Nothing Special   »   [go: up one dir, main page]

Next Article in Journal
Applying a Modified Technology Acceptance Model to Explore Individuals’ Willingness to Use Mobility as a Service (MaaS): A Case Study of Beijing, China
Previous Article in Journal
Development of a Blockchain-Based Food Safety System for Shared Kitchens
You seem to have javascript disabled. Please note that many of the page functionalities won't work as expected without javascript enabled.
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Growth and Stagnation of US Life Expectancy: A Dynamic Simulation Model and Implications

by
Jack Homer
Homer Consulting and MIT Research Affiliate, Barrytown, NY 12507, USA
Systems 2024, 12(12), 510; https://doi.org/10.3390/systems12120510
Submission received: 21 October 2024 / Revised: 6 November 2024 / Accepted: 19 November 2024 / Published: 21 November 2024
Figure 1
<p>Causal-loop diagram overview of the US LEB simulation model. Source: Author’s diagram. Notes: Blue arrow denotes same-polarity causal link; red arrow with minus sign denotes inverse-polarity causal link. “Railroad track” crossing of links (from obesity and smoking to LEB) denotes a delayed effect. Small blue circular arrow (obesity, smoking) denotes a self-reinforcing effect of social influence. Blue text denotes an exogenous variable, determined by input time series. Rectangle indicates an aging chain structure with embedded stocks and flows. The full population aging chain includes stocks for 0–24, 25–64, and 65-plus age groups. The aging chains of high school and college graduates include stocks for 25–64 and 65-plus age groups. Most high schoolers graduate by age 18, and college students by age 25, but the model also depicts significant flows of people completing their education at a later time. All variables in this diagram are supported by historical data (see <a href="#systems-12-00510-t001" class="html-table">Table 1</a>); COVID-19 effect on LEB is inferred from the downward spike of LEB reported by UNDP for 2020–2021 and CDC for 2020–2023.</p> ">
Figure 2
<p>Base run comparison to historical data for seven output variables. Source: Author’s model testing and data described in <a href="#systems-12-00510-t001" class="html-table">Table 1</a>. Notes: See <a href="#systems-12-00510-t001" class="html-table">Table 1</a> for variable definitions and data sources. Thick blue and green lines are from base run simulation. Thin red and black lines are historical data. Simulated LEB reflects assumed COVID-19 effect 2020–2024. Simulated social trust includes exogenous resurgence 1996–2005. (<b>a</b>) Life expectancy at birth (LEB, 65–85), (red = UNDP, black = CDC). (<b>b</b>) Wages fraction of GDP (blue/red, 0–0.6); obesity (green/black, 0–0.6). (<b>c</b>) College grads (blue/red, 0–0.6); smoking (green/black, 0–0.6). (<b>d</b>) Social trust (blue/red, 0–1); suicide death rate (green/black, 0–20).</p> ">
Figure 3
<p>Health care and social spending inputs for base run and counterfactual tests. SOURCE: Author’s model testing. NOTES: In the left-side graph, the blue line is from NHE through 2021 (=0.152), then assumed flat to 2040. The red line is for counterfactual tests CF1 and CF3; the health care spending fraction remains flat at 0.113 after 2000. In the right-side graph, the blue line is from OECD through 2021 (=0.227), assumed to ramp down to 0.20 by 2024, then flat to 2040. The green line is for counterfactual tests CF2 and CF3; the social spending fraction steps up to 0.24 after 2000 and remains there to 2040. (<b>a</b>) Personal health care spending fraction of GDP (0–0.2). (<b>b</b>) Government social spending fraction of GDP (0–0.3).</p> ">
Figure 4
<p>Outputs from base run and three counterfactual tests. Source: Author’s model testing. Notes: In the top-left graph for social trust and in the lower-left graph for obese fraction, the blue line is from the base run and CF2, and the red line is from CF1 and CF3. In the top-right graph for college graduate fraction, the blue line is from the base run and CF1, and the green line is from CF2 and CF3. In the lower-right graph for LEB, the blue line is the base run, red is CF1, green is CF2, and black is CF3.</p> ">
Figure 4 Cont.
<p>Outputs from base run and three counterfactual tests. Source: Author’s model testing. Notes: In the top-left graph for social trust and in the lower-left graph for obese fraction, the blue line is from the base run and CF2, and the red line is from CF1 and CF3. In the top-right graph for college graduate fraction, the blue line is from the base run and CF1, and the green line is from CF2 and CF3. In the lower-right graph for LEB, the blue line is the base run, red is CF1, green is CF2, and black is CF3.</p> ">
Versions Notes

Abstract

:
US life expectancy now lags significantly behind the majority of high-income countries, having grown more slowly since 1980 for reasons that are not evident and have been debated. An exploratory system dynamics model is presented that reproduces the full pattern of US life expectancy from 1960 to the present. Multiple socioeconomic and behavioral factors help to explain the historical pattern, two of them apparently most responsible for the stagnation since 1980: the growth of obesity and the leveling off of growth in social spending. Some of the factors in the model are traced back to earlier causes, and obesity’s growth in particular is traced back to excess growth in private health care spending and its adverse effect on workers’ wages. The model’s base run does a good job of reproducing a variety of historical time series data going back to the 1960s, and counterfactual tests produce plausible results and clarify the model’s main themes. The model may thus be considered a reasonable starting point for more conclusive future modeling of US life expectancy.

