-makers in some developing countries to revert to heavy-handed
regulation of inward FDI. This may include provisions for minimum
technology transfer, compulsory licensing, local content require-
ments and other measures targeted at increasing technology transfer
and spillovers to the benefit of the economy that hosts inward FDI.

This list obviously lacks some more critical views that may not make
it to a Washington-accepted ‘conventional wisdom’ yet still remain
important in many host economies, and not only in the third world.
Those views direct attention to the possibility that inward FDI may
cause environmental damage and may deplete natural resources, and
there are allegations related to land grabbing and its potential risks for
the indigenous societies. Neglecting those points certainly makes an odd
6 The Technological Role of Foreign Direct Investment

compilation: they may not apply to a large share of inward FDI, they
may be overstated in some cases, they may have been more frequent
some years or decades ago, and yet they do exist today, and in some
cases put immense strain on the host countries (see, for example, the
problems associated with environmental damage from oil extraction
in some African countries, predominantly Nigeria, see also the critical
discussion about the role of recent FDI inflows originating from China
around the developing world).
Moran et al. (2005) see the benign effects of FDI to be conditional
on and driven by an open trade and investment policy framework that
gives rise to competitive markets.8 On the other hand, where foreign
affiliates operate behind trade barriers and without local competition,
FDI may even subtract from host country welfare (ibid., p. xii).9 Today,
the empirical literature on average and at the most general level assumes
a rather positive view of inward FDI: “FDI is generally associated with
positive technological spillovers, economic growth, and increasing
income inequality. [ ... ] In all three areas there are, however, significant
counter examples in the literature which must be respected.” (Clark
et al., 2011, p. 2). As much as the Washington consensus can be criticised,
it did contribute to generating a competitive and liberalised economic
environment for foreign investors, hence it secured the right kind of
incentives for efficient economic activity, upon which sustainable
economic growth and development can build. It may also be argued that
the prospect of EU membership had an even stronger disciplining effect
(see perhaps most prominently Lavigne, 1998, in a very large body of
literature). It is the securing of such an economic environment that gave
rise to the general contention that inward FDI into CEECs had so far
positively contributed to systemic change and catch-up development.
This already sets the research agenda for this book: the objective is to
assess the conditions that have to be fulfilled so that inward FDI can have
a positive and important role in the technological process of catching up in
CEE. A positive general developmental role, not restricted to the tech-
nological impact, may be rooted in a number of effects at very different
levels:

● Inward FDI increases employment opportunities for local workers,


inasmuch as the additional investment has increased the amount of
productive capital which is now in need of a new stock of labour
to complement it. The intensity of this effect obviously hinges on
the capital or labour intensity of the investment, and on whether
employees and managers, in addition to capital, are transferred to the
Introduction 7

host location. Whilst foreign investment projects tend to pay higher


wages than domestic firms (often by trying to acquire the best avail-
able human capital embodied in the work force), the best paying jobs
are typically reserved for ‘expatriates’ of the foreign investor, and are
not accessible to domestic managers.
● Where inward FDI is associated with capital inflows (depending on the
definition of FDI) it increases the volume of capital investment in the
host economy – investment that possibly contributes to closing what
is called the savings gap10 in some of the traditional macro-economic
development literature (such as the Harrod–Domar growth model, or
Rostow’s Stages of Growth model, or Nurkse’s vicious circle).
● Inward FDI improves the host country’s current account via capital
imports and thereby contributes to closing the so-called foreign
exchange gap. This is obviously a one-off effect for each FDI project,
giving rise to no lasting improvements (see the recurring difficulties
of, for example, Hungary, where FDI inflow shortfalls keep generating
current account problems, or the contagion effects of the current
financial crisis, see Brezinski and Stephan, 2011). Moreover, FDI
will typically lead to profit repatriation at some stage (if successful,
this is after all amongst the most important raisons d`être for foreign
investment) and may turn this into a negative effect. This has
become a relevant issue in Central East Europe, with profit repatria-
tion amounting to around 10 per cent of FDI inflows (in Hungary,
this even peaked at slightly over 20 per cent in 2008: Hunya, 2010,
p. 13).
● Inward FDI may also have a potentially benign effect on the foreign
trade performance of host countries (in particular exports), assuming
that foreign firms are more expedient in conquering external markets
than are domestic firms (which is often assumed to be the case in
emerging markets). This effect, however, depends on transfer-pricing
behaviour of foreign investors: where FDI, for example, assumes the
character of outward processing trade or if relative corporate taxation
rules between countries motivate this, transnational corporations
(TNCs) will calculate higher prices for their imports from the internal
network and lower values for their exports. Local content rules may
reduce this effect where foreign investment is required to generate a
minimum share of the value of the products or services in the host
country.
● Inward FDI can have effects on competition and market structure
in host countries, which is particularly relevant in countries and/
or sectors where an insufficient endowment with domestic firms
8 The Technological Role of Foreign Direct Investment

