Nothing Special   »   [go: up one dir, main page]

Oil Service Contracts

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 27

Oil and Gas Service Contracts around the World: A Review1

Abbas Ghandia, C.-Y. Cynthia Linb

a
Institute of Transportation Studies, University of California at Davis, One Shields Avenue, 1605
Tilia Street, Suite 100, Davis, CA 95616, United States. Email: aghandi@ucdavis.edu.
b
Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California at Davis, One Shields Avenue,
Davis, CA 95616, United States.
Phone: (530) 752-0824. Fax: (530) 752-5614. Email: cclin@primal.ucdavis.edu

March 14, 2014

Abstract
This paper reviews the energy strategy and oil and natural gas fiscal systems of eight
major oil or natural gas producing countries which have either adopted a variation of a service
contract or have shown interest in this framework as an alternative to production sharing
contracts over the period 1990 to 2014. In particular, we look at each country’s variation of
service contract, and examine how these variations of service contracts are different from each
other. A service contract is a long-term contractual framework that is used by some host
governments to acquire the international oil companies’ expertise and capital without having to
hand over the field and production ownership rights to them. Our review suggests that the new
interest in service contracts might be explained partially by heightened sovereignty concerns and
the political environment on one hand, and the need for international oil companies’ capital and
know-how in developing oil and natural gas fields in the host countries on the other. In our
review, we also explore some of the drawbacks of service contracts including the potential for
economically inefficient outcomes. In addition, we look at some possible solutions for improving
the economic efficiency of service contracts.

Keywords: oil service contracts, energy strategy review, oil and natural gas producing countries

1
The authors would like to thank the Sustainable Transportation Energy Pathways (STEPS) Program at
the Institute of Transportation Studies (ITS) at the University of California at Davis for financial support.
We are also thankful for several individuals at international oil companies for their general comments
about oil service contracts. In addition, we thank the participants of 2013 STEPS seminar and the 51 st
meeting of the Euro Working Group on Commodities and Financial Modeling in London in May 2013.
Lin is a member of the Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics. All errors are our own.
1. Introduction

In recent years, some oil and natural gas producing countries have shown an increasing
interest in adopting variations of service-type contracts rather than production sharing contracts
or concessions in their oil and natural gas development and exploration projects. A service
contract2 is a long-term contractual framework that governs the relation between a host
government and international oil companies (IOCs) in which the IOCs develop or explore oil or
natural gas fields on behalf of the host government in return for pre-determined fees and in
which in most cases the host government does not hand over the control of the extracted or
subsoil or sub-surface resources to the IOCs.3

The move towards service contracts is reminiscent of a similar transition towards


production sharing contracts away from concessionary systems starting in 1966 in Indonesia.4
While opposition against international oil companies’ control over the world oil prices and
sovereignty issues over natural resources might have been the main driving factors behind the
adoption of production sharing contracts in the 1960s (Machmud, 2000), it seems that the new
interest in service contracts might be explained partially by heightened sovereignty concerns on
one hand, and the need for international oil companies’ capital5 and know-how6 in developing oil

2
The term service contract can also refer to oilfield service contracts. There are oilfield service firms,
such as Halliburton, Schlumberger and Baker Hughes, that provide oilfield services and that may
specialize in services such as drilling. These firms are awarded oilfield service contracts to fulfill
particular jobs as part of broader development or exploration plans. Sund and Hausken (2012) analyze
when an operator and a service provider prefer a fixed price oilfield service contract, common in the oil
and gas industry, versus the uncommon incentive-based oilfield service contract. In this paper, we focus
on service contracts between host governments and international oil companies, not on oilfield service
contracts between an operator and a service provider.
3
In some variations of service contracts such as Venezuela’s third round operational service agreements,
the IOCs may enjoy more benefit than usual service contracts in terms of sharing the profit oil, and
therefore have some degree of control over the produced crude. However, in general, service contracts do
not have a profit sharing mechanism.
4
In August 1966, the first version of a production sharing contract was signed between Indonesia’s state
owned company, PERTAMINA, and Independent Indonesian American Petroleum (IIPCO) group
(Machmud, 2000).
5
The degree of need for the IOCs’ capital varies in each country and for different projects inside a
country. In some cases, a country’s bad credit rating may leave the country no other option than to fund
the projects through the IOCs’ capital and pay back them later. This could be the case in production
sharing as well. In addition, the IOCs might have access to cheaper capital compared to what is available
for the host governments. In other words, it might be cheaper for the countries to borrow from the IOCs
than to finance their development projects through other sources. In the case of Iraq, due to the fast cost
recovery mechanism embedded in the technical service contracts, it may look that the country did not
need the IOCs’ capital. However, the total cost of development of all the awarded fields in the first two
<Footnote continues next page.>
and natural gas fields7 in the host countries on the other. As argued by Ghandi and Lin (2012)
for the case of Iran, several major OPEC and non-OPEC oil producing countries have found
service-type contracts a means to address both sovereignty concerns, which mostly are reflected
in these countries’ constitutions and petroleum laws and regulations, and the need for IOCs’
capital and expertise capabilities. As we describe for each of the eight countries we examine in
this paper, the political environment is a contributing factor for the heightened sovereignty
concerns and the move toward service-type contracts as well.

In the late 1980s and early 1990s, service-type contractual frameworks started to appear
in the political economy of several major oil or natural gas producing countries. Venezuela,
Kuwait and Iran signed their first of such contracts in 1991, 1992 and 1995, respectively. More
recently Iraq, Mexico, Bolivia, Ecuador and Turkmenistan have signed new service contracts, or
have shown more interest in adopting variations of service-type contracts rather than production
sharing contracts in order to explore and develop their oil and natural gas fields.

This paper presents a short review of service contracts in the above eight countries. First,
we compare service contracts and production sharing contracts and provide some reasons for the
move towards service contracts. We then discuss some potential drawbacks of service contracts,
mostly due to the loss of profit through time, which is interpreted as economic inefficiency. In
addition, we look at some possible solutions for improving economic efficiency of service
contracts. Then we discuss thoroughly the oil and natural gas fiscal system in each of the eight
countries mentioned above. In particular, we study each country’s variation of service contract,
and how these variations of service contracts are different from each other. We also examine the
political environment and other sources of heightened sovereignty concerns in each country.
Finally, we conclude with an emphasis on the sovereignty concerns as an explanatory factor for
the move towards the service contracts and the consequence of such decisions in terms of
economically inefficient outcomes.

rounds may suggest that financing through government annual budget was really hard and may be
impossible (personal communication with industry experts).
6
In addition to the need to IOCs capital, the participation of the IOCs allows the government to benefit
from their know-how. The know-how is sometimes bigger than just the technology. It also includes
project management in terms of how the capital is invested since IOCs have better advantage on the
process and structural system of managing large scale investment (personal communication with industry
experts).
7
This is particularly the case for mature fields that require enhanced oil recoveries or fields in more
challenging locations.

3
2. Service versus Production Sharing Contracts

Table 1 summarizes some of the differences between four petroleum fiscal regimes:
concessions, production sharing contracts, and service contracts. In this section we focus on
comparing service contracts with production sharing contracts.