1. Introduction

Life expectancy at birth (LEB) in the United States grew robustly from 1960 to 1980, in parallel with other high-income countries; but that growth slowed after 1980, and US LEB was essentially flat after 2010, even before the advent of COVID-19. By 2022, it was 77.5 years, far below the 83-plus years of eight other countries in the Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD, led by Japan at 84.5 years) and 3 years below the OECD average [1].
Many factors have been posited for the stagnation of US LEB or the gap between the US and other high-income countries. Some studies have focused on specific causes of premature death (such as diabetes, heart disease, drug overdoses, suicides, and vehicle crashes) [2,3,4,5,6,7], while others have looked at economic and social determinants and the roles of health and social spending [8,9,10,11,12,13,14,15] (Section S1 in Supplementary Materials summarizes the findings of these studies).
A recent multivariate statistical analysis found several factors in addition to Gross Domestic Product per capita (GDPPC)—obesity, education, social spending, alcohol consumption, and opioid prescriptions—that together accounted for a large portion of the LEB differentials among 34 OECD countries. But these factors explained only half of the US underperformance relative to what would be expected based on GDPPC alone [16].
Thus, it makes sense to focus on the US as a unique case. This paper uses system dynamics simulation to explore a particular social theory in the light of available evidence over a 60-year period and what it may imply for policy. Such dynamic modeling has been used for decades to study many health and social issues [17,18,19,20,21,22], but not the long-term dynamics of US LEB.
What makes the US uniquely vulnerable? Two frequently mentioned possibilities are its highest-in-the-world rates of obesity [23] and health care spending [15,24]. Higher health care spending correlates with better outcomes in other OECD countries but does not do so in the US [13,15]. The US is the one country where most of the working population is covered by private health insurance plans rather than by the government. With the growth in health care spending, these plans have become increasingly expensive since the 1980s, driving down take-home pay for many workers or exposing them to the possibility of medical bankruptcy [25].
But why would stagnant wages for some workers have society-wide effects, when many other Americans have experienced income growth? Indeed, GDPPC, a primary driver of LEB [10,26], has grown robustly in the US for many decades. The argument must be about the corrosive effects of unequal income; about what happens when some workers see their take-home pay stagnating while others are doing much better. Putnam and Garrett document in detail the adverse social, cultural, and political consequences that have accompanied increasing income inequality in the US since the 1970s. These include a decline in social solidarity, social trust, and labor unions, and an increase in corporate power and deaths of despair [27]. Income inequality may also have laid the groundwork for the obesity epidemic [23].
On the surface, then, a plausible case can be made for the idea that growing private health care costs have been the primary culprit behind the stagnation of US LEB. This paper seeks to determine whether this social theory (along with other important factors like education and social spending) can reproduce the historical evidence when it is put in the testable form of a simulation model. Also, counterfactual tests of the model are performed to reveal the relative significance of key causal factors.

2. Materials and Methods

2.1. Data

The modeling process started with a review of the relevant literature and of well-established, long-standing data sources that predate the 1980s and have continued to the present. The prior statistical analysis of OECD LEB differentials [16] also helped in identifying candidate variables.
Candidates were then screened by means of correlation and regression analysis, as well as by simulation, to determine whether they could help explain the US LEB pattern from 1960 to 2021. A number of candidates were dismissed at this point. Poverty and disability, for example, both had declining and fluctuating patterns after 1980 that could not help explain the stagnation of US LEB [28,29,30].
Additionally, annual death rates by 5-year age group and major cause (non-communicable disease, communicable and other disease, and injury) [31] were examined closely and tested with an algebraic LEB calculator to see whether certain age-specific trends, such as a growing rate of deaths from injury among the elderly since 1990 [32], might have had a significant adverse effect on life expectancy. No such significant effect was found (See Section S3 in Supplementary Materials).
Table 1 is a list of the variables that survived the screening process. In all cases, the data were reported from 1960 (or the early 1960s) through the 2020s or late 2010s; in most cases, the frequency of reporting was annual or biannual (Section S2 in Supplementary Materials provides a full table of time series data values, including UNDP medium-variant population projections through 2040.)

2.2. Causal-Loop Diagram (Model Overview)

Figure 1 presents a causal-loop diagram overview of the resulting system dynamics model. The diagram shows eight factors directly affecting LEB, as follows:
(1)
GDP per capita (GDPPC): GDPPC was the most important differentiating factor in the OECD LEB analysis [16]. It is modeled here as the accumulation of an exogenous growth rate that gives the correct GDPPC trajectory through 2021 and is assumed to continue after that at 1% per year, the approximate historical average.
(2)
Obese fraction of age 18-plus: Obesity was a second differentiator in the OECD LEB analysis [16]. It is modeled here as a stock variable driven upward by declines in the wage/salary fraction of GDP (as an indicator of income inequality), as well as by self-reinforcing social influence. The effect of obesity on LEB is modeled in part with a lengthy delay, reflecting the gradual progression of chronic diseases related to obesity.
(3)
College graduate fraction of age 25-plus: College education was a third differentiator in the OECD LEB analysis [16]. It is modeled here with population aging chains including births, net immigration, and deaths, and age groups 0–24, 25–64, and 65-plus. This structure was tuned to produce correct trajectories for total population by age group, high school graduates, and college graduates. The model includes inflows of adults obtaining high school and college degrees after age 25; these inflows are necessary to produce a good fit to the 25-plus data. The high school graduation rate by age 18 is modeled exogenously, rising from 70% in 1960 to 88% by 2020. The college graduation rate by age 25 is modeled algebraically, starting with high school graduates and adding a strong positive influence from government social spending, causing this graduation rate to rise from 10% in 1960 to 37% in 2010–2017.
(4)
Government social spending fraction of GDP: Social spending was a fourth differentiator in the OECD LEB analysis [16]. It is modeled here exogenously using the data series described in Table 1 (source: OECD) and is a potentially key policy input.
(5)
Current smoker fraction of age 18-plus: Smoking did not emerge from the OECD LEB analysis as a differentiating factor, likely due to confounding cross-effects [16]. Nonetheless, smoking is undeniably a major mortality risk affecting LEB [2,4,33,34]. It is modeled as a stock variable driven downward by the increasing college graduate fraction as well as by self-reinforcing social influence. The effect of smoking on LEB is modeled in part with a lengthy delay, reflecting the gradual progression of chronic diseases related to smoking.
(6)
Suicide rate: This variable was not available across countries for the OECD LEB analysis, but it has been described as a key factor affecting US LEB, having grown significantly since its lowest point in 2000 [4,5,6]. It is modeled algebraically, tending to fall with increases in the high school graduate fraction of adults and increases in social spending and tending to rise with declines in social trust. (See Putnam/Garrett on deaths of despair, p. 43 [27]).
(7)
Personal health care spending fraction of GDP: This variable did not emerge from the OECD LEB analysis as a differentiating factor, and the evidence is mixed for a positive net effect of additional health care spending on US LEB [14,15]. Nonetheless, quality health care undeniably saves many lives and is often resource-intensive, so a small positive influence of health care spending on LEB is assumed in the model. But the model also includes the adverse effect that growing health care spending has had on take-home pay in the US, as described above. This variable is modeled exogenously using the data series described in Table 1 (source: National Health Expenditures database) and can be altered in counterfactual testing.
(8)
COVID-19: The model uses a default input time series to represent the spike downward in US LEB that is evident in the data from both UNDP (2020–2021) and CDC (2020–2023); see Table 1. Recovery of LEB from the multiple adverse health system effects of COVID is assumed to be complete by the end of 2024. The model also includes a link from social trust to the magnitude of the COVID effect on LEB (for counterfactual testing), in line with research suggesting that greater social trust can improve the public health response [35].
Social trust was mentioned above in connection with its effects on suicide and the impact of COVID. Social trust declined from about 60% in the early 1960s to 37% in the early 1990s, then temporarily recovered during the late 1990s and early 2000s to a peak of 46%, then declined further to 33% by 2014. It is modeled here in line with the analysis of Putnam/Garrett, which describes a syndrome of reduced social, political, and economic solidarity since the 1960s [27]. The dynamic hypothesis here is that growing income inequality (operationalized as a decline in wages and salaries as a fraction of GDP) led to reduced social solidarity (and the related concept of social trust), which, in turn, undermined union membership, which further exacerbated the relative decline in wages/salaries.
The entry point for this vicious cycle in the model is the growth of private health care spending, which, as noted above, has been a major reason for stagnating take-home pay for wage workers. In the model, monotonic growth in health care spending from 1960 to 2020 leads to monotonic adverse trajectories for the wage/salary fraction, social solidarity, and unionization.
An inverted-U-shaped exogenous time series is introduced during 1996–2005 to recreate the temporary resurgence of social trust seen during those years; that temporary resurgence has been noted by others but not explained [36]. It is the only difference between social solidarity and social trust in the model, and it is included because it may help explain some of the down-and-up pattern (with its lowest point in 2000) seen in the US suicide rate as a response to changes in social trust.