competing for market shares results in low intensities of competition.


This was in fact an important issue in CEECs. This may equally,
however, turn out to be the opposite: if inward FDI involves entry
into oligopolistic markets and the foreign firm has more financial
leverage than domestic competitors, the foreign firm may rationally
try to compete away market shares of domestic firms in a Bertrand
competition scenario.
● Inward FDI can also alter sectoral structures,11 if foreign investment
is able to develop successful industrial clusters (which proved to be
particularly relevant in Central East Europe – in, for example, the
automotive sector in the Czech Republic) and if FDI flows into sectors
that were previously underdeveloped but which promise interesting
potential (that is, in need of substantial investment, in CEE the ICT
industry: Welfens and Borbély, 2009, and Welfens and Wziatek-Kubiak
et al., 2005).
● Traditionally, it is also argued that inward FDI will contribute to
government revenues of the host country by way of taxation of foreign
direct investment and their effects (for example, on employment).
Today however, particularly in emerging markets, governments offer
generous tax concessions to foreign investors (for example, in special
economic zones) and thereby forgo some of this benign effect.
● Inward FDI may transfer knowledge and technology previously
unavailable in the domestic economy, if the investment originates
from countries with higher levels of economic development and/
or from investors with higher levels of productivity. This knowledge
and technology may include anything from hard-core technology to
tacit knowledge (for example, technological skills and experience) to
management experience and entrepreneurial abilities. It may more-
over generate spillovers to the host economy, but only if a number
of conditions are fulfilled, such as: if the foreign investor chooses
to allow or even promote this in a positive sense, or is unable to
prevent the dissipation of its knowledge and technology in a negative
sense; if the affiliate of a knowledge-bearing foreign investor is able to
convey, teach, and explain the knowledge (even if it assumes a rather
tacit character); if the host economy is fit enough to absorb the alien
technology and make good use of it; and if the host economy’s insti-
tutional environment does not put the foreign owner’s intellectual
property at risk. Whilst this effect depends on many “ifs”, it is the
technological aspect that is most interesting for the case of inward
FDI into CEECs, due to the countries’ large technology gaps (see for
example Stephan, 2003).
Introduction 9

● In addition to technology transfer and spillovers, FDI affiliates may


assume an important role as players in the national innovation
systems of the host economies. This is particularly relevant in host
countries where there is a technology gap between themselves and
the home countries of their inward FDI.
● Further, FDI may also have an effect on the distribution of income in
the host economy, on labour market structural issues (skills-upgrading,
brain drain), on the contribution of FDI to structural/sectoral change
(again a particularly important issue in CEECs due to their prior
distortion of sectoral structures, see for example Kalotay, 2010). (For
comprehensive overviews, see for example Blomström and Globerman
and Kokko, 2001; others.)