In a service contract, similar to a production sharing agreement, the closest legal


framework, the international oil company brings the technology and makes the upfront capital
investment. However, in contrast to production sharing contracts, in a service contract the IOCs
agree to a pre-determined return in lieu for sharing profit oil. In addition to the IOC’s method of
compensation, service contracts and production sharing contracts could also differ in four other
major categories: field ownership rights, produced crude ownership rights, field’s operatorship,
and the degree of risk that each side bears. These differences are summarized in Table 1.

One main driving factor why many countries are adopting a variation of service contracts
is their concern for maintaining their sovereignty over their natural resources. Under a service
contract, countries maintain field ownership and in most cases produced crude ownership rights
as well, and do not have to allocate them to the foreign company. Countries are interested in
adopting service contracts because service contracts enable them to give up less control over the
fields and over the produced crude to foreign oil companies while still using the expertise of
these companies.

With production sharing contracts, sovereignty concerns arise in part because these
contracts give decision-making power to the international oil companies in handling the
development/exploration and operation. Under a production sharing contract, countries share
produced crude ownership rights with the foreign company.

When countries relinquish their sovereignty over their natural resources, there is a lower
potential for proper oversight from the host government over the international oil companies’
operation, which is in part due to the many different regulatory, supervisory and operatorship
roles that the state-owned oil companies usually have to play at the same time in these countries.

Another source of sovereignty concerns that arise from production sharing contracts is
the tax code or some institutional deficiencies that could prevent the host governments from
efficiently collecting rent from the international oil companies. As a result, while there have been
efforts in some oil producing countries that have demonstrated interests in service contracts to
reform the tax code in order to attenuate some of the sovereignty concerns arising from
production sharing, the lack of political will and public support, due in part to institutional
problems, have made the implementation of production sharing very difficult.

While a service contract may better address sovereignty concerns, the framework is prone
to huge potential losses in profit, as shown by Ghandi and Lin (2012) and Ghandi and Lin
(2014a) for Iran’s buy-back service contract and Iraq’s producing field technical service contract,
4
respectively.8 In both studies, the state-owned oil companies’ objectives diverge from dynamic
profit maximization, which is one of the factors causing service contracts to be economically
inefficient. In fact, adopting a dynamic profit maximization policy as a means to increase the
economic efficiency of the service-type contract is a common recommendation suggested by
both studies for both cases of service contracts in Iran and Iraq.

The service contract framework is prone to huge potential losses in profit even if the host
government adopts a dynamic profit maximization policy. Even though both Ghandi and Lin
(2012) and Ghandi and Lin (2014a) show that adopting dynamic profit maximization objectives,
as opposed to objectives of maximizing undiscounted revenue or of maximizing cumulative
production through time, could yield more economically efficient outcomes, the adoption of such
a policy might not be enough to make the outcomes under a service contract efficient. The
uncertainty is due to the fact that the dynamic profit maximization concept requires making
incessant optimal decisions through time. In particular, such a policy requires that in each period,
the operator updates its decision on the optimal production quantity and also its optimal new well
drilling plan9 based on updated oil market price forecasts, reserves estimates, required capital
and operation cost and other determinant factors.

However, since the IOCs’ remuneration are pre-determined in association to the


production profile through the lifetime of the contract, the current service contracts lack the
necessary tools for adopting the dynamic profit maximization objectives by the state-owned oil
companies. Specifically, in terms of Iran’s buy back service contracts, the IOCs’ remuneration
entitlement is contingent upon following pre-determined contractual profile for specified amount
of time. Under such requirements, deviation from the contractual production levels might be hard
even though the operator finds it optimal (Ghandi & Lin, 2012). In the case of Iraq, the IOCs’
per barrel remuneration is in close association to reaching and staying at the production plateau
target in the production plateau period (Ghandi & Lin, 2014a) without any mechanism in place to
decide on the production level optimally in each period.

Under production sharing on the other hand, it is more likely that the IOCs, in partnership
with the state-owned oil companies, follow dynamic profit maximization objectives. This is
because under production sharing the IOCs are given decision making power and ownership
rights over the produced crude, and decisions are made over the whole field in conjunction with
their state-owned oil company partner. Therefore, IOCs and their state-owned oil company
partner are more likely to achieve higher economic efficiency under production sharing
framework than the service contract.

8
These two papers discuss in detail evidence for the existence of such economic inefficiency in the case
of Iran’s Soroosh and Nowrooz buy back service contract and Iraq’s Rumaila producing field technical
service contract, respectively.
9
The choice of well drilling plan in addition to production is modelled by Ghandi and Lin (2014a) for the
case of Iraq.

5
Despite the drawbacks to service contracts, these contracts have the potential to be
improved within the service contract framework.10 As Ghandi and Lin (2014a) show for the case
of the Rumaila producing field technical service contract, in comparing the most likely scenario
to be realized with the optimal outcome under the conditions of the contract (their “TSC
optimal” scenario), there is a potential for a profit gain as high as 56 to 83 billion dollars for the
varying and high well productivity cases, respectively. It is therefore still possible to improve the
efficiency of outcomes under a service framework.

Now that we have established the differences among service-type and production sharing
contracts, and the reasons for countries to move towards service contracts, we describe the
current state of service-type contracts in each of the eight above mentioned countries.

10
The adoption of service contracts may also affect the ability of host governments to attract investment
by international oil companies. Ghandi and Lin (2014b) analyze risk factors specific to Iran’s buy-back
service contracts that can contribute to a reduction in the rate of return for the international oil company.
They show that there is a potential for modifying the contracts in order to make them more attractive to
the international oil company, enabling the international oil company to face an actual rate of return
closer to the contractual rate of return even if the contract faces cost overrun or delay, without exceeding
the maximum contractual return that the National Iranian Oil Company is willing to give.

6
Table 1: Petroleum Fiscal Arrangements
Concessionary System Contractual System
Concession Production Sharing Contracts Service Contracts
Oil Field Ownership IOC NOC NOC
Crude Production Ownership IOC IOC/NOC NOC
Oil Field Operator IOC IOC IOC/NOC
How the IOC is Compensated N/A A share of production Flat fee
Who Bears the Risk IOC IOC/NOC IOC/NOC
Notes: IOC denotes “international oil company”. NOC denotes “national oil company”.
3. Summary of Service Contracts around the World

