Chapter Five: Market Structure 5.1 Perfectly Competition Market Structure
Chapter Five: Market Structure 5.1 Perfectly Competition Market Structure
Chapter Five: Market Structure 5.1 Perfectly Competition Market Structure
Market Structure
The structure of the market is a description of the behavior of buyers and sellers in that
market. Market structure is broadly grouped into two: perfectly competitive market and
an imperfectly competitive market. A competitive market is one in which buyers and
sellers assume that their own buying and selling decisions have no effect on market price.
An imperfectly competitive market is a market where either buyers or sellers take into
account the effects of their own actions on market price. This market includes monopoly,
monopolistic competition, and oligopoly (in the case of output market); or monopsony,
monopsonistic competition and ologopsony (the case of factor market). In this chapter we
consider the first one (i.e. perfectly competitive market).
iv) Free entry and exit from the industry (or market).
v) Government intervention into the market is little or nil.
vi) All buyers and sellers have complete knowledge of conditions of the market.
vii) The goal of the firm is profit maximization.
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 1
above P* its sales will fall to zero since all the customers realize that they can buy the
same/identical product elsewhere at the price P*. In other words, the demand curve is
perfectly elastic at the going market price P*.
2. The firm’s Average and Marginal Revenue Curve:
A perfectly elastic demand curve has an important characteristic: the average revenue
(AR) from the sale of every unit will be equal to the marginal revenue (MR) from the sale
of an extra unit. AR is another term for the price at which the firm sells its product. It is
given by total revenue divided by the total quantity sold; i.e. AR = R/Q. MR is the change
in total revenue resulting from the sale of an additional unit of the product. That is, MR =
dR/dQ. Since the firm can sell as much or as little as it wants at the going price, MR must
be equal to AR. This can be shown as below:
P AR (or Demand): P = f(Q); & and hence total revenue (R) is the
product of price & quantity sold; that is,
R = P*Q. Therefore:
P* AR=MR
AR = R/Q = P*Q/Q = P; and
MR = dR/dQ = d(P*Q)/dQ = P[dQ/dQ] = P. Thus, AR,
Q P and MR are all the same in perfect competition since
0
demand is perfectly elastic (or price is fixed).
(i) Total revenue – Total cost Approach: The firm is in equilibrium (maximizes
profit when the difference between revenue (R) and cost (C) is greatest. The
total revenue curve is a straight line through the origin, showing that price is
constant at all level of outputs (see figure below). The slope of revenue curve
is also called marginal revenue (dR/dQ). It is constant and equal to the
prevailing market price. Note that the firm maximizes its profit at the output
level where the distance between revenue and cost curve is the greatest. To the
left of point ‘a’ and to the right of point ‘b’ there is a loss because total cost
exceeds total revenue.
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 2
C/R
C
R
Maximum b
Profit
a
C
Qe Q
If MR exceeds MC, profit has to been maximized and it pays the firm to expand its
output. If MR is less than MC, the level of profit will be reduced and hence it pays the
firm to cut its production. Thus, it follows that short-run equilibrium occurs when MC
equals MR. Thus, the first condition for profit maximization is that MC is equal to MR;
and the second (or sufficient) condition for equilibrium requires that MC curve must cut
MR curve from below (i.e. the slope of MC should be greater than the slope of MR).
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 3
In short, at equilibrium (maximum profit) the following conditions must be satisfied:
1. MR MC; and
2. MC must be rising (i.e. slope of MC must be greater than slope of MR).
P
R, SMC The fact that a firm is in short-run equilibrium
C, SAC doesn’t necessarily mean that it makes excess
profits. Whether the firm makes excess profits
D e
P* C MR=AR or loses depends on the level of the average
A D B cost at short-run equilibrium. If the average
cost is below the price (or AR) at equilibrium,
Excess the firm earns excess profit equal to the
shaded are ABeP* in this figure. If AC>P,
there is a loss equal to the shaded region
0 Qe Q AP*Be.
0 Q1 Q2 Q3 0 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q
Q
If the price falls below P1 the firm will not supply any quantity since it doesn’t cover its
variable costs (i.e. the firm will minimize loss by shutting-down the business in which
case it will only pay TFC). Thus, if we plot the successive points of intersection of MC
and demand (or AR) curves, we will obtain the supply curve of an individual firm. It is
identical to the MC curve to the right of (or above) the shut-down point, e1.
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 4
and supply curve of the industry, the market is in equilibrium at a price which clears the
market (i.e. the price at which quantity demanded is equal to quantity supplied). See
figure below for industry equilibrium.