All the above effects (and possibly some more, not mentioned here)
have the potential to increase host economy growth and to spur
economic development (see for example Sapienza, 2009, in an appli-
cation on CEECs). However, each of these beneficial effects may also
become detrimental: where the foreign investor is dominant, domestic
firms are driven out of the market; foreign investments typically generate
more income for domestic groups with lower propensities to save;
foreign firms often use their established foreign suppliers (that often
follow their clients) and hence drive out domestic firms in upstream
industries; FDI projects may crowd out domestic investors seeking credit
by raising capital locally on an as yet underdeveloped market; etc.
Adding to these qualifications of potentially benign effects of inward
FDI, there are more philosophical or ideological arguments against
inward FDI that are nonetheless noteworthy in a discussion of economic
effects.12

● First, a substantial share of foreign-owned economic activity in large,


powerful and dominant firms gives rise to a dualistic economic
structure, where the host economy assumes the role of labourer and
the foreign investor that of capitalist. Such FDIs will influence host
governments, and their lobbying may not always be targeted to the
benefit of the local economy. Moreover, dominant FDI projects may
divert host economy resources away from ‘natural’ local compara-
tive advantages (much like the Dutch disease problem). This way,
much needed food production is replaced by production of goods
catering to the needs of local elites and/or foreign consumers, not the
local population at large. Dominant foreign investors may not only
drive out domestic indigenous firms, but may also suppress domestic
10 The Technological Role of Foreign Direct Investment

entrepreneurship and thereby inhibit the development of small-scale


domestic enterprises.
● Second, foreign investments in emerging markets often seek the
localisation advantage of lower labour costs, possibly lower labour
unit costs. Where investments are into labour-intensive production
technologies, their international competitiveness depends on low
wages, and may lock the host economy into a low-wage trap that
cannot be overcome without external stimulus. Alas, where invest-
ments are into capital-intensive production, the host economy is said
to suffer from an aggravated unemployment problem. Finally, where
inward FDI is motivated by a laxer protection of labour security, or of
the environment or the like, the private profits of the investor may
exceed social benefits – and in the worst cases the benefits to the host
economy may even turn out to be negative.
● Third, where inward FDI is into countries with less developed infra-
structure, it will typically locate in urban centres and hence aggravate
the already pressing problems of rural–urban migration.
● Finally, host governments competing for foreign investment projects
are able to acquire concessions in the form of excessive (and possibly
targeted) protection,13 tax rebates, investment allowances, and other
state aids, either overt or hidden. It is often argued that domestic enter-
prises do not have this lobby power, because their threat of investing
elsewhere is less powerful due to lower investment volumes.

It is obvious that such a discussion about the extent of beneficial and


detrimental effects of inward FDI on the host economy is highly subjec-
tive and depends to some extent on the individual perception on what
kind of economic development is desirable and what character of the
development process may on the one hand increase growth but on the
other be socially undesirable (see the discussion on the varieties of capi-
talism, for example Hall and Soskice, 2001; Coates et al. 2005; Cernat,
2006; Tridico, 2011; Myant and Drahokoupil, 2012).
To harness this broad field of interest to something manageable (as
well as selecting the issues that are of the greatest interest to the author
of this book), the analysis presented here restricts itself to manufac-
turing industries, because here the largest potentials for technology
and knowledge interaction and transfer can be assumed, and because
empirical analysis can make use of more robust proxies than would be
the case in for example services, where technology is much more about
management techniques, and prices and costs are much more diffi-
cult to substantiate. The analysis presented here focuses on technology
Introduction 11