As shown in Table 2, there are at least eight countries around the world that have pursued
or shown interests in service contracts. Each country, however, has pursed its own variation of
service-type contracts, and often more than one variation. The fact that each country uses its own
unique name for its contracts reinforces that the contracts are not the same.
Table 2: Summary of Countries and their Variations of Service Contracts
Iran’s New Plans for More Attractive
Buy-Back Service Contract First Buy-Back Service Contract Second Buy-Back Service Contract Third Contracts Including Variations of
Iran Generation Generation Generation Iraq’s Technical Service Contracts or
(First Signed in 1995) (First Announced in 2004) (First Signed in 2009) Potentially Production Service
Contracts (2014)
Service Contract Operating Service Contract Enhanced Technical Service Agreement
Kuwait Oil Field Service Contract (2013)
(First Signed in 1992) (First Announced in 1999) (First Signed in 2010)
Service Agreements were Converted into
Operational Service Agreements Operational Service Agreements Operational Service Agreements
Venezuela “mixed enterprise” Frameworks with
(First Round Auctioning in 1991) (Second Round Auctioning) (Third Round Auctioning in 1997)
Majority Stakes for PDVSA (2006-7)
Integrated Exploration and Production
Multiple Service Contract Incentive-Based Multiple Service Contract Incentive-Based Multiple Service Contract
Mexico Service Contract (Third Round Licensing
(First Announced in 2001) (First Announced in 2009) (Second Round Licensing in July 2012)
in July 2013)
Additional Incentives Introduced to the Additional Incentives Introduced for
Operations Contract Operations Contract
Bolivia Operations Contract Exploration Operations Contract (May
(First Announced in 2006) (First Bidding Round in 2012)
(April 2012) 2013)
Integrated Specific Service Contracts over
Service Contract Incremental Production Contract New Licensing Round on 13 Exploration
Ecuador 16 Mature Fields for Enhanced Oil
(First Announced in 2007) (First Signed in February 2012) Blocks (December 2013)
Recovery (Jan 2014)
Producing Field Technical Service
Development and Production Technical Technical Service Contract Technical Service Contract (Fourth Round
Iraq Contract
Service Contract (2009) (Third Round Auctioning in 2010) Auctioning in 2012)
(2009)
Risk Service Contract
Turkmenistan
(First Announced in 2008)
4. Service Contracts’ Major Differences

Table 3 presents five major categories in which the service contracts in Iran, Iraq, and in
Venezuela’s three auctioning rounds differ from each other: the capital cost decision interaction
between the IOC and the national oil company (NOC); the allocation of ownership rights of the
produced crude; the allocation of the developed field’s operatorship rights; remuneration; and
how risk is shared between the IOC and the NOC.

With regards to the IOC/NOC capital cost decision interaction, Iran is different from the
other two countries’ service-type contracts due to the IOCs’ limited options regarding the capital
cost ceiling once the contract is signed. That is because in most Iran’s buy back service contracts,
IOCs do not have the option to change the capital cost level after they sign the contracts, and
such limitation could increase the IOCs risk in these contracts. (Ghandi & Lin, 2014b)

For the case of Iraq, the capital cost decision interaction could be an issue since the Iraqi
government might find it too costly to achieve the production plateau target. As a result, they
may limit the IOCs’ capital expenditures. In doing that, the Iraqi government might increase the
economic inefficiency in the contracts. (Ghandi & Lin, 2014a)

In Venezuela’s third round service contract, the IOCs are entitled to a portion of the
produced crude. That is one unique feature of the Venezuela’s third round contracts, since in the
other service contracts the state-owned oil company retains ownership of the produced crude.

For the operatorship rights of the developed fields, while Iran holds the right for its own
state-owned subsidiaries, it is usually the IOCs who operate the fields under service contracts.
The operatorship could also be a source of economic inefficiency as shown by Ghandi and Lin
(2012) in Iran’s Soroosh and Nowrooz buy-back service contract.

Since IOCs usually do not share the profit oil in a service-type contract, the remuneration
is the only source of the profit for their investment. In Iran’s buy-back service contracts, the
remuneration is calculated in association to a fixed rate of return for the IOCs in the project.
However, in Iraq and Venezuela’s first two rounds service contracts, the remuneration is based
on per barrel production. In the third round, Venezuela has also experienced a sliding mechanism
for the IOCs remuneration based on the project rate of return.

Finally, not all service-type contracts are similar with regards to the IOCs’ risk exposure.
Service contracts differ in how risk is shared between the IOC and the NOC. In addition, while
capital cost overrun could be the main source of the risk for the IOC in Iran’s buy-back service
contracts (Ghandi & Lin, 2014b), it might not be the case in other types of service contracts.
Table 3: Main categories in which the service contracts in Iran, Iraq, and in Venezuela’s three rounds are different
Iran BBSC Iraq TSC Venezuela OSA (1st & 2nd) Venezuela OSA (3rd)

Capital Cost Decision Interaction No leverage for the IOC IOC/NOC IOC/NOC IOC/NOC

Produced Crude Ownership Iran Iraq Venezuela IOC/Venezuela

Oil Field Operator Iran Joint Company IOC IOC

Remuneration Fixed in accordance to the IOC Rate of Return in the Project Per Barrel Production Per Barrel Production Based on the Project Rate of Return

Who Bears the Risk IOC IOC/NOC IOC/NOC IOC/NOC


5. Venezuela’s Service Contracts

Venezuela tried an interesting and complicated service-type contractual approach


between 1991 and 1997 with three rounds of auctions of operational service agreements on 34
fields. During this same time period, Venezuela also pursued two other contractual frameworks:
joint ventures11 and risk exploration agreements.12

In the first two rounds of the operational service agreements, the IOCs’ recovery included
the initial investment plus interest (capital fee) and additional per barrel production operation fee
to cover the IOCs’ operation cost and profit without sharing the profit oil. The payments to the
IOCs were in U.S. Dollars to guard against any exchange rate risk and were adjusted to the U.S.
Energy CPI.

The third round operational service agreements were different since the IOCs were
entitled to a portion of the produced crude through a sliding mechanism based on the projects’
internal rate of return in each year and an incremental value of the production, which is the
market value of the produced crude of the same year minus that year’s capital cost, royalties and
administration fees. In fact due to the internal rate of return sliding mechanism and the allocation
of crude to the IOCs based on the market value, the third round operational service agreements
are considered close to production sharing contracts (Manzano & Monaldi, 2010). Russia’s 1994
Sakhalin II contract, which was the country’s first of three production sharing contracts with a
consortium of IOCs lead by Shell, is a good example of a contract with a rate of return sliding
mechanism. The Russian government is entitled to the 10% (50% after two years) and 70% of
the produced crude once the operator’s13 rate of return reaches 17.5% and 24% respectively
(Rutledge, 2004).

In 2006-2007, the new Venezuelan administration forced the IOCs to accept the
conversion of their operational service agreements into “mixed enterprise” frameworks with
majority stakes for the Venezuela’s state-owned oil company Petróleos de Venezuela, SA
(PDVSA). The contractual changes along with the implementation of the new windfall tax code
in 2008 were implemented in order to increase the government overall take mostly on round
three operational service agreements due to the greater size of the proven reserves and the higher

11
Four joint ventures, known as extra heavy oil association agreements, were formed between the state-
owned PDVSA, as the minority stakeholder, and four consortia of IOCs with majority of stakes, to
develop the world’s largest extra heavy crude reservoir of Orinoco Oil Belt (Manzano & Monaldi, 2010).
12
Eight areas were auctioned in 1996 through risk exploration agreements, which led to three
commercially viable discoveries without any further deals (Manzano & Monaldi, 2010).
13
Sakhalin Energy Investment Company is the contractor and operator of Sakhalin II contract. The initial
stakeholders include Marathon Oil (30%), McDermott (20%), Royal Dutch Shell (20%), Mitsui & Co.
(20%) and Mitsubishi Corporation (20%). Later, in 2000, the company structure changed to Shell (55%),
Mitsui & Co. (25%) and Mitsubishi Corporation (20%) (Rutledge, 2004). In 2007, Russia’s state-owned
Gazprom bought 50% plus one share of SEIC from Shell for $7.45 billion (RIA Novosti, 2007).
number and productivity of the fields under this type of contract (Manzano & Monaldi, 2010).14
Overall, the peak production of operational service agreements in 2006 reached 600,000 barrels
per day, which was beyond the targeted goals of the Venezuelan government.