P* d P*
D
0 qe q 0 Qe Q
The firm is in equilibrium producing qe level of output at price P*. And the industry
reaches equilibrium at the same price P* but producing Qe of output.
B. Long-run Equilibrium:
In he long-run since all inputs are variable the firm has the option of adjusting its plant
size as well as output to achieve maximum profit. Similarly, adjustment f the number of
firms in the industry in response to profit motivation is the key element in establishing
long-run equilibrium.
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 5
5.2 Imperfect Market Structure
5.2.1. Pure Monopoly
5.2.1. Definition
A public Franchise a right granter to a firm by government that permits the firm to
provide a particular good or service and exclude all others from doing the same (thus
eliminating potential competitors by law).
Patents are granted to inventors of a product or process for a certain specific period of
time. For example in Ethiopia, patents are given for a period of 15 years. During this
period, the patent holder is shielded from competitors; no one else can legally produce
and sell the patented produce or process. The rationales behind patent right is to
encourage innovation in an economy.
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 6
Entry into some industries and occupations requires a government granted license.
For example, radio and television stations cannot operate without a license from the
Federal Communication Authority.
III. Natural Monopoly: - the size of the market may be such as not to support
more than one plant of optimal size. The technology may exhibit substantial
economies of scale, which require only a single plant if they are to be fully
reaped. An example of natural monopoly includes communications,
electricity, transport, water, etc usually; government undertakes the
production of the commodity or the service so as the avoided exploitation of
the consumer.
IV. Limit- pricing policy: is a pricing policy aiming at the prevention of new
entry. Such a pricing policy may be combined with other policies such as
heavy advertising which render entry unattractive.
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 7
P
D’
D Q Q
MR
Figure 1.1
dQ =-b
dp
b. The price elasticity of demand is
Ed = dQ * P
dp Q
Ed = -b * P
Q
a. At point D the elasticity approaches infinity
Ed = -b - P
Q ∞
Ed = -b * P
Q 0
c. At the mid point C the price elasticity is unity
Ed = -b * P
Q -1
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 8
TR= P.Q
Q = a – b*P
Q – a = - b*P
b*P = a – Q
P = a - 1*Q
b b
TR = P.Q
TR = (c- d*Q)Q
AR = TR
Q
AR = c*Q-d*Q2
Q
AR = c – d*Q
AR = P
MR = dTR
dQ Where TR = CQ – dQ2
MR = C – 2dQ
That is, the MR is a straight line with the same intercept as the demand curve, but twice
as steep.
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 9
f. Relationship between MR and P
TR = PQ
MR = dTR
dQ
MR = d (P*Q)…………… Apply the Product Rule
dQ
MR = P * dQ + Q* dP
dQ dQ
MR = P + Q. dP
dQ
MR = P - Q. dP Since dP <0
dQ dQ
MR + Q*dP = P
dQ
Hence, P > MR by an amount equal to (Q* dP )
dQ
TR = P*Q
MR = dTR
dQ
MR = P * dQ + Q * dP
dQ dQ
MR = P + Q *dP
dQ
MR = P 1 + Q * dP
P dQ
Remember: Ed = dQ . P
dP Q
1 = dP . P
Ed dQ Q
MR = P [ 1 + 1 ]
(Ed)
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 10
MR = p [ 1- 1 ] , where e = Ed
e
When e > 1: MR > 0
e < 1 : MR < 0
e = 1: MR = 0
Therefore, it can be concluded that the monopolist always operates on the elastic portion
of the demand curve, where MR > 0
5.2.4 Costs
In the traditional theory of monopoly the shapes of cost curves are the same as in the
theory of pure competition. The AVC, MC, and ATC are U-shaped, while AFC is a
rectangular hyperbola.
One point that should be stressed is that the MC curve is not the supply curve of the
monopolist, as in the case of pure competition. In monopoly there is no unique
relationship between price and quantity supplied. To put the same thing differently, a
monopolist has no supply curve at all.
5.2.5 Equilibrium of the Monopolist
A. Short-run Equilibrium
The monopolist maximizes his short-run profit if the following two conditions are fulfilled
1. MR = MC
2. The slope of MR (dMR ) is less than the slope of the MC ( dMC) , i.e
dQ dQ
Earlier, we argued that, profit would be maximized if (i.) MR=MC, and (ii) the slope of
MC is greater than the slope of the MR curve. In the context of economic theory,
however, maximum profit does not always imply positive profit. Like a perfectly
competitive firm a monopolist can make either positive, zero or even negative profit at
the profit maximizing level of output in the short-run. This is because the monopolist is
constrained both by demand and the input market.