transfer and spillovers as the source of the developmental role via


inward manufacturing FDI. This is a controversial issue: considering the
conditions that prevail in CEE, will inward FDI in the manufacturing
industry assume an active and positive role for technological catch-up
development in those countries? How attractive is the region to inter-
national investors? What kind of investors does the region attract? Are
the manufacturing FDI projects dominated by ‘extended work benches’,
or ‘screwdriver industries’, or ‘outward processing trade’? Do FDI projects
originate from investors with the latest knowledge and technology at the
frontier area, with its foreign affiliates remaining excluded from this? Do
manufacturing FDI projects give rise to modernly equipped production
sites in the host economy? And if so, are these fully integrated into the
foreign investor’s network, that is, isolated from the domestic economy,
or do foreign affiliates trade with their host economy? Do affiliates of
foreign investors engage in their own technological activities such as
R&D and innovation in the host economy? Do they use local firms and
institutions in the regional innovation system to exchange knowledge
and technology? And finally, which firm- and region-specific factors
influence foreign investors’ decisions to locate technological activities in
a particular region and to source technology locally? Those questions
are all at the heart of the technological aspect of the developmental role
of manufacturing FDI (in the following, only FDI) and require analysis
both at the level of the host economies and at the level of the firm.
The emphasis is on the conditions of such a role and not on
constructing a general model or theory of technology transfer and spill-
overs. Indeed, a model-like description of the mechanisms behind the
transfer of knowledge and technology and their spillovers can only be
achieved if the concepts of ‘knowledge’ or ‘technology’ are treated as a
homogeneous goods of groups of homogeneous goods. Whilst this may
be applicable to the concept of ‘information’ to a large extent, knowl-
edge and technology are typically very heterogeneous both in their own
character (for example tacit vs tangible and codified, narrative vs formal,
trustworthy vs prejudice and misconception, etc.) and in their useful-
ness for each individual user, which – to complicate matters – may even
change over time. Whilst heterogeneities do not in general preclude the
development of theories that draw a general picture of a representative
average and the mechanisms involved, the many sources of hetero-
geneity both within the concepts of knowledge and technology and
between the many different foreign investors and their host economies
make this avenue a very complicated one, to say the least. The analysis
here is much less ambiguous, and confines itself to analysing the role
12 The Technological Role of Foreign Direct Investment

of FDI for the ‘technological’ dimension of the development process


by use of empirical firm-level data. The analysis makes use of some of
the latest theoretical and conceptual developments in the literature of
international business, strategic management, innovation economics,
institutional economics, and evolutionary economics.

1.3 Conceptual framework for the analysis

1.3.1 Technological development in economic theories


The ‘technological’ focus in theories of economic development tradi-
tionally operates at the macro-economic sphere and has in particular
been less concerned with the sources of technological developments
which originate at the firm level.14 Later additions to the theoretical
debates over technology and development integrate the institutional
dimensions of international and development economics. Most of these
theories are embedded in a world of general equilibrium. Regardless
of whether equilibrium is prevalent in reality at any point of time or
achieved/restored in the long term, or whether there is such a thing as
a tendency towards an equilibrium, those theories still largely remain at
variance with what may be considered to be at the root of dynamism
in a capitalist market system at the micro-level: that is, uncertainty,
transient gains and losses, adjustment costs in friction phases, the
stochastic and non-linear character of technical advance, and last but
very importantly, the diversity of firm characteristics, reactions, and
strategies (firm-heterogeneity, see for an early account Young, 1928). In
any dynamic or evolutionary theory, equilibrium cannot exist, because
everything keeps changing (see Nelson and Winter, 1982).
Indeed, it may be argued that there is a trade-off between those two
families of paradigms: general equilibrium models can be viewed as
theoretical benchmarks for assessing the mechanisms at work if the
economic system is largely frictionless (perfect competition), and com-
putable general equilibrium models help to assess the likely effects
of, for example, policy interventions. Dynamic micro-analyses on the
other hand command less sweeping assumptions, hence are closer to
the reality of a dynamic world, and yet are rather ill-equipped to predict
macro-effects of micro-phenomena (as for example the effects of inward
FDI), the outcome of political interventions for the whole economy
(even if policies are targeted at the firm level), or exogenous or asym-
metric shocks for the whole economy.
Somewhere in this middle ground between the two extremes of
macro- and micro-level analyses are meso-level analyses that assess the
Another random document with
no related content on Scribd:
Years later, when the New York dentist replaced Gabriel's old steel
fillings, he explained to him about the music. Gabriel had been
receiving radio signals in the bits of metal in his head, he said. He
was very scientific about it, even drawing a little diagram to show him
how the radiator had helped ground him. Gabriel listened politely and
smiled but said nothing. To him it was still a miracle.