2.3. Establishing a Base Run

The simulation model (built with the VensimTM software package version 9.3.5 x64) has 192 elements, of which 31 are uncertain parameters related to the structure shown in Figure 1; see Table 2 (a full model listing is presented as Section S4 in Supplementary Materials).
Because of the model’s relatively parsimonious structure, most of its uncertain parameters could be adjusted to achieve a good fit to the data without ambiguity, using the method of partial-model estimation in most cases [41,42]. However, this was less straightforward in the case of 7 exponents corresponding to the 7 primary factors affecting LEB described above (i.e., all with the exception of COVID-19).
The estimation challenge was largely due to collinearity among the explanatory factors. Six of the seven primary factors, all except the suicide rate, moved monotonically upward or downward during the historical period, though with somewhat different patterns of acceleration and deceleration. Prior information suggested only that the positive effect of health care spending on LEB is likely weak [13]. Establishing reasonable values for the other exponents thus required some experimentation, starting with a neutral assumption of equal exponents for the factors other than health care spending, and then adjusting to achieve a better fit to the roughly S-shaped LEB pattern. This was tentatively established as the base run, though with some remaining uncertainty around the LEB exponents.

3. Results

3.1. Base Run Results

Figure 2 presents selected graphical results from the base run and comparison with historical data. Table 3 presents quantitative summaries for 12 historical time series and model goodness of fit. The MAPE (mean absolute percentage error) and MAEM (mean absolute error divided by the mean of the data) metrics [17,43] are in all cases under 10% and under 1% for LEB specifically.
The model indicates that declining LEB growth after 1980 was primarily the result of two factors: the growth of obesity and the leveling off of growth in social spending.
The model’s LEB grows from its initial value of 69.8 years to 77.4 years in 2020; the latter is identical to the value reported by UNDP. In the base run, this increase of 7.6 years is attributable to changes in the eight LEB factors as follows: due to GDPPC growth, +2.5 years; due to obesity growth, −2.4 years; due to college graduate growth, +3.8 years; due to social spending growth, +3.4 years; due to smoking decline, +1.8 years; due to suicide rate (slight net decline from 1960 to 2020), +0.1 years; due to health care spending growth, +0.5 years; and due to COVID, −2.1 years.

3.2. Counterfactual Testing

Counterfactual tests were performed to clarify the roles of two key exogenous model drivers: health care spending and social spending. In the first test (CF1), the personal health care spending fraction of GDP is held constant after 2000 at 11.3% rather than rising to 14.5% by 2010 and 15.2% by 2021; see the left-side graph of Figure 3. This test asks, in essence, to what extent LEB was adversely affected by the consequent decline in social trust, via rising obesity and suicide (see Figure 1), after 2000.
In the second test (CF2), the government social spending fraction of GDP steps up from its 2000 value of 14.1% to 24% in 2001 and beyond, rather than its more gradual historical rise to 19% in 2010 and 18.2% in 2019 (followed by 23.9% in 2020, 22.7% in 2021, and assumed 20% by 2024 and beyond); see the right-side graph of Figure 3. This test asks, in essence, to what extent the stagnation of US LEB in the 2000s could have been avoided by greater social spending, which boosts LEB directly (e.g., by mitigating the health risks of poverty), and through greater college education and reduced smoking and suicide (see Figure 1).
A third counterfactual test (CF3) combines the assumptions of the first two tests, allowing one to see whether their impacts on LEB are simply additive or rather overlapping (less than additive) or synergistic (more than additive).
Selected output variables from the base run and the three counterfactuals are graphed in Figure 4.
The CF1 test (flattened health care spending) causes the wages/salaries fraction to flatten at 0.45 after 2000 rather than declining to 0.435 by 2025 as it does in the base run. This has beneficial effects for obesity, which flattens at 30% soon after 2000 rather than rising to 40% by 2025 as it does in the base run. The flattening of wages/salaries in CF1 also causes social trust to flatten at 0.38 after 2000 rather than declining to 0.335 by 2025. This reduces suicide by about 5%. The beneficial impact of reduced obesity in CF1 is to improve LEB by 0.52 years in 2025 and by 0.71 years in 2040; the suicide improvement contributes only negligibly.
The CF2 test (increased social spending) causes the college graduation fraction to rise more than in the base run; up to 47% by 2025 (base run 41%) and 57% by 2040 (base run 49%). The improvement in education lowers smoking (not graphed) from 13.7% to 12.5% by 2040, and the greater social spending reduces the suicide rate by 2%. The combined effect is to improve LEB by 1.09 years in 2025 and 1.18 years in 2040. More than 45% of this gain is from the direct effect of increased social spending, 35% from increased college graduation, 15% from reduced smoking, and 5% from reduced suicide.
The CF3 test (combining CF1 and CF2) produces improvements in LEB and in intermediate variables that are close to the sum of the individual improvements from CF1 and CF2. By 2025, LEB is boosted from the base run’s 79.6 years to 81.2, 35% of that improvement from CF1 and 65% from CF2. By 2040, LEB is boosted from the base run’s 80.6 years to 82.5, 37% of that improvement from CF1 and 63% from CF2.