A monopolist can’t freely set both its price and its quantity at any level to maximize
profit for it has no control over demand. Once the monopolist set the price, he/she must
adjust output in response to the market demand for the product. Besides demand, the
input market and technology also limit the operation of the monopolist. These constraints
may result in any one of the three outcomes.
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 11
Figure 1.2 shows the case of a monopolist that makes a positive profit.
Birr
P B SMC
SATC
C E
O Q MR D(AR) Quantity
In the above fig 1.2. the equilibrium of the monopolist is defined by point E, at which
the MC intersects the MR curve from below. Thus, price P* will be charged and an
amount of Q* output will be produced and supplied. The monopolist will realize
excess profit of an amount equal to the shaded area.
Profit we argued will be maximized at the level of output and price for which marginal
revenue (MR) and marginal cost (MC) are equal. On the figure the two are equal at point
E. Q represents the profit maximizing level of output. It is determined by drooping a
perpendicular from point E to the quantity axis. P represents the corresponding profit
maximizing price. It is determined by extending the perpendicular up to the demand or
average revenue curve, point B, and reading its value on the price axis.
Total revenue obtained from the sale of Q units of output is by definition OQ multiplied
by OP i.e., the product of price and quantity. The area of rectangle OP BA provides the
total revenue of the monopolist. Total cost of production of the profit maximizing level
of output is O Q multiplied by OC, the product of quantity and average cost of
production. The area of rectangle OCE Q measures the total cost. Total profit of the
monopolist in this case, is given by the area PBEC. Since total revenue exceeds total cost
profit is positive.
In this case of a monopoly, price is set above the marginal cost of production. Thus
consumers are paying more than the true cost of production. Possession of an enormous
degree of monopoly power, as we said earlier, does not always ensure a positive
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 12
economic profit. The state of market demand, or of costs, or of both, may force a zero
profit on the monopolist.
Birr
SATC
P A
D(AR)
0 Q RE Quantity
The tangency of the average cost and average revenue or price at point A in the figure
shows that the maximized total economic profit is zero. Any other price would result in a
negative profit. Note that, the expression zero profit does not mean that the monopolist
receives no returns. The cost curves contain the required normal profit.
A monopolistic zero profit has some features in common with the competitive zero profit
solution. (See Figure) In both cases, the short run average total cost curve (SATC) is
tangent to the average revenue or the demand curve. This indicates that the average
revenue (price) is equal to the average cost, hence, consumers pay no more than the true
cost of production. But a monopolistic zero profit solution has some important aspects
that distinguishes it from perfect competition.
Since the demand curve under monopoly, is a negatively sloped one, the average total
cost can be tangent to it at the range where its slope is negative. This means that the plant
cannot be operated at its lowest cost of production. Since tangency, when it does occur,
must be to the left of the minimum point of the short run average total cost, there is an
inefficient operation of plants which takes the form of under utilization. A monopolist
may have to accept losses in the short run.
If the short run average variable cost curve was to lie entirely above the average revenue
curve, the firm would be unable to cover not only the fixed cost but also part of its
variable cost and would improve its financial position by closing.
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 13
and given the cost function
C = f(Q)
d (TR – TC ) = 0
dQ
dTR dTC
dQ - dQ = 0
MR - MC = 0
MR = MC
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 14
c) Long-run Equilibrium
Long-run equilibrium of a monopolist is the same as short-run equilibrium where MR
is equal to MC, provided that the MC cuts the MR from below. In the long – run the
monopolist has the time to expand its plant, or to use its existing plan at any level
which will maximize his profit. What is certain is that the monopolist will not stay in
business if it makes losses in the long-run; it will most probably continue to earn
supernormal profits even in the long-run, given that entry is blocked.
The equilibrium condition for a monopolist where it sells its product at two different
market is given by:
MR1 = MR2 = MC
If, however, there are N markets the equilibrium condition will be given by:
MR1 = MR2 = …=MRN =MC
The numerical example on price discrimination will be discussed during class room
discussion
Multiplan Monopolist
So far we have assumed that there is only one plant where the monopolist produce its
output , but sells at different markets. Since the monopolist operates only in a single
plant, there exists only one cost structure, hence the equilibrium condition is given by:
MR1 = MR2 = MC
However, let's assume that the monopolist operates with two different plants and sells its
output for only a single market. Let's also assume that the monopolist knows its cost
structure with certainly and the objective of the firms is profit maximization.