THE END
*** END OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK SMALL VOICE,
BIG MAN ***

Updated editions will replace the previous one—the old editions will
be renamed.

Creating the works from print editions not protected by U.S.


copyright law means that no one owns a United States copyright in
these works, so the Foundation (and you!) can copy and distribute it
in the United States without permission and without paying copyright
royalties. Special rules, set forth in the General Terms of Use part of
this license, apply to copying and distributing Project Gutenberg™
electronic works to protect the PROJECT GUTENBERG™ concept
and trademark. Project Gutenberg is a registered trademark, and
may not be used if you charge for an eBook, except by following the
terms of the trademark license, including paying royalties for use of
the Project Gutenberg trademark. If you do not charge anything for
copies of this eBook, complying with the trademark license is very
easy. You may use this eBook for nearly any purpose such as
creation of derivative works, reports, performances and research.
Project Gutenberg eBooks may be modified and printed and given
away—you may do practically ANYTHING in the United States with
eBooks not protected by U.S. copyright law. Redistribution is subject
to the trademark license, especially commercial redistribution.

START: FULL LICENSE


THE FULL PROJECT GUTENBERG LICENSE
PLEASE READ THIS BEFORE YOU DISTRIBUTE OR USE THIS WORK

To protect the Project Gutenberg™ mission of promoting the free


distribution of electronic works, by using or distributing this work (or
any other work associated in any way with the phrase “Project
Gutenberg”), you agree to comply with all the terms of the Full
Project Gutenberg™ License available with this file or online at
www.gutenberg.org/license.

Section 1. General Terms of Use and


Redistributing Project Gutenberg™
electronic works
1.A. By reading or using any part of this Project Gutenberg™
electronic work, you indicate that you have read, understand, agree
to and accept all the terms of this license and intellectual property
(trademark/copyright) agreement. If you do not agree to abide by all
the terms of this agreement, you must cease using and return or
destroy all copies of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works in your
possession. If you paid a fee for obtaining a copy of or access to a
Project Gutenberg™ electronic work and you do not agree to be
bound by the terms of this agreement, you may obtain a refund from
the person or entity to whom you paid the fee as set forth in
paragraph 1.E.8.

1.B. “Project Gutenberg” is a registered trademark. It may only be


used on or associated in any way with an electronic work by people
who agree to be bound by the terms of this agreement. There are a
few things that you can do with most Project Gutenberg™ electronic
works even without complying with the full terms of this agreement.
See paragraph 1.C below. There are a lot of things you can do with
Project Gutenberg™ electronic works if you follow the terms of this
agreement and help preserve free future access to Project
Gutenberg™ electronic works. See paragraph 1.E below.
1.C. The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation (“the
Foundation” or PGLAF), owns a compilation copyright in the
collection of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works. Nearly all the
individual works in the collection are in the public domain in the
United States. If an individual work is unprotected by copyright law in
the United States and you are located in the United States, we do
not claim a right to prevent you from copying, distributing,
performing, displaying or creating derivative works based on the
work as long as all references to Project Gutenberg are removed. Of
course, we hope that you will support the Project Gutenberg™
mission of promoting free access to electronic works by freely
sharing Project Gutenberg™ works in compliance with the terms of
this agreement for keeping the Project Gutenberg™ name
associated with the work. You can easily comply with the terms of
this agreement by keeping this work in the same format with its
attached full Project Gutenberg™ License when you share it without
charge with others.