4. Discussion

The system dynamics model described here was built to test whether a relatively parsimonious theory of US life expectancy dynamics could produce patterns over 60 years that are a good fit to historical data and give plausible results when tested counterfactually. The model arguably does both. It provides a good fit to history along its causal chain, and the counterfactual tests have clarified the model’s key themes.
One theme is that excess growth in health care spending has adversely affected workers’ wages. This wage stagnation has, in turn, allowed the emergence of obesity as a key factor contributing to the stagnation of US LEB.
The other major factor contributing to US LEB stagnation, according to the model, has been a leveling off in the growth of social spending. This flattening has meant that improvements in educational attainment and social conditions have been less than those enjoyed by other high-income countries.
Parts of this story have been told before. Prior studies have pointed to the key roles of excessive health care spending [15,24,25], income inequality [5,7,8,15], obesity [2,3,5,7,10], inadequate social spending [9,10,12,15], and low educational attainment [7,8,9,10,11,15]. However, prior studies have also identified a number of other factors as key contributors to US LEB, such as suicide, homicide, alcohol, opioids, and road injuries [4,5,6], as well as adverse living conditions such as food insecurity and living alone [9,11].
The confusion in this area likely comes from the fact that most of these studies have taken a static or statistical view rather than a dynamic one. They have not ultimately attempted to explain what caused the stagnation of US LEB over the decades. Instead, most have only identified the many differences between the US and other high-income countries, unable to narrow them down or identify their origins. Even when a dynamic view is taken (as in [15]), it is done so only qualitatively rather than through formal simulation.
Thus, the contribution of the model presented here is to offer the first formal simulation capable of reproducing the historical pattern of US LEB from 1960 to the present. This is notable because statistical or qualitative analyses alone have been unable to tell a clear and convincing story of what happened.
However, the current model leaves some uncertainties unresolved, both in terms of its calibration and parts of the theory itself. With regard to calibration, uncertainty remains about the strength of the several factors directly affecting LEB. The current settings suggest that, over the past 60 years, US LEB has benefited most from the growth of college education, social spending (esp. 1970–1980), and GDP per capita, plus the decline of smoking; and has been hindered most (prior to COVID-19) by the growth of obesity since the late 1970s and stagnation in social spending during the 2010s. It is possible that a deeper examination of the literature on mortality risks may help refine these estimates.
With regard to the theory, the greatest uncertainty is about the causal chain from higher health care spending to lower wages and then to the growth of obesity. The model’s fit to history is excellent along this chain, but one may think of other important factors that are part of the full story.
Firstly, the problem of income inequality and stagnant workers’ wages has arisen not only in the US but also in many other countries, and the drivers outside the US are not health care costs but rather the spread of digital technologies, automation, and globalization [44].
Secondly, the growth of obesity in the US is often explained as a consequence of the reduced price of sweeteners and the rapidly growing popularity of fast-food restaurants starting in the 1970s [23]. Perhaps stagnating wages did in fact lay the groundwork for the popularity of fast food, but proving this point would require more investigation.
Thirdly, because this study’s purpose was to investigate a pattern reaching back several decades, many potential variables affecting US LEB were excluded from the analysis for lack of adequate history. These include, for example, many of the social, environmental, commercial, political, and moral determinants of health, also known as vital conditions, that have been identified in recent years [45,46,47].
Finally, the model here includes only a high-level portrayal (through the use of delay functions) of the onset and progression of chronic diseases associated with obesity and smoking; and does not show how their mortality risks increase with age. Previous system dynamics models have addressed these topics [37,38], so adding such detail is certainly possible, though it might expand the size of the model significantly.

5. Conclusions

In 2011, the National Research Council indicated that a systems framework was needed for gaining a deeper understanding of US life expectancy, one that could guide national policy [2]. The model presented here is a first step in that direction, focusing on the question of why the growth in US LEB stagnated after 1980. The model offers a plausible and parsimonious explanation, largely a social theory with emphasis on the rapid growth in health care spending and obesity and the inadequate growth in social spending. Though the model could be improved with more detail and evidence, it may be considered a reasonable starting point for the kind of dynamic model that can identify key priorities for boosting US life expectancy in light of its past history.