Even though the round three operational service agreements had included an internal rate
of return-based sliding mechanism, the previous tax code, before modification in 2008, did not
have such a mechanism to adjust for the higher royalties and income taxes that the PDVSA and
IOCs had to pay as a result of the oil price hikes. The lack of such a mechanism in the tax code
was one justification behind the 2006-2007 expropriation of all contracts in Venezuela, including
the operational service agreements (Manzano & Monaldi, 2010).15 In addition to the tax code,
another reason behind the 2006-2007 expropriation of all contracts in Venezuela might also have
been the broader objectives of the Venezuelan administration, who wished to transform
autonomous institutes such as PDVSA into agents of the government, to gain more control over
the crude production (Ramón, 2010).

Overall, 25 international oil companies are in partnership with the PDVSA through the
“mixed enterprise” or mixed venture framework. These mixed enterprises produce about 800,000
conventional, heavy and extra heavy crude oil. Recently, due to Venezuela’s economic problems
including high inflation rates (56%) and shortages of construction raw materials such as steel and
cement, mixed ventures operations have faced high costs. As a result, the IOCs in the mixed
ventures have raised their objections to the current mixed enterprise business models. The IOCs
would like three significant changes in the mixed ventures. First, they prefer their capital
expenditures, in the form of direct loans, to be transferred directly to their mixed enterprises as
oppose to the PDVSA. Second, the IOCs try to reduce their tax burden. Finally, the IOCs would
like to have the mixed enterprises to be operated and managed more independently with less
interference of the PDVSA (Mogollon, 2014).

6. Kuwait’s Service Contracts

Since the early 1990s, Kuwait has pursued or shown interest in three variations of
service-type contracts. The term service contract was used for the earlier version, which includes

14
While the first two rounds covered 16 fields with 1,725 million barrels of proven oil reserves, the third
round covered 18 fields with 20,510 million barrels. Also, while the initial idea of operational service
contracts was to allocate fields that require secondary operations, the third round included less mature
fields with higher production potentials (Manzano & Monaldi, 2010).
15
Since Venezuela state-owned company signed the operational service agreements with IOCs and due to
the country’s tax code at the time, PDVSA was responsible for paying the 16.67% royalties as well as the
67% oil income tax while the IOCs (operators) were to pay only the 34% non-oil income tax in all three
rounds of the operational service agreements. This was also a major incentive for the IOCs (Manzano &
Monaldi, 2010).

13
5 contracts with BP,16 Chevron, Shell, Exxon, and Total from 1992 until 1997. At the same
time, the Kuwait Ministry of Energy and Kuwait Petroleum Company attempted another
initiative, known as Project Kuwait, in order to open Kuwait’s upstream to the IOCs even more.
However, the attempt has faced long lasting opposition by the Kuwait Supreme Petroleum
Council and the National Assembly since 1995. The opposition was based on Kuwait’s
constitutional restriction on foreign control of Kuwait’s natural resources including crude oil.

In 1999, the Kuwaiti government announced a new variation of service-type contract


known as an “operating service contract” according to which the government could restrain the
control over the ownership of the crude in accordance to constitutional provisions. The dispute
over the terms of the new service-type contract, which was part of a broader quarrel over the
jurisdictions of different branches of the government, prevented any new deals (Stevens, 2008).

In 2010, Shell signed a new version of Kuwait’s service contract, called enhanced
technical service agreement to develop a natural gas field (Business Monitor International,
2011). Other IOCs including Chevron, on Burgan field, and ExxonMobil, on Ratqa heavy oil
field, have also been in negotiations with Kuwait over enhanced technical service agreement
terms (Petroleum Intelligence Weekly, 2011).

Even though Shell’s enhanced technical service agreement was considered as a model
framework, a probe investigation conducted by Kuwait’s parliament over this deal contributed to
Kuwait’s decision to halt awarding similar contracts to other international oil companies (Energy
Compass, 2014). In addition, due to ExxonMobil opposition to enhanced technical service
agreement’s terms, negotiations over Ratqa heavy oil field were abandoned in June 2013 (Energy
Compass, 2014). In October 2013, however, KOC announced its determination to hire service
companies to fulfill the Ratqa heavy oil field first phase development plan which includes
engineering, procurement and construction for a 60,000 barrels per day target production by
2017 (Strouse, 2013).

7. Iran’s Buy-Back Service Contracts

Iran signed its first buy-back service contract on March 6, 199517 with Conoco Oil
Company18 (Alikhani, 2000), which was followed by several other service contracts. While

16
Kuwait had its first service contract with BP in 1992 (Middle East Economic Digest, 2010).
17
Conoco Oil Company backed of the deal on March 20, 1995 following President Clinton executive
order on March 15, 1995, which prohibited any “contract for the financing of the development of
petroleum resources located in Iran” (Alikhani, 2000, p. 183).
18
ConocoPhillips after the merger in 2002

14
Iran’s service contracts are all called buy-back service contracts, their frameworks represent at
least three generations of service-type contracts in the country. Shiravi & Ebrahimi (2006)
discuss the framework that is used for development projects and a more recent one for
exploration and development starting in 2004. In 2009, the National Iranian Oil Company
(NIOC) signed a buy-back service contract with the Chinese Sinopec International Petroleum
E&P Corporation in which Sinopec is allowed to make a final decision on the capital cost level
up to two years after the start of the contract (Ghandi & Lin, 2014b). This accounts for the third
type of buy-back service contracts in Iran. For more on Iran’s buy-back service contracts, see
Ghandi and Lin (2012); Ghandi and Lin (2014b); and van Groenendaal and Mazraati (2006).

Between 2005 and 2013, Iran’s production potential declined significantly from 4.2 to 2.6
million barrels per day due to the US and EU oil and financial sanctions and embargos.
However, along with recent and continuing efforts to ease the relations with the West in 2013
and 2014, Iran’s new administration is also trying to bring back the international oil companies
to the country by potentially introducing new contractual frameworks that are more attractive
than its buy back service contracts (Energy Intelligence Finance, 2013).

8. Mexico’s Multiple Service Contracts

Mexico announced the adoption of its first version of service contracts, known as
multiple service contracts, in 2001. At the time, these contracts were for non-associated natural
gas development projects only. Until then, the state-owned Petróleos Mexicanos (PEMEX) had
relied heavily on oilfield service contracts with smaller work scopes in return for fixed service
payments, as the only framework in utilizing foreign capital and expertise. However, in multiple
service contracts, PEMEX awards multiple services combined in a single long-term framework
to the international oil companies. In general, the decision to adopt the multiple service contracts
framework was taken as a way to invite foreign and private investment in the natural gas
(upstream)19 sector, while also accounting for the country’s strict constitutional exploration and
production restrictions (Soto, 2005).

The natural gas sector was chosen for three reasons. First, PEMEX’s limited financial
resources had been concentrated on keeping the country’s oil production,20 the source of 35% of
the Mexican government revenue through PEMEX tax payments (Morales, 2011). Second,

19
Since 1994, the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) has opened up Mexico’s natural gas
downstream to private and foreign investment without any constitutional changes regarding state-owned
PEMEX’s sole rights in the oil and natural gas sector (Morales, 2011).
20
PEMEX oil production peaked at 3.38 million barrels per day in 2004 (Morales, 2011).