The equilibrium condition for a multiplant monopolist will be
MR = MC1 = MC2 = … = MC
The mathematical derivation of a multi plant monopolist, which operates only in two
different plant, and numerical example will be discussed during the normal class
discussion.
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 15
Social Cost of Monopoly
From the society point of view, monopoly is inefficient in allocating factors of production
as compared to perfect competition. The monopolist produces less amount of output and
charges higher price as compared to perfect competitive firm.
The extent of monopolist inefficiency is measured by the concept of consumer's and
producer's surplus
Consider the following diagram during session
p
O
Q0 Q1 Q
eg =-( C+E)
Thus, welfare has declined by the area C and E. Note that the area B is not lost,
rather transferred from CS to PS
The area C + E is known as Dead Weigh Loss. It's a loss neither gained by the
producer nor by the consumer. It is a loss to society.
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 16
5.3. MONOPOLICTIC COMPETITION
In the first part of this course we examined two "pure" market structures: Perfect Competition and
Pure Monopoly. We defined perfect Competition as the form of market organization in which
there are many sellers of a homogeneous product. Moreover, we defined Pure Monopoly as a
single seller of a commodity for which there are no close substitutes. Between these two extreme
forms of market organization lies monopolistic competition and oligopoly. In this chapter we
consider monopolistic competition. It refers to the case in which there are many sellers of a
heterogeneous or differentiated product & entry into or exit from the industry is rather is easy in
the long run. In summary, an industry is characterized as a monopolistically competitive if:
there are many buyers and sellers.
each firm in the industry (or Product group) produces differentiated product that are close
substitute.
there are free entry into and exit from the industry.
Thus, monopolistic competition is a market structure in which a relatively large number of small
producers are offering similar, but not identical products. Note: as the name implies,
monopolistic competition is a blend of (perfect) competition & monopoly. The Competitive
element arises because:
there are many sellers in the market, each of which is too small to affect the other
sells, and
Firms can enter & leave a monopolistically competitive industry easily in the
long-run.
The monopolistic element arises from product differentiation. That is, since the product of each
seller is similar but not identical, each seller has a monopoly power over the specific product it
sells.
Chamberlin made other heroic assumptions of monopolistic competition. That is,
all firms face the same demand conditions which implies that consumers' preferences are
evenly distributed among different sellers; and
all firms also face the same cost conditions, i.e. the differences in products does not give
rise to differences in costs.
These assumptions help to show the equilibrium of the firm and market on the same diagram.
1.1 Product Differentiation & the Demand Curve
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 17
Differentiated Products are products that are similar but not identical. The similarity of
differentiated products arises from the fact that they satisfy the same basic consumption needs.
Examples include numerous brands of breakfast cereals, toothpaste, cigarettes and cold medicines
on the market today. The product differentiation may be real (when the inherent characteristics
of the products are different) or imaginary (when the products are basically the same but
consumers are persuaded that the products are different)
The real differentiation exists when there are differences in the:
Specification of products, or
Factor inputs used, or
The case of the various breakfast cereals with various nutritional and sugar contents is best
example of real differentiation.
Imaginary (Fancied) differentiation is established by:
Advertising, or
Differences in packaging, or
Differences in product design, or
Brand name; example: The case of different brands of aspirin, all of
which contain the same ingredients.
Demand Schedule: since the product of each seller is similar but not identical, each seller has a
monopoly power over the specific product it sells. This monopoly power, however, is severely
limited by the existence of close substitutes. Thus, these product differentiations create brand
loyalty of consumers and give rise to downward sloping elastic demand curve. That is, consumers
are willing to pay a higher price to enjoy the advantage of product differentiation. Since this
differentiation is slight the firm faces highly elastic demand curve.
Price
Highly elastic
demand curve
0 quantity
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 18
producing similar (or closely related) products. Here, for simplicity we will continue to use the
term "industry" (to refer to all the sellers of the slightly differentiated products in a product
group).
1.2 Price & Output Determination in the Short-run and Long run
Before we examine equilibrium of monopolistically competitive firm let us briefly explain some
basic concepts.
*Costs: Chamberlin adopts the shape of costs of the traditional theory of the firm. That is, ATC,
AVC and MC curves are all U-shaped; and AFC has a geometric hyperbola shape.
*Actual-Sales (or share- of the market) Demand Curve: It is also called proportional (or
prorata) demand curve. It shows the actual sales of a firm at each price after accounting for the
adjustments of the prices of other firms in the group. Alternatively, it is the amount of demand
going to a typical firm when all firms are charging the same price. Here all firms adjust price
simultaneously but independently.