Supplementary Materials

The following supporting information can be downloaded at: https://www.mdpi.com/article/10.3390/systems12120510/s1, Figure S1: Non-communicable disease death rate per 100,000 population by age group, annual 1980–2019; Figure S2: Communicable and other disease death rate per 100,000 population by age group, annual 1980-2019; Figure S3: Injury death rate per 100,000 population by age group, annual 1980–2019; Figure S4: All-causes death rate per 100,000 population by age group, annual 1980–2019; Section S1: Findings of selected studies addressing the stagnation of US life expectancy at birth (LEB) or the gap between US LEB and that of other high-income countries (HIC); Section S2: Time series data; Section S3: Age group-specific death rates by major causes; Section S4: Model equation listing. Section S3 includes the following reference not cited in the main text: Hansen V, Oren E, Dennis LK, Brown HE. Infectious disease mortality trends in the United States, 1980–2014 (Research Letter). JAMA Nov. 22/29, 2016. 316, 2149–2151.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Data Availability Statement

Publicly available data were analyzed in this study; see Sections S2 and S3. The simulation model’s equations and parameters are listed in Section S4.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). Indicators: Life Expectancy at Birth. OECD Data Portal. 2024. Available online: https://data.oecd.org (accessed on 6 November 2024).
  2. National Research Council (US). Explaining Divergent Levels of Longevity in High-Income Countries; Crimmins, E.M., Preston, S.H., Cohen, B., Eds.; National Academies Press: Washington, DC, USA, 2011; p. 194. [Google Scholar]
  3. National Research Council (US). U.S. Health in International Perspective: Shorter Lives, Poorer Health; Woolf, S.H., Aron, L., Eds.; National Academies Press: Washington, DC, USA, 2013; p. 420. [Google Scholar]
  4. Woolf, S.H.; Schoonmaker, H. Life expectancy and mortality rates in the United States, 1959–2017. JAMA 2019, 322, 1996–2016. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  5. Roser, M. Why Is Life Expectancy in the US Lower Than in Other Rich Countries? Our World in Data. 2020. Available online: https://ourworldindata.org/us-life-expectancy-low (accessed on 6 November 2024).
  6. Harper, S.; Riddell, C.A.; King, N.B. Declining life expectancy in the United States: Missing the trees for the forest. Annu. Rev. Public Health 2021, 42, 381–403. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  7. Muennig, P.; Fiscella, K.; Tancredi, D.; Franks, P. The relative health burden of selected social and behavioral risk factors in the United States: Implications for policy. Am. J. Public Health 2010, 100, 1758–1764. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Braveman, P.A.; Cubbin, C.; Egerter, S.; Williams, D.R.; Pamuk, E. Socioeconomic disparities in health in the United States: What the patterns tell us. Am. J. Public Health 2010, 100 (Suppl. S1), S186–S196. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  9. Woolf, S.H.; Braveman, P. Where health disparities begin: The role of social and economic determinants-and why current policies may make matters worse. Health Aff. 2011, 30, 1852–1859. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Chetty, R.; Stepner, M.; Abraham, S.; Lin, S.; Scuderi, B.; Turner, N.; Bergeron, A.; Cutler, D. The association between income and life expectancy in the United States, 2001–2014. JAMA 2016, 315, 1750–1766. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Bundy, J.D.; Mills, K.T.; He, H.; LaVeist, T.A.; Ferdinand, K.C.; Chen, J.; He, J. Social determinants of health and premature death among adults in the USA from 1999 to 2018: A national cohort study. Lancet Public Health 2023, 8, e422–e431. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Bradley, E.H.; Elkins, B.R.; Herrin, J.; Elbel, B. Health and social services expenditures: Associations with health outcomes. BMJ Qual. Saf. 2011, 20, 826–831. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Rothberg, M.B.; Cohen, J.; Lindenauer, P.; Maselli, J.; Auerbach, A. Little evidence of correlation between growth in health care spending and reduced mortality. Health Aff. 2010, 29, 1523–1531. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Weaver, M.R.; Joffe, J.; Ciarametaro, M.; Dubois, R.W.; Dunn, A.; Singh, A.; Sparks, G.W.; Stafford, L.; Murray, C.J.L.; Dieleman, J.L. Health care spending effectiveness: Estimates suggest that spending improved US health from 1996 to 2016. Health Aff. 2022, 41, 994–1004. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Kindig, D.; Chowkwanyun, M. Why did cross-national divergences in life expectancy and health care expenditures both appear in the 1980s? Am. J. Public Health 2020, 110, 1741–1742. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  16. Homer, J.B. Life Expectancy in the U.S. and Other OECD Countries: A Multivariate Analysis of Economic, Social, and Behavioral Factors. 2024. Available online: https://www.academia.edu/121497712/Life_Expectancy_in_the_U_S_and_Other_OECD_Countries_A_Multivariate_Analysis_of_Economic_Social_and_Behavioral_Factors (accessed on 6 November 2024).
  17. Sterman, J.D. Business Dynamics: Systems Thinking and Modeling for a Complex World; McGraw-Hill: Boston, MA, USA, 2000; p. 874. [Google Scholar]
  18. Homer, J.B. Models That Matter: Selected Writings on System Dynamics 1985–2010; Grapeseed Press: Barrytown, NY, USA, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  19. Homer, J.; Milstein, B.; Hirsch, G.B.; Fisher, E.S. Combined regional investments could substantially enhance health system performance and be financially affordable. Health Aff. 2016, 35, 1435–1443. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  20. Darabi, N.; Hosseinichimeh, N. System dynamics modeling in health and medicine: A systematic literature review. Syst. Dyn. Rev. 2020, 36, 29–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Homer, J. Modeling global loss of life from climate change through 2060. Syst. Dyn. Rev. 2020, 36, 523–535. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Homer, J.; Hirsch, G.B. (Eds.) System Dynamics Models for Public Health and Health Care Policy; MDPI: Basel, Switzerland, 2023. [Google Scholar]