1.D. The copyright laws of the place where you are located also
govern what you can do with this work. Copyright laws in most
countries are in a constant state of change. If you are outside the
United States, check the laws of your country in addition to the terms
of this agreement before downloading, copying, displaying,
performing, distributing or creating derivative works based on this
work or any other Project Gutenberg™ work. The Foundation makes
no representations concerning the copyright status of any work in
any country other than the United States.

1.E. Unless you have removed all references to Project Gutenberg:

1.E.1. The following sentence, with active links to, or other


immediate access to, the full Project Gutenberg™ License must
appear prominently whenever any copy of a Project Gutenberg™
work (any work on which the phrase “Project Gutenberg” appears, or
with which the phrase “Project Gutenberg” is associated) is
accessed, displayed, performed, viewed, copied or distributed:
This eBook is for the use of anyone anywhere in the United
States and most other parts of the world at no cost and with
almost no restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away
or re-use it under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License
included with this eBook or online at www.gutenberg.org. If you
are not located in the United States, you will have to check the
laws of the country where you are located before using this
eBook.

1.E.2. If an individual Project Gutenberg™ electronic work is derived


from texts not protected by U.S. copyright law (does not contain a
notice indicating that it is posted with permission of the copyright
holder), the work can be copied and distributed to anyone in the
United States without paying any fees or charges. If you are
redistributing or providing access to a work with the phrase “Project
Gutenberg” associated with or appearing on the work, you must
comply either with the requirements of paragraphs 1.E.1 through
1.E.7 or obtain permission for the use of the work and the Project
Gutenberg™ trademark as set forth in paragraphs 1.E.8 or 1.E.9.

1.E.3. If an individual Project Gutenberg™ electronic work is posted


with the permission of the copyright holder, your use and distribution
must comply with both paragraphs 1.E.1 through 1.E.7 and any
additional terms imposed by the copyright holder. Additional terms
will be linked to the Project Gutenberg™ License for all works posted
with the permission of the copyright holder found at the beginning of
this work.

1.E.4. Do not unlink or detach or remove the full Project


Gutenberg™ License terms from this work, or any files containing a
part of this work or any other work associated with Project
Gutenberg™.

1.E.5. Do not copy, display, perform, distribute or redistribute this


electronic work, or any part of this electronic work, without
prominently displaying the sentence set forth in paragraph 1.E.1 with
active links or immediate access to the full terms of the Project
Gutenberg™ License.
1.E.6. You may convert to and distribute this work in any binary,
compressed, marked up, nonproprietary or proprietary form,
including any word processing or hypertext form. However, if you
provide access to or distribute copies of a Project Gutenberg™ work
in a format other than “Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other format used in
the official version posted on the official Project Gutenberg™ website
(www.gutenberg.org), you must, at no additional cost, fee or expense
to the user, provide a copy, a means of exporting a copy, or a means
of obtaining a copy upon request, of the work in its original “Plain
Vanilla ASCII” or other form. Any alternate format must include the
full Project Gutenberg™ License as specified in paragraph 1.E.1.

1.E.7. Do not charge a fee for access to, viewing, displaying,


performing, copying or distributing any Project Gutenberg™ works
unless you comply with paragraph 1.E.8 or 1.E.9.

1.E.8. You may charge a reasonable fee for copies of or providing


access to or distributing Project Gutenberg™ electronic works
provided that:

• You pay a royalty fee of 20% of the gross profits you derive from
the use of Project Gutenberg™ works calculated using the
method you already use to calculate your applicable taxes. The
fee is owed to the owner of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark,
but he has agreed to donate royalties under this paragraph to
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation. Royalty
payments must be paid within 60 days following each date on
which you prepare (or are legally required to prepare) your
periodic tax returns. Royalty payments should be clearly marked
as such and sent to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation at the address specified in Section 4, “Information
about donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation.”