15
PEMEX also relies on unsustainable borrowing to finance its oil upstream efforts (Soto, 2005).21
The decision to adopt the multiple service contracts was taken to relax some pressure on its oil
upstream financial concerns. Third, PEMEX faced a difficult task in meeting high domestic
natural gas demand, coming mostly from the power sector (Soto, 2005). By using multiple
service contracts in natural gas projects PEMEX would be able to increase the country’s
domestic natural gas potential. Overall, Mexico has held two bidding rounds from 2003 for non-
associated natural gas blocks (Kerr, 2009) with five multiple service contracts awarded in the
first round and two awarded in the second round (Kerr & Hunter, 2005).

In order to make the contracts more attractive especially for the regions with more
technical difficulties, including the deepwater Gulf of Mexico, and to be able to have larger IOCs
with more capabilities, the Mexican government announced a new version of incentive-based
multiple service contracts22 in 2009 (Dow Jones International News, 2009). This policy was
challenged by Mexican Congress in courts. In December 2010, the Mexican Supreme Court
ruled in favor of adopting the new incentive-based multiple service contracts, which paved the
way for a new bidding process for three fields that require secondary enhanced oil recovery
(Morales, 2011). Among 17 companies that were qualified to participate the bidding process
(Business News Americas, 2011a), PEMEX awarded three incentive-based oil exploration and
production multiple service contracts on three mature fields to two companies (Economist
Intelligence Unit - ViewsWire, 2011).23 PEMEX has also started the process of a second bidding
round on incentive-based multiple service contracts for 6 northern areas with mature fields
(Business News Americas, 2012). Sixteen companies were pre-qualified in the second round
(Kerr, 2012a) and PEMEX offered incentive-based service contracts also known as performance-
based service contracts in four out of the six blocks that were originally on offer (Kerr, 2012b).

In December 2012, PEMEX started the process of the third licensing round on the
Chicontepec Basin. For this round, 6 blocks were on offer and 16 companies were pre-qualified.
However, PEMEX only awarded service contracts on three blocks to companies with lowest per

21
In 2003, of a total of $37.1 billion in Mexican government’s borrowings, $10.9 billion were used to
finance PEMEX’s upstream operation (Soto, 2005).
22
Incentives could be considered for fulfilment of activities such as “seismic processing and
interpretation, geological modeling, fields engineering, production engineering, drilling, facility design
and construction, facility and well maintenance and natural gas transportation Services.” (Soto, 2005, p.
13). The incentive-based approach could also be used in order to persuade the private and foreign
companies to increase their operation efficiency. Private companies are also offered incentives if they
increase the reservoirs’ recovery, or if their exploration and production activities increase PEMEX’s
reserves (Morales, 2011).
23
A UK-based company and a Mexico-based company (Economist Intelligence Unit - ViewsWire, 2011)
were awarded three incentive-based service contracts. However, since the Mexico-based company could
not meet the requirements of the Carrizo field oil service contract, the contract was re-awarded to Dowell
Schlumberger de Mexico, which had offered the second-lowest bid at $9.40 per barrel oil equivalent
(Dow Jones International News, 2011).

16
barrel fee as the main bidding category. Even though the third round licensing was held under
similar 2008 energy reform proposal, the third round contracts also known as integrated
exploration and production service contracts due to the additional exploration scope (Kerr,
2013a).

In December 2013, however, the Mexican president signed in to law the Mexican
Congress approved new energy reform bill according which a newly formed government body,
the National Hydrocarbons Commission, resumes the administrative role of awarding the
contracts. In addition, the new law permits four contractual frameworks including service
contracts, production sharing contracts, profit-sharing contracts and licenses (Kerr, 2013b).

9. Bolivia’s Service Operations Contracts

Bolivia, with second largest natural gas reserves in South America,24 adopted operations
contracts as a variation of the service-type contractual framework following the 2004-2006 re-
nationalization of the country’s oil and natural gas sector. The re-nationalization of the state-
owned oil and natural gas company Yacimientos Petrolíferos Fiscales Bolivianos (YPFB) as well
as the forced conversion of all 44 contracts25 (Vargas, 2007) to a service-type contractual
framework were part of a major policy shift towards more state control over the hydrocarbon
resources in Bolivia. Until then, and starting the 1990s, Bolivia had pursued a series of policy
modifications26 with the objective of opening up the hydrocarbon sector in order to incentivize
private and foreign company investment in the country’s up- and down-stream sectors. Such
policies led to an increase in Bolivia’s natural gas production and export potential. However,
growing criticisms of the government’s revenue under the new royalty/tax regime, combined

24
Bolivia holds over 26 trillion cubic feet natural gas reserves as reported by Energy Information
Administration (EIA) (2011) from Oil & Gas Journal.
25
These 44 contracts include contracts with major IOCs such as Total, Repsol YPF, UK BG and
Petrobras (The Oil Daily, 2006).
26
In 1990, Bolivian National Congress, under the private-sector participation law, allowed 50-50 joint
ventures at wellhead prices, known as operation and association contracts, for exploration and production
with private and foreign companies. The 1990 law also opened the country’s natural gas transmission and
downstream to private sector. A few years later by mid 1990s and following the recommendations of
international financial organizations, the Bolivian government announced another major policy
modifications, including a new hydrocarbon law, of privatizing the state-owned YPFB; creation of a
regulatory agency and stripping the YPFB from its regulatory roles; implementing a new royalty/tax code
with clear royalty distinction of 18% for new and 50% for old fields and at the same time increasing the
government take through direct income tax and allowing private and foreign companies to trade and
market the produced hydrocarbons (Navajas, 2010).

17
with the economic slowdown since 1999 led to a series of events known as re-nationalization
that also included the adoption of service-type contracts since 2004 (Navajas, 2010).27

Under the new operations contracts in place since 2006, the YPFB has to pay to the
government three types of royalties (amounting to 18% of production value) plus direct tax (32%
of the production value) from the production gross revenue. The remaining amount minus the
operating cost is the shared profit between the YPFB and the contractor, which is divided based
on the production volume. This means that contractors are still entitled to a portion of the
production without produced hydrocarbon ownership transfer.28 However, under the new sliding
mechanism the government’s take is adjusted with the market value of the produced
hydrocarbons in such a way that the sum of royalty and tax accounts at least for 50% of the value
of the produced hydrocarbon (Vargas, 2007).

Based on the 2006 operations contractual framework, Bolivia had its first bidding round
in 2012. In April 2012, the Bolivian President issued a decree to incentivize the operations
contract by letting the operators to earn USD 30 per produced barrel oil equivalent fiscal credit
note in addition to the USD 10 per barrel oil equivalent cash as outlined in the contracts. In May
2013, it was announced that the government is taking additional steps in incentivizing the
exploration activities by having more flexible contractual terms based on the type of explored
fields, sizes of reserves discoveries and also by arranging faster capital cost recovery for the
contractor (Kerr, 2013d).