  23. Temple, N.J. The origins of the obesity epidemic in the USA-lessons for today. Nutrients 2022, 14, 4253. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Altman, D. The Two Health Care Cost Crises. KFF. 18 January 2024. Available online: https://www.kff.org/from-drew-altman/the-two-health-care-cost-crises (accessed on 20 November 2024).
  25. Miller, B.J.; Nyce, S. Healthcare USA: The big paycheck squeeze. WTW Insider (Willis Towers Watson plc) 2023, 33, 8. Available online: https://www.wtwco.com/en-us/insights/2023/07/the-big-paycheck-squeeze-the-impacts-of-rising-healthcare-costs (accessed on 20 November 2024).
  26. Cutler, D.; Deaton, A.; Lleras-Muney, A. The determinants of mortality. J. Econ. Perspect. 2006, 20, 97–120. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Putnam, R.D.; Garrett, S.R. The Upswing: How America Came Together a Century Ago and How We Can Do It Again; Simon & Schuster: New York, NY, USA, 2020. [Google Scholar]
  28. US Census Bureau. Historical Poverty Tables: People and Families, 1959 to 2023. 2024. Available online: https://www.census.gov/data/tables/time-series/demo/income-poverty/historical-poverty-people.html (accessed on 20 November 2024).
  29. Iezzoni, L.I.; Kurtz, S.G.; Rao, S.R. Trends in U.S. adult chronic disability rates over time. Disabil. Health J. 2014, 7, 402–412. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Zajacova, A.; Margolis, R. Trends in disability and limitations among U.S. adults age 18–44, 2000–2018. Am. J. Epidemiol. 2024. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Institute for Health Metrics and Evaluation (IHME). Global Health Data Exchange (GHDx). 2024. Available online: https://www.healthdata.org/data-tools-practices/data-sources (accessed on 6 November 2024).
  32. National Safety Council. Historical Preventable Fatality Trends; Standardized Rates. 2024. Available online: https://injuryfacts.nsc.org/all-injuries/historical-preventable-fatality-trends/standardized-rate/ (accessed on 20 November 2024).
  33. Jacobs, D.R.; Adachi, H.; Mulder, I.; Kromhout, D.; Menotti, A.; Nissinen, A.; Blackburn, H. Cigarette smoking and mortality risk: 25-year follow-up of the Seven Countries Study. Arch. Intern. Med. 1999, 159, 733–740. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Carter, B.D.; Abnet, C.C.; Feskanich, D.; Freedman, N.D.; Hartge, P.; Lewis, C.E.; Ockene, J.K.; Prentice, R.L.; Speizer, F.E.; Thun, M.J.; et al. Smoking and mortality-beyond established causes. N. Engl J. Med. 2015, 372, 631–640. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Song, E.; Yoo, H.J. Impact of social support and social trust on public viral risk response: A COVID-19 survey study. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2020, 17, 6589. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  36. Vallier, K. US Social Trust has Fallen 23 Points Since 1964. Reconciled. 2020. Available online: https://www.kevinvallier.com/reconciled/new-finding-us-social-trust-has-fallen-23-points-since-1964/ (accessed on 6 November 2024).
  37. Clennin, M.; Homer, J.; Erkenbeck, A.; Kelly, C. Evaluating public health efforts to prevent and control chronic disease: A systems modeling approach. Systems 2022, 10, 89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Hirsch, G.; Homer, J.; Wile, K.; Trogdon, J.G.; Orenstein, D. Using simulation to compare 4 categories of intervention for reducing cardiovascular disease risks. Am. J. Public Health 2014, 104, 1187–1195. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  39. Kitahara, C.M.; Flint, A.J.; de Gonzales, A.B.; Bernstein, L.; Brotzman, M.; MacInnis, R.J.; Moore, S.C.; Robien, K.; Rosenberg, P.S.; Singh, P.N.; et al. Association between Class III obesity (BMI of 40–59 kg/m2) and mortality: A pooled analysis of 20 prospective studies. PLoS Med. 2014, 11, e1001673. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Prospective Studies Collaboration. Body-mass index and cause-specific mortality in 900,000 adults: Collaborative analyses of 57 prospective studies. Lancet 2009, 373, 1083–1096. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Homer, J.B. Partial-model testing as a validation tool for system dynamics (1983). Syst. Dyn. Rev. 2012, 28, 281–294. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Hosseinichimeh, N.; Rahmandad, H.; Wittenborn, A.K. Modeling the hypothalamus–pituitary–adrenal axis: A review and extension. Math. Biosci. 2015, 268, 52–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Wakeland, W.; Homer, J. Addressing parameter uncertainty in a health policy simulation model using Monte Carlo sensitivity methods. Systems 2022, 10, 225. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Qureshi, Z. Rising Inequality: A Major Issue of Our Time. Brookings. 2023. Available online: https://www.brookings.edu/articles/rising-inequality-a-major-issue-of-our-time/ (accessed on 20 November 2024).
  45. Milstein, B.; Payne, B.; Kelleher, C.; Homer, J.; Norris, T.; Roulier, M.; Saha, S. Organizing Around Vital Conditions Moves the Social Determinants Agenda into Wider Action. Health Affairs Forefront. 2023. Available online: https://www.healthaffairs.org/content/forefront/organizing-around-vital-conditions-moves-social-determinants-agenda-into-wider-action (accessed on 20 November 2024).
  46. University of Wisconsin Population Health Institute. County Health Rankings and Roadmaps, What Impacts Health. 2024. Available online: https://www.countyhealthrankings.org/what-impacts-health/county-health-rankings-model (accessed on 6 November 2024).
  47. Holmberg, S.; Rothstein, B. Dying of corruption. Health Econ. Policy Law 2011, 6, 529–547. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Causal-loop diagram overview of the US LEB simulation model. Source: Author’s diagram. Notes: Blue arrow denotes same-polarity causal link; red arrow with minus sign denotes inverse-polarity causal link. “Railroad track” crossing of links (from obesity and smoking to LEB) denotes a delayed effect. Small blue circular arrow (obesity, smoking) denotes a self-reinforcing effect of social influence. Blue text denotes an exogenous variable, determined by input time series. Rectangle indicates an aging chain structure with embedded stocks and flows. The full population aging chain includes stocks for 0–24, 25–64, and 65-plus age groups. The aging chains of high school and college graduates include stocks for 25–64 and 65-plus age groups. Most high schoolers graduate by age 18, and college students by age 25, but the model also depicts significant flows of people completing their education at a later time. All variables in this diagram are supported by historical data (see Table 1); COVID-19 effect on LEB is inferred from the downward spike of LEB reported by UNDP for 2020–2021 and CDC for 2020–2023.