• You provide a full refund of any money paid by a user who


notifies you in writing (or by e-mail) within 30 days of receipt that
s/he does not agree to the terms of the full Project Gutenberg™
License. You must require such a user to return or destroy all
copies of the works possessed in a physical medium and
discontinue all use of and all access to other copies of Project
Gutenberg™ works.

• You provide, in accordance with paragraph 1.F.3, a full refund of


any money paid for a work or a replacement copy, if a defect in
the electronic work is discovered and reported to you within 90
days of receipt of the work.

• You comply with all other terms of this agreement for free
distribution of Project Gutenberg™ works.

1.E.9. If you wish to charge a fee or distribute a Project Gutenberg™


electronic work or group of works on different terms than are set
forth in this agreement, you must obtain permission in writing from
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the manager of
the Project Gutenberg™ trademark. Contact the Foundation as set
forth in Section 3 below.

1.F.

1.F.1. Project Gutenberg volunteers and employees expend


considerable effort to identify, do copyright research on, transcribe
and proofread works not protected by U.S. copyright law in creating
the Project Gutenberg™ collection. Despite these efforts, Project
Gutenberg™ electronic works, and the medium on which they may
be stored, may contain “Defects,” such as, but not limited to,
incomplete, inaccurate or corrupt data, transcription errors, a
copyright or other intellectual property infringement, a defective or
damaged disk or other medium, a computer virus, or computer
codes that damage or cannot be read by your equipment.

1.F.2. LIMITED WARRANTY, DISCLAIMER OF DAMAGES - Except


for the “Right of Replacement or Refund” described in paragraph
1.F.3, the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the owner
of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark, and any other party
distributing a Project Gutenberg™ electronic work under this
agreement, disclaim all liability to you for damages, costs and
expenses, including legal fees. YOU AGREE THAT YOU HAVE NO
REMEDIES FOR NEGLIGENCE, STRICT LIABILITY, BREACH OF
WARRANTY OR BREACH OF CONTRACT EXCEPT THOSE
PROVIDED IN PARAGRAPH 1.F.3. YOU AGREE THAT THE
FOUNDATION, THE TRADEMARK OWNER, AND ANY
DISTRIBUTOR UNDER THIS AGREEMENT WILL NOT BE LIABLE
TO YOU FOR ACTUAL, DIRECT, INDIRECT, CONSEQUENTIAL,
PUNITIVE OR INCIDENTAL DAMAGES EVEN IF YOU GIVE
NOTICE OF THE POSSIBILITY OF SUCH DAMAGE.

1.F.3. LIMITED RIGHT OF REPLACEMENT OR REFUND - If you


discover a defect in this electronic work within 90 days of receiving it,
you can receive a refund of the money (if any) you paid for it by
sending a written explanation to the person you received the work
from. If you received the work on a physical medium, you must
return the medium with your written explanation. The person or entity
that provided you with the defective work may elect to provide a
replacement copy in lieu of a refund. If you received the work
electronically, the person or entity providing it to you may choose to
give you a second opportunity to receive the work electronically in
lieu of a refund. If the second copy is also defective, you may
demand a refund in writing without further opportunities to fix the
problem.

1.F.4. Except for the limited right of replacement or refund set forth in
paragraph 1.F.3, this work is provided to you ‘AS-IS’, WITH NO
OTHER WARRANTIES OF ANY KIND, EXPRESS OR IMPLIED,
INCLUDING BUT NOT LIMITED TO WARRANTIES OF
MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR ANY PURPOSE.

1.F.5. Some states do not allow disclaimers of certain implied


warranties or the exclusion or limitation of certain types of damages.
If any disclaimer or limitation set forth in this agreement violates the
law of the state applicable to this agreement, the agreement shall be
interpreted to make the maximum disclaimer or limitation permitted
by the applicable state law. The invalidity or unenforceability of any
provision of this agreement shall not void the remaining provisions.
1.F.6. INDEMNITY - You agree to indemnify and hold the
Foundation, the trademark owner, any agent or employee of the
Foundation, anyone providing copies of Project Gutenberg™
electronic works in accordance with this agreement, and any
volunteers associated with the production, promotion and distribution
of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works, harmless from all liability,
costs and expenses, including legal fees, that arise directly or
indirectly from any of the following which you do or cause to occur:
(a) distribution of this or any Project Gutenberg™ work, (b)
alteration, modification, or additions or deletions to any Project
Gutenberg™ work, and (c) any Defect you cause.