10. Ecuador’s Service Contracts

Ecuador is the other South American country with a recent move from production sharing
contracts towards service-type contracts (M2 Presswire, 2012). The move towards service-type
contracts is part of a broader policy shift by the Ecuadorian government towards more state
control over the oil sector. The other elements of such policy shift are the 90% windfall tax29 on
IOCs and the joint venture cooperation framework proposal between Ecuador’s state-owned oil

27
Four most important such events include the 2004 referendum on the 50% royalty and the status of the
YPFB, the 2005 National Congress new law on additional 32% royalty and new rent distribution
mechanism to entities such as universities and the army, which was followed by a Supreme Court ruling
in favour of the re-nationalization and finally the 2006 presidential order to transform the joint ventures to
service-type contracts (Navajas, 2010).
28
As a result, operations contracts are also considered hybrid contracts between production sharing and
service contracts (The Oil Daily, 2006). However, under operations contracts as reported for Repsol YPF
(The Oil Daily, 2006), the contractors cannot book the proven reserves.
29
Ecuadorian government also used the windfall tax as a means of pressure to persuade the IOCs to
accept the new oil service contracts (Business News Americas, 2011b).

18
company, PETROECUADOR, and other countries’ state-owned oil companies30 for new oil
exploration and production (APS Review Gas Market Trends, 2011). The process of persuading
the IOCs to accept the transformation of their contracts to service contracts started in 2007
(Business News Americas, 2011b), and by 2010, eight service contracts were signed (Kerr,
2010).
In these new service contractual frameworks, the IOCs’ cost recovery is based on agreed-
upon flat fee (Business News Americas, 2011b), and the government takes are 85%-90% of the
oil fields’ revenue31 (Petroleum Intelligence Weekly, 2010). In February 2012, a joint venture
of four companies, including Schlumberger Ltd. and Canadian Canacol Energy Ltd.,32 signed an
incremental production contract, as a new variation of service contract, on two mature fields in
northern Ecuador. The main scope of the contract is to increase the production of the two fields
in return for U.S. $39.5633 per each additional barrel of produced crude. The contractors could
also enjoy other benefits including a 50%-50% split of the gain from operation cost34 reduction
besides the per barrel reimbursement (Canada Stockwatch, 2012).

In December 2012, the Ecuador administration started licensing process of 16 exploration


blocks under the general service contractual framework introduced in 2010 (Kerr, 2012c).
Among the 16 blocks, foreign companies could bid on 13 blocks and three blocks were reserved
for the state-owned oil company, Petroamazonas EP.35 By December 2013, foreign
companies/entities bid on three of the thirteen blocks. The Petroamazonas-backed consortium of
several national oil companies also bid on one of the three reserved blocks, which brought the
total bid offers to four out of sixteen offered blocks (Kerr, 2013c). In addition, Petroamazonas
EP is in the process of offering integrated specific service contracts on 16 mature fields with
enhanced oil recovery requirements. These new contracts will be aligned with earlier service
contracts that Petroecuador had signed in 2012 (Kerr, 2014).

30
These state-owned companies include Venezuela’s PDVSA, Chile’s ENAP and Indonesian
PERTAMINA. However, Brazil’s PETROBARS was not willing to accept new higher taxes on its
operation on Block 31, or to convert its production sharing contract on Block 18 to a service contract.
Also the company did not accept the joint venture proposal (APS Review Gas Market Trends, 2011).
31
This seems to be the overall government take. In the case of the Repsol YPF service contracts on Block
16 and 36, the government’s share of profit is 70% with 36% direct crude oil allocation up from 17% and
18% from each block respectively through the production sharing frameworks (APS Review Gas Market
Trends, 2011).
32
Canadian Canacol Energy Ltd. has a similar producing field service-type contract on Rancho Hermoso
field in Columbia. Canacol Energy Ltd., as the operator of the field, receives U.S. $17.56 per barrel
production fixed fee in addition to transportation cost, and the produced crude is delivered to
ECOPETROL S.A. (Canacol Energy Ltd., 2012). ECOPETROL S.A. is the principal petroleum company
in Columbia owned by 40 large international oil companies (ECOPETROL, 2012).
33
This is pretty high compared to other countries’ service contracts.
34
PETROECUADOR should cover the operation cost in this contract (Canada Stockwatch, 2012).
35
Petroamazonas is the largest state-owned oil company after it absorbed Petroecuador's upstream assets in
November 2012 (Kerr, 2014)

19
11. Turkmenistan’s Service Contracts

Turkmenistan is another country showing recent interest in service-type contracts. Based


on the country’s 2008 hydrocarbon law, the government has four contractual options:
concessions, production sharing contracts, oilfield service contracts, and service contracts.
However, for its offshore natural gas fields, the Turkmen government has relied upon production
sharing contracts and oilfield service contracts36 as the two preferred methods of cooperation
with foreign companies (International Comparative Legal Guide Series). For the onshore natural
gas fields, the government has shown indications of preferring the risk service contract as a
variation of service-type contract37 with adequate rewards for the risks taken by the IOCs
(International Energy Agancy (IEA), 2010). However, no such contracts have been signed due to
the IOCs’ dissatisfactions with the terms of Turkmenistan risk service contractual framework
(Roberts, At the Wellhead, 2010).

The prospects of any service contracts on Turkmenistan’s onshore gas fields are far from
certain. International oil companies such as ExxonMobil and Chevron still show interest in
participating in developing the giant Galkynysh gas field. However, they seem to disagree at
least on two major areas with the Turkmen government. First, the IOCs insist on taking
“upstream stakes” over the gas fields that supply gas to the planned Turkmenistan-Afghanistan-
Pakistan-India (TAPI) gas export pipeline. Second, they seek a “leadership role, including
assistance in helping to construct and arrange finance the TAPI pipeline.” On the other hand, the
Turkmen government still insists in having the service contract as the framework for the IOCs
cooperation, which contradicts with the IOCs request in having “upstream stake”. In addition and
still as part of the Turkmen government’s determination to keep its control over the extracted
resources, the government wants to have the state-owned Turkmen Gas as the sole entity
marketing the produced gas in international markets. In addition, the Turkmen government
prefers to deliver the gas at the Turkmenistan boarder which means that the government does not
will to participate in details of export pipelines issues outside its borders. The departure of Statoil
from Turkmenistan by closing its office in the capital, Ashgabat, is also a sign that the there is no
immediate prospects for the above mentioned service contracts in Turkmenistan in near future
(Roberts, 2013).

36
Turkmen government has used direct foreign loans to finance hiring service companies for its offshore oilfield
service contracts (Roberts, At the Wellhead, 2010). Turkmenistan has acquired a 9.7 billion U.S. Dollars loan in
2009 and a 4.1 billion U.S. Dollars loan in 2011 for offshore Galkynysh natural gas field, formerly known as
Yoloten. China’s CNPC has been involved in both projects (Trend News Agency (Azerbaijan), 2011).
37
China’s CNPC is the only international company with an onshore production sharing contract in
Turkmenistan (Gurt, 2012).

20
12. Iraq’s Service Contracts

Iraq has also adopted variations of service-type contracts, all known as technical service
contracts, in its massive plan to boost oil production to 12 million barrels per day by 2017. 38
Table 4 includes a summary of the four rounds of auctioning. Iraq uses three different versions
of technical service contracts: producing field technical service contracts; production and
development technical service contracts; and a service-type framework for exploration in the
fourth round (Ghandi & Lin, 2014a). Producing field technical service contracts have been
awarded on the fields with production prior to the start of the contracts. This baseline production
has been used for the cost recovery of the development in these fields. In production and
development technical service contracts, a different mechanism is used for the cost recovery
since these contracts have been awarded on the fields with no production before the start of the
contracts. For more on Iraq’s technical service contracts, see Ghandi and Lin (2014a) and
Sankey, Clark and Micheloto (2010).

Table 4: Iraq's Four Rounds of Auctioning since 2009 (Ghandi & Lin, 2014a)
# Pre-
Round qualified Important Dates Bid Projects’ Scope Outcome
bidders
One contract was awarded (Rumaila).
To develop 6 oil and 2 non-
1 35 [1] June 30, 2009 results announced. [1] Three other oil contracts were signed later.
associated natural gas fields [1]
[1]
Seven contracts were awarded.
December 12, 2009 results
2 9 [1] To develop 10 oil fields [1] Three contracts did not have any bidders.
announced. [1]
[1]
To develop 3 non-associated
October 20, 2010 results announced. Three fields were awarded to two
3 13 [4] natural gas fields including two
[4] international consortia [4]
from the first round
Promotional Conference: August 2011 [2]
To explore 12 oil and natural gas
4 46 [3] Final Tender: November 2011 [2] Not yet determined
Bidding Event: May 2012 [5] blocks [2]
Sources
[1] Sankey, Clark, & Micheloto (2010)
[2] The Petroleum Services Group (PSG) at Deloitte (2011)
[3] Reuters (2012)
[4] Hassan Hafidh (2010)
[5] Hassan Hafidh (2012)

38
In 2013, the Iraqi government negotiated new plateau production targets on its awarded contract to 9 million
barrels per day (combined) by 2017 (Kent, 2013).

21
13. Conclusion

In this paper, we show that in at least eight major oil producing countries, there have been
efforts and interest in adopting service-type contracts an alternative to the production sharing
framework. Among the five main reasons for adopting service contracts are field ownership
rights, produced crude ownership rights, field’s operatorship, international oil companies’
compensation mechanism, and risk aversion of the state-owned oil companies. It seems that
adopting the service contract could best be partially explained by the sovereignty concerns over
natural resources (field and produced cruder ownership rights) in these countries. While the
service-type contract could be an interesting framework with respect to the sovereignty concerns,
the framework can also lead to economically inefficient outcomes. To avoid such outcomes,
countries with an interest in service contracts should also consider having their state-owned oil
companies follow dynamic profit maximization objectives. However, even without adopting
dynamic profit maximization objectives, it is possible to improve the outcomes under a service
contract, as Ghandi and Lin (2012) and Ghandi and Lin (2014a) show for Iran and Iraq,
respectively.

In reviewing the service contract energy strategy, this paper also examines the current
contractual situation in each of eight oil or natural gas producing countries. Our review suggests
that the new interest in service contracts might be explained partially by heightened sovereignty
concerns and the political environment on one hand, and the need for international oil
companies’ capital and know-how in developing oil and natural gas fields in the host countries
on the other. However, even though service contracts may address sovereignty concerns, the
outcomes of these contracts may not be economically efficient.

14. References

Alikhani, H. (2000). Sanctioning Iran: anatomy of a failed policy. London: I.B. Tauris.

APS Review Gas Market Trends. (2011, February 28). Ecuador - Upstream E&P Changes,
Resource Nationalism & Investment Plan. Retrieved April 4, 2012, from Factiva.

Business Monitor International. (2011, August 26). Shell Gas Contract Objections Point To
Troubles For Project Kuwai. Retrieved March 19, 2012, from
http://store.businessmonitor.com/article/510755

Business News Americas. (2011b, April 7). New contract terms to normalize investment -
Moody's VP. Retrieved April 4, 2012, from Factiva.
22
Business News Americas. (2011a, July 31). Pemex prequalifies 17 for incentive-based contracts,
reports refinery fire. Retrieved April 2, 2012, from Factiva.

Business News Americas. (2012, January 19). Pemex watch: Incentive-based contract tender,
US$2.1bn bonds, Ku-S inspection. Retrieved April 2, 2012, from Factiva.

Canacol Energy Ltd. (2012). Operations: Columbia: Rancho Hermoso and Entrerrios. Retrieved
April 4, 2012, from http://www.canacolenergy.com/operations/colombia/rancho-hermoso-
entrerrios.html

Canada Stockwatch. (2012, February 1). CNE Canacol enters 15-year JV production deal in
Ecuador. Retrieved April 4, 2012, from Factiva.

Dow Jones International News. (2011, October 19). Mexico's Pemex Awards Incentive-Based
Contract To Schlumberger . Retrieved April 2, 2012, from Factiva.

Dow Jones International News. (2009, June 12). Update: Mexico To Offer 3 Gas Blocks In July
Bidding Round. Retrieved March 29, 2012, from Factiva.

Economist Intelligence Unit - ViewsWire. (2011, September 6). Mexico industry: First private
oil contracts announced. Retrieved April 2, 2012, from Factiva.

ECOPETROL. (2012). Retrieved April 4, 2012, from


http://www.ecopetrol.com.co/english/contenido.aspx?catID=169&conID=36898

Energy Compass. (2013, June 14). KUWAIT. Retrieved March 11, 2014, from Energy Compass.
Energy Intelligence Group Through Factiva.

Energy Compass. (2014, January 24). Kuwait: Test Time Coming for New Islamist Oil Minister.
Retrieved March 11, 2014, from Energy Compass. Energy Intelligence Group Through Factiva.

Energy Information Administration (EIA). (2011, April). Bolivia Country Analysis Briefs.
Retrieved April 2, 2012, from http://www.eia.gov/cabs/Bolivia/Full.html

Energy Intelligence Finance. (2013, December 11). Iran Woos Majors With Huge Fields, But
Sanctions May Be Here to Stay. Retrieved March 10, 2014, from Energy Intelligence Finance
Through Factiva.

Ghandi, A., & Lin, C.-Y.C. (2012). Do Iran’s buy-back service contracts lead to optimal
production? The case of Soroosh and Nowrooz. Energy Policy , 42, 181-190.

Ghandi, A., & Lin, C.-Y.C. (2014a). Economic Efficiency and Optimal Contractual Design of
Iraq's Technical Service Contracts. Working Paper, University of California at Davis .

23
Ghandi, A., & Lin, C.-Y.C. (2014b). On the Rate of Return and Risk Factors to International Oil
Companies in Iran's Buy-Back Service Contracts. Working Paper. University of California at
Davis.

Gurt, M. (2012, February 24). Turkmen leader reappoints energy heads. Retrieved April 5, 2012,
from Reuters: http://mobile.reuters.com/article/Deals/idUSL5E8DO0HY20120224

Hafidh, H. (2010, October 20). Iraq Lauds Licensing Auction After Awarding Three Fields.
Retrieved April 6, 2012, from The Wall Street Journal Online through Factiva.

Hafidh, H. (2012, January 30). UPDATE: Iraq Delays Energy Bidding Round To May 30-31.
Retrieved April 6, 2012, from Dow Jones News Service through Factiva.

International Comparative Legal Guide Series. (n.d.). Turkmenistan. Retrieved April 4, 2012,
from Gas Regulation:
http://www.iclg.co.uk/index.php?area=4&country_results=1&kh_publications_id=228&chapters
_id=5119

International Energy Agancy (IEA). (2010). World Energy Outlook 2010. Organization for
Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Paris, France.

Kent, S. (2013, December 3). Iraq Nears Deal on Oil Output Targets. Retrieved March 10, 2014,
from Dow Jones Institutional News Through Factiva.

Kerr, J. (2013d, May 31). Bolivia plans to issue decree offering new incentives to oil and gas
companies. Retrieved March 12, 2014, from IHS Global Insight Daily Analysis Through Factiva.

Kerr, J. (2012c, November 29). Ecuador launches new licensing round. Retrieved March 11,
2014, from IHS Global Insight Daily Analysis Through Factiva.

Kerr, J. (2013c, December 2). Ecuador receives offers for four blocks in licensing round.
Retrieved March 11, 2014, from IHS Global Insight Daily Analysis Through Factiva.

Kerr, J. (2010, December 3). Ecuador's Oil Minister Sees Higher Output Following Signing of
New Contracts. Retrieved April 4, 2012, from IHS Global Insight Daily Analysis through
Factiva.

Kerr, J. (2013a, July 15). Licensing round for Mexico's Chicontepec blocks disappoints.
Retrieved March 10, 2014, from IHS Global Insight Daily Analysis Through Factiva.

Kerr, J. (2013b, December 24). Mexican president signs energy reform and widens opportunities
for foreign operators. Retrieved March 10, 2014, from IHS Global Insight Daily Analysis
Through Factiva.

24
Kerr, J. (2012b, June 20). PEMEX Awards Blocks in Licensing Round. Retrieved March 10,
2014, from IHS Global Insight Daily Analysis Through Factiva.

Kerr, J. (2009, June 15). PEMEX to Tender New Gas Blocks. Retrieved March 29, 2012, from
IHS Global Insight Daily Analysis through Factiva.

Kerr, J. (2012a, June 11). Sixteen Companies Qualify to Bid in Mexican Licensing Round.
Retrieved March 10, 2014, from IHS Global Insight Daily Analysis Through Factiva.

Kerr, J. (2014, January 29). Ten companies submit bids for application of enhanced recovery
techniques at fields operated by Ecuadorean state oil company. Retrieved March 11, 2014, from
IHS Global Insight Daily Analysis Through Factiva.

Kerr, J., & Hunter, C. (2005, February 18). Pemex Accepts Monclova Gas Bid. Retrieved March
29, 2012, from World Markets Research Center Limited through Factiva.

M2 Presswire. (2012, February 10). Research and Markets: Ecuador Oil and Gas Report Q1
2012. Retrieved April 4, 2012, from Factiva.

Machmud, T. N. (2000). The Indonesian production sharing contract: an investor's perspective.


Hague, Netherlands: Kluwer Law International.

Manzano, O., & Monaldi, F. (2010). The Political Economy of Oil Contract Renegotiation in
Venezuela. In W. Hogan, & F. Sturzenegger, The natural resources trap: private investment
without public commitment. Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press.

Middle East Economic Digest. (2010, March 15). Technical Service Agreements. Retrieved
March 18, 2012, from Factiva.

Mogollon, M. (2014, February 20). Venezuelan economic crisis hurting PDVSA mixed venture
partners: execs. Retrieved March 12, 2014, from Platts Commodity News Through Factiva.

Morales, I. (2011). The Future of Oil in Mexico. Energy Trade and Security Issues at the
Mexico-U.S. Border. James A. Baker III Institute for Public Policy. Rice University.

Navajas, F. H. (2010). Hydrocarbon Policy, Shocks, and the Collective Imagination: What Went
Wrong in Bolivia? In W. Hogan, & F. Sturzenegger, The natural resources trap: private
investment without public commitment. Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press.

Petroleum Intelligence Weekly. (2010, November 29). ECUADOR. Retrieved April 4, 2012,
from Energy Intelligence Group through Factiva.

Petroleum Intelligence Weekly. (2011, September 12). Kuwait's inability to nail IOC deals laid
bare. Retrieved March 15, 2012, from Factiva.

25
Ramón, E. (2010). Commentary: Not Just a Distributional Matter. In W. Hogan, & F.
Sturzenegger, The natural resources trap: private investment without public commitment.
Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press.

Reuters. (2012, January 4). UPDATE 1-Iraq delays 4th energy auction to Apr 11-12-official.
Retrieved January 25, 2012, from UPDATE 1-Iraq delays 4th energy auction to Apr 11-12-
official: http://www.reuters.com/article/2012/01/04/iraq-energy-auction-
idUSL6E8C418720120104

RIA Novosti. (2007, April 12). Sakhalin II PSA terms infringe on Russia's interests - senato.
Retrieved March 28, 2012, from Factiva.

Roberts, J. (2010, April 26). At the Wellhead. Retrieved April 5, 2012, from Platts Oilgram
News through Factiva.

Roberts, J. (2013, March 27). Statoil set to withdraw from Turkmenistan upstream. Retrieved
March 12, 2014, from Platts Oilgram News. The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc.Through Factiva.

Rutledge, I. (2004). The Sakhalin II PSA – a Production ‘Non-Sharing’ Agreement. Analysis of


Revenue Distribution. Sheff ield Energy & Resources Information Services (SERIS).

Sankey, P., Clark, D. T., & Micheloto, S. (2010). The Mother of All Oil Stories. Deutsche Bank,
Global Market Research.

Shiravi, A., & Ebrahimi, S. N. (2006). Exploration and development of Iran's oilfields through
buyback. Natural Resources Forum , 30 (3), 199-206.

Soto, J. (2005). Multiple Service Contracts: The Beginning of the End for Mexico’s National
Petroleum Policy? Centre for Energy, Petroleum and Mineral Law and Policy. University of
Dundee.

Stevens, P. (2008). Kuwait Petroleum Corporation: Searching for Strategy in a Fragmented Oil
Sector. Program on Energy and Sustainable Development (PESD), Stanford University.

Strouse, T. (2013, October 29). Kuwait Set to Award Billions in New Upstream Contracts.
Retrieved March 12, 2014, from Energy Intelligence Group Inc. International Oil Daily Through
Factiva.

Sund, K., & Hausken, K. (2012). Fixed price contract versus incentive based contract in the oil
and gas industry. International Journal of Global Energy Issues (35 (5)), 371-410.

The Oil Daily. (2006, October 31). Bolivia, Private Firms Strike Contract Deals. Retrieved
March 31, 2012, from Energy Intelligence Group through Factiva.

26
The Petroleum Services Group (PSG) at Deloitte. (2011). Launch of the 4th Licensing Round in
Iraq 2011. Retrieved January 25, 2012, from Launch of the 4th Licensing Round in Iraq 2011:
http://www.psg.deloitte.com/NewsLicensingRounds_IQ_110610.asp

Trend News Agency (Azerbaijan). (2011, April 27). Media outlets: Turkmenistan accelerates
developing major gas field. Retrieved April 5, 2012, from Factiva.

van Groenendaal, W. J., & Mazraati, M. (2006). A critical review of Iran's buyback contracts.
Energy Policy , Volume 34, Issue 18, 3709-3718.

Vargas, M. V. (2007). Bolivia's New Contract Terms: Operating Under the Nationalization
Regime. Oil, Gas & Energy Law Intelligence .

27

You might also like