Figure 1. Causal-loop diagram overview of the US LEB simulation model. Source: Author’s diagram. Notes: Blue arrow denotes same-polarity causal link; red arrow with minus sign denotes inverse-polarity causal link. “Railroad track” crossing of links (from obesity and smoking to LEB) denotes a delayed effect. Small blue circular arrow (obesity, smoking) denotes a self-reinforcing effect of social influence. Blue text denotes an exogenous variable, determined by input time series. Rectangle indicates an aging chain structure with embedded stocks and flows. The full population aging chain includes stocks for 0–24, 25–64, and 65-plus age groups. The aging chains of high school and college graduates include stocks for 25–64 and 65-plus age groups. Most high schoolers graduate by age 18, and college students by age 25, but the model also depicts significant flows of people completing their education at a later time. All variables in this diagram are supported by historical data (see Table 1); COVID-19 effect on LEB is inferred from the downward spike of LEB reported by UNDP for 2020–2021 and CDC for 2020–2023.
Systems 12 00510 g001
Figure 2. Base run comparison to historical data for seven output variables. Source: Author’s model testing and data described in Table 1. Notes: See Table 1 for variable definitions and data sources. Thick blue and green lines are from base run simulation. Thin red and black lines are historical data. Simulated LEB reflects assumed COVID-19 effect 2020–2024. Simulated social trust includes exogenous resurgence 1996–2005. (a) Life expectancy at birth (LEB, 65–85), (red = UNDP, black = CDC). (b) Wages fraction of GDP (blue/red, 0–0.6); obesity (green/black, 0–0.6). (c) College grads (blue/red, 0–0.6); smoking (green/black, 0–0.6). (d) Social trust (blue/red, 0–1); suicide death rate (green/black, 0–20).
Figure 2. Base run comparison to historical data for seven output variables. Source: Author’s model testing and data described in Table 1. Notes: See Table 1 for variable definitions and data sources. Thick blue and green lines are from base run simulation. Thin red and black lines are historical data. Simulated LEB reflects assumed COVID-19 effect 2020–2024. Simulated social trust includes exogenous resurgence 1996–2005. (a) Life expectancy at birth (LEB, 65–85), (red = UNDP, black = CDC). (b) Wages fraction of GDP (blue/red, 0–0.6); obesity (green/black, 0–0.6). (c) College grads (blue/red, 0–0.6); smoking (green/black, 0–0.6). (d) Social trust (blue/red, 0–1); suicide death rate (green/black, 0–20).
Systems 12 00510 g002
Figure 3. Health care and social spending inputs for base run and counterfactual tests. SOURCE: Author’s model testing. NOTES: In the left-side graph, the blue line is from NHE through 2021 (=0.152), then assumed flat to 2040. The red line is for counterfactual tests CF1 and CF3; the health care spending fraction remains flat at 0.113 after 2000. In the right-side graph, the blue line is from OECD through 2021 (=0.227), assumed to ramp down to 0.20 by 2024, then flat to 2040. The green line is for counterfactual tests CF2 and CF3; the social spending fraction steps up to 0.24 after 2000 and remains there to 2040. (a) Personal health care spending fraction of GDP (0–0.2). (b) Government social spending fraction of GDP (0–0.3).
Figure 3. Health care and social spending inputs for base run and counterfactual tests. SOURCE: Author’s model testing. NOTES: In the left-side graph, the blue line is from NHE through 2021 (=0.152), then assumed flat to 2040. The red line is for counterfactual tests CF1 and CF3; the health care spending fraction remains flat at 0.113 after 2000. In the right-side graph, the blue line is from OECD through 2021 (=0.227), assumed to ramp down to 0.20 by 2024, then flat to 2040. The green line is for counterfactual tests CF2 and CF3; the social spending fraction steps up to 0.24 after 2000 and remains there to 2040. (a) Personal health care spending fraction of GDP (0–0.2). (b) Government social spending fraction of GDP (0–0.3).
Systems 12 00510 g003
Figure 4. Outputs from base run and three counterfactual tests. Source: Author’s model testing. Notes: In the top-left graph for social trust and in the lower-left graph for obese fraction, the blue line is from the base run and CF2, and the red line is from CF1 and CF3. In the top-right graph for college graduate fraction, the blue line is from the base run and CF1, and the green line is from CF2 and CF3. In the lower-right graph for LEB, the blue line is the base run, red is CF1, green is CF2, and black is CF3.
Figure 4. Outputs from base run and three counterfactual tests. Source: Author’s model testing. Notes: In the top-left graph for social trust and in the lower-left graph for obese fraction, the blue line is from the base run and CF2, and the red line is from CF1 and CF3. In the top-right graph for college graduate fraction, the blue line is from the base run and CF1, and the green line is from CF2 and CF3. In the lower-right graph for LEB, the blue line is the base run, red is CF1, green is CF2, and black is CF3.
Systems 12 00510 g004aSystems 12 00510 g004b
Table 1. Data variables and years available.
Table 1. Data variables and years available.
VariableSourceYears Available
Life expectancy at birthUNDP1960–2021, annual
Life expectancy at birthCDC1960–2023, annual
Population, 3 age groupsUNDP1960–2021 and projected to 2040 annual
Deaths, 3 age groupsUNDP1960–2021 and projected to 2040 annual
BirthsUNDP1960–2021 and projected to 2040 annual
Net immigrationUNDP1960–2021 and projected to 2040 annual
High school grads % of age 25+Census1962 and 1964–2022, annual
College grads % of age 25+Census1962 and 1964–2022, annual
High school grads % of age 25–29NCES1960, 1970, 1980, 1990, 1995, 2000, and 2005–2017 annual
College grads % of age 25–29NCES1960, 1970, 1980, 1990, 1995, 2000, and 2005–2017 annual
Real GDP per capita, in 2012 dollarsFRED1960–2023 annual
Wages and salaries % of GDPFRED1960–2022 annual