Section 2. Information about the Mission of


Project Gutenberg™
Project Gutenberg™ is synonymous with the free distribution of
electronic works in formats readable by the widest variety of
computers including obsolete, old, middle-aged and new computers.
It exists because of the efforts of hundreds of volunteers and
donations from people in all walks of life.

Volunteers and financial support to provide volunteers with the


assistance they need are critical to reaching Project Gutenberg™’s
goals and ensuring that the Project Gutenberg™ collection will
remain freely available for generations to come. In 2001, the Project
Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation was created to provide a
secure and permanent future for Project Gutenberg™ and future
generations. To learn more about the Project Gutenberg Literary
Archive Foundation and how your efforts and donations can help,
see Sections 3 and 4 and the Foundation information page at
www.gutenberg.org.

Section 3. Information about the Project


Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation
The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation is a non-profit
501(c)(3) educational corporation organized under the laws of the
state of Mississippi and granted tax exempt status by the Internal
Revenue Service. The Foundation’s EIN or federal tax identification
number is 64-6221541. Contributions to the Project Gutenberg
Literary Archive Foundation are tax deductible to the full extent
permitted by U.S. federal laws and your state’s laws.

The Foundation’s business office is located at 809 North 1500 West,


Salt Lake City, UT 84116, (801) 596-1887. Email contact links and up
to date contact information can be found at the Foundation’s website
and official page at www.gutenberg.org/contact

Section 4. Information about Donations to


the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation
Project Gutenberg™ depends upon and cannot survive without
widespread public support and donations to carry out its mission of
increasing the number of public domain and licensed works that can
be freely distributed in machine-readable form accessible by the
widest array of equipment including outdated equipment. Many small
donations ($1 to $5,000) are particularly important to maintaining tax
exempt status with the IRS.

The Foundation is committed to complying with the laws regulating


charities and charitable donations in all 50 states of the United
States. Compliance requirements are not uniform and it takes a
considerable effort, much paperwork and many fees to meet and
keep up with these requirements. We do not solicit donations in
locations where we have not received written confirmation of
compliance. To SEND DONATIONS or determine the status of
compliance for any particular state visit www.gutenberg.org/donate.

While we cannot and do not solicit contributions from states where


we have not met the solicitation requirements, we know of no
prohibition against accepting unsolicited donations from donors in
such states who approach us with offers to donate.

International donations are gratefully accepted, but we cannot make


any statements concerning tax treatment of donations received from
outside the United States. U.S. laws alone swamp our small staff.

Please check the Project Gutenberg web pages for current donation
methods and addresses. Donations are accepted in a number of
other ways including checks, online payments and credit card
donations. To donate, please visit: www.gutenberg.org/donate.

Section 5. General Information About Project


Gutenberg™ electronic works
Professor Michael S. Hart was the originator of the Project
Gutenberg™ concept of a library of electronic works that could be
freely shared with anyone. For forty years, he produced and
distributed Project Gutenberg™ eBooks with only a loose network of
volunteer support.

Project Gutenberg™ eBooks are often created from several printed


editions, all of which are confirmed as not protected by copyright in
the U.S. unless a copyright notice is included. Thus, we do not
necessarily keep eBooks in compliance with any particular paper
edition.

Most people start at our website which has the main PG search
facility: www.gutenberg.org.

This website includes information about Project Gutenberg™,


including how to make donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary
Archive Foundation, how to help produce our new eBooks, and how
to subscribe to our email newsletter to hear about new eBooks.

You might also like