*Perceived (or Planned) demand curves: the amount of demand going to a typical firm when
there is no a simultaneous price adjustment by other firms.
1.3. Short-Run and Long-run Equilibrium
Short-Run Equilibrium: Just like any other firm, the monopolistically competitive firm will
produce as long as the marginal (extra) revenue from selling output exceeds the extra (marginal)
cost of producing that output. In the short-run, maximum profit (or equilibrium) occurs when
these extra revenue (MR) and extra costs (MC) are equal. See point E of figure (a) below. In
general, short-run equilibrium conditions are:
MR = MC and MC is rising, &
Proportional demand curve intersects perceive demand curve.
Graphical illustration of equilibrium:
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 19
P/C
P/C
MC
D D
MC AC
AC
Pe C A
Pe
A
B
d
E e
d
D D
Q 0 Q
0 Qe Qe
MR MR
5.4. OLIGOPOLY
Definition: Oligopoly is the form of market organization in which there are few sellers of
homogeneous or differentiated product. If there are only two sellers in the market, we have a
duopoly. That is, duopoly is a special case of oligopoly in which there are only two sellers in the
market. If the product is homogeneous, we have a pure oligopoly. If the product is
differentiated, we have a differentiated oligopoly.
Because there are only few firms selling a homogeneous or differentiated product in oligopolistic
markets, the action of each firm affects the other firms in the industry, and vice versa. Thus, it is
clear that the distinguishing characteristic of oligopoly is the interdependence or rivalry among
firms in the industry. This interdependence is the natural result of fewness.
The sources of oligopoly are generally the same as for monopoly, that is:
1. Economies of scale, which enable few firms supplying the entire market.
2. Huge capital investment & specialized inputs are required to enter oligopolistic industry
(eg. Automobiles, aluminum, steel, ...)
3. Patent right (exclusive right to produce a commodity or to use a particular
production process).
4. Established firms may have loyal following customers
5. Control over entire supply of raw materials.
6. The government may award a franchise to only few firms to operate.
Types of Oligopoly: In general, oligopoly market is divided into two broad categories:
I. Non-collusive Oligopoly: in which firms may be better rivals of each other through
advertising, product differentiation, and so on.
II. Collusive Oligopoly: in which firms form coalition and cooperate.
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 20
5.4.1. NON-COLLUSIVE OLIGOPOLY
Since an oligopolist knows that its own actions will have a significant impact on the other
Oligopolists in the industry, each oligopolist must consider the possible reaction of competitors in
deciding its pricing policies, the degree of product differentiation to introduce, the level of
advertising to undertake, & so on.
Because competitors can react in many different ways, we do not have a single oligopoly model.
Here we present some of the most important Oligopoly models:
A) Cournot's Model (lies between competition & monopoly)
B) The Stackelberg model (extension of Cournot model).
C) The "Kinked-Demand" model
D) Bertrand's Model (similar with perfect competition)
Definition: Reaction curve of firm A is the locus of points of highest profits that firm A can
attain, given the level of output of rival firm, say B. Similarly, reaction curve of firm B shows
how much output firm B must produce in order to maximize its own profit, given the level of
output of its rival, firm A.
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 21
Mathematical Derivation of Reaction Curves:
Suppose the market demand facing the Duopolist is: Q = a + bP, where Q = market output, P =
price & b = slope, which is less than zero. Assume also that the two duopolists have different
costs:
C1 = f1(Q1), and C2 = f2(Q2).
Thus, 1 = R1 - C1 ------ the first duopolist profit function &
2 = R2 - C2 ----- the 2nd duopolist profit function
Note: R1 = PQ1 and R2 = PQ2 , and Q1 + Q2 = Q
i) The first duopolist maximizes his profit by assuming second firm's output (Q 2) constant,
irrespective of his own decisions; while the second duopolist maximizes his profit by
assuming that Q1 will be remain constant.
The first -order (necessary) condition for profit maximization of each duopolist is:
NB: R1 = MR1, R2 =MR2, C1 = MC1 & C2 = MC2
Q1 Q2 Q1 Q2
Example 1: Assume that the market demand equation is given as: Q = 12-P, where Q = total
quantity of spring water sold in the market & P is the market price. Suppose that spring water is
supplied with zero costs. Thus, MC is zero for the two firms, A & B.
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 22
a) Find the reaction function of both firms.
b) Compute QA & QB that leads to Cournot stable equilibrium.
Solving for QA from expression (1) , we get A's reaction function, i.e.
QA = 12 - QB ------------- (3) A's reaction function
Heinrich Stackelberg (German economist) made an important extension to the Cournot model.
Stackelberg assumed that one of the duopolists, say duopolist A, knows that duopolist B behaves
in the naive Cournot fashion (i.e., firm A knows B's reaction function) and uses that knowledge in
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 23
choosing its own output. Duopolist A is then called the Stackelberg leader, duopolist B is
referred to as the Stackelberg follower. All the other assumptions of the Cournot model hold.
This model shows that duopolist A will have higher profits than under Cournot solution at the
expense of duopolist B (the Stackelberg follower).
The Stackelberg leader substitutes the follower's reaction function in market demand equation
and solve for his output (QA). The resulting expression is the demand function facing duopolist A
(the leader). Then, as usual cases the leader maximizes profit by equating his MR to his MC.
Because products are homogenous, consumers purchase only from the lowest price seller. Thus,
if the two firms charge different prices, the higher priced firm will sell nothing. If both firms
charge the same price, consumers will be indifferent as to which firm they buy from. And it is
assumed that each will supply half the market. In general, this model leads to price competition
over time. Each firm tries to cut price to capture the entire market share. Thus, all will seek to
undercut their rivals and a price cutting war will result. Firms will stop cutting their prices only
when competitive price level is reached. In other words, Bertrand’s equilibrium is at a perfectly
competitive price such that no further price cutting occurs.
Consider the following example where the market demand for a good is: P = 80 – Q, where Q =
Q1+Q2; and both firms have a constant MC of 10. Thus, if price is below this MC, there will be an
incentive to reduce price with the intension of capturing more market share. This price cut will
continue until it equals MC, which is, of course, a competitive price. Thus, for Bertrand
equilibrium occurs when P = MC = 10, and over all equilibrium output equals 70 (Q=80-P),
where each firm supplies half of the market; i.e. Q1=Q2= Q/2=70/2 = 35 units.
One way of avoiding uncertainty (eg. price war) arising from oligopolistic interdependence is to
enter into collusive agreements. There are two types of collusion: Cartels and Price Leadership
Models. Collusion can be explicit or tacit (implicit).
2.1 Cartel: is a combination of firms whose objective is to limit the scope of competitive
forces within a market. There are two forms of Cartels:
A) Centralized Cartel (cartels aiming at joint profit maximization), and
B) Market-sharing cartel.
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 24
the share (distribution) of monopoly profits among member firms.
Thus, total marginal cost is obtained by the horizontal summation of each firm's in the cartel. We
consider a homogeneous commodity or pure oligopoly. Industry (monopoly) price & output is
determined by equating market MR and industry MC (= SMC). Consider two firms form a
cartel.
Given the market demand (DD) & each firm's MC in figure above the monopoly solution, which
maximizes joint profits, is determined by the intersection of total MC & MR (point e). The total
output is Qm and it will be sold at P . The central agency allocates the production (Q m) among
firm A & firm B by equating the common MR to the individual marginal costs (i.e. MR = MC 1 =
MC2; see point e1 & e2). Thus, firm A will produce Q 1 and firm B will produce Q 2. Similarly, the
distribution of profits is decided by a central agency of the cartel
P c P
d
f
g P
a b
MC1=MR MC2=MR e2 MC=MR e
e1
0 Q1 QA 0 Q2 QB 0 Qm=Q1+Q2 D Q
MR
mainly based on their cost structure. The shaded areas (or area abc P for firm A & area of dgf
P for firm B) of figures shown above represents profits of each firm. A total industry profit is
the sum of the profits of the two firms.
1) Non-Price Competition: In this case the member firms agree on common price, at which
each firm can sell any quantity demanded. The price is set by bargaining, with the low - cost
firms pressing for a lower price & the high -cost firms for a high price. But the firms agree not to
sell at a price below the cartel price.
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 25
This form of Cartel is "loose" in the sense that it is more unstable than the complete cartel aiming
at joint profit maximization. This is because with cost differences, the low - cost firms will have
a strong incentive to break away from the Cartel openly & charge a lower price, or to cheat the
other firms (members) by secret price concessions to the buyers. Such cheating will soon be
discovered by the other members, who will gradually lose their customers. Therefore, others may
split from the cartel and price war and instability may develop.
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 26
Compiled by Dechassa G. and Milkessa D. (Msc in Economics) 2017 Microeconomics (Econ 201) 27