Personal health care spending % of GDPNHE1960–2021 annual
Government social spending % of GDPOECD1960–2021 annual
Labor union % of employeesOECD1960–2020 annual
Social trustRoper/Putnam1960–2018 roughly biannual (36 of 59 years)
Obese % of age 18+CDC/WHO1960, 1971, and 1975–2016 annual
Current smoker % of age 18+NHIS1965–1996 roughly biannual and 1997–2021 annual
Suicide deaths per 100,000 populationWHO/OECD1960–2021 annual
Source: Author’s extraction of public data from multiple sources. Notes: UNDP: United Nations Division of Population; 2022–2040 data are from UNDP’s medium variant projections. Age groups: 0–24, 25–64, 65–plus. CDC: US Centers for Disease Control and Prevention. UNDP and CDC estimates of LEB were generally very close (within 0.3 years) except for 2020 and 2021. NCES: National Center for Education Statistics (US Department of Education). FRED: Federal Reserve Economic Data (St. Louis Fed). NHE: National Health Expenditures database (from CMS: Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services); government social spending data updated starting 1980 to include Medicare and Medicaid. OECD: Organization for Economic Cooperation & Development. WHO: World Health Organization (United Nations); obese: body mass index of 30 or greater. NHIS: National Health Interview Survey (CMS); current smoking was reported for 16 of the 32 years 1965–1996, with a maximum reporting gap of 4 years (1966–1978). Suicide death rate (WHO/OECD) is age-standardized for OECD countries. Social trust (Roper/Putnam): Roper Center for Public Opinion Research, based on response to the following: “Generally speaking, would you say that most people can be trusted, or that you can’t be too careful in dealing with people?”, presented as a time series graph in Putnam/Garrett Figure 4.13 [27].
Table 2. Uncertain model parameters and their methods of estimation.
Table 2. Uncertain model parameters and their methods of estimation.
ParameterValueMethod of Estimation
Average time to indirect death from obesity20 yearsLiterature [37,38,39,40]
Indirect frac of obesity related deaths0.8Literature [37,38,39,40]
Obese frac adjustment time5 yearsPartial model estimation
Average time to indirect death from smoking20 yearsLiterature [33,34,37,38]
Indirect frac of smoking related deaths0.6Literature [33,34,37,38]
Smoker frac adjustment time3 yearsPartial model estimation
Exponent for college grad from social spend1.1Partial model estimation
Exponent for LEB from GDPPC0.03Partial model estimation and prior analysis [16]
Exponent for LEB from healthcare spend0.005Partial model estimation and literature [13,14]
Exponent for LEB from higher education0.035Partial model estimation and prior analysis [16]
Exponent for LEB from obesity−0.015Partial model estimation and prior analysis [16]
Exponent for LEB from smoking−0.015Partial model estimation and prior analysis [16]
Exponent for LEB from social spending0.035Partial model estimation and prior analysis [16]
Exponent for LEB from suicide−0.03Partial model estimation
Exponent for obesity from wages−7.0Partial model estimation
Exponent for peer effect on obese frac0.25Partial model estimation
Exponent for peer effect on smoker frac0.25Partial model estimation
Exponent for smoking from college grad−0.5Partial model estimation
Exponent for social cohesion from wages3.5Partial model estimation
Exponent for suicide from high school grad−0.25Partial model estimation
Exponent for suicide from social spend−0.1Partial model estimation
Exponent for suicide from social trust−0.45Partial model estimation
Mitigation of COVID at 1960 social trust0.9Partial model estimation and literature [35]
Exponent for unionization from social cohesion2.0Partial model estimation
Unionization adjustment time3 yearsPartial model estimation
Exponent for wages from healthcare spend−0.07Partial model estimation
Exponent for wages from unionization0.06Partial model estimation
Max college-grad-share gap closing rate 25to643.7% per yearPartial model estimation
Max college-grad-share gap closing rate 65plus1.0% per yearPartial model estimation
Max high-school-grad share gap closing rate 25to 642.5% per yearPartial model estimation
Max high-school-grad share gap closing rate 65plus0.5% per yearPartial model estimation
Source: Author’s analysis and the cited literature.
Table 3. Base run goodness of fit to 12 historical data series.
Table 3. Base run goodness of fit to 12 historical data series.
Time SeriesData PointsTime PatternData Min/MaxModel MAPEModel MAEM
Life expectancy at birth (UNDP)62rise0.880.6%0.5%
Life expectancy at birth (CDC)64rise0.880.6%0.6%
High school grads % of age 25+60rise0.511.7%1.6%
College grads % of age 25+60rise0.235.2%4.8%
High school grads % of age 25–2919rise0.662.1%2.1%
College grads % of age 25–2919rise0.309.7%9.8%
Wages and salaries % of GDP63decline0.811.6%1.6%
Labor union % of employees59decline0.323.5%3.8%
Social trust36decline0.545.9%5.9%
Obese % of age 18+44rise0.285.3%4.7%
Current smoker % of age 18+41decline0.277.1%5.4%
Suicide deaths per 100,00061down and up0.735.6%5.4%
Source: Author’s model testing, data described in Table 1, and author’s spreadsheet calculations. Notes: “Data min/max” is the ratio of the minimum data point to the maximum; the smaller the ratio, the greater the data’s relative range. MAPE is the mean absolute percentage error of model compared with data. MAEM is the mean absolute error (MAE) divided by the mean of the data [17,43].
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Homer, J. The Growth and Stagnation of US Life Expectancy: A Dynamic Simulation Model and Implications. Systems 2024, 12, 510. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems12120510

AMA Style

Homer J. The Growth and Stagnation of US Life Expectancy: A Dynamic Simulation Model and Implications. Systems. 2024; 12(12):510. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems12120510

Chicago/Turabian Style

Homer, Jack. 2024. "The Growth and Stagnation of US Life Expectancy: A Dynamic Simulation Model and Implications" Systems 12, no. 12: 510. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems12120510

APA Style

Homer, J. (2024). The Growth and Stagnation of US Life Expectancy: A Dynamic Simulation Model and Implications. Systems, 12(12), 510. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems12120510

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop