PH DThesisFinal-Janury09 PDF
PH DThesisFinal-Janury09 PDF
PH DThesisFinal-Janury09 PDF
net/publication/228119127
CITATIONS READS
11 306
1 author:
Ichiro Sugimoto
Soka University
8 PUBLICATIONS 17 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
The Construction of Long-term Economic Statistics in Former British Colonies in Southeast Asia View project
All content following this page was uploaded by Ichiro Sugimoto on 09 May 2018.
ICHIRO SUGIMOTO
JANUARY 2009
2009
UNIVERSITY OF MALAYA
ORIGINAL LITERARY WORK DECLATION
ICHIRO SUGIMOTO
JANUARY 2009
2009
ABSTRACT
This thesis has as its main objective the analysis of economic growth of Singapore
Research on the long-term economic growth of Singapore has been hampered until
now due, in large part, to the virtual absence of economic-related statistics prior to 1956
Recognizing this limitation, the first part of this study is devoted to providing the
for the periods 1900-39 and 1950-60. The “Expenditure Approach” was applied to
derive GDP data series in current and constant prices for these periods. Subsequently,
this time-series data was extended to cover entire twentieth century using a single base
By utilizing this historical GDP series, two types of empirical investigations were
attempted to examine the economic growth experiences of Singapore. The first type
deals with the relationship between economic instability and economic growth. Three
related issues were examined, namely extent, sources and consequences of economic
instability during the twentieth century. It was observed that the extent of output
volatility in the pre-WWII period was greater than that of the post-WWII period. In
terms of trade were found to be statistically insignificant for both the pre-WWII and
growth, export instability has negatively impacted on real per capita GDP growth for
ii
the entire twentieth century but the coefficient has fallen over time as the structure of
The second type deals with government fiscal behavior towards economic growth. It
behavior between the British colonial period and the period of self-government that
ensued. This study firstly identifies the nature of colonial government finance behavior
and then goes on to trace the changes in revenue raising, expenditure allocation and
budget balance management patterns in the twentieth century. A major structural change
was observed after WWII. It was mainly due to the shift of the source of revenue from
the sales of opium to revenue obtained from income tax. This transition impacted on the
Nevertheless, the share of government expenditure to GDP during both the British
colonial government and the period of self-government remained small while those of
other developed countries experienced continuous increases over the same period. In
fact, both the British colonial government and self-government attempted to establish
balanced or even a surplus budget structure. For analytical purposes, the validity of
Wagner’s law was empirically tested. The result on Granger causality test found that
period while economic expansion during the post-WWII period could mainly be
iii
ABSTRAK
abad ke-20.
ekoran daripada ketidakwujudan data statististik yang selaras dengan tafsiran Sistem
Perakaunan Negara (SNA) sebelum tahun 1956. Berdasarkan kesedaran ini, kajian
Singapura bagi tempoh 1900-39 dan 1950-60. Pendekatan dari segi perbelanjaan telah
digunakan berasaskan kepada harga semasa dan harga tetap. Selanjutnya, anggaran
KDNK ini digabungkan dengan data am yang diterbitkan dalam jangka masa sepanjang
Dengan menggunakan anggaran KDNK tersebut, dua jenis kajian empirikal telah
digunakan bagi meneliti pertumbuhan ekonomi Singapura. Jenis kajian pertama adalah
dan kesan ketidakstabilan. Ketidakstabilan KDNK dalam jangka masa sebelum Perang
Dunia Kedua menunjukkan kadar yang lebih ketara jika dibandingkan dengan jangka
masa selepas Perang Dunia Kedua. Ini dapat dijelaskan melalui faktor-faktor yang
menyebabkan ketidakstabilan KDNK, jumlah lebihan dan defisit kerajaan dalam KDNK,
perubahan jumlah saiz perdagangan KDNK dan indeks terma perdagangan. Ketiga-tiga
ketidakstabilan eksport ini telah memberi kesan negatif kepada perkembangan per
iv
Namun begitu, koefisien itu telah berkurangan dalam jangka masa tertentu sejajar
tumpuan sama ada terdapat perbezaan atau persamaan dalam konteks pengurusan
kewangan di antara pihak pentadbiran kolonial British dan kerajaan Singapura selepas
kemerdekaan negara tersebut. Kajian pertama ialah sifat pengurusan kewangan kerajaan
kewangan dalam abad ke-20. Ini disebabkan oleh perubahan struktur pengutipan hasil
polisi ini, perbelanjaan negeri juga meningkat. Walau bagaimanapun, jikalau dibanding
berkuasa kolonial British dan kerajaan Singapura telah memberi tumpuan bagi
membentuk struktur kewangan yang seimbang atau lebihan kewangan. Pada masa yang
sama ujian Wagner’s law iaitu Granger causality test dilaksanakan di mana ia telah
diuruskan oleh kerajaan memberi kesan positif bagi menentukan pertumbuhan ekonomi
v
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
It is my pleasure to thank the many individuals who made this thesis possible.
I am greatly indebted to Prof. Dr. Tan Eu Chye as my supervisor for the intellectual
provided me encouragement, sound advice, good teaching and lots of good ideas. I
would have been lost without him. Thanks to his encouragement, I presented part of this
Conference 2007” (Tokyo, Japan) and “The Singapore Economic Review Conference
I would also like to express my deep appreciation to His Royal Highness Raja Dr.
Nazrin Shah, Crown Prince of Perak and Pro-Chancellor, University of Malaya for
experience gained from this project as well as the accessibility accorded me to his
my own thesis.
I want to thank Dato’ Dr. Shaharil Talib, former executive director, Asia-Europe
Institute for giving me great encouragement and for sharing his deep knowledge on
colonial history of Singapore. Mr. Gnaseagarah C. Kandaiya and Mr. Harbans Singh
have guided me in the construction of historical statistics with their profound experience
as statisticians. I have also received valuable comments at various stages from Prof. Dr.
Riitta Hjerppee, Dr. Reino Hjerppee, Dr. Pierre van der Eng, Prof. Dr. Jan Luiten van
vi
Zanden, Dr. Thomas Linblad, Prof. Dr. Om Prakash, Prof. Dr. Yoshihiro Tsubouchi and
The Asia-Europe Institute, University of Malaya headed by Prof. Datuk Dr. Roziah
Omar, has provided me the best facility and resources to carry out my studies all the
way. I am grateful to my former research colleagues Ruhana, Nazli, Anita, Tuah, Tin,
Laili, Zul, Suhaimi and Quang who have been a source of motivation.
My most heartfelt gratitude to Dr. Daisaku Ikeda, founder of Soka University for
guiding me all the way since my decision to pursue further studies in Malaysia.
I am grateful to Prof. Dr. Masami Kita, Prof. Dr. Yoshihisa Baba, Prof. Hirotomo
Teranishi, Prof. Dr. Tsuyoshi Kato, Dr. Motoko Kawano, Mr. Choo Kong Fei, Mrs.
Choo Aiko, Prof. Dr. Christopher Boey, Mrs. Chang Lee Leng, Mrs. Lim Suat San, Mr.
Fumio Nakano, Mr. Hiroyuki Azuma, Mr. Mitsuharu Mori, Mr. Futoshi Ozaki, Mr.
Tomohito Gyota and Mr. Kazunori Wakayama and for their continued moral support.
Finally, I am forever indebted to my wife, Mieko and my son, Yoichi for their
parents-in-law, Fumio Murayama and Tokiko Murayama for their unflagging support.
vii
TABLES OF CONTENTS
ABSTRACT ii-iii
ABSTRAK iv-v
ACKNOWLEDGEMENT vi-vii
2.1 Introduction 24
viii
2.2 Private Final Consumption Expenditure by Resident 31
Households, 1900-39 and 1950- 60
2.2.1 Definition 31
ix
2.2.2.2.3 Construction of Consumer Price Indices 53
1900-39 and 1950-60 (1914=100)
(STEP 3)
2.3.1 Definition 65
2.4.1 Definition 80
x
2.4.2 Investment in Construction 82
2.4.2.1 Definition 82
2.4.3.1 Definition 89
2.4.4.1 Definition 95
xi
2.5.4.2 Exports of Bunker Coal and Petroleum 113
to Foreign Ships
xii
3.3.2.3 Gross Capital Formation in Current and 143
1914 Prices
3.4.1 Transforming the base year from 1914 prices to 1990 160
prices for the period 1900-39 and 1950-60
xiii
4.2.3.3 Terms-of-Trade Volatility 183
xiv
5.2.1.2 Creation of Balanced Budget Structure 219
xv
CHAPTER CONCLUSION 264-271
SIX
APPENDICES 272-335
1 Food Price Indices for the period 1915-17 and 1939 277
xvi
2 Price Indices of “Tobacco” and “Beverages and 278
Tobacco” for the period 1915-1917 and 1939
BIBLIOGRAPHY 336-358
xvii
LIST OF TABLES
1.1 Malaya and Singapore: Gross National Product and Gross Domestic 13
Product, 1947-60, (At Market Prices $ Million)
xviii
2.15 Singapore: Gross Output of Producers' of Government Services, 78
1900-39 and 1950-60
2.22 Singapore: Import Unit Value Indices of Cement, 1900-39 and 1950- 88
60 (1914=100)
xix
2.36 Coconuts, Cost-per-acre Estimate, Smallholdings, 1900-39 in 1934 101
Prices
2.42 Singapore: Weights Assigned for the Change of Stocks to GDP (%) 107
in relation to GDP Growth Rate
2.44 Singapore: Merchandize Net Exports in Current Prices, 1900-39 and 112
1950-60
2.45 Singapore: Imports and Export Price Index for Goods and Services, 118
1960-95 (1990=100)
2.49 Singapore: Export Value and Quantity by Major Commodity Goods 122
1927-39 and 1949-60 (based on figures by W.G. Huff )
2.50 Singapore: Export Unit Value Index, 1927-39 and 1950-60 124
(1914=100)
2.51 Singapore: Import Unit Value Indices and Export Unit Value 125
Indices, 1900-39 and 1950-60 (1914=100)
2.52 Weighted Price Indices on Fuel and Communication of the United 126
Kingdom, 1900-39 and 1950-60 (1914=100)
2.53 Singapore: Net Exports of Goods and Services at Current and 126
Constant Prices, 1900-39 and 1950-60
xx
3.3 Singapore: Gross Domestic Product at Current prices, 1956-1960, 134
(Straits $ in millions)
3.4 Singapore: Average Annual Growth Rate of GDP and Its 135
Components at Current and Constant Prices, 1900-2000
3.5 Singapore: Gross Domestic Product and its Components at Current 135
Prices, 1900-1970
3.6 Singapore: The Results of Unit Root Tests of GDP and Its 139
Components (1990 Prices), 1960-2000
3.7 Singapore: The Results of Unit Root Tests of GDP and Its 140
Components (1914 Prices), 1900-39
3.12 Singapore: Exports by Country and Region, 1911/13, 1925/27 and 150
1957/59, (Annual Average)
3.13 Singapore: Imports by Country and Region, 1911/13, 1925/27 and 151
1957/59 (Annual Average)
3.14 Percentage Share of Components of GDP to Total GDP for Selected 157
Countries at Current Prices, 1900-60
3.15 Conversion Ratio from 1914 price to 1990 price for the period 161
1900-39 and 1950-60
xxi
4.1 Standard deviations of annual real GDP growth (GDP % Growth 178
Volatility)
4.2 Real GDP growth volatility (Standard Deviations and Mean of 179
Growth)
4.4 Singapore: Tin, Rubber and Petroleum Export Quantity Indices and 187
Percentage Contributions to Merchandize Exports, 1900-70
4.8 Singapore: Instability Indicators of GDP and the Aggregate Demand 198
Components, 1900-2000 at 1990 Prices and Relative Instability
Indicators of the Each Component of GDP (1914-39=100)
4.14 Singapore: Regression Results with the Rate of Growth of Real GDP 208
Per Capita as the Dependent Variable, 1900-39,1950-2000 and
1975-2000
xxii
5.5 Percentage Share of Government Social Expenditure to GDP 239
(Average of OECD Countries)
5.7 Unit Root (Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test and Philips-Perron Test) 256
Test for Stationary
5.9 The Results of Granger Causality tests, 1900-39 and 1950-2000 259
Appendix Tables
1 The Assigned Weights of Food by Item for the Construction of Food 274
Price Indices for All Standards
xxiii
LIST OF FIGURES
2.2 Steps involved for the Estimation of GFCE, 1900-39 and 1950-60 27
2.6 Steps involved for the Estimation of Changes in Stock, 1900-39 and 30
1950-60
2.7 Steps involved for the Estimation of Imports and Exports of Goods 30
and Services, 1900-39 and 1950-60
xxiv
2.13 Singapore: Classification for Total Output of Producers' of 69
Government Services
2.18 Singapore: Import Unit Value Indices and Export Unit Value 125
Indices, 1900-39 and 1950-60 (1914=100)
3.2 Singapore: Annual Growth Rate of GDP and its components at 130
Current Prices, 1900-39 and 1950-60
3.4 Singapore: Annual Growth Rate of GDP and its components at 1914 132
Prices, 1900-39 and 1950-60
3.6 Annual Growth Rates (%) of GDP of Singapore against Selected 152
Countries, 1900-39 at Current Prices
3.9 Annual Growth Rates (%) of Gross Capital Formation (GCF) of 154
Singapore against Selected Countries, 1900-39 at Current Prices
3.10 Annual Growth Rates (%) of Exports of Goods and Services 155
(EXGS) of Singapore against Selected Countries, 1900-39 at Current
Prices
3.11 Annual Growth Rates (%) of Imports of Goods and Services (IMGS) 155
of Singapore against Selected Countries, 1900-39 at Current Prices
xxv
3.12 Percentage Share of Private Final Consumption Expenditure in 158
Gross Domestic Product in Current Prices, 1900-39, Singapore and
Selected Countries
3.16 Singapore; GDP at Current and Constant (1990 Prices), 1900-39 and 166
1950-2000
3.17 Singapore: Per-capita GDP at Current and Constant (1990 Prices), 166
1900-39 and 1950-2000
3.19 Singapore: Saving and Investment as ratio of GNP and Current 170
Account Balance, 1960-2000
4.5 Singapore: Export Unit Value Indices (1914=100) of Rubber, Tin 188
and Petroleum, 1900-70
4.6 Singapore: Trend GDP, Actual GDP and Percentage Deviation of 193
GDP from Trend, 1900-2000 (Trend obtained using HP filter)
xxvi
4.9 Singapore: Gross Capital Formation, Trend, Actual and Percentage 196
Deviation from Trend, 1900-2000 (1990 Prices)
4.10 Singapore: Exports of Goods and Services, Trend, Actual and 197
Percentage Deviation from Trend, 1900-2000 (1990 Prices)
4.11 Singapore: Imports of Goods and Services, Trend, Actual and 197
Percentage Deviation from Trend, 1900-2000 (1990 Prices)
5.5 Singapore: Budget Deficit (-)/ Surplus at Current Prices, 1900-1939, 243
1950-79 and 1980-2000
Appendix Figure
1 335
LIST OF MAP
1.1 The Malay Peninsula, c. 1925 6
xxvii
LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS
STCOPUK Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions of the
United Kingdom
xxviii
STCPP Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions and
Protectorates
xxix
CHAPTER ONE
INTRODUCTION
Singapore during the twentieth century. According to official statistics released since
1960, the economic indicators of Singapore show a sustained and relatively rapid
economic growth over this period. For the period 1960-2000, real GDP (1990 prices)
rose at an average annual rate of 7.7 percent. With population growth at 2.2 percent, real
per capita GDP increased by 5.5 percent on average each year. In fact, real per capita
GDP has increased 9.7 times within 40 years. Out of 107 countries, Singapore registered
the highest growth performance1 during the period 1960-2000 (Ghesquiere 2007:14).
This phenomenon was frequently cited as an “economic miracle”. On the other hand,
economic performance of Singapore prior to 1960 was never quantified in the same
manner due to the complete absence of comparable economic statistical indicators such
as GDP and other relevant statistical time-series. Given these serious constraints of data
availability for the earlier period, the existing literature on the pre-1960 economic
Admittedly, though these specific studies help to shed some light on certain aspects of
the economic activities in Singapore during this period they certainly are not enough to
give any detail insight into the long-term economic growth of Singapore during the last
100 years.
In order to fill this void, the first part of this thesis focuses on the construction of
historical GDP estimates of Singapore in both current and constant prices for the period
1900-39 and 1950-60. It should be noted here that the World War II period (1941-45)
1
National Income expressed in PPP dollars.
1
and the years immediately after WWII are not covered in this exercise because of the
difficulties in estimating historical GDP time-series due to the complete absence of data
for some of the components of GDP. The construction of historical GDP of Singapore
involved three major steps. The first requires the identification and collection of existing
statistical records published by the British colonial authority. Secondly, it involves the
methodologies while at the same time ensuring that the concepts and definitions
2
conformed to those as outlined in A System of National Accounts (SNA) 1968 for each
component of GDP. Thirdly, it involves checking the reliability and validity of the
explain the upturns and downturns of each component of GDP in both current and real
terms.
Based on this newly derived historical GDP and official time-series database for the
post-1960 period, the second part of this thesis focuses on the empirical investigation
with regards to Singapore’s long-term economic growth during the entire twentieth
economic instability and economic growth. This topic deals with three related issues,
namely (i) extent of real GDP volatility (ii) source of the real GDP volatility and (iii) the
The second topic deals with government fiscal behavior towards economic growth.
This study firstly identifies the ramifications of colonial government finance and
subsequently observes the transition of government fiscal behavior from the British
colonial rule to the period of self-government. Based on the observations, this thesis
focuses on whether there existed any notable differences or similarities between various
types of government expenditure and economic growth. For analytical purposes two
2
Up till now, three different versions of SNA were released by United Nations for the years 1953, 1968 and 1993. In this study, the
SNA 68 was utilized for the estimation of each component of historical GDP. This is mainly because all official GDP estimates of
Singapore for the period 1960-2000 were constructed based on the SNA 68.
2
econometric techniques of cointegration and Granger causality tests are applied.
The structure of the remaining part of this chapter is organized as follows. Section
historical statistics and lastly the concept of GDP and the three different approaches that
can be used in its estimation. Section 1.3 explains the data required for the construction
of historical GDP estimates. Finally, the layout of the thesis is briefly presented in
Section 1.4.
This section briefly conducts a literature review relevant to this study. Three areas of
literature review are identified, namely [1] economic history of Singapore prior to
Independence, [2] the construction of historical GDP estimates and [3] concept of GDP.
Wong Lin Ken (1979) provided a literature review on the economic history of
Economic History: A Select Bibliographic Survey”. In his article, Wong Lin Ken stated
that “research in this region is still on the frontier area of the social sciences. Analytical
methodology grounded in economic theory was lacking”. Some two decades later,
Drabble, John H (2000), in his book on “Economic History of Malaysia” which covered
stating that “from the standpoint of the economic historian the situation is still to a large
extent as Wong described”. Loh Wei Leng (2005) also stated that “(quantitative) data
found in official documents are seldom questioned and are yet to be closely scrutinized
as to their likely use in support of specific policies. There is an obvious need to be more
sensitive to these implications in future work”. The above statements made by economic
historians made abundantly clear that research in this field of economic history saw
3
little progress.
socio-economy during the British colonial period. The studies on the economic history
of Singapore approached from various aspects ranging from trade, commercial activity,
the world depression in early 1920s and 1930s. Apart from this, studies on demographic
supply and port facilities as well as opium revenue collection by the British
Singapore as an entrepôt and a regional trading centre was often highlighted. For
example, Kaoru Sugihara worked on the statistics of intra-Asian trade during the
nineteenth and early half of 20th century to clarify the nature of the western impact and
the role of regional trade in Asia’s economic development (Sugihara, Kaoru, 1980 and
1996 and 1998). In a related study, Lindblad, J.Thomas (1997, 1998) examines the role
of foreign direct investment (FDI) in Southeast Asia from the late nineteenth century.
He contrasts the statistical evidence pertaining to the late 1930s and the late 1980s and
various statistical databases and interpreted Singapore’s economy during the British
colonial period.
indirect rule examines the similarities and differences in economic activities between
the colonial administered territories of British Malaya (See Map 1)3 and Netherland
Indies. Subsequently, Lim Chong Yah’s book (1967) entitled Economic Development of
3
Prior to World War II, the territory of British Malaya was administrated as three different entities, namely the Straits Settlements,
Federated Malay States and Unfederated Malay States. Frequently, the term “British Malaya” was considered as the summation of
these three administrative units.
4
Modern Malaya examined the socio-economic development of Malay states from
various aspects such as the role of major export commodities (eg. rubber and tin), trade
Figure 1.1
List of Previous Studies on Singapore Relating to Socio-Economic Issues Prior to
Independence
5
These two studies by Emerson, Rupert (1964) and Lim Chong Yah (1967) provided
different from that of the other states of Malaya which concentrated in the production of
primary export commodities. The island of Singapore formed a part of the Straits
Map 1.1
The Malay Peninsula, c. 1925
4
The establishment of the Straits Settlements followed the Anglo-Dutch Treaty of 1824 between the United Kingdom and the
Netherlands, by which the Malay archipelago was divided into a British zone in the north and a Dutch zone in the south. This
resulted the exchange of the British settlement of Bencoolen (on Sumatra) for the Dutch colony of Malacca and undisputed control
of Singapore. Its capital was moved from Penang to Singapore in 1832. In 1867, the Settlements became a British Crown Colony,
making the Settlements answerable directly to the Colonial Office in London instead of the Calcutta government based in India on
April 1. Earlier on February 4, a "Letters Patent" granted the Settlements a colonial constitution. This allocated much power to the
Settlements' Governor, who administered the Colony of the Straits Settlements with the aid of an Executive Council, composed
wholly of official (i.e. ex-officio) members, and a Legislative Council, composed partly of official and partly of nominated members,
of which the former had a narrow permanent majority. The work of administration, both in the Colony and in the Federated Malay
States, was carried on by means of a civil service whose members were recruited by competitive examination held annually in
London. Penang and Malacca were administered, directly under the Governor, by resident councilors.
6
The third study was that of W.G. Huff (1994) contained in the book entitled The
Economic Growth of Singapore, Trade and Development in the Twentieth Century. This
is the first major research work which traces the long-term economic development of
Singapore as an economic entity during the twentieth century. “The history of Singapore
is written mainly in statistics” is the opening sentence in Huff's book. Huff had
immersed himself in the collection and integration the statistical material from a host of
primary, secondary and even obscure data sources. The result is a systematic attempt at
tracing economic linkages between the metropolis and its hinterland and connections
between agriculture, trade, banking and industry. He argues that essentially Singapore
was a port dealing in staple commodities. It built its original development on tin exports
from Malaya and the Netherland East Indies. In the twentieth century came a further
developmental thrust with the rubber boom, driven by the requirements of the
Apart from tin and rubber, the other major export commodity of Singapore in the
1930s was petroleum which was imported from the Dutch East Indies. But this did not
have much direct effect on the Singapore economy as it created little employment and
its installations were confined to offshore islands. It did, however, create employment
opportunities in the extensive shipyard facilities which the British had established. In
this study, Huff highlights the fact that Singapore achieved economic development
These three studies mentioned above have, in fact, immensely contributed in the
7
grounded in economic theory which was described being still on the frontier area. This
existing fundamental research gap was purely due to the lack of analytical work
treated as such and no compatible analysis was conducted with a view to identifying the
This phenomenon is not merely observed for Singapore. In fact, most of the former
colonies faced a similar predicament. Michael Havinden and David Meredith’s works
(1996) entitled Colonialism and Development: Britain and Its Tropical Colonies,
1850-1960 set out to consider the policy decisions of Great Britain in regard to the
economic development of its tropical possessions from 1860 through 1960. This study,
however, resorted to the used of the “size of foreign trade” as a proxy to measure the
economic development of the respective colonies with the author acknowledging with a
caveat that foreign trade was not a reliable proxy to indicate economic growth. This
implies that deficiencies of the relevant economic indicators do not permit the conduct
of modern quantitative economic analysis. Based on this recognition, the collection and
integral part of this study represents a fundamental but crucial step towards filling this
void, notwithstanding the painstaking and tedious task of compiling the required raw
been regarded as one of the most dynamic branches of economic history (Heikkienen,
Sakari and Luiten Van Zanden, Jan (eds), 2004) in western countries. The emergence of
this branch of studies was closely associated with the creation of the System of National
Accounts (SNA). The first major research in the field of historical national accounts
8
emerged in the 1930s when Clark (1937) and Kuznets (1934) published their pioneering
works. Subsequently, the first standardized SNA was designed and formulated in a large
part by Maede and Stone (1941). They made the first official estimates of national
income for the United Kingdom in 1941. Subsequently, the United Nations in 1953
(SNA) and it has been widely applied in most countries. Following this, the United
Nations published two further revised versions of SNA, namely in 1968 and 1993.
In line with this development of SNA in the 1950s, the methodology employed in the
incremental improvements. Most of the empirical research since then has focused on
expanding and deepening the database on which the comparative and summarizing
studies of Kuznets were based, while much of the theory-oriented research has
economic activities using the SNA approach was crucial in the attempts to seek general
The empirical research has been widened by expanding the construction of historical
national accounts to other countries, and, increasingly, by updating the previous work in
order to comply with the procedures as set out in the System of National Accounts.
Among of these prominent research studies are those initiated by Craft, N.F.R (1984,
While both “old” and “new” economic historians emphasized the importance of
Reconstruction of historical national accounts was made available for almost all
5
Historical researchers using economic models and advanced mathematical methods of data processing and analysis.
9
OECD countries by the 1970s. This reconstruction exercise has been carried out in
Angus Maddison emerged as the central hub in the network of historical national
and made them internationally comparable as far as it was possible. The broadening of
the database has been one of the major achievements of the worldwide network of
the measurement and analysis of productivity growth, has been another major field of
research. The emergence of the Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) method was aimed at
resolving the problem caused by exchange rates, which are not good indicators of the
Kenessey, Heston and Summers (1975) laid the foundation for a system of international
comparisons of GDP and this made it possible to integrate the long-term growth of GDP
real GDP time-series (Maddison, 2001, 2003), it was obvious that the availability of
historical GDP estimates in Asian countries was found wanting (See Figure 1.2).
In Asian countries, historical GDP estimates pertaining to the period prior to World
War II was initiated by two major research teams. The first major collaborative research
project was The Long-term Economic Statistics of Japan 1867-1965 7 , led by the
Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University and was carried out over the
6
It must be noted here that historical GDP estimates of Singapore conducted in this study does not convert to international
comparative prices such as PPP or Geary-Khamis Prices due to the absolute deficiencies of necessary data to initiate this study.
7
It was in 1957 when professors Ohkawa, Shinohara, Umemura and others of the Institute of Economic Research at the
Hitotsubashi University launched a monumental project to estimate a GDP series of Japan from the Meiji period onwards. The
project was completed in 1988, when the last volume in the series Long-term Economic Statistics of Japan, 1867-1965 was
published. The project started in 1957 was mainly financed by the Rockefeller Foundation.
10
period 1957-88. This project also covered former Japanese colonies such as Korea and
Taiwan. The second research group undertook a study of the Netherland Indies, and was
led by Creutzberg, P and P. Boomgaard (1975-96) from the Royal Tropical Institute.
They compiled 16 volumes of historical statistics on the Netherland Indies entitled The
These two research efforts were regarded as one of the first long-term projects in the
Asian region. Other than these two collaborative research projects, other studies were
made by individual scholars. The commencement of all these research work started in
the 1960s. Unfortunately, other countries did not initiate similar research. In the 1960s,
in fact, Simon Kuznets visited some Asian countries and investigated the possibility of
starting a project on the construction of historical GDP estimates in Asian countries but
proceeded no further as it was ascertained that the project would require skilled
statistical specialists who were in short supply in these countries.8 In fact, reliability of
GDP estimates in the early 1950’s in the selected countries were highly questionable
(Oshima, Harry T., 1956). Attention was focused on the creation of reliable modern
GDP estimates rather than historical GDP estimates (Goh Keng Swee, 1956).
GDP in Asian countries was attempted for many decades. The rapid and sustained
economic growth recorded in East Asian countries since the 1970s encouraged further
University organized the Asian Historical Statistics Project for the period 1995-2000
with Konosuke Odaka as its project director.9 In 1998, H.R.H. Raja Dr. Nazrin Shah
embarked on a study to compute GDP estimates of Peninsular Malaysia for the period
8
According to Oshima (1997), upon the request of the Ford Foundation, Kuznets embarked on a trip to explore the possibilities of
studying pre-war Asian economic conditions soon after World War II. However, his conclusion was that with the exception of Japan,
this would not be a feasible project. He suggested to the Ford Foundation that before undertaking any economic analysis, it would
be necessary to start with training statistical survey specialists in the various Asian countries.
9
The interim Report on the Asian Historical Statistics Database project was released (Odaka, Konosuke, 2007). The listed
countries are Taiwan, Vietnam, Mainland China, Korea, Thailand, India/Pakistan, Indonesia, Russia, Egypt and Turkey, Philippines,
Central Asia and Russia and Japan. Malaya and Singapore are not included in this project.
11
1900-39.10 In fact, this study on the GDP estimates of Singapore is very much indebted
Figure 1.2
Historical GDP Estimates Available in Asian Countries prior to World War II
1890
1900
1913
1929-38
East Asia Korea 1911-
1870
Taiwan 1912-
Hong Kong
1913
Indonesia (Java) 1870-1941
Philippines
1870
1902-40
Peninsular Malaysia 1900-39
Singapore 1900-39
Southeast
Thailand
1890
1929
Asia
1870
1938
1913
Burma
1901
1906
1911
1916
1921
1926
1931
1936
Vietnam
Laos
Cambodia
India 1884-
Sri Lanka 1870-
South Asia Bangladesh
Nepal
1870
1913
Pakistan
Sources:
(Japan) Ohkawa, Shinohara and Umemura (eds.) (1974)
(China) Maddison, Angus (1998)
(Korea) Mizoguchi and Umemura (eds.) (1988)
(Taiwan) Mizoguchi and Umemura (eds.) (1988)
(Indonesia (Java)) Eng, P. Van Der (2002)
(Philippines) Hooley, Richard (2005)
(Peninsular Malaysia) Nazrin, Raja (2000, 2002 and 2006)
(India) Sivasubramonian, S (2000)
(Sri Lanka) Snodgrass, D.R. (1966)
As is shown in Table 1.1, data on national income was only available for the entity
Singapore) for the period 1947-55. Subsequently, the official estimates of the Federation
of Malaya for the period 1956-60 were computed by the Department of Statistics,
Federation of Malaya. Additionally, Rao, B. provided another set of GDP estimates for
the Federation of Malaya for the period 1947-55. In the case of Singapore, the first
estimate of the national income of Singapore was prepared by Benham, Frederik (1959)
for the year 1956. Subsequently, unofficial GNP figure was constructed by Department
10
Nazrin (2000, 2002 and 2006).
12
of Statistics, Singapore for the years 1957-60. For the same period, no GDP figures
were available for Singapore.11 Official GDP figures were computed by the Department
Table 1.1
Malaya and Singapore: Gross National Product and Gross Domestic Product,
1947-60 (At Market Prices $ Million)
In SNA, there are four accounts of the nation, namely Gross Domestic Product
Account, Income and Outlay Account, Capital Transactions Account and Balance of
Payments Account. Out of these accounts, the basic measure of the output arising from
economic activity is known as Gross Domestic Product (GDP). The first question that
must be answered is what constitutes an economic activity, since this determines what
falls within the scope of the national accounting system. There is no difficulty in
defining as economic those activities that result in the production of goods and services
for sale on the market. There is also general agreement that government activities in the
areas of public administration, law and order, health, education, and social services (and
13
counted as economic activity, even though their output is not sold on the market.
However, SNA does not include unpaid services rendered by housewives and other
household members. Once the boundary of economic activity has been established, as
Figure 1.3
The Components of GDP from Production, Income and Expenditure Approach
A B C
14
The first approach looks at output. It measures the contribution of output made by
each producer, by deducting from the total value of its output the value of the goods and
services it has purchased from other producers and used up in producing its own output.
What is left is the value added by the producer in question; what is used up in
bank services plus import duties), the total value added by all producers equals GDP at
market prices. This method of GDP compilation is commonly known as the production
approach to GDP. The second approach considers the costs incurred by the producer
within his own operation: the incomes paid out to employees, net indirect taxes less
subsidies, consumption of fixed capital, and the operating surplus; this also adds up to
value added. This method is often called the income approach. The third method, known
as the expenditure approach, looks at the final uses of the country’s output for private
capital formation and net exports of goods and services; in other words, it shows what
becomes of the output once it has been produced.12 Conceptually, the results derived
from each of these three approaches should be identical but invariably different methods
of estimating GDP will not yield similar statistical results due to leakages.
an input-output table, displays production and cost inter-relationships. This chart shows
how the various types of input into economic activity (listed in the rows of the chart)
flow through the economy and are purchased by various users (listed in the columns).
The chart is divided into three quadrants. Quadrant I is concerned with the intermediate
consumption of producers. Across the top, producers are grouped by the kind of activity
in which they engage. Down the side, the goods and services which they purchase for
use in production are listed by type. Although the labels on the columns and rows of this
15
Figure 1.4
Integrated Framework for Measurement of GDP
Intermediate consumption by kind of activity Final demand Gross Output
(Column
Industry
14+20)
Producers' of government
services
Producers of private non-
profit services to
households
Domestic services of
households
Total All Activities
(Column 1-13)
Government Final
Consumption Expenditure
Private Final Consumption
Expenditure
Gross Capital Formation
Exports of Goods and
Services
Less: Imports of Goods and
Services
Total Final Expenditure
(Column 11-15)
Agriculture, hunting,
forestry and fishery
Mining and quarrying
Manufacturing
Electricity, gas and
water
Construction
Wholesale and retail
trade and restaurants
and hotels
Transport, storage and
communication
Financing, insurance,
real estate and business
services
Owner-occupied
dwellings
Community, social and
personal services
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21
Agriculture, hunting, forestry and fishery 1
Manufacturing 3
Construction 5
Wholesale and retail trade and restaurants and
Industry
6
hotels
Transport, storage and communication 7 Quadrant I (Intermediate Consumption) Quadrant II (Final Expenditure)
Financing, insurance, real estate and business
8
services
Owner-occupied dwellings 9
Compensation of employees 17
Quadrant III (Value Added) B
Costs
Operating surplus 18
Source: Department of International Economic and Social Affairs, United Nations (1986:6)
16
Non-agricultural goods, for example, may be produced by establishments classed in
goods and services classified elsewhere. The column heading refer to whole
establishments, classified by their principal activity. The rows, on the other hand, refer
to goods and services, classified by their own nature. The subtotal row at the bottom of
this quadrant shows total intermediate consumption of producers engaged in each kind
of activity. The sub-total column at the right side of this quadrant divides the same total
Quadrant III (the lower left-hand corner) is concerned with the rest of the production
costs of producers (that is, costs that do not arise from purchases from other producers).
These remaining costs are the components of value added as listed in (B) of Figure 1.3
Addition across the rows of this quadrant yields, in the total column at the right, the
entries in Figure 1.4. Adding down the columns yields, in the total row at the bottom of
Quadrant III, the entries in (A) of Figure 1.3. The grand total row, Gross Input, at the
bottom of the chart is the sum of all production costs and profits of the producers
classified in each kind of activity; it is, of course, necessarily equal to the sum of
intermediate consumption and value added. Thus, another way of deriving (A) of Figure
1.3 is by subtracting the total row of Quadrant I (intermediate consumption), from the
grand total row representing Gross Input. Finally, Quadrant II (the upper right-hand
corner) is concerned with the final uses of GDP. Across the top, the column headings
are the categories of final expenditure that appear in Figure 1.4. The total column at the
right side of this quadrant contains the entries of (C) of Figure 1.3. The total column at
the right side of this quadrant shows the kinds of goods and services that go to make up
GDP.
17
The grand total column (Gross Output), at the extreme right of the chart is the sum
others (shown in Quadrant II), classified by type of goods and services. Total gross
output is, by definition, equal to total gross input. It is seldom the case that national
accountant will be able to use all three approaches for making complete and
dearth of data. Wherever possible, however, the use of more than one approach is
desirable, not only because of the analytic usefulness of the figures but also as a check
1.3 Statistical Sources and Possible Approach for the Construction of GDP of
Singapore
estimates has more serious constrains on the grounds that every step in the estimating
important step in constructing GDP estimates. Ideally, estimates using the three
these estimates can be evaluated one against the other. However, this is again
Prior to World War II, the British colonial authority compiled statistical information
on British Malaya based on the constituent administrative units, namely the Straits
Settlements, Federated Malay States and the five individual Unfederated Malay States.
Among these administrative units, the Straits Settlements had the most complete and
18
data on Singapore prior to World War II, namely the Blue Book, Straits Settlements,
1899-1938, Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions of The
United Kingdom, 1900-01, Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other
These reports provided detailed statistical figures on trade, market prices, agricultural
liabilities).
provided descriptive explanations and statistical data with regards to education, health
care, public works, and post and telecommunications. Apart from these reports, the
British colonial administration also released other specific data on Singapore. For
matters pertaining to economic indices, the Average Prices, Declared Trade Values,
Exchange, Currency and Cost of Living, Malaya, 1929-38 and 1948-51 provided
average market prices on major consumer items and cost of living indices as reflected
by consumption standards which were based on ethnicity and occupation. In the case of
trade, the Appendix to the Report on Trade, Straits Settlements, 1896-1906, 1908-17,
1921-28; British Malaya, Return of Foreign Imports and Exports, 1921-39 and Foreign
trade by (i) class of goods and (ii) country of origin and destination. Private
investment in perennial crops was compiled and published in the Malayan Agricultural
19
Statistics, 1931-39, 1947-49. The Reports on Population Censuses (Straits Settlements,
1871,1881,1891,1901 and 1911) and British Malaya, (1921, 1931, 1947 and 1957)
geographical distribution. For inter-censal years, the yearly reports entitled Registration
of Births and Deaths, Straits Settlements, 1899-1939 and the Administration Report on
and gender.
The end of World War II and the Japanese occupation of British Malaya in 1945
marked the end of the Straits Settlements as an administrative unit. Singapore was
compiling and publishing its own statistical data. Annual Report, the Colony of
Singapore provided a wide range of statistical figures and descriptive information while
the Financial Statement of Singapore and Singapore’s External Trade contained detailed
data on government finance and trade respectively. To recapitulate, the British colonial
authority had in place devices to collect and compile a wide range of statistical
Figure 1.5 illustrates the availability of relevant statistical information for the
Other than these two components, unfortunately, no direct statistical information was
available to comply with the definitions of SNA 68. Under these circumstances,
alternative methods were used depending on the availability of the relevant statistical
data.
20
Figure 1.5
Singapore: List of Source Materials Utilized for the Computation of Each
Component of GDP, (Expenditure Approach), 1900-39 and 1950-60
Private Final Government Final Gross Fixed Capital Formation Net Exports of Goods and Services
Consumption Consumption
Investment on Investment on Investment on Net Exports of Net Exports of
Expenditure by Expenditure
Construction Machinery and Cultivated Goods Services
Resident
Equipments Assets (Merchandize)
Househoulds
Abbreviations:
AP Average Prices, Declared Trade Values, Exchange, Currency and cost of Living, Malaya
ARCCS Administration Reports on City Council, Singapore
ARCPSS Annual Report, Chinese Protectorate, Straits Settlements
ARCS Annual Report, Colony of Singapore
AREDS Annual Report, Education Department, Colony of Singapore / State of Singapore
AREDSS Annual Report, Education Department, Straits Settlements
ARGMSS Annual Report, Government Monopoly Department, Straits Settlements
ARIISS Annual Report, Indian Immigrations, Straits Settlements
ARLDS Annual Report, Labour Department, Colony of Singapore
ARMDS Annual Report, Medical Department, the Colony of Singapore / State of Singapore
ARMDSS Annual Report, Medical Department, Straits Settlements
ARRBDMS Annual Report, Registration of Births and Deaths Marriages and Persons, Singapore
ARRBDSS Annual Report, Registration of Birth and Death, Straits Settlements
ARSHB Annual Report, Singapore Harbour Board
ARSM Administration Report on the Singapore Municipality
ARS Annual Report, the Colony of Singapore / State of Singapore
ARSS Annual Report, Straits Settlements
ARTCFMS Annual Report, Trade and Custom, Federated Malay States
ARTSS Appendix to the Report on Trade, Straits Settlements
BM British Malaya, Return of Foreign Imports and Exports
CSS Population Census, Straits Settlements
CBM Population Census of British Malaya
CMU Population Census of Malayan Union
CS Population Census of Colony of Singapore
FSCS Financial Statements, the Colony of Singapore
FSSS Financial Statements, Straits Settlements
FTM Foreign Trade of Malaya
MAS Malayan Agricultural Statistics
MSBFM Monthly Statistical Bulletins, Federation of Malaya
SET Singapore External Trade
SSBB Straits Settlements, Blue Book
STCOPUK Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions of the United Kingdom
STCPP Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions and Protectorates
STBCPP Statistical Tables Relating to British Colonies, Possessions and Protectorates
21
In view of the nature of data that was available, the expenditure approach was
selected for the purpose at hand. The other two approaches, namely the production
approach and the income approach were found to be not feasible since the data required
introduction to the issue at hand. Chapter 2 shows the methodology employed for the
Expenditure (GFCE), Gross Capital Formation (GCF) and Net Exports of Goods and
Services in both current and constant (1914) prices. Chapter 3 examines the result of
GDP estimates by conducting consistency checks between estimated figures and official
figures and also by comparing with available historical GDP estimates of other
of GDP are provided. Additionally, the overall pattern of Singapore’s GDP growth for
the entire twentieth century is commented upon. Based on this, two types of empirical
twentieth century.
Chapter Four examines economic instability and economic growth. This topic deals
with four related issues, namely (i) has the degree of output volatility dampened over
time? (ii) what are the explanatory variables for the decline in output volatility? (iii)
how has economic instability impacted on economic growth? and (iv) comparison of
fiscal behavior and economic growth. This study firstly identifies the features of fiscal
22
policy during the British colonial period and describe the transition of government fiscal
analysis whereby the validity of Wagner’s Law is tested. For analytical purposes two
econometric techniques, namely cointegration test and Granger causality test were
employed.
23
CHAPTER TWO
2.1 Introduction
This chapter will provide the estimating procedures for each component of GDP,
and Net Exports of Goods and Services. Each component would be discussed in the
following manner. Firstly, the definition of each component will be explained briefly.
Subsequently, an attempt will be made to identify the data availability for the period
under study. Thirdly, the methodologies employed for the construction of the respective
components of GDP in current prices would be explained. Finally, the choice of the
most suitable deflator to obtain constant prices for each component is described. It will
be noted here that for the periods 1900-39 and 1950-60, 1914 was selected as the base
year. This is mainly because the cost of living index which was utilized for the
construction of Consumer Price Indices set 1914 as a base year. The year 1914 was
Before providing the detail explanations on the methodology employed for the
estimation exercise. As is discussed in Chapter One, the concept and definition of each
data series in the British colonial documents are not fully available to construct each
component of GDP. Thus, various creative methodologies were applied but always
24
consciously conforming, as closely as was possible, to the definitions as outlined in
Presently, household budget surveys and commodity flow tables are widely utilized
for the computation of PFCE. However, these approaches could not be employed due to
arriving at these estimates. As presented in Figure 2.1, two distinctive approaches were
employed viz the direct and indirect approach. In the direct approach, data on
consumption expenditure pertaining to opium, education, medical fees and utilities (gas,
water supply and electricity) was gathered independently from various official sources.
The indirect approach involved the estimate of PFCE on food, beverages and tobacco,
clothing, rent, domestic servants and transport. Summing up the expenditures derived
from these two approaches provides us the PFCE in current and constant prices.
Figure 2.1
Steps of Estimating Private Final Consumption Expenditure, 1900-39 and 1950-60
Direct Component Indirect Component
Beverage &
Food Clothing Rent
Tobacco
Transport Servants Clubbing Miscellaneous
25
The indirect approach estimates involved a number of steps. Firstly, six
consumption standards were classified based on the recognition that there are significant
differences in consumption levels and expenditure patterns exist among ethnic groups.
Subsequently, the current per capita consumption expenditure of each major object of
consumption was identified for each standard. These figures were then deflated by the
consumer price indices of each major object of consumption to obtain the expenditure in
constant prices. Real per capita consumption expenditure of each major object of
consumption of each standard was then adjusted based on the changes in real income
over time taking into account the income elasticities of demand by each major object of
consumption. For example, annual figures on PFCE were computed for food for the
European standard in both constant and current prices as follows. If in the base year (t),
the real per capita expenditure on food for European standard is RPCFt and if the real
wage indices13 increases from 1 in year t to 1.2 in year t+1, real per capita expenditure
If the real earnings index increases to 1.5 in year t+2, per capita food expenditure in
Real per capita expenditure of the European standard on food for the period 1900-39
was then multiplied by the population of each year of the European Standard to obtain
the real PFCE of the European Standard on food for each reference year. The derived
figures were then inflated by the food indices to arrive at the PFCE in current prices.
Similar procedures were applied for each major object of consumption for the six
consumption standards. PFCE in the domestic market was then derived by aggregating
the figures of the direct components and indirect components. In order to obtain PFCE
26
Government final consumption expenditure (GFCE) was derived by deducting from
the government output (goods and services), the sales of other goods and services
produced by the producers of government services (Please see Figure 2.2). Output of
Council of Singapore and Rural Boards.14 In the case of government sales of goods and
services, school fees and hospital fees were identified and deducted from government
Figure 2.2
Steps involved for the Estimation of GFCE, 1900-39 and 1950-60
Step 1 Estimation of output of producers’ government services at current prices
construction, machinery and equipment and cultivated assets. Inventories include stocks
total construction output based on the first construction survey in 1972. Total
construction expenditure that went into fixed capital formation was then derived by
deducting from total output of construction, the expenditures incurred on repairs and
maintenance.
14
Military expenditure on capital formation items have been treated as intermediate consumption of goods and services and form
part and parcel of output.
27
Figure 2.3
Steps involved for the Estimation of Construction Output Capitalized, 1900-39
and 1950-60
In the case of investment on machinery and equipment (M&E), it was assumed that
the M&E produced locally during the period was negligible for the period under study.
This means that total net imports valued at market prices was equivalent to total
investments in M&E. Net imports of M&E at c.i.f. values were obtained from official
trade statistics. No commodity taxes were levied against M&E which meant that the c.i.f.
(basic) and producers’ values were identical. As is presented in Figure 2.4, trade and
transport margins were added to producers’ value to arrive at market prices. The final
step was to determine what proportion of net imports was to be capitalized. Some of
these imports would have been used as inputs into construction activity and some as part
Figure 2.4
Steps involved for the Estimation of Machinery and Equipment Capitalized,
1900-39 and 1950-60
In preparing the estimates on the investment for cultivated assets, only rubber and
coconut were selected since other perennial crops were found to be negligible. All
28
expenses sunk into perennial crops prior to their reaching the bearing age were treated
as part and parcel of capital expenditure. As presented in Figure 2.5, three types of
information were utilized for the above computation, namely, newly planted acreage for
each year, number of years it takes for the crop to reach bearing age and annual cost per
acre of bringing the crop into production. The yearly estimates of expenditure on
cultivated assets at different years of maturity were derived by multiplying the total
immature acreage with the corresponding base year estimates of cost of investment per
acre at different stages of maturity. These yearly estimates were then aggregated to
arrive at the yearly estimates of real capital expenditure. Total real investment in
cultivated assets was then inflated by the nominal rubber tapper’s earnings indices. For
both rubber and coconut, a distinction was made between smallholding and estate
cultivation.
Figure 2.5
Steps involved for the Estimation of Investment for Cultivated Assets,
1900-39 and 1950-60
Step 3 Computation of Cultivated Assets for various period with different base year
Inventory as defined in SNA 68, consists largely of raw materials and supply,
finished or partly finished products awaiting sale and unpaid work in progress on assets
which take a long time to produce. The colonial government records, however, did not
constraints of data availability, the official figures available after 1960 were utilized. It
was observed that there are positive correlation between GDP growth and value of
changes in stock (See Figure 2.6). Based on the prevailing economic conditions as
29
reflected in the level of GDP growth rate, the percentage contribution of changes in
Figure 2.6
Steps involved for the Estimation of Changes in Stock, 1900-39 and 1950-60
Observe relationship between GDP growth and level of change in stock for post-war
Step 1
Singapore
Export and import statistics cover transactions of goods and services between the
residents of one country and non-residents of another. Data on merchandize imports and
exports of Singapore were available for the period 1900-27. For the period 1928-39, 50-
60, W.G. Huff’s estimates (1994) were applied. Exports and imports of services were
captured in this estimate by using port and other related statistics (See Figure 2.7).
Figure 2.7
Steps involved for the Estimation of Imports and Exports of Goods and Services,
1900-39 and 1950-60
Real GDP figures were arrived at by deflating each component of aggregate demand
in current prices by various deflators into constant 1914 prices for the period 1900-39
and 1950-60. Figure 2.8 portrays the various deflators used in the deflation process. For
example, CPI and Import and Export Unit Value Indices were computed using the
Laspeyres Price Indices15. Unit values of commodities were derived from the quotients
of values and quantities. As it was not feasible to derive an outright continuous unit
15 Pn
Laspeyres Price Indices computed using the following formula; ∑ PnQo = ∑ Po
* PoQo
∑ PoQo ∑ PoQo
where Pn = Price in current period
Qo = Quantity in base period.
Currently, Department of Statistics, Singapore uses the Laspeyres method in computing Consumer Price Indices as well as Import
and Export Unit Value Indices.
30
value indices series due to changing composition of exports, the sample period was
broken down into several but overlapping intervals with different base years. The
criteria for the selection of intervals and their base years include relative stability of the
shares of commodities and a relatively tranquil year. In this exercise, the base year of
each interval is identified based on the proximity of the price of the commodity that
commands the largest weight to its average price level during the corresponding interval.
Figure 2.8
Summary of Deflator Employed by Each Component of GDP
GDP Components Method Applied / Deflators
Private Final Consumption Expenditure
Indirect Approach Consumer Price Indices for each major object of
consumption
Direct Approach Consumer Price Indices
Government Final Consumption Expenditure
Government Output
Compensation of Employees Consumer Price Indices
Intermediate Consumption Consumer Price Indices
Sales of Government Services Consumer Price Indices
Gross Capital Formation
Cultivated Assets Indian Rubber Tapper's Wage Indices
Construction Import Unit Value Indices of Cement
Machinery and Equipment UK Indices of Machinery and Plant
Changes in Stock Import Unit Value Indices
Exports of Goods and Services
Merchandize Export Unit Value Indices
Port (goods and services) UK Weighted Indices for Fuel and Light, Transport,
Communication and Other Services
Non-residents consumption in domestic market Consumer Price Indices
Imports of Goods and Services
Merchandize Import Unit Value Indices
2.2.1 Definition
the SNA68 is the actual total consumption of private households and non-profit
making institutions16 on current goods and services less sales of similar goods and
services. PFCE by resident households include purchases of goods and services made
16
Private non-profit institutions are basically private organizations such as clubs, clan associations, religious organizations and
trade unions. This series, however, does not take into account the PFCE of private non-profit making institutions because the
magnitude of their final consumption expenditure is rather small or negligible.
31
abroad by resident households17 and excludes purchases by non-resident households
(e.g., by foreign tourists) made in the domestic market. Normally, PFCE made in the
number of approaches, namely (i) household budget survey method,18 (ii) commodity
flow approach,19 (iii) retail valuation method20 and (iv) retail sales method.21 In this
exercise, however, none of the methodologies described above could be used for the
estimation of the PFCE for the years 1900-39 and 1950-60 due to the dearth of data. No
household budget surveys or wholesale, retail and catering trades censuses were
conducted during the period 1900-39 for the entity of Singapore. In fact, the first
household budget survey in respect of Singapore was only conducted in 1947/48. This
survey, however, was not comprehensive since it only covered the pattern of
expenditure of Europeans and the higher income Asiatic group. The consumption of the
In Singapore, the first attempt at estimating PFCE in the domestic market was
conducted by Benham (1959) for the year 1956. In this exercise, he utilized net imports
17
In addition, net value of gifts sent abroad is taken into account.
18
Household budget survey method is the summation of household consumption expenditure to cover all households by inflating
the data collected in a sample household survey. However, the use of data from the household expenditure survey are subject to
three major constraints. Firstly, the household survey is based on a small sample of households and / or may refer to particular
groups of the population only. Secondly, respondents are reluctant to the provide actual expenditure pattern. Thirdly, the
household survey does not cover the rent of owner-occupied dwellings.
19
The commodity flow approach only can be adopted if we have fairly good statistics on production, imports, exports, capital
formation, intermediate consumption, stocks and other related statistics. The commodity flow table traces the use of a particular
commodity by various end-users, e.g. household consumers, intermediate consumption by industries, producers of government
services or other final demand. Based on the commodity flow table, it is relatively easy to construct an input/output table which can
then be used to determine the PFCE based on the movements of production of commodities, imports, etc. However, the coefficients
of the input/output tables should be revised from time to time but the construction of a commodity flow table itself is admittedly
time consuming.
20
Retail value method is utilized when primary information on household consumption is available in terms of quantities. The
household expenditure is then computed by multiplying the quantity consumed by the households by the retail prices paid by the
consumers. However, the compilation of appropriate average retail prices to value the quantities of commodities that households
consume or acquire may be difficult to obtain. Correct weights for geographical price differences, adjustments for variations in
quality, etc, are not available.
21
Retail sales method takes into account data on sales gathered from retailers and other outlets selling goods and services direct to
household consumers. Issues of apportioning items of expenditure between final consumption expenditure of households and the
intermediate consumption or gross capital formation of industries arises in instances of goods utilized by professional practitioners
and other individual proprietors both in production and in household consumption.
32
(quantity) of non durable, semi-durable and durable goods consumed by households and
multiplied them by the respective retail prices. In addition, locally produced goods
multiplying the quantity thus consumed by producer’s price (See Table 2.1).
Table 2.1
Singapore: Summary of Expenditure by Private Households
at Market Prices, 1956
Unfortunately, this methodology could not be employed for the period under study
since the required data was not available for this period. This being the scenario, we had
no other choice but to adopt an alternative technique of constructing the PFCE in the
domestic market.
The remainder of this section attempts to describe the data and methods used to put
together the PFCE series in constant and current prices. Basically two approaches were
combined to estimate the PFCE. PFCE on opium, education, medical services, utilities
and passenger rail transport were compiled for each year in current prices using the
direct approach. Expenditure on food and groceries, beverages and tobacco, clothing,
rent, domestic services, clubs, passenger transport (other than rail and ferry) and other
Summing up the expenditures from these two approaches in current and constant prices
gives us the PFCE in the domestic market in both current and constant prices. Further
33
adjustments were made by taking into account consumption made by residents outside
Singapore and deducting consumption of non-residents (eg. foreign tourists) made in the
domestic market.
education, medical fees, utilities (gas, water supply and electricity) was gathered
methodology that was then applied to derive estimates for years for which data was not
Opium consumption in Singapore prior to World War II was not unlawful and data
household opium consumption were made for Singapore for the period prior to World
War II. However, after World War II with household opium consumption not being
sanctioned by the government, there was no data available whatsoever on the household
consumption of opium. The paucity of this data meant that this component of PFCE was
The distribution and sale of opium in Singapore prior to World War II had
experienced many transitions. As shown in Figure 2.9, purchases and sales of opium
were entirely operated by Chinese revenue farms since the early nineteenth century. It
was not until 1910 that the British colonial authority took over the right for purchasing
and selling opium from Chinese revenue farms. Nevertheless, a majority of retail shops
that sold opium to consumers were operated by licensed private (Chinese) retailers. At
34
Figure 2.9
(a) Singapore: Transformation of Revenue Collection from (b) Singapore: Methods Adopted to Estimate The Private
Final Consumption the Sales of Opium, 1899-1939 Expenditure of Opium / Chandu, 1899-1939
1899 1899
1900 1900
1901 1901
1902 1902
1903 1903
1904 1904
1905 Chinese Revenue Farms only 1905
1906 1906
1907 1907
1908 1908
1909 1909
1910 1910
1911 1911
Total Tahil Sold x Retail Price
1912 1912
1913 1913
1914 1914
1915 1915
1916 Licenced Private Retail Shops 1916
1917 1917
1918 1918
1919 1919
1920 1920
1921 Government Monopoly 1921
1922 1922
1923 Department 1923 [1] Government Receipts from Sales of Opium / Chandu to [2] Government Receipts from Sales of Opium / Chandu to [3] Margins of Licenced
1924 1924 Consumers (Retail Prices) Licenced Private Retail Shops (Wholesale Prices) Private Retail Shops
1925 1925
1926 1926
1927 1927
1928 1928
1929 1929
1930 1930
1931 1931
1932 1932
1933 Government Monopoly Department 1933 [1] Government Receipts from Sales to Consumers of Opium / Chandu (Retail Prices)
1934 1934
1935 1935
1936 1936
1937 1937
1938 1938
1939 1939
0% 100%
Sources: Constructed based on the Straits Settlements and Federated Malay States Opium Commission, (1908) Commission Appointed to Inquire into Matters Relating to the Use of Opium in the Straits Settlements and the
Federated Malay States and British Malaya Opium Committee (1924), Proceedings of the British Malaya Opium Committee.
35
Between 1910 and 1926, the proportion of government retail shops increased
significantly. Eventually, licensed private retail shops were abolished by 1926 and fully
For the computation of the PFCE on opium in Singapore, three different procedures
were applied based on the availability of data on opium consumption (See Figure
2.1(b)). For the period 1899-1922, statistical information on the quantity of opium sold
to consumers and its retail price was utilized from the two reports by the Opium
Committee for the years 1908 and 1924. Subsequently, due to the deficiencies of
information on quantity sold and retail prices, government revenue figures on the sales
Settlements and the Blue Book, Straits Settlements were then utilized to estimate the
PFCE on opium for the period 1923-25, details of which are given in Table 2.2. It
should be noted that government revenue figures on the sale of opium as contained in
these two reports for the period 1923-25 did not fully represent the actual consumption
figures. The revenue figures for this period were estimated using a combination of (i)
government receipts from sales of opium to consumers in retail prices and (ii)
government receipts from sales of opium to licenced private retail shops at wholesale
prices. The wholesale price was adjusted to obtain the retail price by making use of the
1922 trade and transport margin which was estimated to be approximately 4.2%. For the
remaining period between 1926-39 the figures pertaining to government revenue from
the sale of opium to household consumers were directly obtained from the Annual
Table 2.2
Singapore: Methodology Adopted to Estimate PFCE on Opium for the period
1923-25
Gross Government Gross Government Revenue Gross Government Receipts from Trade and Dealers Receipts from Total Private Final
Revenue Receipts from Receipts from the Sales of Opium the Sales of Opium / Chandu to Transport Consumers (Retail Prices) Consumption of Opium /
the Sales of Opium / / Chandu to Consumers (Retail Retail Shops (Wholesale Prices) ) Margins (%) ($) Chandu ($)
Chandu ($) Prices) ($) ($)
[1] [2] [3]= [1]x[2] [4] [5]=[1]x[4] [6] [7]=[5]x(1+[6]) [8]=[3]+[7]
36
2.2.2.1.2 Education and Medical fees
Total school fees collected by the Department of Education and Education Board
were utilized as expenditure on education. The figures for the period 1900-39 were
extracted from the Blue Book, Straits Settlements and Annual Report, Education
Singapore were utilized to obtain the information for the period 1948-56 and 1957-60
respectively.22
For medical expenditure, revenue collected in the form of hospital fees by the
from the Blue Book, Straits Settlements, Annual Report, Medical Department, Straits
Penang. For some years, the related information was not available. Estimates were
derived by employing the average ratio of Singapore’s revenue collected from hospital
fees in relation to that of Penang. For the period 1947-60, figures on hospital fees were
compiled from Annual Report, Medical Department, Colony of Singapore, 1947-56 and
In the case of Singapore, revenue collection for utilities was undertaken by the
water were taken as final expenditure on utilities. Expenditure by businesses and public
authorities was excluded, as far as possible. However, it must be noted that in some
instances the government publications did not clearly distinguish the revenue obtained
from private as against public users. In such instances, the average ratio of private use
against total use was used to interpolate and derive the estimated figures. For the period
22
For the period of 1953-58, unfortunately, no figures were presented in The Colony of Singapore, Report of the Educational
Department. Considering these contraints, a compound growth rate (11.6%) was derived from given figures for 1952 and 1959
respectively. The figures for the years 1953-58 were then computed based on this compound growth rate.
37
between 1900-39, figures were compiled from the Annual Administration Report on
Singapore Municipality while for the years 1947-60, the Annual Administration Report
entirely different method. The remainder of this section will explain the process of
38
Figure 2.10
Flow Chart for Computation of PFCE in Domestic Market at Current Prices, 1900-39
(11) (12) (13)
Direct Approach (Current Prices)
1. Opium / chandu
2. Health
3. Education
4. Utilities
5. Passenger Transport (rail and ferry)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)=(7) x (8) (10)
Indirect Population / Per capita Consumer Price Per capita Final Real Wage Income Elasticities of Per capita Private Final Population Private Final Inflate real PFCE
Consumption Consumption Indices of Major Consumption Index Demand by Major Object of Consumption Numbers by Consumption of Major Objects
Approach Standards Expenditure of Objects of Expenditure of Consumption and Standard Expenditure of Major Consumption Expenditure of Consumption (Plus)
Major Objects of Consumption Major Objects of Objects of Consumption Standard by Major by Price Indices Direct
Consumption and (1914=100) Consumption and (Food=0.7)
(Food =0.8) and Standards in 1914 Object of (1914 =100) Purchases
Standards in Standards in 1914 (Beverages and Tobacco =1.0) prices Consumption Abroad,
1. Food and Groceries Current Prices Prices for Selected (Clothing =1.0) and Standard Resident
(Rent = 0.8) Households in
for Selected Years in 1914 prices
2. Beverages and Tobacco (Transport =1.0)
Years Current
(Domestic Servants =1.0)
Private Final Prices (Straits $) Private Final
3. Clothing (Club 1.0) Consumption Consumption
Expenditure in (Minus) Expenditure by
4. Rent Domestic Direct Resident
Market in Purchases in Households in
5. Domestic Servants Current Prices The Domestic = Current Prices
(Asiatic and Eurasian + Market, Non- (Straits $)
Clerical Standards and Malay Labour Resident
European Standard only) Standard 1936 1900-39 Series Households in
Current
6. Passenger Transport Prices (Straits $)
Chinese
other than rail and ferry Labour
(Asiatic and Eurasian 1936 1900-39 Series
Standard
Clerical Standards and
European Standard only)
Indian Labour
Standard 1933 1900-39 Series
7. Clubs (European
Standard only)
Asiatic
Clerical 1930 1900-39 Series
Standard
Eurasian
Clerical 1930 1900-39 Series
Standard
European
Standard 1930 1900-39 Series
Miscellaneous
39
2.2.2.2.1 Estimate of Population and Consumption Standards (STEP 1)
In most countries, population censuses are carried out on a decennial basis, with the
more frequent basis. In modern times, a Post Enumeration Survey (PES) is often carried
evaluating the completeness and accuracy in terms of coverage and content, that is the
data on population characteristics collected in the census (Muhsam, 1960). The results
of the PES often serve as a basis for adjusting the population census count for under-
there are two approaches to conducting a population census, namely the de facto and the
de jure methods. While the de facto approach enumerates persons in terms of the place
where they were physically present on Census Night, the de jure method involves
enumerating persons according to their usual place of residence at the time of the census
This population figure derived from the population census was then used as a base
excess of births over deaths) and net immigration (ie excess of immigration / arrivals
over emigration / departures) that had occurred over the one-year period. This method
of arriving at annual population estimates continues until the next population census is
held whereby the figure from latest census will be used as a new base to make post-
It should be noted here that although the population censuses were generally
conducted in March or April, for purposes of this exercise the population census figure
has been taken to represent the population as at 1st January in the year that the census
23
Department of Economic and Social Affairs Statistics Division, United Nations (1997: 63)
40
was conducted. It was felt that this would to some extent neutralize the phenomenon of
For the period 1900-30, the total estimated population of the Colony of Singapore
was available in the Annual Report, Registration of Birth and Death, Straits Settlements.
This annual report provided the total estimated end-year population as well as the
number of births and deaths. The figure presented in this report yielded relatively steady
rates of population growth for the period 1901-10 (2.3-2.4%) and 1911-20 (2.8%).
However, kinks in population growth rates were observed between the Census year and
the year preceding to it, much of it being attributed to the rather inaccurate data
pertaining to net immigration. Information relating to the issue of net immigration was
documented in the Annual Report, Chinese Protectorate, Straits Settlements. The report
provided the number of Chinese arrivals into Singapore.24 These figures, however, did
not reflect the actual number of immigrants to Singapore. Annual Report, Indian
The coverage of this report, however, was limited only to immigrants arriving and
departing from Penang. The number of Indians who proceeded to Singapore was not
Given the above data constraints, the following estimation procedure was applied.
Firstly, the population numbers recorded in The Report of the Population Census of
1947 for the years 1901, 1911, 1921 and 1931 were set as the anchor figures. 25
Secondly, the inter-censal annual population estimates were obtained by adding to the
census base population the natural increase and net migration that occurred over each
year. While the figures on births and deaths were deemed to be reasonable the same
could not be said of net migration which was obtained by deducting departures from
24
Chinese immigrants who were examined on board in Singapore mainly proceeded to FMS, Penang and Malacca in the territory
of British Malaya & Bangkok and Rangoon (outside of British Malaya).
25
The census data ordinarily pertained to the months of March and April. This is, however, assumed to pertain to January 1 of the
relevant years. It is hoped that this procedure would largely neutralize the phenomenon of under-counting of the population in the
census years.
41
arrivals. 26 As a consequence there was a big difference between the inter-censal
population estimate and the census figure for the same year. Since it was strongly
believed that the figures obtained from the censuses must be given more credence than
the constructed inter-censal figures, the inter-censal figures were adjusted to bring them
in line with the census figures. To clarify this estimation procedure, Figure 2.11
illustrates the adjustments applied for the years 1921-31, as an example. To begin with,
the 1921 census population figure was used as the base figure representing the
population as at 1st January 1921. Subsequently, the annual natural increase and net
immigration figures were added year by year from the 1st of January 1921 to the 1st of
January 1931. Logically, the inter-censal derived figure on the 31st December 1930 (or
1st January 1931) should be identical to that of the 1931 census figure but the derived
inter-censal figure was found to be much higher than the 1931 Census figure. Thus an
exercise had to be undertaken to reconcile these figures. The birth and death figures
were left unchanged while net migration bore the full brunt of the adjustments. The
adjustment was made in the following manner. Firstly, the net immigration for the
period 1st January 1921 – 1st January 1931 was obtained as a residual by taking the
population growth (obtained by taking the 1931 census population minus the 1921
census population) less the natural increase between 1st January 1921–1st January 1931.
The ratio of this residual net migration figure in relation to the sum of yearly net
immigration between 1921-31 (1st January) was then used as an adjustment factor and
applied to the latter. The resulting adjusted net immigration figures when added to the
figures of natural increase for each year of the 10-year period respectively using 1921
census population as the base would yield intercensal population estimates in line with
26
Annual Report, Chinese Protectorate Department, Straits Settlements provided the number of Chinese arrivals and departures
during the year. This number of net immigrants, however, is far different from figure in Annual Report, Registration of Birth and
Death, Straits Settlements. This is because Annual Report, Chinese Protectorate Departments, Straits Settlements regards Singapore
as the entry and exit point of Chinese migration to British Malaya.
42
Figure 2.11
Singapore: Methodology to Derive Adjusted Total Population
For the period 1931-60, the Report on the Registration of Birth and Deaths,
Malayan Union, 1940-1946 and Annual Report, Registration of Births and Deaths
Marriages and Persons for the year 1965, Singapore provided figures on mid-year
hitherto had been deemed to be grossly inaccurate, were then accepted as reliable
figures based on the statements made in the Population Census Report of 1947.27 The
estimated mid-year population for Singapore for individual years as well as annual
population growth rates for the period 1900-39 and 1947-60 is given in Table 2.3.
27
It is only fair to point out that the pre 1930 figures for Chinese did not even purport to be migration statistics. They were merely
departmental records kept by the Chinese Protectorate in Singapore of arrivals there of deck passengers from China including
passengers in transit to other Malaysian ports or other countries and of departures to China alone. Naturally, the use of these figures
on the assumption that they were genuine migration statistics provided absurdly high estimates. There was gross under- counting of
departures (Census Report 1947:28). However the whole system of collecting migration statistics had been completely overhauled
in 1930 and subsequently the figures were as complete as could reasonably be expected though, doubtless, small movements by
junk or boat to and from China and Indonesia and over the Siamese border went unrecorded (Census Report, 1947:28).
43
Table 2.3
Singapore: Mid-year Population, 1900-39 and 1947-60
expenditure patterns between ethnic groups, between rural and urban areas and between
series, an attempt was made to take these differences in population characteristics into
account. To this end, expenditure patterns were classified into six consumption
standards for the periods 1900-39 and 1950-60. In this exercise, occupations were first
classified into professional / managerial, clerical and manual and this classification
scheme was then used alongside the information on ethnicity to establish the total
number of employed for the various consumption standards mentioned above. For
example, it was assumed that Eurasian manual workers shared the same lifestyle as their
Indian counterparts and were consequently placed in the Indian labor standard. Non-
European standard. Altogether, six benchmark years are involved that generally
44
corresponds with the availability of data on the total number of employed by occupation
and by ethnic group in Singapore. Those years include 1901, 1911, 1921, 1931, 1947
and 1957. Figures for inter-censal years were estimated based on approximations from
benchmark years as no breakdown figures of employment are available for those years.
Hence, 1901 has been used as the reference year for the period 1900-10, 1911 for 1911-
20, 1921 for 1921-30, 1931 for 1931-39, 1947 for 1947-56 and 1957 for 1957-60.
However, census data of 1901 and 1911 does not provide information on population by
occupation. Therefore, the population by occupational categories for the years 1900-20
was estimated based on the assumption that its distribution would be very much akin to
Table 2.4 lists out the six consumption standards based on the above-mentioned
occasions to the data obtained from source documents when it was felt that the number
of persons of a specific ethnic group reported for a particular occupational category was
incredibly large. For instance of the total Malays employed as accountants and
bookkeepers, it would be deemed that not all of them were actually in the
professional/managerial category and thus were adopting the European lifestyle. Instead,
it would be assumed, based on local knowledge, that only a certain percentage of them
actually fell in the professional/managerial category (European standard) while the rest
were in the clerical category (Asiatic clerical standard) and lists out the six consumption
28
For the years 1900-10 and 1911-20, the distribution of six consumption standards was based on the 1921 Census with slight
adjustments being made for 1901 and 1911 (See Table below). It was assumed that the composition of European Standard, Asiatic
clerical, Chinese labour standard and Indian labour standard was slightly smaller prior to 1921. On the other hand, the composition
of Malay labour standard was assumed to be higher based on the assumption that substantial immigration of this group occurred in
the early 20th century.
45
Table 2.4
Singapore: Population by Consumption Standard, 1899-1939 and 1947-60
European Asiatic Clerical Eurasian Clerical Chinese Labour Indian Labour Malay Labour Total
Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard
1899 13,667 19,362 2,278 135,535 15,945 41,002 227,790 1899
1900 13,566 19,219 2,261 134,530 15,827 40,698 226,100 1900
1901 13,911 19,707 2,318 137,948 16,229 41,732 231,845 1901
1902 14,310 20,273 2,385 141,912 16,696 42,931 238,508 1902
1903 14,720 20,853 2,453 145,970 17,173 44,159 245,328 1903
1904 15,141 21,449 2,523 150,145 17,664 45,422 252,345 1904
1905 15,575 22,065 2,596 154,457 18,171 46,726 259,591 1905
1906 16,023 22,699 2,670 158,890 18,693 48,068 267,042 1906
1907 16,483 23,351 2,747 163,456 19,230 49,449 274,717 1907
1908 16,958 24,023 2,826 168,162 19,784 50,873 282,626 1908
1909 17,445 24,714 2,908 172,999 20,353 52,336 290,754 1909
1910 17,946 25,423 2,991 177,962 20,937 53,837 299,096 1910
1911 18,503 27,137 3,084 185,643 21,586 52,424 308,378 1911
1912 19,118 28,039 3,186 191,815 22,304 54,167 318,630 1912
1913 19,750 28,967 3,292 198,160 23,042 55,959 329,169 1913
1914 20,400 29,920 3,400 204,683 23,800 57,801 340,005 1914
1915 21,069 30,901 3,511 211,389 24,580 59,695 351,144 1915
1916 21,756 31,909 3,626 218,286 25,382 61,642 362,602 1916
1917 22,464 32,947 3,744 225,385 26,208 63,647 374,393 1917
1918 23,192 34,015 3,865 232,691 27,057 65,710 386,530 1918
1919 23,941 35,113 3,990 240,206 27,931 67,832 399,013 1919
1920 24,711 36,243 4,118 247,933 28,829 70,014 411,849 1920
1921 27,757 46,973 4,270 258,351 34,162 55,513 427,026 1921
1922 29,018 49,107 4,464 270,088 35,714 58,035 446,426 1922
1923 30,082 50,907 4,628 279,989 37,023 60,163 462,792 1923
1924 31,165 52,741 4,795 290,074 38,357 62,330 479,462 1924
1925 32,515 55,025 5,002 302,638 40,018 65,030 500,229 1925
1926 33,811 57,218 5,202 314,698 41,613 67,621 520,163 1926
1927 35,143 59,473 5,407 327,100 43,253 70,286 540,660 1927
1928 36,493 61,758 5,614 339,668 44,915 72,986 561,434 1928
1929 37,864 64,077 5,825 352,424 46,602 75,727 582,519 1929
1930 37,403 63,298 5,754 348,138 46,035 74,807 575,435 1930
1931 36,586 61,915 2,814 354,606 50,658 56,287 562,866 1931
1932 35,489 60,059 2,730 343,972 49,139 54,599 545,988 1932
1933 33,443 56,595 2,573 324,135 46,305 51,450 514,500 1933
1934 34,140 57,775 2,626 330,894 47,271 52,523 525,228 1934
1935 37,200 62,954 2,862 360,555 51,508 57,231 572,310 1935
1936 39,206 66,348 3,016 379,993 54,285 60,316 603,163 1936
1937 42,347 71,663 3,257 410,436 58,634 65,149 651,486 1937
1938 46,152 78,104 3,550 447,323 63,903 71,004 710,037 1938
1939 47,292 80,032 3,638 458,365 65,481 72,756 727,564 1939
European Malay Clerical Chinese, Indian, Chinese Labour Indian Labour Malay Labour Total
Standard Standard Eurasian Clerical Standard Standard Standard
Standards
The second step involved the determination of the annual consumption expenditure
consumption. The methodology involved for estimating the per capita consumption
46
expenditure on major objects of consumption of the various consumption standards may
be described as follows:
From the 1930 Family Budget Survey of Singapore, it was established that a typical
Table 2.5
Singapore: European Family Budget, 1930
Major Objects of Consumption Straits $
Food 157.00
Market and Cold Storage 120.00
Groceries 30.00
Bakery 7.00
Beverages and Tobacco 47.63
Whisky, gin, vermouths, port, sherry, liquers, bitters and wine 36.03
Aerated waters 4.40
Tobacco 7.20
Servant 170.00
Boy, cook, tukang ayer, gardener, amah and syce 170.00
Transport 53.47
Petrol, tyres, insurance covering car, lubricating oil, repairs, etc. 53.47
Clothing 80.00
Man 25.00
Wife 40.00
Child in Malaya 15.00
Club 61.00
Entrance fees, subscriptions, expenses (caddies, etc) 61.00
Rent 80.00
Rent 80.00
Total 649.10
The above figure ($649.10) excludes expenditure on certain consumption items (e.g.
health, education and utilities) that has already been estimated via the direct approach.
This European budget also excludes consumption of a non-resident family member. Not
included also is the miscellaneous expenditure which would be taken into account only
at the final stages in the computation of PFCE of all standards. The monthly and yearly
47
b) The Eurasian / Asiatic Clerical Standards (1930)
It should be noted here that for the Eurasian and Asiatic clerical standards in
Singapore the procedure of deriving monthly and yearly per capita consumption
expenditures was similar to those adopted for the European standard as described above.
The source data was again obtained from the Family Budget Survey of 1930 for
The consumption of an adult of this standard was obtained from the Indian
Labourer’s Specimen Monthly Budget, 1933 as contained in the Annual Report, Johore,
Table 2.6
A Labourer’s Specimen Monthly Budget (1933)
Items Amount Unit of Price in cents Cost (Straits $)
Quantity per gantang,
chupak or kati
Food 3.855
Rice 6 gantang 20 1.200
Salt 1.5 chupak 3 0.045
Chilies 0.5 kati 17 0.085
Coriander 0.75 chupak 6 0.045
Tamarind 1.5 kati 7 0.105
Dhal 1.5 chupak 12 0.180
Green Peas 1 chupak 8 0.080
White beans 0.5 chupak 10 0.050
Onions 1 kati 6 0.060
Garlic 0.5 kati 8 0.040
Thalippu 0.5 chupak 24 0.120
Pepper 1.25 chupak 5 0.060
Turmeric 1.25 chupak 16 0.040
Curry Masala 0.040
Coconut Oil 1 bottle 10 0.100
Salted Fish 1 bottle 19 0.190
Mutton 1 kati 48 0.480
Vegetables 0.400
Potatoes 1 kati 5 0.050
Coffee 1 tin 12 0.120
Sugar 1 kati 4.5 0.045
Tin Milk 1 tin 18 0.180
Gingelly Oil 0.5 bottle 28 0.140
Tobacco 0.420
Betel nut & Tobacco 0.420
Clothing 0.250
Clothing 0.250
Per capita Adult Consumption 4.525
Source: Annual Report, Johore 1933, Labourer’s Specimen Monthly Budget 1933, p.27.
48
The above expenditure does not include miscellaneous expenses incurred on items
such as soap, kerosene oil, pots and pans, mats, pillows etc. The monthly and yearly
weighted per capita consumption expenditure was then derived based on the assumption
that an adult female would consume the same amount of food and clothing as the adult
adult.29 It should be noted that the figure for food was revised upwards to account for
own-account consumption.30 The per capita consumption of tobacco was based solely
on the consumption made by an adult male. Data on rent for the Indian standard was not
available for any one year during this period. Expenditure on rent was therefore
estimated based on surrogate data. The cost-of-living index of the Eurasian Clerical
standard, 1914-39 gave a weight of 8% for rentals for the base year in relation to all
goods and services consumed. This was taken into account and an assumption was made
that the rental expenditure for the Indian standard would account for about 5 % of all
goods and services consumed. The treatment of miscellaneous items was similar to that
The food consumption pattern of a full meat diet of a Malay and a Chinese adult was
based on the 1936 diet scale of government hospitals. Since food provisions in
government hospitals were deemed to be the minimum dietary requirements, the food
consumption data was adjusted upwards to reflect the normal intake of an adult.
Subsequently, the monthly and yearly weighted per capita consumption for the Malay
and Chinese standards were arrived at in a procedure similar to that as described for the
29
This information was derived from the Health and Nutrition Information Infrastructure Database System (1995) developed by
the National Institute of Health and Nutrition (NIHN) in collaboration with the Japan Science and Technology Agency (JST).
Annual mean of total amount of food, both animal food and vegetable food, for an adult (30-39 years old) and child (1-6 years old)
were 1,479.8 grams and 983.4 grams respectively. Based on this available information, it was decided that child consumption on
food was almost 2/3 of an adult.
30
For example, this includes consumption of home-grown poultry and livestock products, vegetables etc.
49
(ii) Tobacco, Clothing and Rent (1936)
No data was available for 1936 on the per capita consumption of tobacco, clothing
and rent. Given this predicament, estimates for the various major objects of
consumption in 1936 were made based on per capita consumption of such objects
(except rent) in the year 1949 for which data was available. It was assumed that the
relation to food as observed in 1949 would remain unchanged in 1939. Based on this
assumption, the consumption of food in 1939 was computed. However, the changes in
real consumption due to changes in real income were not taken into account. Having
determined the per capita consumption of food in 1939, the per capita consumption of
tobacco and clothing for 1939 was computed based on the relationship of these major
objects of consumption to food in 1949. The data for 1936 was then obtained by
deflating each major object of consumption by the relevant price index to reflect price
changes for the two years (1936 and 1939) using 1914 as the base year.
Data on rent was not available for the year 1949. It was noted that rent constituted
8% of the per capita expenditure of the Eurasian clerical standard in 1914. It was then
posited that the percentage of expenditure on rent for the Malay and Chinese labour
standards would certainly be less than the Eurasian clerical standard. An assumption
was therefore made that the percentage would only be about 5% for the Malay labour
standard and around 6% for the Chinese labour standard. As for the miscellaneous items
clerical standards as described earlier. I have so far described the manner in which
the six consumption standards has been constructed for each major object of
consumption in current prices for the selected years. The results of the above exercise
50
(II) Post World War II Period
Clerical and Chinese, Indian, Eurasian Clerical standards respectively. Original data
provide quantity consumed on food, tobacco and transport while total value of
consumption for beverages, clothing, clubs and rents at 1948 prices. In order to derive
the value in 1948 for food items, tobacco and transport, available market prices of that
particular year were derived from the Monthly Statistical Bulletin, Federation of Malaya
and Malayan Statistics Monthly Digest of Economic and Social Statistics Relating to the
b) Chinese, Malay and Indian Labour standards for the year 1949
information on quantity consumed by an adult male for each item, namely food, tobacco
and clothing. The monthly and yearly weighted per capita consumption expenditure was
then derived based on the assumption that an adult female would consume the same
amount of food and clothing as the adult male while a child’s consumption of these
on rent, an assumption was therefore made that the percentage would only be about 5%
for the Malay and Indian labour standards and around 6% for the Chinese labour
standard. The results of the estimates are presented in Table 2.7 (B).
51
Table 2.7
Singapore: Annual Per Capita Private Consumption Expenditure by Standard,
Selected Years
Notes:
1. Per capita consumption was derived based on household size of each standard household.
2. Consumption per capita is assumed to be 25% more than the full meat diet scale of adults in government hospitals. Male and
female adults consume the same amount whereas children consume 2/3 of adult amount.
3. Applied the ratio of beverages and tobacco to food in 1949 to 1939 and deflated to 1936.
4. Applied the ratio of clothing to food in 1949 to 1939 and deflated to 1936.
5. Applied the ratio of rent to food in 1949 to 1939 and deflated to 1936.
6. Consumption per capita is assumed to be 20% more than that of Labourer’s Specimen, Johore, 1933. Male and female adults
consume the same amount whereas children consume 2/3 of adult amount.
7. Computed as a 5% of total expenditure on food, clothing, beverages and tobacco.
Sources:
[1] Milles (1931:14-16 and 20-23).
[2] Annual Report, Johore 1933, Labourer’s Specimen Monthly Budget, p.27.
[3] Allen, L.A. (1938:1705).
[4] Annual Report Labour Department, Colony of Singapore, 1949, p. 74-76.
Notes:
1. Per capita consumption was derived based on household size of each standard household.
2. Male and female adults consume the same amount whereas children consume 2/3 of adult amount.
Computed as a percentage of expenditure on food, clothing, beverages and tobacco: Malay and Indian Labor 5%, Chinese Labor 6%.
Sources:
[1]Department of Statistics, Federation of Malaya (1949: 74-77).
[2] Annual Report, Labour Department, the Colony of Singapore,1949, pp. 74-76.
52
2.2.2.2.3 Construction of Consumer Price Indices 1900-39 and 1950-60
(1914=100) (STEP 3)
Consumer price indices (CPI) forms a basis for measuring the rate of inflation and a
useful tool for deflating PFCE, wage rates, etc. It provides a measure of the average rate
of change in prices of a fixed basket of consumer goods and services which represents
the household expenditure pattern. 31 For this purpose, CPI by major object of
consumption was required to obtain the respective real per capita consumption
expenditure. Additionally, the overall CPI was utilized to compute real wage indices.
Firstly, estimate the private final consumption expenditure of each major object of
consumption for each consumption standard for the base year (1914=100). Secondly,
compute the base weights of private final consumption using the total private final
standard. The weights of private final consumption of each consumption standard within
the base weights of private final consumption of each consumption standard within a
particular major object of consumption by the relevant price indices of each year. Based
on the above procedures, derive the overall price index of each major object of
This would give you the overall price index for each major object of consumption
for each year. The details on how the price indices for each major object of consumption
were estimated and the results of such an exercise are presented in Appendices 1-3. It
will be apparent from these Appendices that there are essentially two (2) series of price
indices. The first series covering the period 1900-39 had 1914 as its base year
(1914=100) while the second series encompassing the period 1939, 1947-60 had 1949
31
A base weighted price index, ie a Laspeyres Price Index was used in the computation. It can be computed using the following
formula.
Pn
∑ PnQo ∑ Po * PoQo
53
as the base year. With 1939 being common to both series of price indices, it was then
possible to reconstruct one continuous series for the period 1900-39 and 1950-60 with
1914 as the base year (1914=100) by using the overlapping 1939 price indices
The weights of private final consumption expenditure in the base year of each major
Subsequently, multiply the base weights so derived by the price indices of each major
object of consumption for each year. Lastly, derive the overall price index by adding up
the base weighted index for each major object of consumption for each year. The
estimated Consumer Price Indices (CPI) so derived for the year 1900-39 and 1950-60
are presented in Table 2.8. The computation of procedures of CPI for the various
periods namely 1899-1914, 1914-39 and 1939, 1947-60 are presented in Appendix
Table 3-5.
54
Table 2.8
Singapore: Price Indices by Major Object of Consumption and Consumer Price
Index, 1899-1939 and 1947-60 (1914=100)
55
2.2.2.2.4 Estimating the Per Capita Final Consumption Expenditure of Major
Objects of Consumption and Standards in 1914 Prices for Selected Years (STEP 4)
By utilizing the consumer price indices constructed in Step 3, figures on real per-
capita consumption expenditure by each major object of consumption and each standard
using 1914 as the base year were derived and the results are presented in Table 2.9.
Table 2.9
Singapore: Real Per Capita Private Consumption Expenditure by Standard,
Selected Years
(A) 1899-1939 (1914 Prices)
Consumption European Eurasian Asiatic Malay Chinese Indian
Standard Standard Standard Clerical Labour Labour Labour
Major
Object of (1930) (1930) Standard Standard Standard Standard
Consumption (1930) (1936) (1936) (1933)
Food and
$434.85 $141.39 $133.49 $91.68 $95.45 $96.88
Groceries
Beverages and
$100.82 $5.08 $5.08 $6.95 $5.55 $10.55
Tobacco
Clothing $206.01 $22.32 $22.32 $10.61 $10.47 $8.80
Rent $112.68 $28.17 $28.17 $3.50 $4.42 $5.97
Not Not Not
Domestic Servants $428.52 $15.70 $15.70 Applicable Applicable Applicable
Transport (Other Not Not Not
$225.12 $30.99 $30.99 Applicable Applicable Applicable
than Railway)
Not
Not Not Not Not
Clubs $140.68 Applicable Applicable Applicable Applicable
Applicable
Ideally a real wage index should be constructed using the weighted average of
wages in all sectors of the economy. Unfortunately, no such detailed time series data
56
applied to compute the real wage indices. For the period 1899-1939, the wage index was
constructed based on the daily wage rates of carpenters, joiners, blacksmiths and
bricklayers in Singapore and the Indian factory workers in Singapore to capture wage
movements in the non-agriculture sectors,32 while the Indian rubber estate tappers’
wage rate was used to reflect wage movements in the agriculture sector.
A weighted wage index was constructed based on the employment data of the
Population.33 Real earnings index was then derived by deflating the earnings index with
For the period 1947-57, the information on number of labourers by industry for the
year 1947 and 1957 was provided in the Population Census 1957, the Colony of
Singapore. According to this census report, more than half of the working population
was employed in the manufacturing and services sectors for both 1947 and 1957. Based
on this observation, minimum daily wage information was extracted from the Annual
Report, Labour Department, the Colony of Singapore. The data presentation, however,
has changed over time. Therefore, synchronizations needed to be made. These selected
representative wage rates for each industry were then converted to a wage index with
1957 as the base year. Subsequently, the weighted wage index was computed based on
the 1957 Census. The derived nominal weighted wage index was then deflated by the
overall Consumer Price Indices. The real wage indices for the period 1899-1939 and
Agriculture Non-agriculture
Sector sector
1921 13.8% 86.2%
1931 12.9% 87.1%
1947 8.1% 91.9%
1957 6.9% 93.1%
57
Table 2.10
Singapore: Weighted Real Wage Indices, 1899-1939 and 1947-60 (1914=100)
1899-1939, 1947-1960 (1914=100)
1899 116.03 1920 89.13 1947 164.71
1900 113.92 1921 112.82 1948 179.65 250.0
1901 112.77 1922 123.66 1949 220.02
1902 108.67 1923 126.94 1950 203.15
1903 107.35 1924 127.47 1951 181.26 200.0
1904 107.24 1925 124.53 1952 176.19
1905 105.29 1926 120.44 1953 206.53
1906 106.94 1927 127.57 1954 208.97 150.0
1907 107.05 1928 131.90 1955 204.74
1908 107.87 1929 131.51 1956 230.57
1909 110.50 1930 129.23 1957 215.81
1910 108.44 1931 115.38 1958 215.37 100.0
1911 98.90 1932 122.09 1959 194.19
1912 97.22 1933 136.87 1960 230.48
1913 95.24 1934 130.38 50.0
1914 100.00 1935 137.02
1915 93.86 1936 148.89
1916 88.38 1937 150.08
-
1917 100.72 1938 155.10
1899
1901
1903
1905
1907
1909
1911
1913
1915
1917
1919
1921
1923
1925
1927
1929
1931
1933
1935
1937
1939
1947
1949
1951
1953
1955
1957
1959
1918 104.36 1939 154.06
1919 92.87
In steps 1-5, the necessary statistical information was prepared, namely population
consumption and standard in current prices, consumer price indices by major object of
consumption and standard in 1914 prices and real wage indices. In deriving yearly
private consumption expenditure in both 1914 and current prices (steps 6-11), the
element of changes in real income levels having an impact on the consumption patterns
needs to be factored in. As a result certain assumptions were made with regards to
income elasticities of demand to adjust the expenditure series for changes in real income
over time: the assumed income elasticities of demand being 0.7 for food,34 1.0 each for
beverages, tobacco, clothing, domestic servants, and transport (other than railway), and
0.8 for rent. To give an example, if in the base year (t) real per capita expenditure on
food for the European standard is RPCFt and if the real wage indices increases from 1 in
34
The basis for using an income elasticity of demand of 0.7 for food was very much guided by other related studies. In this regard,
Derkson, J.B.D. and Tinbergen, J. (1945) established that the income elasticity of demand on food was 0.7 for the Netherlands. In
the case of pre-war Malaya, a study by Nazrin (2006) set 0.8 as elasticity of demand on food. In the light of this, it was assumed that
elasticity of demand on food for Singapore ought to be lower than pre-war Malaya and to be not too dissimilar to that of the
Netherlands.
58
year t to 1.3 in year t+1, then the real per capita expenditure on food in year t+1
If the real earnings index increases to 1.5 in year t+2, real per capita expenditure in year
This computation is illustrated in more detail in Table 2.11, (Columns (1) to (5)) taking
the consumption expenditure on food for the European Standard, as an example. The
real per-capita expenditure of the European standard on food for the period 1899-1939
(Column 5) was then multiplied by the population of the European standard (Column 6)
to obtain the real private consumption expenditure on food for the Europeans standard
in 1914 prices (Column 7). This was finally inflated by food indices (Column 8) to
obtain private final consumption expenditure on food for the European standard in
current prices (Column 9). Similar procedures were applied to compute PFCE on food,
tobacco, clothing, rent, domestic servants and clubs, wherever applicable, for each
standard in both current and constant prices using their respective income elasticities of
demand (See Appendix Table 6). The summation of each of the major objects of
consumption for each standard in constant and current prices gave us the total PFCE of
those items in both constant and current prices respectively (See Appendix Table 7).
The miscellaneous items expenditure was then computed for each year based on the
indirect approach of computing the total PFCE in current prices. The miscellaneous
items included among others, furniture and furnishings, household equipment and
household utensils and other non-durable goods, e.g. matches, soap, candles, shoe
polish, etc. It also included cultural services and other goods and services, including
personal care, e.g barbers, laundry, etc. based on the indirect approach. Based on
statistical evidence, the miscellaneous expenditure was taken to be 10.0% of the total
59
private final consumption expenditure in current prices based on PFCE derived from the
indirect approach.35 The estimates are therefore, subject to errors. The miscellaneous
expenditure in constant terms for each year was determined by dividing the
miscellaneous expenditure in current terms by the overall consumer price indices. The
overall PFCE in the domestic market for each year was then derived by summing up the
major objects of consumption in both current and constant prices based on the direct and
35
Department of Statistics, Singapore (1983) provides the figures on private final consumption expenditure in the domestic market
by major objects of consumption for the period 1960-82 at current prices. According to this time series data, a weight on the other
goods and services (expenditure on personal care, restaurants, cafes and hotels) for the period 1960-65 was in the range of 15-16%.
However, this category includes the consumption expenditure on clubs. The weight on this specific consumption was approximately,
3-5%. Based on this, 10% was assigned for deriving miscellaneous expenditure. It will be noted in Nazrin’s (2006) estimates of
private consumption expenditure for pre-war Malaya, a figure of 7% was applied for miscellaneous expenditure.
60
Table 2.11
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
European Standard – Food in Current and 1914 Prices
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita European Total Real Private Food Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Wage Indices Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Final of Agriculture (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption and Non- (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Food in the
Expenditure in agriculture on Rel Wages and Food in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Sectors Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) (1914=100 ) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
C1906
-1 = 1.09%
C1905
C1906
= 1.09% + 1
C1905
375.97
= 1.0109
C1905
C1905 = 375.97
1.0109
C1905 = 371.91
61
Table 2.12
Singapore: Private Final Consumption Expenditure in the Domestic Market,
1900-39 and 1950-60 at Current and Constant Prices
Private Final Consumption Expenditure in the Domestic Market Per-capita Private Final Consumption Expenditure in the
by Resident and Non-resident Households Domestic Market by Resident and Non-resident
Households
Current Prices Growth rate 1914 Prices Growth rate Current Prices Growth rate 1914 Prices Growth rate
(Straits $) (%) (Straits $) (%) (Straits $) (%) (Straits $) (%)
62
2.2.2.3 Private Consumption Expenditure by Resident Households
As discussed above, PFCE in the domestic market was computed based on the
procedures as outlined in steps 1-10. This derived estimate, however, required further
market should be calculated independently but it was difficult to construct such data. As
an alternative option, the available official figures for the period 1960-70 were used as a
guide. As is presented in Table 2.13, 10-15 % of total PFCE in the domestic market was
non-resident consumption made in the domestic market. On the other hand, direct
purchases abroad by residents were around 1%. Based on this observation, it was
decided that 20% and 15% of the PFCE36 in the domestic market was taken to represent
purchases in the domestic market by non-resident households for the period 1900-32
and 1933-60 respectively. The results are presented in Table 2.14. It should be noted
negligible. In order to derive the PFCE in the domestic market by resident households in
1914 prices, current price data was then deflated by overall Consumer Price Indices.
Table 2.13
Singapore: Direct Purchases made Abroad by Resident Households and Direct
Purchases in the Domestic Market made by Non-resident Households as a
percentage of Total PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1960-70
1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970
36
It was assumed that the weights on the non-resident consumption made in the domestic market were higher in the period after
the formation of self-government due to the relatively free flows of migration. Since the early 1930s, the Colonial government of
Straits Settlements had imposed restrictions on Chinese immigration from China (Annual Report, Chinese Protectorate, Straits
Settlements). Based on this observation, weights on resident household consumption in the domestic market have been taken to
increase from 80% to 85%. These figures must be treated with great reserve. However, it is important to note here that non-resident
consumption made in the domestic market was regarded as exports of services. Therefore, the total GDP figure remained unchanged.
63
Table 2.14
Singapore: PFCE in the Domestic Market, PFCE by Resident Households and
Non-resident Household Consumption Expenditure made in the Domestic Market,
1900-39 and 1950-60 at Current Prices
1948 870,785,958 85% 740,168,064 130,617,894 252,774,860 344.50 214,850,296 37,924,564 1948
1949 1,030,867,837 85% 876,237,662 154,630,176 304,461,754 338.58 258,796,929 45,664,825 1949
1950 1,073,862,182 85% 912,782,854 161,079,327 299,061,922 359.02 254,244,530 44,817,393 1950
1951 1,272,003,340 85% 1,081,202,839 190,800,501 281,946,415 451.51 239,464,811 42,481,604 1951
1952 1,366,152,822 85% 1,161,229,899 204,922,923 290,898,659 469.80 247,177,082 43,721,577 1952
1953 1,609,481,462 85% 1,368,059,242 241,422,219 351,634,837 458.41 298,436,369 53,198,467 1953
1954 1,626,152,653 85% 1,382,229,755 243,922,898 372,052,806 436.94 316,341,017 55,711,790 1954
1955 1,639,802,301 85% 1,393,831,956 245,970,345 383,467,220 427.08 326,361,963 57,105,257 1955
1956 1,921,470,437 85% 1,633,249,872 288,220,566 444,809,033 431.66 378,360,750 66,448,283 1956
1957 2,014,487,496 85% 1,712,314,371 302,173,124 455,456,344 444.20 385,479,118 69,977,226 1957
1958 2,093,107,385 85% 1,779,141,277 313,966,108 475,456,393 441.93 402,588,812 72,867,580 1958
1959 1,988,598,796 85% 1,690,308,977 298,289,819 456,342,816 436.87 386,911,225 69,431,592 1959
1960 2,371,715,294 85% 2,015,958,000 355,757,294 544,423,403 437.05 461,262,368 83,161,035 1960
Note:
(*) = Represents the total private final consumption expenditure by resident households only in the domestic market.
64
2.3 Government Final Consumption Expenditure
2.3.1 Definition
the gross output of general department (producers of government services),37 less the
value of government sales38 and less the value of any own-account capital formation
equal to the value of goods and services produced by the government for its own current
use. Since government output is mainly not sold, SNA68 measures its value by the cost
of producing it, namely, the sum of four component items, that is (i) compensation of
consumption of fixed capital 41 (iv) net indirect taxes paid, and own-account
construction, if any.42 In most cases, units classified as governmental will not pay
indirect taxes nor receive subsidies, so that only the first three components need to be
Prior to World War II, British colonial authority formed six separate general
Settlements (1868), Municipality (1886), Rural Board (1908), Education Board (1909)
37
The producers’ of government services (General Department) include all bodies, departments and establishments of government-
central, state or provincial, district or country, municipal, town or village, which engages in a wide range of activities, for example,
administration, defense and regulation of the public order, health, educational, cultural, recreational and other social service. The
legislative executive, departments, establishments and other bodies of government are also included. However, government
expenditure incurred by industries (trading departments) e.g. post and telegraph, electricity, public works, printing, drainage and
irrigation and the like were not included on the ground that the nature of activities of these departments deals purchases and sales.
38
Government sales include receipts from reproduction of museums, publications sold by statistical office, fees for medical and
hospital treatment, sales of maps and charts, etc. Fees that are levied for regulating purposes are excluded such as passport and
driving licenses.
39
Compensation of employees consists of (a) personal emoluments (wages and salaries in cash, payment in kind, contributions to
social security).
40
Intermediate consumption is defined as the non-durable goods and services that are purchased by producers and used up in the
process of production. Fixed capital formation on defense (exclusive of private dwelling) was treated as intermediate consumption.
41
Consumption of fixed capital is a cost of production. It may be defined as the decline in the current value of the stock of fixed
assets owned and used by a producer as a result of physical deterioration, normal obsolescence or normal accidental damage.
42
Department of International Economic and Social Affairs, United Nations (1986: 118).
65
and Hospital Board (1910). In the case of Municipality and Rural Board, individual
government expenditure accounts were available for Singapore alone. On the other hand,
figures were consolidated and presented for the Straits Settlements as a whole.
After World War II, due to the dissolution of Straits Settlements, Singapore was
renamed as the City Council. Due to the increasing urbanization of Singapore, the
trading activities of City Council viz electricity, gas and water were subsequently
separated from that of the City Council and were reconstituted as part of the newly
created Utility Board. The Rural Board was continuously in existence under the
Municipal Ordinance. With elected self-government under the 1959 Constitution, the
PAP Government abolished these two levels of local government and these functions
were integrated as part of the Central Government on the grounds that Singapore was
administrative bodies and also within each administrative body over time. However,
was necessary to set up a coding system that would identify for estimating
others.43 For convenience, major codes of 1-5 were assigned for personal emoluments,
expenditure incurred under the major code, further detailed breakdown were made
43
Government Finance Statistics Manual (GFS Manual) defines the coding system for all headings of government expenditure
incurred by all government bodies. For the construction of GFCE, GFS transaction category on (1) compensation of employees
[Code 21], (2) use of goods and services (intermediate consumption) [Code 22], (3) consumption of fixed capital [Code 23] and (4)
Sales of government services [Code 142] could be utilized. (Department of Statistics, IMF, 2001: Appendix 3-4). In this exercise,
however, the coding system is not followed exactly due to the fact the available information during the research period were rather
limited. (Department of Statistics, IMF, 2001: Appendix 3-4).
66
Figure 2.12
Singapore: Coding System for Identifying the Different Classes of
Government Expenditures
Major Code Sub Code
Compensation of employees 1
Emoluments (proper) 1 1
Annual recurrent expenditure 1 2
Special expenditure 1 3
Special services 1 4
Other charges 1 5
Blank 1 6
Others 1 9
Intermediate consumption 2
Fixed Capital Formation 3+4
Construction 3
Residential building 3 1
Non-residential building 3 2
Other construction 3 3
Residential and non-residential building 3 4
Residential and other construction 3 5
Non-residential and other construction 3 6
Residential, non-residential and other construction 3 7
Others 3 9
Machinery and Equipment 4
Transport 4 1
Others 4 9
Transfer Payments and Others 5
To meet the definitions of SNA68, the following steps were taken to identify the
employees) and other charges (annual recurrent and special expenditure). Under this
the expenditure incurred was available. In view of this, it was necessary to set up a
coding system that would identify for our purpose, compensation of employees,
the sales of other goods and services by producers of government services. For the
67
(i) Drainage and Irrigation Department
(ii) Electric Supply Department
(iii) Gas Supply Department
(iv) Government Monopolies Department
(v) Post and Telegraph Department
(vi) Printing Department
(vii) Public Works Department
(viii) Railway Department
(ix) Water Supply Department
are also excluded. Having done these deductions, the output of producers of government
Consumption of fixed capital, however, is very difficult to trace due to the dearth of
data. Therefore, based on the available post independent information, it was assumed
depreciation allowance.44
government services. Sales of other goods and services produced by the producers of
These standard procedures however, were not fully applicable for all government
accounts due to the deficiencies of data. Therefore, the following approach was applied
44
Information on this which was available for the 1960s was used as an indicative guide. The data on consumption of fixed capital
and its percentage share of government output for Singapore for the years 1960-170, was in the range of 1% to 2%. Based on this
statistical evidence it was assumed that the percentage share of consumption of fixed capital to total government output for
Singapore during the study period 1900-39, 1950-60 would have been in the region of 1%.
68
Figure 2.13
Singapore: Classification for Total Output of Producers’ of Government Services
Total Government Expenditure
69
2.3.2.1 Colony of Singapore, 1900-39 and 1950-60
The government expenditures for the Colony of Singapore are published in the
yearly Blue Book, Straits Settlements for the period 1900-38. For the 1939 the data is
available in the Financial Statements of the Colony of the Straits Settlements while for
the years 1950-56 the data is available from the Financial Statements of the Colony of
Singapore and for the years 1957-60 in the Financial Statements of the State of
Singapore. Availability of expenditure details varied over time. For the period 1900-09,
the expenditures incurred were presented in a manner that was quite different from that
of 1910-39. For the period 1900-09, detailed expenditure by heads of departments was
available for each of the Settlements with regards to personal emoluments, annual
recurrent and special expenditures. From the detailed expenditures incurred, we were
and others”. In the case of “Crown Agents”, we were also able to assign, in most cases,
the expenditure incurred in each of the Settlements based on the information provided in
the source documents. Only in some cases were we not able to assign with precision the
expenditure incurred by the “Crown Agents”. The magnitude of these expenditures was
relatively negligible. Overall it could be said that the estimated expenditure incurred by
the “Crown Agents” in the respective Settlements was fairly reliable. The detail
consumption of goods and services of the producers of government services (major code
of 1 and 2 in Figure 2.6), although not taking into account initially the consumption of
For the period 1910-39, data on personal emoluments and input were available by
heads of departments on a consolidated basis for the Colony of the Straits Settlements.
70
instances, were only available on a consolidated basis. This being the case, the
on a simple average basis to each of the Settlements in the Colony based on the
structure of each department for the period 1900-09 (See Appendix Table 8). In cases,
where a particular department that existed in 1910-39 but not in the period 1900-09, we
had to find an alternative approach to identify the proportion of emoluments that ought
to be allocated to each entity of the Settlements in the Colony. The apportioning of the
emoluments in this instance was based on the input structure (intermediate consumption
of goods and services) of each department for which data was available. This
methodology was adopted as it was felt that there was a stable relationship within each
Appendix Table 9). Relevant information was also available to distinguish the producers
In cases where sufficient data on inputs were not available, estimates of emoluments
were made for each of the regions based on local knowledge of the department (See
Appendix Table 10). It should be noted that in the accounts of the Straits Settlements
proper, government contributions to Hospital Board, Education Board and Rural Boards
After World War II, the island of Singapore was treated as a separate entity (British
Crown Colony of Singapore) due to the dissolution of the Straits Settlements. Financial
Statements of Colony of Singapore, for 1950-56 and Financial Statement of the State of
expenditure.
71
2.3.2.2 The Municipality of Singapore, 1900-39 and the City Council of
Singapore, 1950-60
1900-02, 1904-09 and 1911-39 was utilized to obtain government accounts. In the pre-
World War II period, the local government of Singapore was known as the Singapore
Municipality and subsequently was renamed as the Singapore City Council. For the pre-
war period, two different formats of accounts were provided. For the period 1900-16,
the heading of [1] personal emoluments, [2] other charges and [3] special services. No
further detail expenditure breakdown was available. Personal emoluments can in its
and special services generally contain a whole host of expenditures. However, most of
consumption expenditure and the expenditure on special services was not classified as
1917-39, the figures for the Colony of Singapore were relatively well documented.
Detailed expenditure of each department was available and personal emoluments and
output of goods and services of Singapore Municipality. For the post-war period, the
different formats and the classifications used were rather crude. As an alternative option,
Singapore’s City Council Estimate for the year 1954 was utilized. This report provided
very detailed expenditure accounts for the year 1952 for each department. The
percentage distribution of each expenditure item for each department by object was
identified. These distribution patterns were then applied to the other years. The derived
72
figures, therefore, are inevitably crude estimates considering that a fixed (1952)
percentage distribution pattern was applied for the period 1950-60. In contrast to the
Colony of Singapore, the City Council of Singapore did not have any kind of
government sales of goods and services such as education and hospital fees. Therefore,
the government final consumption expenditure was treated as equal to the expenditure
on government output.
The Rural Boards existed only in the Settlements of Singapore, Penang and
Malacca; having their origin in the Municipal Ordinance of the former Straits
Settlements. Actual operation of Rural Boards started since 1908.45 In effect, they cover
the whole area of Singapore with the exception of the municipal areas.46 Unfortunately,
only total expenditure figures were available in Blue Books, Straits Settlements for the
period 1911-38. For the post World War II period, the Annual Report of Singapore,
accounts for the years 1950-57. As detailed information on expenditure was not
available for the years 1911-39, there was no other option but to apply the percentage
capital formation and "transfers and others") as observed for Rural Boards in the early
1980's. For the years 1908-10, the average ratio between rural boards and municipality
for compensation of employees and intermediate consumption was applied to obtain the
estimated figures.
For the period 1950-60, the Annual Report of Singapore provided the expenditure
by department. These figures on expenditure were then reclassified by objects and total
45
[1] In December, 1907, the Secretary of State signified his approval of the institution of Rural Boards in the Country Districts
outside Municipal limits (Source: Straits Settlements (1909) Proceeding's of the Legislative Council of the Straits Setltements for
the year 1908, p.C149). [2] The institution of Rural Boards outside Municipal limits I (Secretary of State) mentioned last year
(1908), and I am glad to be able to say that hitherto they have worked well. (Source: Straits Settlements (1910) Proceeding's of the
Legislative Council of the Straits Settlements, for the year 1909, p.C.97).
46
Taylor, W.C. (1949: 61)
73
expenditure on personal emolument and intermediate consumption expenditure were
The Education Board of Straits Settlements was formed for the following reasons.
receive all such fees. Secondly, to submit to the government the annual estimates for
government as to the purposes for education should be expended upon any matters
connected with education which may from time to time be referred to it by the Governor.
Department and Education Board by class of account for Singapore was then estimated
for the period 1910-39 based on the average share of the expenditure by class of account
of Singapore in relation to the Straits Settlements expenditure for the period 1900-09.
and Education Board on a consolidated basis for Singapore, we were able to determine
the expenditure by class of account for the Education Board proper for Singapore by
deducting from the consolidated account of the Education Department and Education
Department. In the case of the Education Board proper, the data available was only in
respect to total expenditure on a consolidated basis for the period 1900-39 without
breakdown by class of account. Estimation by class of account for each of the entity
For the period 1900-09, the total expenditure on education was the sole
responsibility of the Education Department (SS). With the setting up of the Education
Board in 1909, the expenditure on education became the joint responsibility of the
74
Education Department and the Education Board (SS). For the period 1911-39, the
However, no such data was available in the case of Education Board (SS) whereby only
the total expenditure was known. The percentage distribution from 1900-09 of the
Education Department (SS) was then utilized to determine the pattern of expenditure of
the Education Board (SS) and the Education Department (SS) on a consolidated basis
for the period 1910-39. Having identified the total expenditure pattern by class of
account on a consolidated basis, the expenditure pattern of the Education Board proper
(SS) was derived by isolating from the expenditure pattern of the Education Department
(SS) and the Education Board (SS) on a consolidated basis. In the post-war period,
Singapore. Therefore, there was no other option but to estimate the figures by
extrapolation.
The Hospital Board was formed for a number of reason, namely (a) to determine the
amount of fees to be charged in all Hospitals and Asylums and (b) to disburse all sums
voted by Governor in Council for the purposes of Hospitals and Asylums and (c) to
advise the Government on any matters in connection with Hospitals and Asylums. In the
case of Hospital Board, separate data on total expenditure incurred was available for
Singapore and the Hospital Board of Singapore by class of account for the period 1910-
39 was derived based on the expenditure pattern by class of account from 1900-09 of
total expenditure pattern of the Medical Department and the Hospital Board on a
consolidated basis, the expenditure pattern by class of account of the Hospital Board
75
was derived by isolating the consolidated expenditure pattern of the Medical
Department and the Hospital Board, the expenditure of the Medical Department for the
period 1910-39. In the post-war period, expenditure on Hospital Boards was not
available in the relevant reports a situation similar to that of the Education Board as has
been mentioned earlier. Therefore, the extrapolation method was applied under these
Table 2.15 presents the total expenditure incurred for (1) compensation of
employees and (2) intermediate consumption by each government body. Two features
can be highlighted here. Firstly, the share of personal emoluments for the Colony was
very high (in the region of over 70%) during the period under review while the share of
total personal emoluments for all government bodies averaged about 55% and 66% for
the period 1900-39 and 1950-60 respectively. Secondly, the share of that of the local
bodies particularly the Municipality was relatively high particularly during the period
up the output from all government bodies. As is presented in Table 2.16, each
similar weights with the official figure. As was stated earlier, a depreciation rate of 1%
was applied against gross output of producers of government services. Finally, in order
from the estimate of gross output were all of the elements entering into it that were not
final consumption; that is amount received for any part of government gross output that
76
in fact is sold on the market. In these estimates, only school fees and hospital fees which
appeared in the Blue Books, Straits Settlements and Annual Report, Financial Statement
indices (CPI) were applied as an alternative deflator for both output of producers of
77
Table 2.15
Singapore: Gross Output of Producers’ of Government Services, 1900-39 and 1950-60
(Straits Millions $)
A: Colony B: Municipality C: Rural Board D: Education Board E: Hospital Board Total Percentage Share:-
[1] [1]/[3] [2] [2]/[3] [3]= [1]+[2] [1] [1]/[3] [2] [2]/[3] [3]= [1]+[2] [1] [1]/[3] [2] [2]/[3] [3]= [1]+[2] [1] [1]/[3] [2] [2]/[3] [3]= [1]+[2] [1] [1]/[3] [2] [2]/[3] [3]= [1]+[2] [1] [1]/[3] [2] [2]/[3] [3]= [1]+[2] A B C D E
1900 0.88 69 0.40 31 1.28 0.20 20 0.77 80 0.96 1.08 48 1.17 52 2.25 57 43 1900
1901 0.99 67 0.48 33 1.47 0.23 19 0.99 81 1.23 1.22 45 1.48 55 2.70 55 45 1901
1902 1.11 67 0.54 33 1.66 0.26 28 0.67 72 0.93 1.37 53 1.21 47 2.58 64 36 1902
1903 1.25 61 0.82 39 2.07 0.27 22 0.94 78 1.21 1.52 46 1.76 54 3.28 63 37 1903
1904 1.27 57 0.96 43 2.24 0.28 19 1.18 81 1.46 1.56 42 2.15 58 3.70 60 40 1904
1905 1.32 68 0.61 32 1.93 0.31 22 1.12 78 1.43 1.63 49 1.73 51 3.36 57 43 1905
1906 1.24 67 0.62 33 1.86 0.33 25 1.00 75 1.32 1.57 49 1.62 51 3.19 58 42 1906
1907 1.26 67 0.62 33 1.88 0.35 27 0.93 73 1.28 1.61 51 1.55 49 3.16 60 40 1907
1908 1.41 70 0.59 30 2.00 0.37 28 0.94 72 1.31 0.03 44 0.04 56 0.06 1.81 54 1.57 46 3.38 59 39 2 1908
1909 1.53 74 0.54 26 2.07 0.38 32 0.82 68 1.20 0.03 48 0.03 52 0.06 1.94 58 1.39 42 3.33 62 36 2 1909
1910 1.61 77 0.49 23 2.11 0.41 26 1.14 74 1.55 0.03 42 0.04 58 0.07 0.02 41 0.03 59 0.05 0.04 26 0.12 74 0.17 2.12 54 1.83 46 3.95 53 39 2 1 4 1910
1911 1.55 81 0.36 19 1.91 0.43 23 1.46 77 1.89 0.03 38 0.04 62 0.07 0.05 56 0.04 44 0.09 0.03 20 0.12 80 0.15 2.09 51 2.02 49 4.11 47 46 2 2 4 1911
1912 1.67 83 0.35 17 2.01 0.43 25 1.29 75 1.72 0.04 38 0.07 62 0.11 0.05 54 0.04 46 0.09 0.01 10 0.12 90 0.14 2.20 54 1.86 46 4.07 49 42 3 2 3 1912
1913 1.76 84 0.35 16 2.10 0.56 22 1.98 78 2.54 0.04 38 0.07 62 0.11 0.07 59 0.05 41 0.12 0.01 9 0.14 91 0.16 2.45 49 2.59 51 5.03 42 51 2 2 3 1913
1914 1.82 82 0.41 18 2.23 0.66 28 1.71 72 2.37 0.08 38 0.12 62 0.20 0.05 53 0.05 47 0.10 0.03 17 0.16 83 0.19 2.64 52 2.45 48 5.09 44 47 4 2 4 1914
1915 1.76 83 0.37 17 2.13 0.50 24 1.58 76 2.08 0.06 38 0.10 62 0.16 0.06 54 0.05 46 0.11 0.03 15 0.15 85 0.17 2.40 52 2.25 48 4.65 46 45 4 2 4 1915
1916 1.71 63 1.00 37 2.72 0.43 27 1.16 73 1.59 0.05 38 0.09 62 0.14 0.12 65 0.06 35 0.18 0.03 18 0.15 82 0.19 2.35 49 2.47 51 4.82 56 33 3 4 4 1916
1917 1.78 84 0.35 16 2.13 0.61 29 1.52 71 2.13 0.06 38 0.10 62 0.16 0.06 53 0.05 47 0.11 0.04 20 0.17 80 0.21 2.55 54 2.18 46 4.73 45 45 3 2 4 1917
1918 2.20 58 1.56 42 3.76 0.59 26 1.69 74 2.28 0.07 38 0.12 62 0.20 0.07 55 0.06 45 0.13 0.06 25 0.19 75 0.25 3.00 45 3.61 55 6.61 57 35 3 2 4 1918
1919 2.98 72 1.15 28 4.13 0.77 36 1.40 64 2.17 0.09 38 0.14 62 0.22 0.09 58 0.07 42 0.16 0.13 33 0.27 67 0.39 4.06 57 3.01 43 7.07 58 31 3 2 6 1919
1920 5.55 82 1.25 18 6.80 1.15 34 2.25 66 3.40 0.09 38 0.14 62 0.23 0.44 72 0.17 28 0.61 0.11 24 0.33 76 0.44 7.34 64 4.14 36 11.49 59 30 2 5 4 1920
1921 6.11 81 1.40 19 7.51 1.69 36 3.06 64 4.75 0.09 38 0.15 62 0.24 0.22 61 0.14 39 0.37 0.19 30 0.46 70 0.66 8.31 61 5.21 39 13.53 56 35 2 3 5 1921
1922 5.48 80 1.35 20 6.84 1.29 27 3.46 73 4.75 0.08 38 0.12 62 0.20 0.17 55 0.14 45 0.31 0.10 22 0.36 78 0.46 7.12 57 5.43 43 12.56 54 38 2 2 4 1922
1923 5.05 80 1.29 20 6.34 1.34 26 3.74 74 5.08 0.09 38 0.15 62 0.24 0.19 56 0.14 44 0.33 0.11 23 0.37 77 0.48 6.78 54 5.69 46 12.47 51 41 2 3 4 1923
1924 5.43 78 1.49 22 6.93 1.41 27 3.88 73 5.29 0.11 38 0.17 62 0.28 0.21 56 0.16 44 0.37 0.15 30 0.36 70 0.51 7.31 55 6.07 45 13.38 52 40 2 3 4 1924
1925 5.63 83 1.12 17 6.75 1.49 33 2.98 67 4.48 0.13 38 0.21 62 0.34 0.23 56 0.18 44 0.41 0.04 6 0.53 94 0.57 7.53 60 5.02 40 12.55 54 36 3 3 5 1925
1926 5.84 83 1.21 17 7.06 1.53 29 3.70 71 5.23 0.11 38 0.18 62 0.29 0.32 61 0.21 39 0.52 0.02 3 0.54 97 0.56 7.82 57 5.84 43 13.66 52 38 2 4 4 1926
1927 5.79 83 1.21 17 7.00 1.61 27 4.26 73 5.87 0.18 38 0.29 62 0.47 0.36 61 0.23 39 0.58 0.15 17 0.76 83 0.91 8.08 55 6.74 45 14.83 47 40 3 4 6 1927
1928 6.14 82 1.35 18 7.50 1.74 31 3.93 69 5.67 0.15 38 0.24 62 0.39 0.37 61 0.24 39 0.61 0.08 9 0.79 91 0.87 8.49 56 6.56 44 15.05 50 38 3 4 6 1928
1929 6.76 80 1.67 20 8.43 1.85 32 4.00 68 5.86 0.24 38 0.39 62 0.64 0.39 60 0.26 40 0.64 0.03 4 0.73 96 0.76 9.28 57 7.05 43 16.33 52 36 4 4 5 1929
1930 6.96 79 1.86 21 8.82 1.82 30 4.28 70 6.10 0.24 38 0.39 62 0.64 0.41 60 0.28 40 0.69 0.03 4 0.75 96 0.78 9.47 56 7.56 44 17.03 52 36 4 4 5 1930
1931 7.14 78 1.97 22 9.10 2.03 34 3.89 66 5.92 0.24 38 0.39 62 0.64 0.41 58 0.30 42 0.71 0.03 4 0.75 96 0.78 9.85 57 7.30 43 17.15 53 35 4 4 5 1931
1932 6.51 80 1.60 20 8.11 2.07 38 3.40 62 5.46 0.14 38 0.22 62 0.36 0.35 55 0.29 45 0.64 0.04 5 0.67 95 0.71 9.10 60 6.18 40 15.28 53 36 2 4 5 1932
1933 6.26 83 1.26 17 7.52 1.73 37 3.00 63 4.73 0.14 38 0.22 62 0.36 0.32 54 0.27 46 0.59 0.04 7 0.56 93 0.59 8.48 61 5.32 39 13.80 55 34 3 4 4 1933
1934 6.10 87 0.92 13 7.02 1.60 38 2.58 62 4.18 0.11 38 0.18 62 0.30 0.27 51 0.26 49 0.53 0.04 6 0.56 94 0.60 8.13 64 4.51 36 12.64 56 33 2 4 5 1934
1935 6.58 87 0.97 13 7.55 1.70 39 2.66 61 4.36 0.14 38 0.22 62 0.36 0.28 51 0.27 49 0.54 0.05 7 0.67 93 0.72 8.75 65 4.79 35 13.54 56 32 3 4 5 1935
1936 6.54 82 1.42 18 7.97 1.80 44 2.26 56 4.06 0.16 38 0.26 62 0.41 0.32 53 0.28 47 0.60 0.04 6 0.69 94 0.73 8.86 64 4.92 36 13.77 58 29 3 4 5 1936
1937 7.35 82 1.62 18 8.97 1.82 46 2.12 54 3.94 0.17 38 0.27 62 0.43 0.34 53 0.30 47 0.64 0.03 4 0.69 96 0.72 9.71 66 5.00 34 14.71 61 27 3 4 5 1937
1938 7.29 80 1.84 20 9.13 1.86 41 2.73 59 4.59 0.21 38 0.35 62 0.56 0.38 55 0.32 45 0.70 0.06 6 0.82 94 0.87 9.81 62 6.05 38 15.85 58 29 4 4 6 1938
1939 7.01 75 2.32 25 9.32 1.90 40 2.84 60 4.73 0.25 38 0.40 62 0.65 0.43 56 0.34 44 0.76 0.02 2 0.93 98 0.95 9.60 58 6.82 42 16.43 57 29 4 5 6 1939
76 24 30 70 39 61 56 44 14 86 55 45 54 38 3 3 4
1950 41.31 73 14.92 27 56.23 5.04 38 8.21 62 13.25 0.29 20 1.16 80 1.45 0.96 56 0.74 44 1.70 0.29 14 1.83 86 2.12 47.89 64 26.86 36 74.76 75 18 2 2 3 1950
1951 50.21 72 19.30 28 69.51 6.30 38 10.28 62 16.59 0.30 17 1.43 83 1.73 1.15 56 0.89 44 2.04 0.35 14 2.19 86 2.54 58.32 63 34.09 37 92.41 75 18 2 2 3 1951
1952 58.37 73 21.85 27 80.22 7.26 38 12.09 62 19.35 0.39 20 1.56 80 1.95 1.29 56 1.00 44 2.29 0.39 14 2.46 86 2.85 67.70 63 38.96 37 106.66 75 18 2 2 3 1952
1953 68.55 72 26.33 28 94.88 7.80 38 12.49 62 20.28 0.55 22 1.94 78 2.49 1.65 56 1.27 44 2.93 0.50 14 3.15 86 3.65 79.06 64 45.17 36 124.23 76 16 2 2 3 1953
1954 73.34 66 37.07 34 110.41 8.66 38 14.18 62 22.84 0.51 17 2.43 83 2.93 1.95 56 1.50 44 3.44 0.59 14 3.71 86 4.30 85.04 59 58.89 41 143.93 77 16 2 2 3 1954
1955 84.63 73 31.58 27 116.21 10.35 38 16.74 62 27.08 0.58 19 2.56 81 3.14 2.08 56 1.60 44 3.69 0.63 14 3.97 86 4.60 98.28 64 56.44 36 154.72 75 18 2 2 3 1955
1956 93.84 79 25.04 21 118.88 12.05 37 20.79 63 32.83 0.57 16 3.10 84 3.67 2.43 56 1.87 44 4.31 0.74 14 4.63 86 5.37 109.63 66 55.43 34 165.06 72 20 2 3 3 1956
1957 98.98 79 25.65 21 124.63 12.08 46 14.12 54 26.20 1.02 22 3.53 78 4.55 3.02 56 2.32 44 5.34 0.92 14 5.75 86 6.66 116.02 69 51.36 31 167.38 74 16 3 3 4 1957
1958 106.55 79 27.66 21 134.21 13.01 46 15.23 54 28.23 1.11 23 3.75 77 4.86 3.22 56 2.48 44 5.71 0.98 14 6.14 86 7.12 124.87 69 55.27 31 180.14 75 16 3 3 4 1958
1959 106.54 75 34.61 25 141.14 13.00 41 19.05 59 32.05 0.96 25 2.85 75 3.82 2.53 56 1.95 44 4.48 0.77 14 4.82 86 5.59 123.81 66 63.28 34 187.09 75 17 2 2 3 1959
1960 105.16 75 35.05 25 140.21 105.16 75 35.05 25 140.21 100 1960
74 26 40 60 20 80 56 44 14 86 66 34 75 17 2 3 3
Notes: [1] Compensation of Employees, [2] Intermediate Consumption Expenditure [3] Output of Producers’ of Government Services
78
Table 2.16
Singapore: Government Final Consumption Expenditure, 1900-39 and 1950-60
at Current and 1914 Prices
(Straits Millions $)
Current Prices 1914 Prices
Government Output Sales of Government Services Govt. Final
Compensation of Intermediate Depreciation Total School Fees Hospital Fees Total Consumption Government Sales of Govt. Final
Year Employees Consumption Expenditure Output Govt. Consumption Year
Services Expenditure
[1] [2] [3]= [4]-[1]- [4]= ([1]+[2]) [5] [6] [7]=[5]+[6] [8]=[3]-[4]-[7] A B C=A-B
[2] / 0.99
1900 1.08 1.17 0.02 2.27 0.01 0.03 0.04 2.23 2.74 0.05 2.70 1900
1901 1.22 1.48 0.03 2.72 0.01 0.03 0.04 2.69 3.26 0.04 3.21 1901
1902 1.37 1.21 0.03 2.61 0.01 0.04 0.05 2.56 3.01 0.06 2.95 1902
1903 1.52 1.76 0.03 3.32 0.03 0.04 0.07 3.25 3.78 0.08 3.70 1903
1904 1.56 2.15 0.04 3.74 0.03 0.04 0.07 3.67 4.25 0.08 4.18 1904
1905 1.63 1.73 0.03 3.39 0.08 0.04 0.12 3.27 3.79 0.13 3.66 1905
1906 1.57 1.62 0.03 3.22 0.03 0.05 0.08 3.14 3.65 0.09 3.56 1906
1907 1.61 1.55 0.03 3.20 0.04 0.04 0.08 3.12 3.63 0.09 3.54 1907
1908 1.81 1.57 0.03 3.41 0.04 0.05 0.09 3.32 3.82 0.11 3.72 1908
1909 1.94 1.39 0.03 3.37 0.18 0.05 0.23 3.14 3.86 0.26 3.60 1909
1910 2.12 1.83 0.04 3.99 0.12 0.06 0.18 3.81 4.49 0.20 4.29 1910
1911 2.09 2.02 0.04 4.15 0.13 0.07 0.20 3.95 4.26 0.20 4.06 1911
1912 2.20 1.86 0.04 4.11 0.14 0.06 0.20 3.91 4.15 0.20 3.95 1912
1913 2.45 2.59 0.05 5.08 0.16 0.06 0.22 4.86 5.03 0.22 4.81 1913
1914 2.64 2.45 0.05 5.14 0.16 0.06 0.22 4.92 5.14 0.22 4.92 1914
1915 2.40 2.25 0.05 4.69 0.17 0.08 0.25 4.44 4.41 0.24 4.17 1915
1916 2.35 2.47 0.05 4.87 0.05 0.10 0.15 4.72 4.30 0.13 4.17 1916
1917 2.55 2.18 0.05 4.78 0.05 0.13 0.18 4.60 4.06 0.15 3.91 1917
1918 3.00 3.61 0.07 6.68 0.05 0.16 0.21 6.46 4.75 0.15 4.60 1918
1919 4.06 3.01 0.07 7.14 0.06 0.20 0.26 6.88 4.15 0.15 3.99 1919
1920 7.34 4.14 0.12 11.60 0.07 0.25 0.32 11.28 5.24 0.14 5.10 1920
1921 8.31 5.21 0.14 13.66 0.08 0.32 0.39 13.27 7.82 0.22 7.59 1921
1922 7.12 5.43 0.13 12.68 0.08 0.40 0.48 12.21 8.12 0.31 7.82 1922
1923 6.78 5.69 0.13 12.60 0.09 0.50 0.59 12.00 8.28 0.39 7.89 1923
1924 7.31 6.07 0.14 13.52 0.10 0.26 0.36 13.16 8.92 0.24 8.68 1924
1925 7.53 5.02 0.13 12.68 0.12 0.34 0.47 12.21 8.18 0.30 7.88 1925
1926 7.82 5.84 0.14 13.80 0.12 0.38 0.50 13.30 8.61 0.31 8.29 1926
1927 8.08 6.74 0.15 14.98 0.12 0.37 0.50 14.48 9.48 0.31 9.16 1927
1928 8.49 6.56 0.15 15.20 0.14 0.39 0.53 14.68 9.70 0.34 9.37 1928
1929 9.28 7.05 0.16 16.49 0.15 0.46 0.61 15.88 10.76 0.40 10.36 1929
1930 9.47 7.56 0.17 17.20 0.16 0.55 0.72 16.48 11.80 0.49 11.31 1930
1931 9.85 7.30 0.17 17.32 0.18 0.66 0.83 16.49 13.91 0.67 13.24 1931
1932 9.10 6.18 0.15 15.43 0.19 0.78 0.97 14.46 14.08 0.88 13.20 1932
1933 8.48 5.32 0.14 13.94 0.18 0.79 0.97 12.97 13.70 0.95 12.75 1933
1934 8.13 4.51 0.13 12.77 0.19 0.91 1.10 11.67 12.23 1.05 11.17 1934
1935 8.75 4.79 0.14 13.67 0.20 0.81 1.01 12.66 12.60 0.93 11.67 1935
1936 8.86 4.92 0.14 13.91 0.21 0.86 1.07 12.84 13.04 1.00 12.04 1936
1937 9.71 5.00 0.15 14.86 0.23 0.81 1.04 13.82 13.14 0.92 12.22 1937
1938 9.81 6.05 0.16 16.01 0.22 0.86 1.08 14.93 14.64 0.99 13.65 1938
1939 9.60 6.82 0.17 16.59 0.21 0.91 1.13 15.47 15.06 1.02 14.04 1939
1950 47.89 26.86 0.76 75.51 0.33 0.73 1.06 74.45 21.03 0.30 20.74 1950
1951 58.32 34.09 0.93 93.34 0.50 0.92 1.42 91.92 20.67 0.31 20.36 1951
1952 67.70 38.96 1.08 107.74 0.54 0.99 1.53 106.21 22.93 0.33 22.61 1952
1953 79.06 45.17 1.25 125.48 0.56 1.15 1.71 123.77 27.37 0.37 27.00 1953
1954 85.04 58.89 1.45 145.38 0.56 1.18 1.74 143.64 33.27 0.40 32.87 1954
1955 98.28 56.44 1.56 156.28 0.63 1.19 1.82 154.47 36.59 0.43 36.17 1955
1956 109.63 55.43 1.67 166.73 0.70 1.20 1.90 164.83 38.63 0.44 38.19 1956
1957 116.02 51.36 1.69 169.07 0.78 1.46 2.24 166.83 38.06 0.51 37.56 1957
1958 124.87 55.27 1.82 181.95 0.87 1.52 2.39 179.56 41.17 0.54 40.63 1958
1959 123.81 63.28 1.89 188.98 0.98 1.35 2.32 186.65 43.26 0.53 42.73 1959
1960 105.16 35.05 1.42 141.63 1.23 1.31 2.54 139.09 32.41 0.58 31.82 1960
79
2.4 Gross Capital Formation
2.4.1 Definition
Gross capital formation contains two major components, namely gross fixed capital
formation and the increase in stocks during a period which do not enter into the
considered to be used up during the account period, or to yield benefits in the future.47
The 1968 SNA provides for the classification of gross fixed capital formation according
to the kind of economic activity of the owner and the type of fixed assets. The
classification according to the type of fixed assets is given in Figure 2.14 below.48
Figure 2.14
The Components of Gross Capital Formation (SNA 68)
Currently, data on fixed capital formation may be obtained from specialized surveys
or from general production surveys and in the case of government and public
corporations, directly from the accounts. Changes in inventories, however, are more
Nevertheless, in most cases, the indirect approach is used by employing the commodity
47
Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Statistical Office of the United Nations (1968:110).
48
The coverage of gross fixed capital formation has changed from SNA68 to SNA93. For example, SNA93 has recommended that
computer software which are used in the production of goods and services for more than one year are to be treated as investment
instead of intermediate consumption.
49
Department for Economic and Social Affairs, Statistics Division, United Nations (1999: 9-10).
80
flow table. Estimates of gross capital formation by the commodity flow method,
activity of the purchasers. In practice, in most cases, the indirect approach is the only
way of estimating gross fixed capital formation simply because data on gross fixed
capital formation occurring in all sectors of the economy are generally not available. In
the case of Singapore, the first estimates were provided by Benham (1959). As is
presented in Table 2.17, the figures on capital formation was constructed based on the
aggregations of retained imports, domestic production, new building and public works
were small as Singapore heavily relied on imports from overseas due to the lack of
domestic production.
component of Gross Capital Formation (GCF) despite the small weight attached to it. In
this estimate, GCF was classified into (1) construction, (2) machinery and equipment,
50
In these estimates, other capital formation (roads, etc.) was included in the current expenditure of the city council and Rural
Board. Part of the plant and machinery, etc. included in this estimate was used for renewals and replacements. On the other hand,
the estimates for local output of machinery and for increase in local livestock are on the low side, and attap houses are excluded.
Hence the figure of $194 million may be taken as about equal to net capital formation. The above value for machinery, etc. includes
the costs and profits of distribution. Domestic production of machinery and equipment for export (mainly to the Federation) is
excluded. Domestic production of implements and tools was less than $1 million. Animal husbandry represents mainly the increase
in the number of pigs. Poultry are excluded. Other agricultural investment (apart from roads, etc. included in Public Works) was
relatively small. Durable consumer goods such as private motor cars, furniture, and refrigerators have been shown under a separate
heading. Owing to lack of information, changes in stock were omitted.
81
Table 2.17
Singapore: Estimates of Capital Formation for the year 1956
Straits $ %
(millions)
I. Retained Imports 91 46.9
1. Machinery, excluding parts 44 22.7
2. Implements and tools 7 3.6
3. Industrial electrical equipment 19 9.8
4. Telegraph and telephone equipment and transmitting 8 4.1
5. Commercial vehicles 13 6.7
II. Domestic Production: 8 4.1
1. Machinery and equipment 6 3.1
2. Ships and sailing vessels 2 1.0
III. New Building and Public Works 94 48.5
1. Public authorities 63 32.5
2. Private 31 16.0
IV. Animal Husbandry 1 0.5
1. Animal Husbandry 1 0.5
Total 194 100.0
Source: Benham (1959:23-24)
2.4.2.1 Definition
into account the output of the characteristic products of the construction industry at
purchaser's values, less the sum of construction for military uses excepting family
buildings (dwellings), plus construction on own account and for sale by other kinds of
activity less the characteristic output of construction activity that is for maintenance and
buildings and other construction is often estimated as the sum of the estimated value of
the building and construction materials used, overhead costs and value added, based on
inflating the value of a few basic materials used, such as cement, sawn timber, plywood,
mild steel bars and rods, floor tiles, (terrazzo, mosaic, etc.), bricks, roofing tiles, etc., by
coefficients from input-output studies.51 The gross output of the construction industry is
should be noted, however, that gross output of the construction industry and gross fixed
51
Department of International Economic and Social Affairs, Statistical Office, United Nations (1986: 141).
82
capital formation in construction are not equal; some of the output of the construction
industry consists of maintenance and current repairs and therefore should not be
capitalized.
For the period 1900-39 and 1948-60, it is not possible to compute the value of
construction output that goes into capital formation due to the paucity of data. No
survey on construction output was carried out during this period. The first survey of
construction in respect of Singapore was only carried out in 1972. Thereafter, surveys
were carried out on an annual or biennial basis. The only information on construction
for the period 1900-39 and 1948-60 that could be used to estimate part of the
construction output was the information that was incorporated in the financial
and the government trading departments. One among other options to estimate the total
construction output was to inflate the value of a few basic materials used in construction,
such as cement, sawn timber, plywood, mild steel bars and rods, floor tiles, bricks, etc
information on the inputs mentioned above for the period was scarce and no continuous
series of data was available except for cement. Even in this case, net imports of cement
retained in the territory of Singapore were available only for the period 1900-12 and
1933-39. They were provided for in the Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and
Other Possessions of The United Kingdom for the period 1900-01, Statistical Tables
Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions and Protectorates for the period 1902-
Colonies, Possessions and Protectorates for the period 1908-12. For the period 1933-39,
the Annual Report, Returns of Imports and Exports, British Malaya and Malayan
Statistics provided figures on imports, exports and net imports retained in Singapore.
83
Unfortunately, figures for the years 1913-27 and 1928-32 were not available. As
illustrated in Table 2.18, figures on net imports of Singapore for the period 1913-27
were calculated using two steps. Firstly, the figures of net imports of cement for
Singapore for the period 1913-27 were treated as 80% of Straits Settlement’s total
figure based on experiences of 1908-12. For the period 1928-32, similar procedures
were applied based on the relationship between net value of imports of cement into
Singapore and total net cement imports into British Malaya as a whole for the period
1933-39. It was decided that 50% and 60% of the total value of net imports of cement of
British Malaya be allocated to Singapore for the period 1928-30 and 1931-32
respectively.
Subsequently, the net import value of cement in Singapore for the period 1950-60
The Report on the Colony of Singapore and Singapore’s External Trade provides the
quantity of cement exports and imports for the period 1953-58 but value data was not
available. As an alternative option, weights of cement import and export values to that
of total merchandize imports and exports were applied to estimate data for missing
years. In the case of imports, 0.5% of total merchandize imports was treated as cement
for the period 1950-56 based on the 1957 figure. Subsequently, 0.4% and 0.3% were
applied for the year 1958 and 1959 respectively based on the fact that weights on
cement imports against total merchandize imports was 0.2% for the year 1960. Similar
procedures were employed to estimate cement exports for the period 1950-56 and 1958-
84
Table 2.18
Net Imports Value of Cement Retained in Singapore, 1900-39
(Straits $)
Straits [b] /[a] Singapore [c]/[b] British
Settlements Malaya
[a] [b] [c]
1900 137,601
1901 174,859
1902 231,109
1903 266,285
1904 456,583
1905 341,007
1906 243,722
1907 361,569
1908 731,979 0.8 588,755
1909 1,012,271 0.9 935,311
1910 1,021,781 0.9 884,914
1911 1,033,553 0.7 729,444
1912 1,311,534 0.8 1,011,788
1913 1,437,048 0.8 1,170,209
1914 1,127,613 0.8 918,232
1915 1,025,719 0.8 835,258
1916 1,263,359 0.8 1,028,772
1917 1,314,887 0.8 1,070,732
1918 2,062,321 0.8 1,679,379
1919 1,918,128 0.8 1,561,960
1920 3,764,525 0.8 3,065,508
1921 3,391,003 0.8 2,761,344
1922 1,571,905 0.8 1,280,026
1923 1,567,542 0.8 1,276,473
1924 1,380,399 0.8 1,124,079
1925 1,899,811 0.8 1,547,044
1926 2,076,033 0.8 1,690,544
1927 3,193,865 0.8 2,600,812
1928 4,214,191 0.5 8,428,382
1929 3,788,160 0.5 7,576,319
1930 2,583,546 0.5 5,167,092
1931 2,411,288 0.6 4,018,813
1932 1,641,887 0.6 2,736,479
1933 1,223,569 0.7 1,849,716
1934 885,452 0.6 1,516,025
1935 1,568,647 0.7 2,396,194
1936 1,814,001 0.6 2,795,513
1937 2,486,377 0.6 4,003,490
1938 2,449,133 0.6 4,289,340
1939 3,534,574 0.6 5,480,500
Sources:
(Singapore)
1900-01: Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions of the United Kingdom
1902-07: Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions and Protectorates
1933-37: Returns of Imports and Exports, British Malaya
1938-39: Foreign Trade of Malaya
(Singapore and Straits Settlements)
1908-12: Statistical Tables Relating to British Self-Governing Dominions, Crown Colonies, Possessions and Protectorates
1913-15: Appendix to the Report on the Trade, Straits Settlements
1916-27: Blue Book, Straits Settlements
(British Malaya)
1928-37: Returns of Imports and Exports, British Malaya
1938-39: Foreign Trade of Malaya
85
Table 2.19
Singapore: Estimating Net Imports of Cement, 1950-60
(Straits $)
Imports of [a] /[b] Total Merchandize Exports of [c] / [d] Total Merchandize Net Imports of
Cement, Imports, Singapore Cement, Exports, Singapore Cement,
Singapore Singapore Singapore
[a] [b] [c] [d] [a] -[c]
1950 16,176,492 0.5% 3,273,497,000 6,090,184 0.2% 3,025,750,000 10,086,308
1951 17,353,987 0.5% 5,027,204,000 6,265,155 0.2% 4,745,242,000 11,088,832
1952 18,531,482 0.5% 3,750,056,000 6,440,127 0.2% 3,199,610,000 12,091,356
1953 14,927,286 0.5% 3,020,706,000 5,342,160 0.2% 2,654,114,000 9,585,126
1954 14,947,779 0.5% 3,024,853,000 5,405,370 0.2% 2,685,518,000 9,542,409
1955 19,088,308 0.5% 3,862,736,000 6,780,466 0.2% 3,368,699,000 12,307,842
1956 19,417,486 0.5% 3,929,349,000 6,901,789 0.2% 3,428,975,000 12,515,697
1957 20,220,446 0.5% 4,091,837,000 7,519,418 0.2% 3,478,133,000 12,701,028
1958 18,700,325 0.5% 3,740,065,000 5,852,524 0.2% 3,140,343,000 12,847,801
1959 19,538,350 0.5% 3,907,670,000 3,134,997 0.1% 3,440,263,000 16,403,353
1960 20,388,430 0.5% 4,077,686,000 1,967,923 0.1% 3,477,053,000 18,420,507
Sources: 1950-56: Annual Report, Colony of Singapore
1957-60: Singapore’s External Trade
Estimated figures on the value of net imports of cement for the territory of
Singapore for the period 1900-39 and 1950-60 were then utilized to compute the
Singapore for the year 1972, the input value of cement and concrete products to total
Table 2.20
Singapore: Production Account - Construction, 1972
Purchase of Materials and Services 644 48.8%
In these estimates, it was assumed that the input of value of cement to total output
value was 6%, 8% and 9% for the periods 1900-07, 1907-27 and 1928-60 respectively.
These coefficients were assigned based on the conventional premise that input of
cement was lesser in the earlier period. The total construction that would go into fixed
capital formation was derived by deducting from total output of construction, the repairs
86
and maintenance and those used by the military (except family dwellings). These
percentages were used to estimate total investments in construction, the results of which
Table 2.21
Singapore: Total Investment in Construction (Construction output Capitalized)
in Current Prices, 1900-39
(Straits $)
Net Imports of Total Output by Different Repairs and maintenance Investment in
Cement in Input - Output Ratios Construction
Singapore (Construction output
Capitalised)
[A] [B] [C]=[A]/[B] [D] [E]=[C]x[D] [F]=[C]-[E]
1900 137,601 6.0% 2,293,350 2.0% 45,867 2,247,483
1901 174,859 6.0% 2,914,317 2.0% 58,286 2,856,030
1902 231,109 6.0% 3,851,817 2.0% 77,036 3,774,780
1903 266,285 6.0% 4,438,083 2.0% 88,762 4,349,322
1904 456,583 6.0% 7,609,717 2.0% 152,194 7,457,522
1905 341,007 6.0% 5,683,450 2.0% 113,669 5,569,781
1906 243,722 6.0% 4,062,033 2.0% 81,241 3,980,793
1907 361,569 6.0% 6,026,150 2.0% 120,523 5,905,627
1908 588,755 8.0% 7,359,438 3.0% 220,783 7,138,654
1909 632,344 8.0% 7,904,306 3.0% 237,129 7,667,177
1910 679,161 8.0% 8,489,514 3.0% 254,685 8,234,829
1911 729,444 8.0% 9,118,050 3.0% 273,542 8,844,509
1912 1,011,788 8.0% 12,647,350 3.0% 379,421 12,267,930
1913 1,170,209 8.0% 14,627,615 3.0% 438,828 14,188,786
1914 918,232 8.0% 11,477,898 3.0% 344,337 11,133,561
1915 835,258 8.0% 10,440,728 3.0% 313,222 10,127,506
1916 1,028,772 8.0% 12,859,649 3.0% 385,789 12,473,860
1917 1,070,732 8.0% 13,384,150 3.0% 401,524 12,982,625
1918 1,679,379 8.0% 20,992,232 3.0% 629,767 20,362,465
1919 1,561,960 8.0% 19,524,501 3.0% 585,735 18,938,766
1920 3,065,508 8.0% 38,318,856 3.0% 1,149,566 37,169,290
1921 2,761,344 8.0% 34,516,800 3.0% 1,035,504 33,481,296
1922 1,280,026 8.0% 16,000,319 3.0% 480,010 15,520,310
1923 1,276,473 8.0% 15,955,908 3.0% 478,677 15,477,231
1924 1,124,079 8.0% 14,050,992 3.0% 421,530 13,629,462
1925 1,547,044 8.0% 19,338,053 3.0% 580,142 18,757,911
1926 1,690,544 8.0% 21,131,805 3.0% 633,954 20,497,851
1927 2,600,812 8.0% 32,510,145 3.0% 975,304 31,534,840
1928 4,214,191 9.0% 46,824,344 3.0% 1,404,730 45,419,614
1929 3,788,160 9.0% 42,090,661 3.0% 1,262,720 40,827,941
1930 2,583,546 9.0% 28,706,067 3.0% 861,182 27,844,885
1931 2,411,288 9.0% 26,792,087 3.0% 803,763 25,988,324
1932 1,641,887 9.0% 18,243,193 3.0% 547,296 17,695,898
1933 1,223,569 9.0% 13,595,211 3.0% 407,856 13,187,355
1934 885,452 9.0% 9,838,356 3.0% 295,151 9,543,205
1935 1,568,647 9.0% 17,429,411 3.0% 522,882 16,906,529
1936 1,814,001 9.0% 20,155,567 3.0% 604,667 19,550,900
1937 2,486,377 9.0% 27,626,411 3.0% 828,792 26,797,619
1938 2,449,133 9.0% 27,212,589 3.0% 816,378 26,396,211
1939 3,534,574 9.0% 39,273,044 3.0% 1,178,191 38,094,853
1950 10,086,308 9.0% 112,070,093 3.0% 3,362,103 108,707,991
1951 11,088,832 9.0% 123,209,245 3.0% 3,696,277 119,512,968
1952 12,091,356 9.0% 134,348,397 3.0% 4,030,452 130,317,945
1953 9,585,126 9.0% 106,501,398 3.0% 3,195,042 103,306,357
1954 9,542,409 9.0% 106,026,771 3.0% 3,180,803 102,845,968
1955 12,307,842 9.0% 136,753,795 3.0% 4,102,614 132,651,182
1956 12,515,697 9.0% 139,063,305 3.0% 4,171,899 134,891,406
1957 12,701,028 9.0% 141,122,533 3.0% 4,233,676 136,888,857
1958 12,847,801 9.0% 142,753,344 3.0% 4,282,600 138,470,744
1959 16,403,353 9.0% 182,259,478 3.0% 5,467,784 176,791,693
1960 18,420,507 9.0% 204,672,300 3.0% 6,140,169 198,532,131
87
2.4.2.3 Investment in Construction in 1914 Prices
The output of construction in real terms is arrived at by deflating the current output
by using the movements of price increases or decreases in cement imports with 1914 as
the base year (See Table 2.22). Undoubtedly, the deflator used is rather weak. A more
appropriate deflator should be used that takes into account price movements in salaries
and wages paid and the inputs used to generate the construction output.
Table 2.22
Singapore: Import Unit Value Indices of Cement,
1900-39 and 1950-60 (1914=100)
1900-39 and 1947-60 (1914=100)
1900 134.40 1910 100.15 1920 300.09 1930 102.64 1950 262.29
1901 132.96 1911 94.64 1921 279.44 1931 84.89 1951 330.69
1902 125.01 1912 100.39 1922 176.26 1932 81.46 1952 377.29
1903 131.06 1913 112.24 1923 132.11 1933 72.49 1953 351.30
1904 123.58 1914 100.00 1924 128.77 1934 58.51 1954 325.31
1905 115.78 1915 111.67 1925 121.10 1935 57.42 1955 331.00
1906 90.63 1916 131.44 1926 122.59 1936 56.53 1956 320.32
1907 104.27 1917 176.55 1927 122.99 1937 58.12 1957 314.21
1908 105.29 1918 242.95 1928 121.89 1938 68.55 1958 269.95
1909 102.16 1919 248.81 1929 118.52 1939 76.28 1959 271.47
1960 241.55
Sources:
(FMS)
1903-32: Annual Report, Trade and Custom, Federated Malay States
(Singapore)
1900-01: Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions of the United Kingdom
1902-07: Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions and Protectorates
1908-12: Statistical Tables Relating to British Self-Governing Dominions, Crown Colonies, Possessions and Protectorates
Straits Settlements
1916-27: Appendix to the Report on Trade, Straits Settlements
(British Malaya)
1921-27: Returns of Foreign Imports and Exports, British Malaya
1928-39: Foreign Trade of Malaya
Investment of construction in constant prices for the period 1900-39 and 1950-60 is
Table 2.23
Singapore: Construction Investment, 1900-39 and 1950-60 in 1914 Prices
(Straits $)
1900-39 and 1950-60 (1914=100)
1900 1,672,225 1910 8,222,647 1920 12,385,907 1930 27,128,671 1950 41,445,484
1901 2,148,013 1911 9,345,441 1921 11,981,683 1931 30,615,392 1951 36,140,083
1902 3,019,550 1912 12,219,773 1922 8,805,342 1932 21,723,699 1952 34,540,107
1903 3,318,515 1913 12,641,360 1923 11,715,038 1933 18,192,688 1953 29,406,546
1904 6,034,725 1914 11,133,561 1924 10,584,176 1934 16,310,505 1954 31,614,434
1905 4,810,708 1915 9,069,382 1925 15,490,189 1935 29,441,597 1955 40,075,494
1906 4,392,325 1916 9,490,320 1926 16,721,087 1936 34,585,492 1956 42,111,745
1907 5,663,897 1917 7,353,695 1927 25,639,347 1937 46,103,537 1957 43,566,392
1908 6,779,901 1918 8,381,259 1928 37,262,057 1938 38,507,737 1958 51,295,409
1909 7,505,372 1919 7,611,772 1929 34,447,940 1939 49,943,553 1959 65,124,024
1960 82,190,271
88
2.4.3 Investment in Transport, Machinery and Equipment
2.4.3.1 Definition
of the value of their acquisitions of new existing transport, machinery and equipment
less the value of disposals of existing ones. It covers transport equipment and other
machinery and equipment, including office equipment, furniture, etc. New machinery
and equipment that has not yet been sold forms part of additions to inventories of
finished goods held by the producers of the assets. Similarly, imported machinery and
equipment is not recorded as gross fixed capital formation until it is acquired by the unit
that intends to use it. Machinery and equipment such as vehicles, furniture, kitchen
for the purpose of private final consumption are not fixed assets and their acquisition is
not treated as gross fixed capital formation. Proceeds of sales by resident producers of
their used and scrapped fixed assets of the same type and the cost net of dealers’
margins and other transfer charges, of purchases of these second-hand items by resident
producers for uses are classified as fixed assets (Department of Economic and Social
Commodity flow analysis is often used in estimating gross fixed capital formation in
transport, machinery and equipment based on statistics on foreign trade and domestic
production.52 In this estimates, it was assumed that there was no M&E produced locally
during the years 1900-39 and 1950-60 and all M&E supplies came as imports from
abroad. This means that total expenditure on M&E equals to net imports valued at
figures on the net import value of M&E for Singapore were available for the period
52
Department of International Economic and Social Affairs, Statistical Office, United Nations (1986: 142).
89
1900-12, 1924-27, 1933-39 and 1956-60 based on seven different sources. The sources
are the Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions of The United
Kingdom for the period 1900-1901, Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and
Other Possessions and Protectorates for the period 1902-1907 and Statistical Tables
Protectorates for the period 1908-12. Appendix to the Report on Trade, Straits
Settlements for the period 1924-27, the Annual Report, Returns of Import and Exports,
British Malaya and Malayan Statistics for the period 1933-39 and the Annual Report,
Singapore’s External Trade for the period 1956-60. Unfortunately, a complete set of
data on net imports of M&E for Singapore was not available for many years. This being
the case, it was necessary to make estimates of M&E for the missing years. In the case
of pre World War II period, a two-step estimation procedure was used. Firstly,
Singapore’s import value of M&E for the period 1913-23, 1928 and 1932 were
estimated based on the average ratio against the total import value of M&E for Straits
M&E for the Straits Settlements were distributed to Singapore on the grounds that large
amounts of M&E were purchased for Singapore for infrastructure building such as the
53
Annual Report, Straits Settlements, 1920, p.51.
90
Table 2.24
Estimating Singapore’s Imports of Transport, Machinery and Equipment for the
period 1913-23 and 1928-32
(Straits $)
Singapore [1]/[2] Straits Settlements
[1] [2]
1900 2,789,534 100% 2,789,534
1901 2,844,144 95% 2,989,628
1902 1,996,283 85% 2,348,134
1903 3,107,048 92% 3,364,716
1904 1,762,233 85% 2,065,266
1905 1,902,332 77% 2,456,378
1906 2,493,448 84% 2,985,329
1907 2,967,486 80% 3,690,461
1908 3,368,956 80% 4,199,327
1909 3,087,451 78% 3,973,806
1910 3,875,828 71% 5,466,342
1911 3,644,147 73% 4,993,771
1912 4,294,793 63% 6,771,441
1913 4,707,839 69% 6,813,000
1914 3,169,654 69% 4,587,000
1915 2,017,744 69% 2,920,000
1916 4,683,653 69% 6,778,000
1917 5,395,392 69% 7,808,000
1918 3,953,949 69% 5,722,000
1919 9,075,010 69% 13,133,000
1920 29,519,100 90% 32,799,000
1921 12,013,056 73% 16,435,000
1922 5,227,854 73% 7,152,200
1923 8,735,505 73% 11,951,000
1924 12,566,154 73% 17,191,691
1925 22,650,025 72% 31,669,998
1926 28,861,834 73% 39,338,957
1927 23,421,318 68% 34,607,035
1928 22,647,239 60% 37,630,239
1929 23,832,851 60% 39,600,229
1930 14,731,930 60% 24,478,305
1931 7,618,502 53% 14,459,288
1932 5,530,315 53% 10,496,082
1933 5,815,076 53% 11,036,535
1934 12,031,077 94% 12,765,495
1935 13,787,495 55% 24,908,410
1936 13,597,542 51% 26,688,037
1937 19,222,710 48% 40,424,359
1938 17,317,989 53% 32,486,643
1939 15,459,511 51% 30,544,750
Estimated Figure
Sources:
(Singapore)
1900-12: Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions of The United Kingdom
1902-07: Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions and Protectorates
1908-12: Statistical Tables Relating to British Self-Governing Dominions, Crown Colonies, Possessions and Protectorates
1924-27: Appendix to the Report on the Trade, Straits Settlements
1933-37: Report on Foreign Imports and Exports, British Malaya
1938-39: Foreign Trade of Malaya
(Straits Settlements)
1900-27: Appendix to the Report on the Trade, Straits Settlements
1928-39: Foreign Trade of Malaya
91
Secondly, total export values on M&E for the period 1913-23 and 1928-32 were
estimated based on the average percentage between import and export values on M&E
for the year 1910-12 and 1924 (See details in Table 2.25). Finally net imports were
derived by subtracting the value of exports from imports for the period 1900-39.
Table 2.25
Estimating Singapore’s Net Imports of Transport, Machinery and Equipment for
the period 1913-23 and 1928-32
(Straits $)
Imports [1]/[3] Exports [2]/[3] Total trade Net Imports
[1] [2] [3] [1]-[2]
1900 2,789,534 77% 828,767 23% 3,618,301 1,960,767
1901 2,844,144 77% 867,112 23% 3,711,256 1,977,032
1902 1,996,283 73% 750,491 27% 2,746,774 1,245,792
1903 3,107,048 79% 841,909 21% 3,948,957 2,265,139
1904 1,762,233 71% 710,643 29% 2,472,876 1,051,590
1905 1,902,332 69% 853,504 31% 2,755,836 1,048,828
1906 2,493,448 75% 843,608 25% 3,337,056 1,649,840
1907 2,967,486 70% 1,282,859 30% 4,250,345 1,684,627
1908 3,368,956 81% 801,176 19% 4,170,132 2,567,780
1909 3,087,451 77% 917,596 23% 4,005,047 2,169,855
1910 3,875,828 72% 1,515,728 28% 5,391,556 2,360,100
1911 3,644,147 68% 1,740,194 32% 5,384,341 1,903,953
1912 4,294,793 67% 2,123,872 33% 6,418,665 2,314,790
1913 4,707,839 69% 2,132,350 31% 6,840,188 2,575,489
1914 3,169,654 69% 1,435,651 31% 4,605,305 1,734,004
1915 2,017,744 69% 913,909 31% 2,931,653 1,103,835
1916 4,683,653 69% 2,121,395 31% 6,805,049 2,562,258
1917 5,395,392 69% 2,443,767 31% 7,839,159 2,951,625
1918 3,953,949 60% 2,635,966 40% 6,589,915 1,317,983
1919 9,075,010 60% 6,050,007 40% 15,125,017 3,025,003
1920 29,519,100 60% 19,679,400 40% 49,198,500 9,839,700
1921 12,013,056 60% 8,008,704 40% 20,021,759 4,004,352
1922 5,227,854 60% 3,485,236 40% 8,713,090 1,742,618
1923 8,735,505 60% 5,823,670 40% 14,559,175 2,911,835
1924 12,566,154 60% 8,288,299 40% 20,854,453 5,253,258
1925 22,650,025 61% 14,577,710 39% 37,227,735 10,535,117
1926 28,861,834 73% 10,739,152 27% 39,600,986 15,789,544
1927 23,421,318 63% 13,924,529 37% 37,345,847 11,553,270
1928 22,647,239 68% 2,812,682 32% 25,459,921 19,834,558
1929 23,832,851 68% 1,970,445 32% 25,803,295 21,862,406
1930 14,731,930 68% 1,541,426 32% 16,273,355 13,190,504
1931 7,618,502 71% 1,294,530 29% 8,913,032 6,323,971
1932 5,530,315 71% 1,036,928 29% 6,567,243 4,493,387
1933 5,815,076 71% 2,387,656 29% 8,202,732 3,427,420
1934 12,031,077 82% 2,668,216 18% 14,699,293 9,362,861
1935 13,787,495 81% 3,196,168 19% 16,983,663 10,591,327
1936 13,597,542 80% 3,355,608 20% 16,953,150 10,241,934
1937 19,222,710 80% 4,737,509 20% 23,960,219 14,485,201
1938 17,317,989 78% 4,812,617 22% 22,130,606 12,505,372
1939 15,459,511 77% 4,591,334 23% 20,050,845 10,868,177
Estimated Figure
Sources:
1900-01: Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions of The United Kingdom
1902-07: Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions and Protectorates
1908-12: Statistical Tables Relating to British Self-Governing Dominions, Crown Colonies, Possessions and Protectorates
1924-27: Appendix to the Report on the Trade, Straits Settlements
1933-37: Returns of Foreign Imports and Exports, British Malaya
1938-39: Foreign Trade of Malaya
92
In the post-war period, the presentation of trade data changed significantly. The
figures on net imports of machinery for the period 1956-60. However, prior to 1956 no
statistical data on net imports of machinery and equipment into Singapore was available.
Alternatively, two different methods were employed for the period 1953-55 and 1950-
52 respectively. For the period 1953-55, the ratio of total imports to exports on M&E in
Singapore against the Federation of Malaya’s imports to exports recorded in 1956 was
against Singapore’s total merchandize imports and exports for the year 1953 was
Table 2.26
Estimating Singapore’s Net Imports of Transport, Machinery and Equipment,
1948-60
(Straits $)
Imports of Transport, Machinery and Equipment Total Exports of Transport, Machinery and Equipment Total
Federation of [a]/[b] Singapore [b]/[c] Merchandize Federation of [a]/[b] Singapore [b]/[c] Merchandize
Malaya Imports Malaya Exports
[a] [b] [c] [a] [b] [c]
1950 199,738,539 6.1% 3,273,497,000 1950 143,266,747 4.7% 3,025,750,000
1951 306,744,250 6.1% 5,027,204,000 1951 224,683,264 4.7% 4,745,242,000
1952 228,816,678 6.1% 3,750,056,000 1952 151,498,874 4.7% 3,199,610,000
1953 172,800,000 94% 184,314,024 6.1% 3,020,706,000 1953 14,100,000 11% 125,670,091 4.7% 2,654,114,000
1954 148,700,000 94% 158,608,191 3,024,853,000 1954 9,600,000 11% 85,562,615 2,685,518,000
1955 174,300,000 94% 185,913,972 3,862,736,000 1955 13,700,000 11% 122,104,982 3,368,699,000
1956 231,500,000 94% 246,925,327 3,929,349,000 1956 17,600,000 11% 156,864,795 3,428,975,000
1957 244,900,000 281,354,832 4,091,837,000 1957 25,500,000 172,293,132 3,478,133,000
1958 222,700,000 254,978,710 3,740,065,000 1958 19,100,000 166,727,342 3,140,343,000
1959 242,500,000 225,009,047 3,907,670,000 1959 18,100,000 181,928,013 3,440,263,000
1960 330,300,000 287,421,374 4,077,686,000 1960 30,800,000 232,912,385 3,477,053,000
Sources:
(Federation of Malaya) 1953-60: Monthly Statistical Bulletin, Federation of Malaya
(Singapore) 1956-60: Singapore’s External Trade
No commodity taxes were levied on imports on M&E during this period so that cost,
insurance and freight (c.i.f) and producers’ values were identical. Estimated trade and
transport margins of 16% and 2%54 respectively were added to the producers’ values to
arrive at market prices. The final step was to determine what proportion of net imports
54
Due to the complete absence of information, this study used similar margins introduced by Nazrin (2002: 26)
93
to capitalize. Some of these imports would have been used as inputs in construction
consumption (repairs and maintenance) and some as current consumption in the case of
military expenditure. It was not possible to determine these values from historical
records. Consequently, 10% of net import was assigned for the above and the remaining
Table 2.27
Singapore: Transport, Machinery and Equipment Investment,
1900-39 and 1950-60 in Current Prices (Straits $)
Singapore Net Imports of Plus 18% [Trade Margin (16%) Investment in Machinery, Transport
M&E (CIF) and Transport (2%)] and Equipment
55
Due to the complete absence of information, this study used similar margins introduced by Nazrin (2002: 26)
94
2.4.3.3 Investment in M&E in 1914 Prices
No proper price indices were available for Singapore during the British colonial
period. As an alternative option, UK price indices for capital goods on plant and
machinery provided by Feinstein (1972) were utilized on the grounds that Singapore
had imported M&E to a large extent from UK (See Table 2.28). These deflators were
then applied to obtain investment in M&E in constant prices, the data being presented in
Table 2.29.
Table 2.28
Singapore: Deflators for Investment for Machinery, Equipment and Transports
(1914=100)
Table 2.29
Singapore: Transport, Machinery and Equipment Investment,
1900-39 and 1950-60 in 1914 Prices
(Straits $)
1900-39and 1950-60 (1914=100)
1900 2,042,406 1910 2,673,094 1920 4,124,390 1930 11,344,603 1950 17,477,718
1901 2,168,792 1911 2,088,625 1921 2,378,224 1931 5,820,059 1951 23,666,617
1902 1,426,987 1912 2,436,259 1922 1,367,683 1932 4,146,661 1952 20,056,793
1903 2,651,651 1913 2,604,923 1923 2,408,106 1933 3,292,109 1953 14,688,992
1904 1,231,028 1914 1,841,512 1924 4,264,282 1934 8,470,362 1954 18,251,082
1905 1,227,795 1915 919,646 1925 8,579,322 1935 9,355,782 1955 15,206,936
1906 1,931,360 1916 1,790,975 1926 13,122,429 1936 8,484,017 1956 20,273,714
1907 1,908,040 1917 1,601,587 1927 9,431,241 1937 10,464,819 1957 23,671,270
1908 2,816,840 1918 650,583 1928 15,972,324 1938 8,983,161 1958 18,658,017
1909 2,457,619 1919 1,275,886 1929 17,141,288 1939 7,472,729 1959 9,079,681
1960 11,353,367
2.4.4.1 Definition
consists of trees (including shrubs) and are cultivated and take more than a year to
95
become productive for the products that they yield year after year. Cultivated assets
produced on own-account are valued by the value of cost incurred in their production
during the period. For example, the calculation takes into account, the cost of preparing
the ground (including felling, clearing, stumping and burning, soil conservation,
draining and chankolling), lining, holing and planting (including seedlings and plants),
fertilizers applied), pruning, weeding, upkeep, draining, etc, until the trees reach
The perennial crops investment in Singapore examined are rubber and coconut. No
estimates were made for other perennial crops since the investments were negligible.56
preparing the estimates, all expenses sunk into perennial crops prior to their reaching the
fruit-bearing age were treated as an investment expense. Once the trees began to yield
expense. The following information was compiled for rubber and coconuts.
maturity are derived by multiplying the total acreage (newly planted) with the
corresponding base year estimates of cost of development per acre at different stages of
maturity. This yearly estimates are then aggregated to arrive at the yearly estimates of
96
assets are transformed into nominal investment figures based on the nominal earnings
index of rubber tappers (See Figure 2.15). This procedure was resorted to in the absence
this was not a major drawback, since wages of rubber tappers was the single largest
acreage for rubber and coconut were obtained by taking the year-to-year changes in
total planted acreage. This method should give a fairly accurate picture of new plantings
as long as there was not much replanting activity being undertaken. Consider the
following example. If old coconut trees were completely removed and the land
replanted with coconut seedlings, the records will show no change in total planted
acreage of coconuts, and our estimates will understate the actual investment in coconut
planting.
Figure 2.15
Singapore: Format for Calculating Investment on Coconut Planting
at Current Prices, 1910-16
1910 1911 1912 1913 1914 1915 1916
Newly Planted Acreage for 1910 [1] 10 10 10 10 10 10
Cost per acre (1911 prices) [2] 50 20 20 20 20 20
Value [A]= [1]x[2] 500 200 200 200 200 200
1910 1911 1912 1913 1914 1915 1916
Newly Planted Acreage for 1911 [3] 30 30 30 30 30 30
Cost per acre (1911 prices) [4] 50 20 20 20 20 20
Value [B]=[3]x[4] 1500 600 600 600 600 600
1910 1911 1912 1913 1914 1915 1916
Investment (1911 prices) [C]=[A]+[B] 500 1700 800 800 800 800 600
Rubber Tappers Indices (1911 prices) [D] 90 100 110 120 130 140 150
Investment (Current Prices) [E]=[C]x[D]/100 450 1,700 880 960 1,040 1,120 900
Instead, if the land was converted to rubber, then the records will show an increase
in total rubber acreage, and this new investment in rubber will be included in our
estimates. The historical records indicate that there were no significant replanting that
were undertaken for the crops considered here, except in the case of rubber.
There were some years in which data on planted acreage were not available and it
was necessary to make some broad assumptions. The method of estimation employed
97
was to assume constant annual increases in newly planted acreage for the missing years.
If the records show a reduction in total acreage planted between any two years, this
estimates show no new plantings and hence no investment in those years. For both
rubber and coconut, a distinction was made between smallholding and estate cultivation.
This is because the cost structure of the estate was considerably higher than that of the
investments. In some years, the breakdown of total acreage into smallholding and estate
cultivation could be obtained directly from source materials. In other years, this
information was not directly available, and the breakdown was derived in two stages.
First, estate acreage was established based on the assumption that its share of total
acreage was the same as that of the nearest year for which data on both total acreage and
estate acreage were available. Second, smallholding acreage was obtained by taking the
difference between total and estate acreage. The cost-per-acre estimates used was
governed by data availability. The calculations took into account the cost of land
preparation (including felling, clearing, stumping and burning, soil conservation and
draining), lining, holing and planting, protection from weather and disease (including
use of insecticides, pesticides and fertilizer), pruning, weeding, and upkeep until the
trees reached maturity. Contemporary estimates were used wherever possible. Since our
study period spans 40 years (1900-39), an attempt was made to use varying cost
estimates for different sub-periods in order to take into account more accurately changes
in costs over time. For the rubber estate, three sets of cost estimates were used
respectively for the entire period. In the case of rubber smallholdings, however, only
one period was selected due to the general unavailability of data. The estimates for
estates rubber tabulated in Tables 2.30, 2.31 and 2.32 were used in the calculations
covering the period 1900-20, 1921-30 and 1931-39 respectively. Table 2.33 shows the
98
Table 2.30
Rubber, Cost-per-acre Estimates, Estate, 1900-20 in 1911 Prices
Year
Item Total
1 2 3 4 5 6
Survey 1.00 1.00
Felling, clearing and burning 15.00 15.00
Cleaning up after burning 7.50 7.50
Weeding 18.00 12.00 9.00 5.00 5.00 5.00 54.00
Draining 5.00 5.00
Holing, lining and filling 4.00 4.00
Planting and supplying 2.00 2.00
2 year old plants 4.00 4.00
Tools 10.00 10.00
Management 12.50 12.50 12.50 12.50 12.50 12.50 75.00
Hospital, medical attendance 3.75 3.75 3.75 3.75 3.75 3.75 22.50
Contingencies 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 12.00
Cultivated Assets 84.75 30.25 27.25 23.25 23.25 23.25 212.00
Source: Figart (1925:90)
Table 2.31
Rubber, Cost-per-acre Estimate, Estate, 1921-30 in 1924 Prices
Year
Item Total
1 2 3 4 5 6
Preliminary Expenses 3.00 3.00
Felling 12.00 12.00
Clearing and burning 40.00 40.00
Stumping and burning 80.00 80.00
Sundry expenses in connection with clearing 4.00 4.00
Soil conservation, draining and chankolling 30.00 30.00
Lining, holing and planting including nurseries 17.00 17.00
Upkeep 12.00 20.00 20.00 15.00 15.00 15.00 97.00
Miscellaneous purchases, etc. 7.00 7.00
General charges: Superintendence, $130, labour charges
35.00 37.00 35.00 36.00 36.00 36.00 215.00
(recruiting, medical expenses, etc) $60, other $25
Cultivated Assets 240.00 57.00 55.00 51.00 51.00 51.00 505.00
Source: Figart (1925:52).
Table 2.32
Rubber, Cost-per-acre Estimate, Estate, 1931-39 in 1934 Prices
Year
Item Total
1 2 3 4 5 6
Survey 1.00 1.00
Felling, clearing and burning 10.50 10.50
Cleaning up after burning 5.25 5.25
Weeding 12.60 8.40 6.30 3.50 30.80
Draining 3.50 3.50
Holing, lining and filling 4.00 4.00
Planting and supplying 2.00 2.00
2 year old plants 4.00 4.00
Tools 8.00 8.00
Management 6.66 6.66 6.66 6.66 6.66 6.66 40.00
Hospital, medical attendance 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 12.00
Contingencies 1.08 1.08 1.08 1.08 1.08 1.08 6.48
Cultivated Assets 60.59 18.14 16.04 13.24 9.74 9.74 127.53
Source: Bauer, P.T.(1948: 129-130)
Table 2.33
Rubber, Cost-per-acre Estimate, Smallholdings, 1900-39 in 1924 Prices
Year
Item Total
1 2 3 4 5 6
Clearing and burning 50.00 50.00
Soil conservation, draining and chankolling 5.00 5.00
Lining, holing and planting including nurseries 5.00 5.00
Upkeep 10.00 8.00 8.00 8.00 8.00 8.00 50.00
Cultivated Assets 70.00 8.00 8.00 8.00 8.00 8.00 110.00
Source: Figart (1925: 90).
99
In the case of coconuts, different cost production estimates were used for estates and
smallholdings. In the case of the former, two sets of estimates were used, one for the
period 1900-27 (Table 2.34) and the other for the period 1928-39 (Table 2.35). The
estimates for smallholdings are shown in Table 2.36. The period to maturity was 6 years
for estates and 8 years for smallholdings. These tables present the estimates on private
Table 2.34
Coconuts, Cost-per-acre Estimate, Estate, 1900-27 in 1908 Prices
Year
Item Total
1 2 3 4 5 6
Felling and clearing 10.00 10.00
Draining 12.00 12.00
Cost of seed 6.40 6.40
Fencing 2.00 2.00
Lining and planting 2.00 2.00
Tools 2.00 2.00
Stationery and postage 0.10 0.10
Medical 0.10 0.10
Weeding 6.00 12.00 8.40 7.00 7.00 7.00 47.40
Contingencies 1.00 1.00
Superintendence 6.00 6.00 6.00 6.00 6.00 6.00 36.00
Supplying 0.60 0.60
Cultivated Assets 47.60 18.00 15.00 13.00 13.00 13.00 119.60
Source: Straits Settlements and Federated Malay States (1909). Agricultural Bulletin, No.5, Vol.8, Appendix. B, pp.237-238.
Table 2.35
Coconuts, Cost-per-acre Estimate, Estate, 1928-39 in 1928 Prices
Year
Items Total
1 2 3 4 5
Tools 0.40 0.40 0.40 0.40 0.40 2.00
Felling, burning and clearing 27.00 27.00
Seeds 2.00 2.00
Lining, holing and planting 3.00 3.00
Supplying 0.60 0.60 0.60 0.60 0.60 3.00
Circle cultivation of seedlings 3.00 3.00
Weeding 4.20 4.20 4.20 4.20 4.20 21.00
Cover crops 0.80 0.80 0.80 0.80 0.80 4.00
Pests and diseases 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 10.00
Survey Fees, Suprintendence, Medical
7.52 7.52 7.52 7.52 7.52 37.60
& Contingencies and Quit-rent*
Total 50.52 15.52 15.52 15.52 15.52 112.60
Note:
The above estimate does not take into account cost of premium on land , survey fees, permanent buildings, renticing and bunding (at
present 20 cents per foot) and other overhead charges.
* Item 1-9 excludes (i)survey fees, (ii) suprintendence, (iii) medical and contingencies, and (iv) quit-rent. Item 10 [(i)survey fees,
(ii) suprintendence, (iii) medical and contingencies, and (iv) quit-rent]- estimates based on Coconut estates cost structure, 1908.
100
Table 2.36
Coconuts, Cost-per-acre Estimate, Smallholdings, 1900-39 in 1934 Prices
Year
Item Total
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
Seeding 7.00 7.00
Copra sun dried nuts 2.00 2.00
Tools and stores 5.00 5.00
Cover crop 1.00 1.00
Pest and disease 0.62 0.62 0.62 0.62 0.62 0.62 0.62 0.62 4.96
Contingencies 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.75 6.00
Cultivated Assets 16.37 1.37 1.37 1.37 1.37 1.37 1.37 1.37 25.96
Source: Federated Malay States (1932) Third Inter-Departmental Agricultural Conference, Kuala Lumpur: Government Printing
office, Appendix p.5.
Even for the same crop at the same point in time and employing the same type of
cultivation, the costs of opening up an acre of land could vary considerably depending
on location, type of land and other local circumstances. It is, of course, not possible to
cover all cases. Instead it was necessary to resort to some generalizations. Subsequently,
these estimates of total real investment in cultivated assets were transformed into
nominal investment figures based on the nominal rubber tappers’ wage indices.57 The
nominal figures of investments for rubber and coconut planting with breakdown on
57
Blue Book, Straits Settlements, provides information on minimum Indian rubber tappers’ wage for the period 1913-38. For the
year 1939, wage of 1938 was applied. Prior to 1913, no specific wage for rubber tapper was available. As an alternative option, the
movement of wage rate for predial workers provided in Blue Book, Straits Settlements for the period 1900-14 was treated as a
proxy of Indian rubber tappers wage.
101
Table 2.37
Singapore: Rubber, Cultivated Assets, 1900-39 in Current Prices
(Straits $)
Estate Smallholding Total
1900-20 1921-30 1931-39 1900-39
1911 Rubber Current 1924 Rubber Current 1934 Price Rubber Current 1924 Price Rubber Current Current
Price Tappers Prices Price Tappers Prices Tappers Prices Tappers Prices Prices
Earnings Earnings Earnings Earnings
Index Index Index Index
(1911=100) (1924=100) (1934=100) (1924=100)
[1] [2] [3]=[1]*[2] [1] [2] [3]=[1]*[2] [1] [2] [3]=[1]*[2] [1] [2] [3]=[1]*[2]
/100 /100 /100 /100
102
Table 2.38
Singapore: Coconuts, Cultivated Assets, 1900-39 in Current Prices
(Straits $)
Estate Smallholding Total
1900-27 1928-39 1900-39
6 years to Maturity (1908=100) 4 years to Maturity (1928=100) 8 years to Maturity (1934=100)
1908 Price Rubber Current 1928 Price Rubber Current 1932 Price Rubber Current Current
Tappers Prices Tappers Prices Tappers Prices Prices
Earnings Earnings Earnings
Index Index Index
(1908=100) (1928=100) (1932=100)
rubber tappers’ wage indices as illustrated in Table 2.39.58 By utilizing these indices,
cultivated assets in constant prices were obtained and are presented in Table 2.40.
58
Real wage indices of rubber tappers were derived by deflating nominal wage indices by the consumer price indices.
103
Table 2.39
Singapore: Indian Rubber Tapper’s Wage Indices, 1900-39 (1914=100)
Table 2.40
Singapore: Cultivated Assets in 1914 Prices, 1900-39
(Straits $)
1900-39 (1914=100)
1900 - 1910 1,964,924 1920 1,958,281 1930 907,778
1901 131,963 1911 2,860,613 1921 1,396,065 1931 32,921
1902 84,863 1912 2,118,880 1922 1,175,007 1932 978,619
1903 48,990 1913 1,424,238 1923 575,530 1933 243,763
1904 389,060 1914 1,346,877 1924 387,926 1934 1,101,203
1905 475,762 1915 1,232,312 1925 38,539 1935 703,827
1906 289,807 1916 801,289 1926 23,011 1936 350,130
1907 1,224,631 1917 2,057,063 1927 3,725 1937 345,771
1908 602,615 1918 1,537,395 1928 3,136 1938 238,974
1909 800,500 1919 2,782,751 1929 2,379 1939 181,813
2.4.5.1 Definition
Stocks, or inventories, consist mainly of goods that have been purchased for
intermediate consumption but not yet used, goods produced for sale but not yet sold,
(work in progress), and livestock being raised for slaughter. Government stocks of
strategic materials, grains and other goods of special importance to a country in time of
crisis are also included. Work in progress on heavy machinery, ships and similar items
104
are included in stocks, but work in progress on construction is treated as gross fixed
capital formation. The natural increase in standing crops and timber is not included in
stocks, nor are new discoveries (or additions to proven reserves) of mineral resources
such as oil. In practice, problems may arise in drawing the line between the increase in
stocks and gross fixed capital formation for heavy machinery and ships that take a
considerable time to complete. It often happens that the basic data supplied by
What enters into gross capital formation is not total inventories, but the addition to
inventories in the period of account. Since prices are likely to change over the course of
the period, it is necessary to distinguish between the change in the value of inventories
and the value of the physical change in them. It is the latter that is wanted, valued at
purchasers’ prices when acquired from other units and at producers’ prices when
produced by the unit owning the stocks. The valuation should in principle be at the
prices current at the time the additions to stocks are made, and withdrawals from stocks
for internal processing or for sale should similarly in principle be valued at the prices
current at the time the withdrawal takes place. Work in progress, for which there is
almost never possible to follow these principles strictly. In devising alternative methods,
the objective should be to ensure that what is being measured is the change in the
physical quantity of stocks, measured at suitable fixed prices during the whole
accounting period.
Currently, data on the value of stocks are collected in production censuses and
surveys, and in special quarterly or annual surveys of stocks. The colonial government
records, however, did not provide sufficient information to construct reliable estimates.
59
Department of International Economic and Social Affairs, Statistical Office, United Nations (1986: 143).
105
Under these serious constraints of data unavailability, an observation was made to
examine whether there is any statistical relationship between GDP growth rate and
value of changes in stocks for the period 1960-2000.60 For the period 1960-2000,
correlations between these variables are 0.42334. The correlation of closest period of
1960-1969 was even higher, that is 0.77217. This correlation test somewhat portrays the
fact that GDP growth rate has been positively correlated with the level of change in
stock.
GDP for the period 1960-1969 were observed, as is presented in Table 2.41, size of
Table 2.41
Singapore: Change in Stocks as a proportion to GDP, 1960-69
Based on this observation, the following ranges of weights were assigned for the
Changes of Stock to GDP in relation to GDP growth rate (See Table 2.42).
Subsequently, similar ranging bands were assigned based on the growth rate of
estimated GDP (exclusive of change of stocks) for the period 1900-39 and 1950-60 as
60
Figures obtained from Department of Statistics, Singapore (1996) and Asian Development Bank (2001).
106
Table 2.42
Singapore: Weights Assigned for the Change of Stocks to GDP (%) in relation to
GDP Growth Rate
Table 2.43
Singapore: Percentage Contributions of Change in Stocks to GDP,
1900-39 and 1950-60
1900 0.0 1910 1.5 1920 0.0 1930 -2.0 1950 0.0
1901 1.5 1911 -1.0 1921 2.5 1931 -3.0 1951 2.0
1902 0.0 1912 -1.5 1922 0.0 1932 -2.0 1952 -1.5
1903 -1.5 1913 0.0 1923 -1.5 1933 2.0 1953 2.5
1904 1.0 1914 1.5 1924 -1.5 1934 -1.0 1954 1.0
1905 2.0 1915 2.5 1925 2.0 1935 2.5 1955 -1.0
1906 1.0 1916 -1.5 1926 0.0 1936 0.0 1956 2.0
1907 0.0 1917 3.0 1927 0.0 1937 2.0 1957 0.0
1908 2.0 1918 2.0 1928 2.5 1938 0.0 1958 0.0
1909 0.0 1919 3.0 1929 2.5 1939 2.0 1959 0.0
1960 1.5
stock appreciation in the accounting period as well. Stock appreciation is the change in
the money value of stocks, in the accounting period, which is due to changes in price
rather than changes in physical quantity of stocks. Based on this recognition, import unit
value index was alternatively used as deflator. Admittedly, these arbitrary assignments
of stock values are not entirely satisfactory from a methodological point of view and
107
2.5 Net Exports of Goods and Services
2.5.1 Definition
As is presented in Figure 2.16, Exports and Imports of Goods and Services defined
miscellaneous goods and services.61 The definitions of merchandize trade used in SNA
and in foreign trade statistics are similar in most respects. Merchandize exports are
value.63
Figure 2.16
Classification of Exports and Imports of Goods and Services
Source: Department of International, Economic and Social Affairs, United Nations (1986:148-149).
61
It refers to the gross margin realized by resident merchants on goods purchased in another country and sold in a third country
and reimbursements of the cost of home office services of parent companies by foreign branches and subsidiaries.
62
In addition to the producer’s value of commodities at the establishment of the exports, f.o.b values include all costs of
transporting the goods to the custom frontier of the exporting country, exports duties and the cost of loading the goods onto the
international carrier.
63
Freight and insurance charges incurred after the merchandize has left the establishment of the exporters and until it reaches the
customs frontier of the importer should be added to its f.o.b. value. Import duties and the cost of unloading the goods from the
carrier are not included in the c.i.f. value.
108
Other than merchandize trade figures provided in foreign trade statistics, a number
of items should be included as service trade. These are (1) fuel and stores sold or
resident enterprises, (2) repair work done as exports or imports of services. Additionally,
exports of services, and direct purchases abroad by resident households are included as
It is important to note that all transactions in goods and services between residents
the goods passes between buyer and seller in the definition of national accounting. In
other words, trade statistics as represented by the transaction of goods and services
between the national geographical boundaries (ie. across national custom frontiers) does
not provide an actual picture of external trade in the national accounting sense.64
The export and import figures recorded for Singapore during the British colonial
period in official publications essentially referred to imports and exports of goods which
crossed the customs frontier. Since we were not able to identify the ownership of these
goods, data in this series could not be used to provide specific figures for the exports
and imports of goods and services in line with the national accounting framework.
Therefore, only data on net exports of goods and services are presented in order to
64
Practically, it is difficult to quantify the difference between the value of goods that still remain in the country of exporter after
the change in ownership has occurred and the value of goods that have crossed custom boundaries of a country without change in
ownership. (Department of International Economic and Social Affairs, United Nations (1986: 147).
109
2.5.2 Merchandize Trade in Current Prices
available during the 1900-39. For the period 1900-27, the Appendix to the Report on the
Trade, Straits Settlements provided information on Singapore's trade with the Rest Of
the World or ROW (exclusive of trade with the Malay states) and also Singapore's trade
with Malay States. However, this set of data series is no longer available after 1927.
Figure 2.17
Singapore: Statistical Sources of Trade Statistics, 1900-39
Singapore as a Separate Entity (1) + (2)
(1) Singapore's trade with Rest of World (exclusive of trade with Malaya) (2) Singapore's trade with Malaya
1899-1901 1902-1907 1908-12 1900-19 1900-27 1921-37 1928-39 1899-1901 1902-1907 1908-12 1900-19 1900-27 1928-39
1899
STCOP
STCOP
UK
UK
1900
1901
1902
1903
STCPP
STCPP
1904
1905
1906
1907
1908
SSBB
SSBB
STBCPP
STBCPP
1909
1910
1911
1912
ARTSS
ARTSS
1913
1914
1915
1916
1917
1918
1919
1920
1921
1922
1923
1924
1925
1926
1927
1928
BM
1929
1930
1931
Not Available
1932
FTM
1933
1934
1935
1936
1937
1938
1939
Abbreviations:
STCOPUK Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions of the United Kingdom
STCPP Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions and Protectorates
STBCPP Statistical Tables Relating to British Colonies, Possessions and Protectorates
SSBB Blue Book, Straits Settlements
ARTSS Appendix to the Report on Trade, Straits Settlements
BM Returns of Foreign Imports and Exports, British Malaya
FTM Foreign Trade, Malaya
110
This is mainly because the British colonial authority created British Malaya (Straits
Settlements, Federated Malay States and the five Unfederated Malay States) as one
consolidated administrative entity from 1921 onwards. The Annual Report, Returns of
Imports and Exports, British Malaya provided fairly detailed information on trade such
as the quantity and value of imports / exports as well as the origin and destination of
each item. Singapore was treated as a major entry / exit gate for British Malaya. Data
recorded in the Annual Report, the Foreign Trade of Malaya partially provided trade
figures on Singapore with the ROW (exclusive of trade with the Malay States).
However, data on Singapore's trade with the Malay States became no longer available
due to the termination of compiling trade data which treated Singapore as a separate
entity.
For the above time periods, the figures for merchandise trade of Singapore was only
available from 1956 onwards in the Annual Report, Singapore’s External Trade. For the
periods 1928-39 and 1950-55 no official data on total merchandise trade of Singapore
was available. Given this scenario, estimates constructed by G.W. Huff for the missing
including but not limited to false invoicing of imports and exports, simple errors in
counting and recording, time lags, and smuggling. In fact, sudden fluctuation of trade
import and export value for several years seems quite impossible to explain when we
aggregate the other components of GDP. Therefore, in order to check the reliability of
trade figures, quantitative investigations were made by observing the net import value
of selected major categories. Here, it is assumed that the quantity of net imports retained
111
in the domestic market was fully consumed (exclusive of stock) by both resident and
non-resident households at market prices. In this exercise, the net import value of
manufactured textiles retained in Singapore was computed for the period 1900-27 based
on the Appendix to the Report on Trade, Straits Settlements. Subsequently, this data
series was compared with private final consumption expenditure on clothing in the
domestic market.
Generally, net import values on manufactured textiles were always higher than that
of private final consumption expenditure on clothing. In addition, it was found that the
total net import value of food and beverages was generally higher than that of private
final consumption expenditure on these items save for a couple of years. Based on this
observation, it was decided to adjust the import value of merchandise items accordingly.
The resulting adjusted net exports in current prices for the period 1900-39 and 1950-60
Table 2.44
Singapore: Merchandize Net Exports in Current Prices,
1900-39 and 1950-60
(Straits $ Millions)
Merchandize Net Exports at Current Prices
1900 -28.3 1920 -117.5 1950 -247.7
1901 -25.8 1921 -77.7 1951 -282.0
1902 -26.9 1922 -43.6 1952 -550.4
1903 -33.6 1923 -63.2 1953 -366.6
1904 -34.7 1924 -85.3 1954 -339.3
1905 -28.7 1925 -87.3 1955 -494.0
1906 -24.4 1926 -106.6 1956 -500.4
1907 -29.4 1927 -137.6 1957 -613.7
1908 -25.1 1928 -106.5 1958 -599.7
1909 -25.3 1929 -64.9 1959 -467.4
1910 -24.4 1930 -57.0 1960 -600.6
1911 -32.1 1931 -64.2
1912 -44.7 1932 -57.8
1913 -54.0 1933 -16.7
1914 -49.5 1934 -36.8
1915 -35.4 1935 -28.8
1916 -51.4 1936 -44.0
1917 -45.3 1937 -45.1
1918 -65.7 1938 -74.0
1919 -44.3 1939 -61.9
112
2.5.4 Services Trade, 1900-39 and 1950-60
no direct information is available on trade in services for the period 1900-39 and 1950-
60. Official figures on trade in services for Singapore only can be traced from the
percentage contribution of services trade changed over time. In 1960, the percentage
contribution of service exports to total goods and services exported was 16.7% and its
proportion increased to 24.5% by 1970. On the other hand, the percentage contribution
of service imports (exclusive of freight and insurance) to total goods and services
imported was negligible. In 1960, the figure was only 1.7% and its proportion increased
slightly to 3.3% by 1970. The percentage contribution of merchandise trade has varied
over time and its composition has been subject to change. Therefore, the conversion
ratio method might not be favorable to identify the value of service trade for Singapore.
Due to the deficiencies of available information on the service trade, two possible areas
of estimates were deemed to be feasible, namely the (i) trade of goods and services
made in port and (ii) non-resident consumption made in the domestic market. The
following procedures were applied for their estimation for the period 1900-39 and 1950-
60.
It is assumed that a major portion of coal retained in Singapore (total imports less
total exports of coal) was utilized for the supply of bunker coal to foreign ships. Trade
information was derived from the Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other
Possessions of The United Kingdom for the period 1900-01, Statistical Tables Relating
to the Colonial and Other Possessions and Protectorates for the period 1902-07 and
113
Possessions and Protectorates for the period 1908-12. No figures were available for the
storage and stevedorage were applied. Subsequently for the period 1922-39, The
was not available. Therefore, the proportion for Singapore was estimated based on the
number of vessels that entered Singapore and Penang. After World War II, net import
figures of coal were again not available. However, the outward movement of outwards
tonnage on coal ships from Singapore which was provided for in the Singapore
Harbour Board Report, 1963 was utilized as a proxy to estimate the figure on sales of
coal.
Due to the technological innovation, some ships started to use petroleum. Singapore
served as a supplier of Petroleum. The Foreign Trade of Malaya provided data for the
petroleum sold for ships entering Singapore for the period 1922-38. After World War II,
outwards tonnage on petroleum ships from Singapore which was provided in the
Singapore Harbour Board Report, 1963 was utilized as the proxy to estimate the figure
on the sale of water to ships for the period 1918-39. The Annual Administration Report
of City Council, Singapore also provided specific revenue obtained from the sale of
water to ships for the period 1950-59. No figures were available prior to 1918. Thus, an
estimation procedure was applied to fill the gap for the period 1900-17. Due to the
deficiencies of data, the movement of revenue derived from wharfage, storage and
stevedorage were applied to calculate water revenue during the said period.
114
2.5.4.4 Revenue collection based on services provided by the Singapore Harbour
Board
The Annual Report, Singapore Harbour Board provided the revenue collected from
services provided to foreign ships by docks and machine shops. Additionally, the
Singapore Harbour Board collected revenue from services on wharfage, storage and
stevedorage. Statistical figures on the above-mentioned revenue were available for the
period 1910-36 and 1950-60. Prior to 1910, the movement of earnings from the sale of
coal was applied as a proxy to estimate the revenue earned from wharfage, storage and
stevedorage.
The Blue Book, Straits Settlements provided figures on revenue from port and
A large number of foreign ship passengers purchased goods and services in the
Singapore. Most western industrialized countries and Japan stationed embassies or high
commissions in Singapore but the data on the actual number of people employed was
not available. Most importantly, there was a massive number of immigrants, mainly
from mainland China, who entered Singapore for a short period before departing to
another part of British Malaya as well as other countries in the South East Asian region.
2.5.5.1 Construction of Import and Export Unit Value Indices, 1900-39 and
1950-60 (1914=100)
In the economy of any country there are a large variety of trading goods and
services. From one period to the next, both the quantity and price of these goods and
115
services are subject to change due to the transition of market structure. Price indices of
imports and exports attempt to isolate the effects of price changes on the value of these
goods and services and measure the aggregate effect of these changes in a single
number. For the construction of price indices, three different types of indicies can be
constructed, namely, the Laspeyres Price Index, Paasche Price Index and Fisher Price
Index. The most commonly used indices are the fixed weight indices where quantities
are held constant for either some past period or the current period. The Laspeyres Index
keeps the quantities (Q) fixed for some period in the past (0). In its simplest form, it is a
ratio of what it costs today to purchase the same set of goods and services that were
purchased in a specific previous period. The Paasche index keeps the quantities fixed at
their levels in the current period (t). In its simplest form, it is the ratio of what today’s
purchases cost compared to what they would have cost in the previous period. Both of
these indices fail the time reversal, circularity and factor reversal tests. There are classes
of indices, called superlative indices, which pass the factor reversal test and have the
property of being a closer approximation to the ideal consumer utility function than the
Paasche or Laspeyres. These indices use weight information from two periods. The
simplest of these indices is the Fisher index which is the geometric mean (square root)
comparison to which all price measures are related. Chained indices use a current period
as the point of reference and then link the index for this period to that of the previous
period. When the comparison point is changed in fixed-base indices, the entire series
must be recalculated using the aggregation weights of the new comparison point.
External trade is usually covered through export and import price indices which
measure the change in prices of representative export and import transactions. When
specific information from exporters and importers cannot be obtained, unit values
(average prices for specific products) were used as a proxy for prices to compute indices.
116
The use of chained-Laspeyres price indices with annual weight updates are an
Laspeyres indices were utilized as an appropriate proxy for these estimates.65 In the
case of Singapore, the feature of import and export unit value indices was quite different
from other countries. For example in the case of neighboring country like Malaya, the
export unit value indices could be constructed based on a few major export commodities
such as rubber and tin since the price movements of these few items can represent the
pattern of total merchandize exports. On the other hand, the movement of import unit
value indices of Malaya followed in tandem with that of the Consumer Price Indices
(CPI) since Malaya mainly imported various consumer items due to the lack of a local
food production and manufacturing base. Therefore, the level and movement of export
and import unit value indices in Malaya were very different throughout the period.
In the case of Singapore, however, the level and movement of export and import
unit value indices was almost identical. As is illustrated in Table 2.45, the official
import and export price indices of Singapore (1990=100) was fairly close to each other
in the 1960s, 1970s and 1980s and subsequently even in the first half of the 1990s the
price indices did not deviate very much. This phenomenon can be explained because
Singapore served as an entrepôt. The bulk of the items imported into Singapore were re-
exported to other parts of world. Based on this observation, it would be safe to assume
that this situation prevailed retrospectively during the 1900-39 and 1950-60 time
periods. The nature of statistical data that was available necessitated the construction of
import / export price indices for three different periods, namely the 1900-27, 1928-39
65
Currently, Department of Statistics Singapore conducts compilation of Export and Import Unit Value Indices using the
Laspeyres formula (Department of Statistics, Singapore, 2008).
117
Table 2.45
Singapore: Imports and Export Price Index for Goods and Services,
1960-95 (1990=100)
Exports of Imports of Exports of Imports of Exports of Imports of Exports of Imports of
Goods and Goods and Goods and Goods and Goods and Goods and Goods and Goods and
Services Services Services Services Services Services Services Services
1960 52.5 53.4 1970 52.6 53.5 1980 113.1 116.1 1990 100.0 100.0
1961 52.5 53.4 1971 53.2 54.1 1981 116.9 119.7 1991 97.6 96.4
1962 52.5 53.4 1972 53.4 54.4 1982 116.6 117.2 1992 94.0 93.0
1963 52.4 53.3 1973 60.5 61.6 1983 111.0 111.2 1993 93.1 91.9
1964 53.3 54.2 1974 85.4 85.7 1984 104.9 106.2 1994 92.1 89.2
1965 53.0 53.9 1975 86.1 86.7 1985 103.3 105.1 1995 91.3 88.1
1966 50.7 51.6 1976 91.9 92.6 1986 89.5 91.1
1967 51.0 51.9 1977 95.6 96.7 1987 96.3 98.7
1968 48.2 49.0 1978 97.5 98.8 1988 97.9 99.4
1969 50.2 51.1 1979 102.8 104.9 1989 99.3 99.9
For this period, the Appendix to the Report on the Trade, Straits Settlements
provided trade statistics of Singapore as an entity. Fortunately this report provided value
of merchandize imports and exports by class of commodities, viz [A] Live animals,
food, drinks and narcotics, [B] Raw materials and [C] Manufactured and partly
manufactured articles. In the case of Class [B] and Class [C] further breakdown was
made for [a] Textile goods, [b] Metal goods and [c] Others (See Table 2.46) and the
price indices which represent each component were chosen and used for each class of
commodities. Weights of each major class of commodities for imports / exports varied
over time. In particular, weights on food, drinks and narcotics have frequently changed.
As presented in Table 2.47, Import unit value indices made use of 7 time intervals,
namely 1900-08, 1908-14, 1914-16, 1916-19, 1919-20, 1920-22 and 1922-27. Weights
being chosen for import unit value indices for the years 1904, 1914, 1916, 1918,
1919,1921 and 1923. In the case of export unit value indices, 8 time intervals were
and 1925-27. The weights chosen were for the years 1904, 1914, 1916, 1918, 1919,
1921, 1924 and 1927 (See Table 2.48). The various interval series were then chained at
their overlapping years to generate a continuous import and export unit value index
series with 1914 as the reference year by applying the conversion factors.
118
Table 2.46
Singapore: Price Indices by Class of Commodities, 1900-27 (1914=100)
Notes: The following price indices were applied for the construction of weighted import and export unit value indices.
[A] Live animals, food, drinks and narcotics: Weighted food & beverage price indices which is constructed in the Consumer Price
Indices by major object of consumption for the Private Final Consumption Expenditure.
[1] Textiles: Weighted Clothing Price Indices which is constructed in the Consumer Price Indices by major object of consumption
for the Private Final Consumption Expenditure.
[2] Metal: Tin Export Price Indices,
[3] Other: Rubber Price Indices
*In the beginning of the 20th century, rubber was not the major commodity item. Its importance only emerged in 1908 and drastic
expansion was only experienced after 1910. Alternatively, rubber and other staple commodities weighted indices were applied for
the period 1900-14.
119
Table 2.47
Singapore: Import Unit Value Indices, 1900-27 (1914=100)
Weights Base Year
A- Live Animals, Food, Drinks and Narcotics Total Food & Beverage Indices 0.4189
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0096
B- Raw Materials [b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.1720
1900-1908 [c] Other Rubber and Staple Commodities Weighted Price Indices 1904
0.2040
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0956
C- Manufactured and Partly Manufactured
[b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0358
Articles
[c] Other UK M&E Indices 0.0640
A- Live Animals, Food, Drinks and Narcotics Total Food & Beverage Indices 0.4585
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0029
B- Raw Materials [b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.1463
1908-1914 [c] Other Rubber and Other Commodities Weighted Price Indices 1914
0.2362
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0689
C- Manufactured and Partly Manufactured
[b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0360
Articles
[c] Other UK M&E Indices 0.0512
A- Live Animals, Food, Drinks and Narcotics Total Food & Beverage Indices 0.3555
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0029
B- Raw Materials [b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.1161
1914-1916 [c] Other Rubber Price Indices 0.3564 1916
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0761
C- Manufactured and Partly Manufactured
[b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0387
Articles
[c] Other UK M&E Indices 0.0543
A- Live Animals, Food, Drinks and Narcotics Total Food & Beverage Indices 0.3638
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0013
B- Raw Materials [b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.1206
1916-1919 [c] Other Rubber Price Indices 0.3516 1918
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0797
C- Manufactured and Partly Manufactured
[b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0257
Articles
[c] Other UK M&E Indices 0.0574
A- Live Animals, Food, Drinks and Narcotics Total Food & Beverage Indices 0.3167
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0021
B- Raw Materials [b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0806
1919-1920 [c] Other Rubber Price Indices 0.4200 1919
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0979
C- Manufactured and Partly Manufactured
[b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0358
Articles
[c] Other UK M&E Indices 0.0469
A- Live Animals, Food, Drinks and Narcotics Total Food & Beverage Indices 0.3950
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0023
B- Raw Materials [b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0986
1920-1922 [c] Other Rubber Price Indices 0.2705 1921
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.1147
C- Manufactured and Partly Manufactured
[b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0618
Articles
[c] Other UK M&E Indices 0.0571
A- Live Animals, Food, Drinks and Narcotics Total Food & Beverage Indices 0.3187
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0025
B- Raw Materials [b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0768
1922-1927 [c] Other Rubber Price Indices 0.4175 1923
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0872
C- Manufactured and Partly Manufactured
[b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0425
Articles
[c] Other UK M&E Indices 0.0547
120
Table 2.48
Singapore: Export Unit Value Indices, 1900-27 (1914=100)
Weights Base Year
A- Live Animals, Food, Drinks and Narcotics Total Food & Beverage Indices 0.4161
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0104
B- Raw Materials [b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.2096
1900-1908 [c] Other Rubber and Staple Commodities Weighted Price Indices 1904
0.2030
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.1007
C- Manufactured and Partly Manufactured
[b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0164
Articles
[c] Other UK M&E Indices 0.0438
A- Live Animals, Food, Drinks and Narcotics Total Food & Beverage Indices 0.4224
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0030
B- Raw Materials [b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.1812
1908-1914 [c] Other Rubber and Other Commodities Weighted Price Indices 1914
0.2659
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0657
C- Manufactured and Partly Manufactured
[b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0228
Articles
[c] Other UK M&E Indices 0.0389
A- Live Animals, Food, Drinks and Narcotics Total Food & Beverage Indices 0.3474
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0030
B- Raw Materials [b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.1396
1914-1916 [c] Other Rubber Price Indices 0.3771 1916
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0654
C- Manufactured and Partly Manufactured
[b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0270
Articles
[c] Other UK M&E Indices 0.0406
A- Live Animals, Food, Drinks and Narcotics Total Food & Beverage Indices 0.3513
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0015
B- Raw Materials [b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.1533
1916-1919 [c] Other Rubber Price Indices 0.3569 1918
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0703
C- Manufactured and Partly Manufactured
[b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0196
Articles
[c] Other UK M&E Indices 0.0470
A- Live Animals, Food, Drinks and Narcotics Total Food & Beverage Indices 0.2968
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0021
B- Raw Materials [b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.1022
1919-1920 [c] Other Rubber Price Indices 0.4619 1919
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0826
C- Manufactured and Partly Manufactured
[b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0164
Articles
[c] Other UK M&E Indices 0.0381
A- Live Animals, Food, Drinks and Narcotics Total Food & Beverage Indices 0.4033
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0021
B- Raw Materials [b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.1008
1920-1922 [c] Other Rubber Price Indices 0.3214 1921
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0889
C- Manufactured and Partly Manufactured
[b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0322
Articles
[c] Other UK M&E Indices 0.0513
A- Live Animals, Food, Drinks and Narcotics Total Food & Beverage Indices 0.2797
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0008
B- Raw Materials [b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0017
1922-1925 [c] Other Rubber Price Indices 0.3711 1924
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0709
C- Manufactured and Partly Manufactured
[b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.1620
Articles
[c] Other UK M&E Indices 0.1137
A- Live Animals, Food, Drinks and Narcotics Total Food & Beverage Indices 0.2311
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0001
B- Raw Materials [b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.0015
1925-1927 [c] Other Rubber Price Indices 0.4001 1927
[a] Textiles Clothing Indices 0.0643
C- Manufactured and Partly Manufactured
[b] Metal Tin Price Indices 0.1468
Articles
[c] Other UK M&E Indices 0.1137
121
2.5.5.1.2 1928-39 and 1950-60 Series
The termination of the collection of trade figures whereby Singapore was treated as
a separate entity in 1927 meant that the previous time series database were no longer
available beginning in 1928. W.G. Huff’s time series database on major export
commodities of Singapore were instead utilized for the period 1928-39 and 1950-60
Table 2.49
Singapore: Export Value and Quantity by Major Commodity Goods 1927-39 and
1949-60 (based on figures by W.G. Huff )
Tin Rubber Petroleum Canned pineapples Palm oil
Value Volume Unit Value Volume Unit Value Volume Unit Value Volume Unit Value Volume Unit
($,000) (tons) Value ($,000) (tons) Value ($,000) (tons) Value ($,000) (tons) Value ($,000) (tons) Value
1927 91,929 37,634 2.44 271,354 200,307 1.35 73,659 466,257 0.16 7,494 36,259 0.21 1927
1928 82,565 42,756 1.93 162,407 201,263 0.81 61,577 417,443 0.15 7,761 42,739 0.18 1928
1929 76,560 43,352 1.77 183,592 253,875 0.72 49,494 368,629 0.13 8,735 55,352 0.16 1929
1930 47,257 37,468 1.26 100,461 233,799 0.43 57,298 405,616 0.14 7,297 53,515 0.14 1930
1931 29,800 29,784 1.00 49,937 220,545 0.23 65,101 442,603 0.15 6,545 54,620 0.12 1931
1932 24,565 20,840 1.18 28,536 184,296 0.15 58,145 420,106 0.14 7,002 58,139 0.12 1932
1933 51,208 30,913 1.66 45,451 230,352 0.20 42,285 394,082 0.11 5,382 51,769 0.10 1,031 9,202 0.11 1933
1934 45,333 23,550 1.92 124,045 315,990 0.39 44,649 453,958 0.10 5,971 57,166 0.10 1,034 12,603 0.08 1934
1935 52,725 27,999 1.88 112,379 258,579 0.43 50,911 511,457 0.10 6,644 60,481 0.11 2,528 18,045 0.14 1935
1936 63,457 37,511 1.69 131,428 218,697 0.60 42,416 480,939 0.09 7,099 64,243 0.11 3,066 21,478 0.14 1936
1937 77,692 38,150 2.04 206,172 285,933 0.72 54,047 627,518 0.09 6,988 65,197 0.11 4,834 28,344 0.17 1937
1938 39,082 24,784 1.58 120,511 225,751 0.53 54,924 742,949 0.07 6,372 64,382 0.10 4,063 33,111 0.12 1938
1939 69,527 36,044 1.93 178,765 259,238 0.69 52,561 681,242 0.08 8,869 74,050 0.12 3,472 36,061 0.10 1939
1949 120,591 23,935 5.04 381,691 484,848 0.79 121,621 1,522,957 0.08 5,551 7,115 0.78 24,407 35,004 0.70 1949
1950 207,190 35,855 5.78 1,405,274 655,025 2.15 160,677 1,906,991 0.08 11,049 13,173 0.84 22,243 34,475 0.65 1950
1951 261,457 29,399 8.89 2,518,844 750,221 3.36 201,701 1,880,855 0.11 15,714 15,761 1.00 26,434 31,192 0.85 1951
1952 217,429 27,013 8.05 915,895 555,343 1.65 307,796 2,358,420 0.13 11,625 10,913 1.07 30,302 31,865 0.95 1952
1953 172,292 26,853 6.42 750,764 506,480 1.48 341,584 2,613,622 0.13 17,797 16,264 1.09 17,710 26,174 0.68 1953
1954 195,912 33,263 5.89 785,088 555,297 1.41 350,556 2,732,430 0.13 23,461 19,890 1.18 15,822 23,645 0.67 1954
1955 202,192 33,322 6.07 1,399,635 604,152 2.32 371,097 3,115,858 0.12 27,172 25,898 1.05 17,810 27,153 0.66 1955
1956 138,657 21,330 6.50 1,216,551 596,600 2.04 446,236 2,936,508 0.15 29,048 28,333 1.03 20,737 28,996 0.72 1956
1957 133,562 20,843 6.41 1,171,094 617,198 1.90 444,964 3,005,649 0.15 31,229 34,837 0.90 16,516 22,094 0.75 1957
1958 48,337 7,884 6.13 1,045,556 650,204 1.61 370,308 2,459,169 0.15 31,145 38,754 0.80 17,730 27,867 0.64 1958
1959 4,448 677 6.57 1,533,074 722,580 2.12 371,657 2,494,965 0.15 26,586 36,599 0.73 19,078 26,026 0.73 1959
1960 5,161 775 6.66 1,426,513 598,378 2.38 379,209 2,687,573 0.14 25,243 35,937 0.70 23,811 33,767 0.71 1960
Given that the information on import value and volume was rather weak, it was
assumed that the export unit value indices would be a good proxy for the import unit
value index, an assumption not altogether unreasonable as seen from the data shown in
Table 2.45 for the years 1960-95. Based on the information on value and volume of
exports of tin, rubber, petroleum, canned pineapples and palm oil, the unit value of each
commodity was derived. During the period 1927-60 (excluding the year 1940-49), the
criteria for the selection of intervals and their base years include the element of relative
stability of the export share of commodities. Eleven intervals were set, namely 1927-28,
and 1958-60 and the commodity weights for the respective base years 1928, 1929, 1930,
122
1931, 1932, 1934, 1936, 1950, 1953, 1957 and 1959 were identified. These staple
commodities based export unit value indices, however, only accounted for 30-50% of
total merchandize exports of Singapore. Thus, it was necessary to consider other trade
items such as food, beverages and tobacco, clothing, transport, etc. Unfortunately, it was
impossible to trace the specific unit value for many items. As an alternative the CPI was
By linking the two separate series of import and export unit value indices, separate
set of import and export unit value indices (1914=100) for the period 1900-39 and
1950-60 were obtained. As can be seen from the Table 2.51 and Figure 2.18, both
import and export unit value indices for the period 1900-39 and 1950-60 (1914=100)
123
Table 2.50
Singapore: Export Unit Value Index, 1927-39 and 1950-60 (1914=100)
Items Weights of Export Weights of Export Base year
Items Commodity Items and CPI
Tin 0.2627
Rubber 0.5167
0.4692
1927-28 Canned pineapples 0.0247 1928
Petroleum 0.1959
CPI 0.5308
Tin 0.2405
Rubber 0.5766
0.4611
1928-29 Canned pineapples 0.0274 1929
Petroleum 0.1555
CPI 0.5389
Tin 0.2226
Rubber 0.4732
0.4020
1929-30 Canned pineapples 0.0344 1930
Petroleum 0.2699
CPI 0.5980
Tin 0.1969
Rubber 0.3299
0.4619
1930-31 Canned pineapples 0.0432 1931
Petroleum 0.4300
CPI 0.5381
Tin 0.2077
Rubber 0.2413
0.4356
1931-32 Canned pineapples 0.0592 1932
Petroleum 0.4917
CPI 0.5644
Tin 0.2118
Rubber 0.5796 0.5428
1932-34 1934
Petroleum 0.2086
CPI 0.4572
Tin 0.2564
Rubber 0.5311
Petroleum 0.1714 0.5588
1934-39 1936
Canned pineapples 0.0287
Palm oil 0.0124
CPI 0.4412
Tin 0.1147
Rubber 0.7779
Petroleum 0.0889 0.6023
1939,1949-51 1950
Canned pineapples 0.0061
Palm oil 0.0123
CPI 0.3977
Tin 0.1713
Rubber 0.8225
Petroleum 0.2624 0.4899
1951-53 1953
Canned pineapples 0.0133
Palm oil 0.0191
CPI 0.5101
Tin 0.0743
Rubber 0.6516
Petroleum 0.2476 0.5168
1953-1958 1957
Canned pineapples 0.0174
Palm oil 0.0092
CPI 0.4832
Tin 0.0023
Rubber 0.7842
Petroleum 0.1901 0.5682
1958-60 1959
Canned pineapples 0.0136
Palm oil 0.0098
CPI 0.4318
124
Table 2.51
Singapore: Import Unit Value Indices and Export Unit Value Indices,
1900-39 and 1950-60 (1914=100)
Import Unit Export Unit Import Unit Export Unit Import Unit Export Unit Import Unit Export Unit Import Unit Export Unit
Value Value Value Value Value Value Value Value Value Value
Indices Indices Indices Indices Indices Indices Indices Indices Indices Indices
1900 87.68 87.24 1910 98.21 99.49 1920 189.99 177.60 1930 78.26 76.90 1950 235.24 231.13
1901 90.33 89.82 1911 105.98 106.68 1921 117.89 116.09 1931 64.84 63.70 1951 332.36 326.55
1902 96.03 95.60 1912 110.11 110.97 1922 100.81 99.74 1932 55.87 54.89 1952 273.39 263.69
1903 94.31 94.05 1913 108.07 108.47 1923 113.59 110.37 1933 53.14 55.47 1953 232.56 228.50
1904 88.83 88.58 1914 100.00 100.00 1924 119.72 113.46 1934 68.67 67.47 1954 226.04 222.09
1905 91.02 90.95 1915 110.78 110.24 1925 149.97 145.08 1935 69.73 68.51 1955 266.17 261.52
1906 96.64 96.99 1916 121.89 121.22 1926 137.37 132.91 1936 72.66 71.39 1956 258.56 254.04
1907 90.71 90.93 1917 131.16 131.05 1927 126.37 124.16 1937 80.37 78.97 1957 252.80 248.38
1908 86.08 85.79 1918 144.57 145.01 1928 103.98 102.16 1938 69.01 67.80 1958 243.88 239.61
1909 89.45 89.87 1919 150.70 154.34 1929 98.40 96.68 1939 76.98 75.63 1959 267.22 262.55
1960 273.29 268.51
Figure 2.18
Singapore: Import Unit Value Indices and Export Unit Value Indices,
1900-39 and 1950-60 (1914=100)
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
-
1900
1901
1902
1903
1904
1905
1906
1907
1908
1909
1910
1911
1912
1913
1914
1915
1916
1917
1918
1919
1920
1921
1922
1923
1924
1925
1926
1927
1928
1929
1930
1931
1932
1933
1934
1935
1936
1937
1938
1939
1950
1951
1952
1953
1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
1959
1960
There were no price indices which could represent the price movement of port
services such as bunkering and water supply services, revenue from the services on port
wharfage, storage and stevedorage and port harbour dues. Hence, as an alternative, the
weighted price indices on fuel and communication of the United Kingdom were applied
125
Table 2.52
Weighted Price Indices on Fuel and Communication of the United Kingdom,
1900-39 and 1950-60 (1914=100)
1900-39 and 1950-60 (1914=100)
1900 97.86 1910 93.96 1920 220.26 1930 167.88 1950 281.55
1901 95.60 1911 94.67 1921 230.35 1931 166.69 1951 302.80
1902 93.28 1912 103.97 1922 195.97 1932 164.75 1952 329.27
1903 92.99 1913 100.54 1923 180.89 1933 162.24 1953 343.68
1904 92.83 1914 100.00 1924 181.91 1934 160.69 1954 355.37
1905 92.51 1915 105.51 1925 179.01 1935 158.72 1955 372.86
1906 94.36 1916 119.94 1926 183.75 1936 160.82 1956 401.81
1907 98.48 1917 139.44 1927 174.33 1937 163.65 1957 422.72
1908 96.14 1918 165.28 1928 168.33 1938 165.03 1958 438.94
1909 94.93 1919 194.08 1929 169.10 1939 172.73 1959 442.61
1960 447.48
Source: Based on Feinstein (1972:T134-135).
Table 2.53 provides the net exports of goods and services at Current and Constant
Table 2.53
Singapore: Net Exports of Goods and Services at Current and Constant Prices,
1900-39 and 1950-60
(Straits $ Millions)
Current Prices 1914 Prices
Net Exports (Merchandize) Net Exports (Services) Net Exports of Goods and Services Net Exports of Goods and Services
126
CHAPTER THREE
3.1 Introduction
then constructed. This estimated GDP series, however, requires to be checked from
various aspects to assess the reliability or validity of the estimate. After these processes,
the historical GDP series (1900-39 and 1950-60) supplemented with the official GDP
series 1960-2000 in both current and constant prices was then obtained after which the
pattern of economic growth in Singapore for the twentieth century was examined.
This chapter is organized as follows. Section 3.2 presents the result of GDP
estimates of Singapore for the period 1900-39 and 1950-60 in both current and 1914
prices. Based on these derived time-series, an attempt was made to assess the reliability
of each component of GDP in Section 3.3. Subsequently, this derived series was
time-series with a single base year (1990=100) for conducting quantitative analysis of
Singapore for the twentieth century which appear in chapters 4 and 5. Section 3.4
explains the overall pattern of growth for 100 years in respect of GDP growth and share
The results of GDP estimates and its components in both current and 1914 prices for
the period 1900-39 and 1950-60 are presented in Tables 3.1-3.2 and Figures 3.1-3.4.
127
The average annual growth rate of GDP for the period 1900-39 and 1950-60 in current
prices was 5.2% and 7.2% while this growth rate in 1914 prices was 4.5% and 4.8%
respectively. The average annual per-capita GDP growth rate for same time periods was
2.2% and 2.4% in current prices and 1.5% and 0.03% in 1914 prices.
An examination of the yearly growth rates in GDP in current prices during the
period under review, however, yielded years which experienced extremely high growth
rates as in 1917 (41%), 1919 (38%) and 1928 (36%) and conversely extremely low
growth rates well into the negative territory for the year 1931 (-38%). Similarly
extremely high GDP growth rates in real terms were recorded for the years 1917 (29%),
1922 (23%), 1933 (46%) and 1953 (36%) while high negative rates were noted for 1916
notable features. Firstly, the share of private final consumption expenditure (PFCE) was
high. For the year 1903-04, 1912-14, 1916 and 1927, total PFCE recorded was higher
than that of GDP in current prices. 66 This implied that personal consumption
Secondly, it is also important to note that the share of net exports of goods and services
to GDP in current prices was in most years in the negative territory. Its share has
fluctuated heavily from -58% in 1913 and to +11% in 1933 in current prices and -69%
in 1932 to +2% in 1951 in 1914 prices. Thirdly, it was observed that the share of
in current prices and 5% to 16% in 1914 prices during the period under review.
66
Weight on private final consumption expenditure by resident households in Finland (1917) and Dutch (1844-46) exceeded the
figure of GDP. Other than these countries, historical estimates of Korea experienced the weight of more than 90% for most of the
1910s. Therefore, this phenomenon is not merely recorded in Singapore.
128
Table 3.1
Singapore: Gross Domestic Product in Purchasers’ Value in Current Prices,
1900-39 and 1950-60 (Straits $ in millions)
Private Final Consumption Government Final Consumption Gross Capital Formation (GCF) Net Exports of Goods GDP at Martket Prices
Expenditure in The Domestic Expenditure (GFCE) and Services (NETEX) (Current Prices)
Market by Resident Households
(PFCE)
129
Figure 3.1
Singapore: Gross Domestic Product in Purchasers’ Value in Current Prices,
1900-39 and 1950-60 (Straits $ in millions)
2,500
2,000
1,500
Strait $ (millions)
1,000
500
0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1951
1953
1955
1957
1959
-500
Year
GDP at Market Prices Private Final Consumption Expenditure
Government Final Consumption Expenditure Gross Capital Formation
Net Exports of Goods and Services
Figure 3.2
Singapore: Annual Growth Rate of GDP and its components at Current Prices,
1900-39 and 1950-60
50%
40%
30%
20%
Growth Rate (%)
10%
0%
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1951
1953
1955
1957
1959
-10%
-20%
-30%
-40%
-50%
Year
130
Table 3.2
Singapore: Gross Domestic Product in Purchasers’ Value in 1914 Prices,
1900-39 and 1950-60 (Straits $ in millions)
Private Final Consumption Government Final Consumption Gross Capital Formation (GCF) Net Exports of Goods GDP at Martket Prices
Expenditure in The Domestic Expenditure (GFCE) and Services (NETEX) (1914 Prices)
Market by Resident Households
(PFCE)
131
Figure 3.3
Singapore: Gross Domestic Product in Purchasers’ Value in 1914 Prices,
1900-39 and 1950-60 (Straits $ in millions)
600
500
400
Straits $ (millions)
300
200
100
0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1951
1953
1955
1957
1959
-100
-200
Year
Figure 3.4
Singapore: Annual Growth Rate of GDP and its components at 1914 Prices,
1900-39 and 1950-60
50%
40%
30%
20%
Growth Rate (%)
10%
0%
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1951
1953
1955
1957
1959
-10%
-20%
-30%
-40%
-50%
Year
GDP at Market Prices Private Final Consumption Expenditure
Government Final Consumption Expenditure Gross Capital Formation
Net Exports of Goods and Services
132
3.3 Assessment of GDP Estimates
In the field of historical GDP estimates, there are broadly three ways in which the
reliability of the main aggregates can be assessed: (1) by comparison with other
estimates, (2) by comparison from two or more different approaches (eg. production and
income approach in the case of GDP) and (3) by reference to the subjective evaluations
of statistical personnel responsible for the compilation of the each component (Feinstein,
1972:10). In the case of GDP estimates of Singapore, however, there are constraints in
conducting these reliability checks. To begin with there were no previous exercises
attempted in the construction of historical GDP estimates for Singapore. For second
method, up till today, no attempt has been made in constructing GDP estimates from the
income and production approach. This is mainly because the statistical data is so much
lacking that it does not permit the construction of GDP using these alternative
approaches. In the case of the income approach, the British colonial authority did not
collect basic statistical information relating to income and profit earnings by various
sectors. For the production approach, as was described earlier, Singapore, as a regional
entrepôt had been primarily engaged in wholesale trade and the services sector.67
Therefore, estimates for value added by sector would be extremely difficult due to the
deficiencies of data. The third method involves assessing the reliability of the GDP
series, undertaken by the investigator responsible for the estimates and expressed in
terms of reliability grades (Feinstein, 1972: 20). However, this assessment would be
arbitrary because it is rare that we can set a correct margin of error. In view of these
constraints, the following four alternative approaches were employed. Firstly, this study
examines if the estimates made, bear any consistency with the official figures compiled
by the Department of Statistics, Singapore for the years after 1960. Firstly, a check of
the level of GDP between the estimated figure and available official figure released by
67
In 1960, 78% of GDP was Service Sector (Peebles, Gavin and Peter Wilson,1996:5).
133
Department of Statistics, Singapore for the years 1959-60 was made. Subsequently, the
average annual growth rate and share of each component of GDP for the periods
1900-39 and 1950-2000 was also observed. Nelson and Plosser (1982) presented
macroeconomic time series for the US. Similar tests were employed for Singapore to
evaluate whether each component of the GDP figure was consistent with the overall
Secondly, economic factors and events gleaned from official documents and records
which contributed towards the upturns and downturns of each component of GDP for
Thirdly, the historical GDP estimates from this exercise were compared with figures
available for other countries to compare the patterns, levels and trends of these
estimates.
The first official GDP of Singapore was constructed by the Department of Statistics
for the year 1960. Additionally, GDP estimates for the year 1959 were released by Goh
Keng Swee (1995). As presented in Table 3.3, notably, estimates of GDP were fairly
close with that of the figures from the above sources despite the differing methodologies
employed for their computation. Unfortunately, other than for these two years, only
Table 3.3
Singapore: Gross Domestic Product at Current Prices,
1959-60, (Straits $ in millions)
134
The average annual growth rate of each component of GDP for each decade for the
period 1900-39 and 1950-2000 in both current and constant prices is shown in Table 3.4.
Generally, the GDP and its components showed relatively higher average annual growth
rates during the second half of the 20th century as compared with that of the pre-World
War II period. It may be possible to conclude that the rapid and sustained growth of
Singapore’s GDP recorded in our estimate may find general acceptance for both the
British Colonial period and the period of self-government. It will also be noted that the
share of each component of GDP of Singapore in both current and constant prices was
also not significantly different from that of 1960s (See Table 3.5).
Table 3.4
Singapore: Average Annual Growth Rate of GDP and Its
Components at Current and Constant Prices, 1900-2000
At Current Prices At Constant Prices
PFCE GFCE GCF NETEX GDP PFCE GFCE GCF NETEX GDP
1914 prices
1900-1910 3.3 5.4 10.8 5.6 2.6 4.7 13.1 5.0
1910-1920 10.8 10.9 13.5 8.7 1.7 1.7 2.9 1.7
1920-1930 2.2 3.8 -2.7 4.9 6.4 8.0 5.9 6.0
1930-1939 1.8 -0.7 4.3 1.2 4.9 2.4 7.4 5.1
1950-1960 7.9 6.3 5.5 7.2 6.0 4.3 5.9 4.8
1990 prices
1960-1970 7.1 14.6 22.2 9.9 6.1 13.3 14.5 8.8
1970-1980 11.9 12.6 16.4 14.6 6.8 7.0 8.9 8.6
1980-1990 8.7 10.2 7.4 10.0 5.9 6.5 5.0 7.0
1990-2000 7.3 9.0 7.2 8.5 5.7 8.1 7.0 7.2
Table 3.5
Singapore: Gross Domestic Product and its Components
at Current Prices, 1900-1970
CURRENT PRICES
PFCE GFCE GCF NETEX GDP
1960 89 8 11 -8 100
1965 79 10 22 -11 100 [B]
1970 68 12 39 -18 100
Sources: [A] Sugimoto’s Estimates and [B] Department of Statistics, Singapore (1996)
Abbreviations: PFCE=Private Final Consumption Expenditure by resident households, GFCE=Government Final Consumption
Expenditure, GCF=Gross Capital Formation, NETEX=Net Exports of Goods and Services
Note: For the years 1960, 1965 and 1970, percentage share of statistical discrepancy to GDP were allocated under NETEX.
135
3.3.1.1 Unit Root Test
section conducts unit root tests for checking the consistency of time-series data on GDP
and its components. Relating to this, Nelson and Plosser (1982) presented statistical
evidence that supports the hypothesis of a unit root in the macroeconomic time series
for the US which included GNP, employment, wages, prices, interest rate and stock
and econometrics. The presence or absence of unit roots, to put it simply, helps to
series has no unit roots, it is characterized as stationary, and therefore exhibits mean
reversion in that it fluctuates around a constant long run mean. Also the absence of unit
roots implies that the series has a finite variance which does not depend on time and that
the effects of shocks dissolve over time. Alternatively, if the series feature a unit root
they are better characterized as non-stationary processes that have no tendency to return
Considered below are two alternative models used to represent GDP time series:
yt = a + bt + e t (1)
yt = a + yt-1 + e t (2)
Where:
The first specification implies that GDP equals the constant a at time zero (y0 = a)
and growth over time at a constant rate b, with the error term explaining deviations from
the trend in each year. In other words, the variable yt presents a stationary fluctuation
around the time trend a + bt. Therefore, the variable is described as trend stationary
(TS), and stationarity is achieved by removing the time trend (“detrending”), i.e.
136
regressing yt on t. In short, for the first specification, the effects of a shock at time t tend
to zero over time, since the error term affects the outcome in the current period but has
Model (2), on the other hand, specifies that GDP grows at rate a from its previous
value, with an error term playing a role every year. Despite the apparent similitude
between the two models, they are indeed very different, and lead to different
implications in many respects. First, model (2) is non-stationary and cannot be made
stationary through detrending. It will be noted that the first difference of the series is
and the model is called difference stationary (DS). Model (2) is one of the simplest
AR(1) processes, and can be described as a random walk with drift. The dependent
variable displays a random fluctuation given by the error term et, in addition to the
growth given by the drift term a. Contrarily to model (1), however, there is no tendency
accumulation of disturbances. In other words, the error term affects not only what
happens in the current period, but also what happens in all succeeding periods. In order
to better visualize this point, we can substitute repeatedly for the lagged yt value in
t
yt = y0 + at + ∑ ei (3)
i =1
It is straightforward to see that the variance of yt without bound over time, and that
shocks to the system (captured by the error term) have a permanent effect on the series.
The study by Nelson and Plosser (1982) conclude that the evidence presented
time series. In other words, their study found that many fluctuations in GDP and its
components are permanent, in the sense that there is no tendency for GDP to revert to
trend line following a shock. Similar results were obtained amongst others by
137
Sosa-Escudero (1997), Carrera, Feliz, and Panigo (1999), Noriega and Ramirez-Zamora
Many studies begin by testing for unit root using Augmented Dickey-Fuller’s test
(Dickey and Fuller, 1979, 1981) and Philips and Perron’s (Philips and Perron, 1988). To
test the unit root property of the ∆GDP (Y) time series, the following regression
p
∆Y = α 0 + α1Yt −1 + α 2T + ∑ β j ∆Yt − j + ε t (4)
j =1
Gaussian white noise. The number of lags, p in the dependent variable is chosen to
ensure that the errors are white noise. The two most commonly used methods for the
selection of lag length are Akaike Information Criteria (AIC) and Schwartz Info Criteria
(SIC). This study employed the SIC approach which has been widely used in the
literature for the selection of the optimal lag length. Unit root tests of this type are
referred to as Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) tests. The null hypothesis is that the
series is non-stationary against the alternative hypothesis of stationarity. The ADF test
is based on the estimated parameter α1 and its corresponding t-statistic. When α1=0,
the time series βt is non-stationarity so that the standard asymptotic analysis cannot be
used to obtain the distributions of the test statistics. A problem with the ADF test is that
it involves the inclusion of extra differences terms in the testing equation. Alternatively,
the Philips-Perron (PP) approach allows for the presence of unknown forms of
testing regression (1), except that p=0. This method uses a nonparametric correction for
serial correlation. The statistics are then transformed to remove the effects of serial
correlation on the asymptotic distribution of the test statistics. For both tests, a t-statistic
138
larger in absolute value than the critical value results in the rejection of the null
Table 3.6 shows the result of unit root tests for GDP and its components of
Singapore for the period 1960-2000 (1990 prices) for Singapore, based on official data
compiled from Department of Statistics, Singapore and the ADB Key Indicators. For
unit root tests, Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) and Philips-Perron (PP) approaches
were conducted.
As is observed from the results of unit root tests, time series of real GDP and its
components are all integrated of order one, I(1), since only its first difference and
second difference are stationary. This result portrays that the null hypothesis of a unit
root test cannot be rejected, indicating that Singapore’s time series of GDP and its
components are difference stationary for the period 1960-2000. These results are similar
Table 3.6
Singapore: The Results of Unit Root Tests of GDP and Its Components
(1990 Prices), 1960-2000
Notes:
1. All variables are natural logarithm figure.
2. Automatic selection of lag were determined by Schwartz Info Criterion
3. Bandwidth was determined based on the Newey-West using Bartlett kernel
4. (***,** ,*) denotes significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively.
5. I(0) = stationary, I(1) = unit root
Abbreviations:
PFCE=Private Final Consumption Expenditure by resident households, GFCE=Government Final Consumption Expenditure,
GCF=Gross Capital Formation, EXGS= Exports of Goods and Services, IMGS= Imports of Goods and Services
139
A similar exercise on unit root tests was made this time for the period, 1900-39
using 1914 as the base year.68 As is observed in Table 3.7, the results of two different
unit root tests for both 1900-39 and 1950-60 are of order Integrated (1). The results
were similar to that of the data for the period 1960-2000 as seen earlier in Table 3.6.
The result of these econometric tests bears out the fact that there are consistencies in the
nature of long-term time series data on Singapore for the entire twentieth century.
Table 3.7
Singapore: The Results of Unit Root Tests of GDP and Its Components
(1914 Prices), 1900-39
Phillips-Perron Test
Levels trend Bandwidth2 First Difference trend Bandwidth2 Second Difference trend Bandwidth2 Order
Notes:
1. All variables are natural logarithm figure.
2. Automatic selection of lag were determined by Schwartz Info Criterion
3. Bandwidth was determined based on the Newey-West using Bartlett kernel
4. (***,** ,*) denotes significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively.
5. I(0) = stationary, I(1) = unit root
Abbreviations:
PFCE=Private Final Consumption Expenditure by resident households, GFCE=Government Final Consumption Expenditure,
GCF=Gross Capital Formation, EXGS= Exports of Goods and Services, IMGS= Imports of Goods and Services
Similar unit root test was conducted for other Asian countries, namely Japan,
Taiwan, Korea and Malaya and all countries showed a similar result of unit root test.69
68
For the period of 1950-60, no Unit Root Test was conducted due to the shortage of number of observations.
69
For unit root test, Philips-Perron approaches were tested. For all countries, real GDP of Japan, Taiwan, Korea and Malaya were
integrated of order one, I(1) difference stationary. Therefore, null hypothesis of unit root for all countries listed below were not
rejected at 1% level.
Period Base year Levels trend Bandwidth2 First Difference trend Bandwidth 2 Second trend Bandwidth2 Order
Difference
Japan 1903-38 1934-36 -0.331987 Yes 1 -5.593847*** Yes 1 -16.33138*** Yes 10 I(1)
Taiwan 1903-38 1934-36 -1.308562 Yes 4 -8.309289*** Yes 1 -16.18597*** Yes 4 I(1)
Korea 1911-38 1934-36 -0.99868 Yes 3 -5.329979*** Yes 2 -23.55882*** Yes 9 I(1)
Malaya 1900-39 1914 -2.979818 Yes 3 -6.733598*** Yes 6 -22.90363*** Yes 16 I(1)
140
3.3.2 Upturns and Downturns of Each Component of GDP, 1900-39 and 1950-60
production or exports of major commodities like rubber and tin may more or less
portray the movement of real GDP. On the other hand, in the case of Singapore, due to
movement of real GDP. Alternatively, a greater insight into the upturns and downturns
component of GDP.
domestic market was the single largest component which represented on average 86.5%
and 85.7% of GDP for the two periods 1900-39 and 1950-60 respectively. In terms of
growth rate, the average annual growth rate of PFCE in current prices was 4.6% and
7.9% for the periods 1900-39 and 1950-60 respectively while in constant terms, the
average annual growth rate was recorded at 3.9% and 6.0% for these two periods.
In per-capita terms, the PFCE of Singapore grew at an average annual rate of 1.4%
and 2.8% in current terms while in constant terms they grew by 0.7% and 0.6%
respectively.
in constant terms showed frequent fluctuations during the period. In current terms,
PFCE grew remarkably for the period 1917-20, namely 17.6% (1917), 23.4% (1918),
13.9% (1919) and 24.8% (1920) respectively. Their growth rate in real terms was,
however, in the negative territory for the later years of this period recording rates of
13.5% (1917), 5.9% (1918), -6.6% (1919) and -0.3% (1920) for the respective years.
141
This could be attributed to the sharp increase in CPI by some 20.4% in 1919 and 25.0%
in 1920. This increase was mainly fuelled by the sharp increase in the prices of nearly
The sharp decline in the growth rates of PFCE in both current and constant terms for
Singapore was experienced during the Great Depression years of 1930-32. In current
terms, negative growth rate of -14.3% (1930), -29.7% (1931) and -12.2% (1932) were
recorded for respective years. In constant terms, negative growth was observed for the
years 1930 (-9.4%) and 1931 (-13.7%). Singapore faced serious downturns as a result of
the world-wide slump. In line with this, major export commodities such as rubber, tin
and petroleum experienced a drastic fall in their prices. The reasonableness of PFCE
Table 3.8. This table provides the percentage share of PFCE for each major object of
consumption in current prices for selected years. It would be comforting to note that the
independently arrived percentage share of each major object of consumption for the
selected years 1905, 1918, 1929, 1955, 1965 and 1980 are similar in pattern with
Table 3.8
Singapore: Percentage Private Final Consumption Expenditure by Major Object
of Consumption, Selected Years (Per Cent)
Source: For the year 1965 and 1980, the figures were derived from Department of Statistics, Singapore (1983:64-65).
* Estimates made by Benham (1959:1).
142
3.3.2.2 Government Final Consumption Expenditure in Current and 1914 Prices
compensation of employees and intermediate consumption was 55% and 45% for the
period 1900-39 and 65% and 35% for the period 1950-60 respectively. This distribution
services generally experienced gradual increases throughout the period under review.
Significant increases were recorded for the years 1918 (34%) and 1920 (49%). Both
these expansions could be attributed to the British colonial government allocating huge
temporary allowances to compensate for sudden price increases of consumer goods. The
Unlike PFCE and GFCE, the level of GCF experienced frequent fluctuations.
Additionally, the share of GCF against GDP was high on certain occasions. During the
second decade of the twentieth century, when rubber and tin production was rapidly
capital formation. In order to consolidate its position as the foremost premier entrepôt in
the region, massive capital formation was initiated by both the private and government
sectors. Despite its small resident population, Singapore needed to undertake relatively
large scale infrastructure projects such as port and aerodrome facilities to meet regional
since there was no specific information which could portray the movement of gross
70
In this estimate, the value of depreciation was estimated as 1% of aggregated figures of compensation of employees and
intermediate consumption based on an educated guess. Therefore, it hardly gave any significant impact to total government output.
143
capital formation. The only available time-series data in our collection was capital
financial statements contained in reports emanating from the Singapore Harbour Board,
Colony of Singapore and Singapore Municipality. Table 3.9 lists some major
facilities which were constructed during the period 1908-20 were regarded as “second to
no port out East”.71 This large-scale capital formation contributed greatly to ensure the
office buildings undertaken by the authority of Colony of Singapore, while road, street
and bridge construction was initiated by the Singapore Municipality in the later half of
the 1920’s. These expenditures were incurred to meet the increasing demand for
71
Huff (1994:140).
144
Table 3.9
Singapore: Gross Capital Formation and Major Government
Construction Projects, 1900-39 and 1950-60
Year GCF Current Singapore Harbour Board Colony of Singapore Singapore
Prices Municipality
1900 4.3 0%
1901 4.6 7% 0.7
1902 5.1 10% 0.5
1903 7.0 30%
1904 8.6 21% 0.1
1905 6.5 -28% 0.5
1906 5.7 -14%
1907 8.4 39%
1908 9.4 11%
1909 10.4 10% 1.5
1910 11.2 8% 1.0
1911 12.6 12% 2.0 0.2 1.1
1912 16.3 26% 2.4 2.0 0.6
1913 18.2 11% 2.8 1.3
1914 13.1 -33% 1.1 1.8
1915 12.1 -8% 2.0
1916 16.5 31% 2.2
1917 14.0 -16%
1918 25.8 61% 2.4
1919 18.5 -33% 2.5
1920 49.8 99% 15.1
1921 35.4 -34%
1922 18.1 -67%
1923 19.8 9%
1924 20.2 2%
1925 28.3 34% 1.3
1926 37.3 28% 2.1 1.6
1927 43.8 16% 2.7 1.0
1928 50.3 14% 1.7 1.5
1929 58.7 15% 0.2 1.0
1930 43.6 -30% 1.1
1931 38.0 -14% 0.3
1932 25.1 -41%
1933 15.3 -50%
1934 25.6 52% 0.9
1935 24.7 -4% 1.1
1936 29.6 18% 2.1
1937 38.8 27%
1938 39.8 3% 0.7
1939 47.0 17%
1950 180.0 0%
1951 186.6 4%
1952 224.8 19%
1953 125.9 -58%
1954 171.9 31%
1955 208.4 19%
1956 202.2 -3%
1957 252.7 22%
1958 222.2 -13%
1959 222.5 0%
1960 233.9 5%
3.3.2.4 Net Exports of Goods and Services in Current and 1914 Prices
As was observed in Tables 3.1 and 3.2 earlier, net exports of goods and services of
Singapore were generally in the negative territory in both current and constant prices.
145
This was purely due to the fact that Singapore did not have any significant domestic
production base. Singapore imported various types of items from many parts of world.
A major portion of these imported items were then re-exported. Parts of the imports
retained in the domestic market were eventually allocated for intermediate and final
One might wonder how Singapore which experienced consistent negative net
exports together with an income balance which was usually represented by an outflow
could be viable economically. This anomaly can be explained by observing the official
merchandize trade balance was regularly negative even after achieving self-governance,
the combined invisible trade and capital and financial account (CFA) was positive
largely due to inflows of foreign direct investment, generating an overall surplus and a
posited that it was not implausible that the overall balance of payments during the
Table 3.10
Singapore: Balance of Payments, 1960-71
(Straits $ in millions)
Year Merchandize Merchandize Merchandize Invisible Trade Overall
Imports Exports Net Exports and Net Balance
Capital
Inflows
1960 3,497 2,964 -533 647 114
1961 3,358 2,750 -608 623 15
1962 3,431 2,860 -571 762 191
1963 3,996 3,291 -705 785 80
1964 3,252 2,601 -651 561 -90
1965 3,570 2,810 -760 728 -32
1966 3,825 3,168 -657 844 187
1967 4,149 3,239 -910 1,269 359
1968 4,759 3,589 -1,170 1,718 548
1969 5,863 4,471 -1,392 1,860 468
1970 7,047 4,428 -2,619 3,080 461
1971 8,090 5,075 -3,015 3,846 831
Source: Goh Keng Swee (1995: 12-13)
146
3.3.2.4.1 Exports of Goods and Services
from $ 185.8 million in 1900 to $435.9 million in 1939. Between 1950-60, it increased
from $3.0 billion to $3.5 billion. The annual growth rate of exports, however,
Three major downturns of merchandize exports were experienced for the years
1920-21 (-55%), 1930-31 (-48%), 1937-38 (-37%) and 1951-52 (-39%). On the other
hand, five booms were recorded for the years 1918-19 (37%), 1924-25 (49%), 1936-37
economic conditions. A boom during World War I (1915-17); the immediate post-war
buying euphoria and world-wide inflation in 1919; recession from mid 1920 to 1921; a
sharp upswing in the mid-1920s; and the slump in the early 1930s, followed by a partial
recovery in the form of a mini-boom in 1937 were some of the extreme conditions
during the 1900-39 period. For the period 1950-60, drastic expansion was recorded for
attempt was made to provide supportive reasons, which led to these fluctuations. As
presented in Table 3.10, rubber, tin and petroleum were the three major commodities
which can portray the movement of merchandize exports. In 1917, the three comprised
47% of Singapore’s total exports. This proportion rose to 61% in 1925, due to further
rapid increases in rubber exports and the sudden growth of petroleum trade. In 1955,
these three commodities combined to account for some 59% of Singapore’s exports
though the share of tin had significantly decreased. Out of these three commodities, the
share of rubber to total merchandize exports in particular rapidly increased after 1914.
The share of rubber varied from 5% (1913) to 45% (1925) and 53% (1951). In line with
147
the growing predominance of rubber exports, in relation to Singapore’s total
merchandize exports, it has inevitably influenced the level and the resulting fluctuations
World demand for rubber was basically strongly tied to the development of
motorized transport. The automobile industry needed rubber mainly for the manufacture
of tyres. Between 1913 and the 1930s, the United States annually imported one half to
three quarters of world rubber production. Its automotive industry took three quarters of
these imports. Because of high export dependence on the United States and the demand
and supply conditions for rubber, instability in the American economy had a powerful
States, which mainly comprised rubber, tin and petroleum increased more than 10 times
between 1911 and 1927. In the 1950s, however, the destination of Singapore’s primary
exports shifted from the United States to Europe due to the invention and widespread
use of the cheaper synthetic rubber in United States paralleled by the emergence of a
148
Table 3.11
Singapore: Total Merchandize Exports and Exports of Major Commodities,
1900-39 and 1950-60
Total Merchandize Exports [1] Rubber [2] Tin [3] Petroleum [4]= [1]+[2]+[3]
Value ($,000) Growth Value Growth % share Value Growth % share Value Growth % share Value ($,000) % share
rate (%) ($,000) rate (%) ($,000) rate (%) ($,000) rate (%)
1900 185,788 - 34,505 19 2,282 1 36,787 20 1900
1901 194,810 5 - 36,896 7 19 2,238 -2 1 39,134 20 1901
1902 209,278 7 - 38,592 4 18 1,543 -37 1 40,135 19 1902
1903 211,524 1 - 41,782 8 20 3,422 80 2 45,204 21 1903
1904 199,956 -6 26 0 41,796 0 21 5,818 53 3 47,640 24 1904
1905 197,619 -1 528 301 0 38,980 -7 20 1,068 -170 1 40,576 21 1905
1906 202,211 2 1,648 114 1 46,333 17 23 833 -25 0 48,814 24 1906
1907 201,830 0 2,895 56 1 43,929 -5 22 835 0 0 47,659 24 1907
1908 181,050 -11 2,940 2 2 33,478 -27 18 922 10 1 37,340 21 1908
1909 185,627 2 5,438 62 3 32,038 -4 17 925 0 0 38,401 21 1909
1910 219,520 17 9,838 59 4 34,669 8 16 854 -8 0 45,361 21 1910
1911 226,768 3 12,435 23 5 41,373 18 18 473 -59 0 54,281 24 1911
1912 241,814 6 10,270 -19 4 47,879 15 20 724 43 0 58,873 24 1912
1913 256,154 6 13,961 31 5 55,875 15 22 621 -15 0 70,457 28 1913
1914 228,330 -11 21,328 42 9 40,905 -31 18 663 7 0 62,896 28 1914
1915 303,860 29 54,642 94 18 55,000 30 18 1,206 60 0 110,848 36 1915
1916 377,950 22 103,254 64 27 51,410 -7 14 3,213 98 1 157,877 42 1916
1917 491,849 26 171,637 51 35 60,828 17 12 841 -134 0 233,306 47 1917
1918 496,637 1 139,136 -21 28 73,454 19 15 696 -19 0 213,286 43 1918
1919 720,347 37 260,934 63 36 72,427 -1 10 1,259 59 0 334,620 46 1919
1920 724,271 1 232,510 -12 32 70,491 -3 10 1,956 44 0 304,957 42 1920
1921 415,808 -55 83,918 -102 20 41,713 -52 10 1,890 -3 0 127,521 31 1921
1922 414,959 0 104,132 22 25 44,721 7 11 10,762 174 3 159,615 38 1922
1923 512,781 21 158,185 42 31 46,727 4 9 34,833 117 7 239,745 47 1923
1924 551,010 7 151,856 -4 28 75,168 48 14 30,768 -12 6 257,792 47 1924
1925 899,853 49 405,844 98 45 72,556 -4 8 71,127 84 8 549,527 61 1925
1926 874,758 -3 342,328 -17 39 76,338 5 9 78,658 10 9 497,324 57 1926
1927 791,614 -10 271,354 -23 34 91,929 19 12 73,659 -7 9 436,942 55 1927
1928 652,825 -19 162,407 -51 25 82,565 -11 13 - 244,972 38 1928
1929 658,964 1 183,592 12 28 76,560 -8 12 49,494 8 309,646 47 1929
1930 526,016 -23 100,461 -60 19 47,257 -48 9 - 147,718 28 1930
1931 326,419 -48 49,937 -70 15 29,800 -46 9 65,101 20 144,838 44 1931
1932 269,487 -19 28,536 -56 11 24,565 -19 9 58,145 -11 22 111,246 41 1932
1933 289,624 7 45,451 47 16 51,208 73 18 42,285 -32 15 138,944 48 1933
1934 331,880 14 124,045 100 37 45,333 -12 14 44,649 5 13 214,027 64 1934
1935 345,552 4 112,379 -10 33 52,725 15 15 50,911 13 15 216,015 63 1935
1936 365,742 6 131,428 16 36 63,457 19 17 42,416 -18 12 237,301 65 1936
1937 492,141 30 206,172 45 42 77,692 20 16 54,047 24 11 337,911 69 1937
1938 339,475 -37 120,511 -54 35 39,082 -69 12 54,924 2 16 214,517 63 1938
1939 435,886 25 178,765 39 41 69,527 58 16 52,561 -4 12 300,853 69 1939
Not Available
Figure 3.5
Singapore: Merchandize Exports by Major Export Commodities
(A) 1900-39 (B) 1950-60
1,000,000 5,000,000
900,000 4,500,000
800,000 4,000,000
Exports Value (Straits $ ,000)
700,000 3,500,000
600,000 3,000,000
500,000 2,500,000
400,000 2,000,000
300,000 1,500,000
200,000 1,000,000
100,000 500,000
- -
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1950
1951
1952
1953
1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
1959
1960
Year Year
Total Merchandize Exports Value ($,000) Total Merchandize Exports Value ($,000)
[1] Rubber Value ($,000) [1] Rubber Value ($,000)
[2] Tin Value ($,000) [2] Tin Value ($,000)
[3] Petroleum Value ($,000) [3] Petroleum Value ($,000)
149
Table 3.12
Singapore: Exports by Country and Region, 1911/13, 1925/27 and 1957/59,
(Annual Average)
1911/1913 1925/1927 1957/1959
$'000 % $'000 % $'000 %
Southeast Asia 123,111 47.8% 304,543 35.1% 1,317,149 39.3%
Malaya (Peninsular Malaysia) 58,485 22.7% 148,631 17.1% 694,688 20.7%
Netherland East Indies (Indonesia) 39,358 15.3% 102,041 11.8% 244,642 7.3%
Siam (Thailand) 9,666 3.8% 22,405 2.6% 82,283 2.5%
Indo-China (Vietnam) 2,323 0.9% 9,463 1.1% 49,737 1.5%
British Borneo (Sarawak, North Borneo and Brunei) 6,182 2.4% 14,102 1.6% 164,467 4.9%
Burma 5,467 2.1% 5,900 0.7% 23,937 0.7%
Philippine Islands and Sulu Archipelago 1,630 0.6% 2,000 0.2% 57,395 1.7%
Europe, North America and Japan 105,916 41.1% 470,440 54.2% 1,381,892 41.2%
United Kingdom 35,925 13.9% 49,208 5.7% 278,808 8.3%
Europe 33,372 13.0% 75,460 8.7% 594,735 17.7%
United States 31,188 12.1% 316,768 36.5% 253,309 7.6%
Canada 638 0.2% 2,378 0.3% 46,226 1.4%
Japan 4,793 1.9% 26,626 3.1% 208,814 6.2%
Rest of World 28,597 11.1% 93,295 10.7% 653,872 19.5%
Hong Kong 8,137 3.2% 6,826 0.8% 50,881 1.5%
China 3,240 1.3% 7,959 0.9% 75,498 2.3%
India 11,553 4.5% 14,399 1.7% 62,144 1.9%
Sri Lanka 1,919 0.7% 4,152 0.5% 12,147 0.4%
Australia 1,501 0.6% 30,619 3.5% 118,724 3.5%
Others 2,246 0.9% 29,339 3.4% 334,477 10.0%
Gross Exports (Inclusive of Coins and Bullions) 257,624 100.0% 868,278 100.0% 3,352,913 100.0%
Notes:
1 The figures include treasure of bullion and specie.
2 Columns may not add to totals due to rounding.
Source: Huff (1994:81 and 282-283).
As was described earlier, the structure of imports by major object was similar to that
of merchandize exports though the former was consistently higher than the latter. Apart
from rubber, tin, petroleum and other commodities, most of the major consumer and
capital goods imported recorded higher values than exports since retained imports in the
domestic market were finally distributed for either intermediate or final consumption,
capital formation and stocks. Singapore’s pattern of imports from Asia has been
with the import and export of commodities such as rubber, tin, petroleum etc. The city
Netherlands East Indies and British Borneo which were the main suppliers of these
commodities which were re-exported to the West. As is presented in Table 3.13, these
three territories combined, accounted for 39.8% (1911/1913), 59.1% (1925/1927) and
150
51.4% (1957/1959) of total merchandize imports of Singapore. Other than these major
manufactures from the Western countries for domestic consumption and re-exports.
Table 3.13
Singapore: Imports by Country and Region, 1911/13, 1925/27 and 1957/59
(Annual Average)
1911/1913 1925/1927 1957/1959
$'000 % $'000 % $'000 %
Southeast Asia 182,584 57.3% 694,775 69.7% 2,229,456 57.0%
Malaya (Peninsular Malaysia) 64,565 20.3% 203,537 20.4% 742,144 19.0%
Netherland East Indies (Indonesia) 56,577 17.8% 344,747 34.6% 1,066,791 27.3%
Siam (Thailand) 30,329 9.5% 72,565 7.3% 142,220 3.6%
Indo-China (Vietnam) 11,560 3.6% 20,196 2.0% 41,698 1.1%
British Borneo (Sarawak, North Borneo and Brunei) 5,431 1.7% 40,087 4.0% 200,837 5.1%
Burma 12,430 3.9% 12,336 1.2% 33,496 0.9%
Philippine Islands and Sulu Archipelago 1,692 0.5% 1,306 0.1% 2,269 0.1%
Europe, North America and Japan 65,382 20.5% 184,419 18.5% 1,045,944 26.7%
United Kingdom 34,656 10.9% 89,396 9.0% 390,957 10.0%
Europe 16,183 5.1% 35,860 3.6% 270,696 6.9%
United States 4,825 1.5% 30,824 3.1% 127,015 3.2%
Canada 104 0.0% 2,328 0.2% 11,390 0.3%
Japan 9,614 3.0% 26,011 2.6% 245,886 6.3%
Rest of World 70,572 22.2% 117,662 11.8% 637,790 16.3%
Hong Kong 25,909 8.1% 27,180 2.7% 86,295 2.2%
China 8,395 2.6% 32,233 3.2% 135,122 3.5%
India 19,934 6.3% 30,821 3.1% 66,395 1.7%
Sri Lanka 621 0.2% 798 0.1% 2,430 0.1%
Australia 10,781 3.4% 13,481 1.4% 112,726 2.9%
Others 4,932 1.5% 13,151 1.3% 234,821 6.0%
Gross Imports (Inclusive of Coins and Bullions) 318,538 100.0% 996,856 100.0% 3,913,191 100.0%
Notes:
1. The figures include treasure of bullion and specie.
2. Columns may not add to totals due to rounding.
Source: Huff (1994:81and 282-283).
that of other nations. For this purpose, six countries were chosen, based on data
availability, they being UK, USA, Japan, Korea, Taiwan and Finland. Figure 3.6 depicts
the comparison of Singapore’s annual growth rate of GDP with these selected countries
for the period 1900-39 at current prices.72 One outstanding feature arising from these
comparisons was the volatility in the GDP growth rates of Singapore compared to the
other countries during this period. Nevertheless, there was a common pattern amongst
72
Ideally, comparison would be made based on the constant prices with same base year. However, it is impossible to conduct this
exercise since each country used different base years. Therefore, it was decided to utilize current price figures for international
comparison.
151
all countries reflected in the sharp dip in GDP growth rates during the period of WWI
and the Great Depression years in the early 1930s. It would be noted that the growth of
Singapore in the 1930s was very similar to that of Malaya and USA.73
Figure 3.6
Annual Growth Rates (%) of GDP of Singapore against Selected Countries,
1900-39 at Current Prices
[A] Singapore and Malaya [B] Singapore and Japan [C] Singapore and Korea
50.0
50.0 50.0
40.0
40.0 40.0
30.0
30.0 30.0
20.0
20.0 20.0
growth rate (%)
10.0
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
-10.0
-10.0 -10.0
-20.0
-20.0 -20.0
-30.0
-30.0 -30.0
-40.0
-40.0 -40.0
-50.0 -50.0 -50.0
Year Year Year
Singapore Japan
Singapore Malaya Singapore Korea
[D] Singapore and Taiwan [E] Singapore and UK [F] Singapore and Finland
50.0 50.0 80.0
40.0 40.0
60.0
30.0 30.0
40.0
20.0 20.0
0.0 0.0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
0.0
-10.0 -10.0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
-20.0 -20.0 -20.0
-30.0 -30.0
-40.0
-40.0 -40.0
40.0
30.0
20.0 Sources: (Malaya) Nazrin, Raja (2002), (Japan, Korea and Taiwan)
growth rate (%)
10.0
0.0
Mizoguchi, Toshiyuki and Umemura, Mataji (edit.) (1988), (UK) Feinstein,
C.H, (1974), (Finland) Hjerppe, Riitta (1996), (USA) Carter, Susan B.
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
-10.0
-20.0
-30.0
(2006).
-40.0
-50.0
Year
Singapore USA
Subsequently, annual growth rate of each component of GDP was observed (See
Figures 3.7-3.11). Unlike annual growth rate of GDP, annual growth rate of each
component of GDP was somewhat not significantly different from that observed for the
In the case of PFCE, all selected countries recorded remarkably steep annual growth
rate increase during the 1916-20 period. Subsequently, all selected countries
experienced a continuous negative growth during the world depression in the early
and Japan during the World War I period and The Japan-Russo War respectively.
73
For the period 1929-1939, correlations of GDP growth between (a) Singapore and Malaya and (b) Singapore and USA was
0.7187 and 0.5959 respectively.
152
Unlike these countries, Singapore did not experience wide fluctuations of government
Figure 3.7
Annual Growth Rates (%) of Private Final Consumption Expenditure by Resident
Household (PFCE) of Singapore against Selected Countries,
1900-39 at Current Prices
[A] Singapore and Malaya [B] Singapore and Japan [C] Singapore and Korea
30.0
50.0 50.0
30.0 30.0
10.0
20.0 20.0
growth rate (%)
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
-10.0 -10.0
-20.0
-20.0 -20.0
-30.0
-30.0 -30.0
-40.0 -40.0 -40.0
Year Year Year
[D] Singapore and Taiwan [E] Singapore and UK [F] Singapore and Finland
40.0 30.0 70.0
60.0
30.0
20.0 50.0
40.0
20.0
10.0 30.0
10.0 20.0
0.0
10.0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
0.0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
0.0
-10.0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
-10.0 -10.0
-20.0 -20.0
-20.0
-30.0
Sources: (Malaya) Nazrin, Raja (2006), (UK) Feinstein, C.H, (1974), (Finland) Hjerppe, Riitta (1996), (Japan, Korea and Taiwan)
Mizoguchi, Toshiyuki and Umemura, Mataji (edit.) (1988)
Figure 3.8
Annual Growth Rates (%) of Government Final Consumption Expenditure
(GFCE) of Singapore against Selected Countries,
1900-39 at Current Prices
[A] Singapore and Malaya [B] Singapore and Japan [C] Singapore and Korea
100.0
100.0 100.0
50.0 50.0
50.0
growth rate (%)
0.0 0.0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
0.0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
-50.0
-50.0
-50.0
-100.0
Year -100.0
Year
Year
[D] Singapore and Taiwan [E] Singapore and UK [F] Singapore and Finland
100.0 150.0 100.0
100.0
50.0 50.0
growth rate (%)
growth rate (%)
50.0
0.0
0.0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
0.0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
-50.0
-50.0
-50.0
-100.0
-100.0 -100.0
Year
Year Year
Sources: (Malaya) Nazrin, Raja (2002), (UK) Feinstein, C.H, (1974), (Finland) Hjerppe, Riitta (1996), (Japan, Korea and Taiwan)
Mizoguchi, Toshiyuki and Umemura, Mataji (edit.) (1988)
153
The percentage annual growth rate of Gross Capital Formation for the period
1900-39 experienced relatively frequent volatilities. During the early 1920s and 1930s,
most of the countries experienced negative growth due to the world wide recessions.
Interestingly, the movement of Singapore was somewhat very similar to that of Malaya
(See Figure 3.9). Figures 3.10 and 3.11 portray the annual growth of both exports and
imports of goods and services. As was observed in the case of Gross Capital Formation,
annual growth rates of both imports and exports of goods and services experienced
similar patterns. Interestingly, Malaya, Japan, Taiwan and Korea have all recorded
observe the difference in the percentage contribution of each GDP component to total
Figure 3.9
Annual Growth Rates (%) of Gross Capital Formation (GCF) of Singapore against
Selected Countries, 1900-39 and 1950-60 at Current Prices
[A] Singapore and Malaya [B] Singapore and Japan [C] Singapore and Korea
100.0
100.0 100.0
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
-50.0 -50.0 -50.0
[D] Singapore and Taiwan [E] Singapore and UK [F] Singapore and Finland
100.0 200.0 150.0
150.0 100.0
50.0
100.0
50.0
growth rate (%)
growth rate (%)
50.0
0.0
0.0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
0.0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
-50.0
-50.0
-50.0
-100.0
-100.0
-150.0
-100.0 -150.0
Year
Year Year
Sources: (Malaya) Nazrin, Raja (2002), (UK) Feinstein, C.H, (1974), (Finland) Hjerppe, Riitta (1996), (Japan, Korea and Taiwan)
Mizoguchi, Toshiyuki and Umemura, Mataji (edit.) (1988)
154
Figure 3.10
Annual Growth Rates (%) of Exports of Goods and Services (EXGS) of Singapore
against Selected Countries, 1900-39 and 1950-60 at Current Prices
[A] Singapore and Malaya [B] Singapore and Japan [C] Singapore and Korea
60.0
60.0 60.0
40.0
40.0 40.0
20.0
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
-20.0 0.0 0.0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
-40.0
-20.0 -20.0
-60.0
-40.0 -40.0
-80.0
[D] Singapore and Taiwan [E] Singapore and UK [F] Singapore and Finland
60.0 60.0 150.0
40.0
40.0 100.0
20.0
20.0
0.0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
0.0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
-20.0 0.0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
-20.0
-40.0
-50.0
-40.0 -60.0
-100.0
-60.0 -80.0
Year
Year Year
Sources: (Malaya) Nazrin, Raja (2002), (UK) Feinstein, C.H, (1974), (Finland) Hjerppe, Riitta (1996), (Japan, Korea and Taiwan)
Mizoguchi, Toshiyuki and Umemura, Mataji (edit.) (1988)
Figure 3.11
Annual Growth Rates (%) of Imports of Goods and Services (IMGS) of Singapore
against Selected Countries, 1900-39 and 1950-60 at Current Prices
[A] Singapore and Malaya [B] Singapore and Japan [C] Singapore and Korea
60.0
60.0 60.0
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
-20.0 -20.0 -20.0
-80.0 -80.0
-80.0
Year Year
Year
[D] Singapore and Taiwan [E] Singapore and UK [F] Singapore and Finland
60.0 60.0 200.0
0.0 0.0
50.0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
-20.0 -20.0
0.0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
-40.0 -40.0
-50.0
-60.0 -60.0
-100.0
-80.0 -80.0
Year
Year Year
Sources: (Malaya) Nazrin, Raja (2002), (UK) Feinstein, C.H, (1974), (Finland) Hjerppe, Riitta (1996), (Japan, Korea and Taiwan)
Mizoguchi, Toshiyuki and Umemura, Mataji (edit.) (1988)
155
3.3.3.2 Share of Each Component of GDP to GDP
comparisons are presented in Table 3.14 and Figures 3.12-3.15. In terms of share of
PFCE and GCF to GDP, Singapore has experienced a relatively higher percentage share
than that of the other countries. On the other hand, in terms of the share of GFCE,
Singapore has shown to have relatively smaller percentage share than the other nations.
One unique feature that does not escape notice in general is the continuous negative
share of Singapore’s net export of goods and services to GDP throughout the entire
study period.74 Singapore had extensive contacts with other nations and each of them
served as a crucial port for their respective hinterland, undertaking certain essential
distributive, financial and transportation functions. This entrepôt background gave them
certain initial advantages. But, Singapore is almost totally lacking in natural resources.
Its arable land can provide only a small portion of its food requirements. Additionally,
Singapore does not have her own rural hinterlands in which a majority of their people
still live and support themselves by subsistence or commercial agriculture. Nor do they
have a domestic market large enough to serve as the initial base for industrialization.
Hence, Singapore’s very existence depended upon its ability to import, which in turn
rested upon its capacity to earn the necessary foreign exchange by exporting goods and
external economic shocks and consequently its impact on GDP (Peebles, Gavin and
74
It will be noted that the share of each component of GDP for Singapore has been relatively similar to that of the Dutch.
Unfortunately, the share of each component of the Dutch GDP was available for the period 1814-1913 only.
75
As is described in page 146, while the merchandize trade balance was consistently negative, the combined invisible trade and
capital and financial account (CFA) was positive largely due to the inflow of foreign direct investments.
156
Table 3.14
Percentage Share of Components of GDP to Total GDP for Selected Countries
at Current Prices, 1900-60
Private Final Consumption Expenditure by Resident Households
Singapore Japan Korea Taiwan UK Finland Dutch
1900 96 - - - 84 85 84
1911 88 73 99 78 84 85 91
1926 94 78 92 72 87 81 -
1934 81 71 88 64 84 67 -
1950 81 - - - 73 65 -
1960 87 - - - 67 59 -
Sources: (Japan, Korea and Taiwan) Mizoguchi, Toshiyuki and Umemura, Mataji (edit.) (1988), (UK) Feinstein (1974), (Finland)
Hjerppe, Riitta (1996), (Dutch) J.-P.Smits, E.Horlings and J.L.van Zanden (2000).
157
Figure 3.12
Percentage Share of Private Final Consumption Expenditure in
Gross Domestic Product in Current Prices, 1900-39
Singapore and Selected Countries
120.0
100.0
80.0
% of GDP
60.0
40.0
20.0
0.0
1900
1901
1902
1903
1904
1905
1906
1907
1908
1909
1910
1911
1912
1913
1914
1915
1916
1917
1918
1919
1920
1921
1922
1923
1924
1925
1926
1927
1928
1929
1930
1931
1932
1933
1934
1935
1936
1937
1938
1939
Year
Sources: (Malaya) Nazrin, Raja (2002), (Japan, Korea and Taiwan) Mizoguchi, Toshiyuki and Umemura, Mataji (edit.) (1988),
(UK) Feinstein (1974), (Finland) Hjerppe, Riitta (1996), (Dutch) J.-P.Smits, E.Horlings and J.L.van Zanden (2000).
Figure 3.13
Percentage Share of Government Final Consumption Expenditure in
Gross Domestic Product in Current Prices, 1900-39
Singapore and Selected Countries
40.0
35.0
30.0
25.0
% of GDP
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
0.0
1900
1901
1902
1903
1904
1905
1906
1907
1908
1909
1910
1911
1912
1913
1914
1915
1916
1917
1918
1919
1920
1921
1922
1923
1924
1925
1926
1927
1928
1929
1930
1931
1932
1933
1934
1935
1936
1937
1938
1939
Year
158
Figure 3.14
Percentage Share of Gross Capital Formation in Gross Domestic Product in
Current Prices, 1900-39, Singapore and Selected Countries
40.0
35.0
30.0
25.0
% of GDP
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
0.0
1900
1901
1902
1903
1904
1905
1906
1907
1908
1909
1910
1911
1912
1913
1914
1915
1916
1917
1918
1919
1920
1921
1922
1923
1924
1925
1926
1927
1928
1929
1930
1931
1932
1933
1934
1935
1936
1937
1938
1939
Year
Figure 3.15
Percentage Share of Net Exports of Goods and Services in Gross Domestic Product
in Current Prices, 1900-39, Singapore and Selected Countries
50.0
40.0
30.0
20.0
10.0
% of GDP
0.0
1900
1901
1902
1903
1904
1905
1906
1907
1908
1909
1910
1911
1912
1913
1914
1915
1916
1917
1918
1919
1920
1921
1922
1923
1924
1925
1926
1927
1928
1929
1930
1931
1932
1933
1934
1935
1936
1937
1938
1939
-10.0
-20.0
-30.0
-40.0
-50.0
-60.0
Year
159
3.4 Overall Pattern of Singapore’s GDP during the Twentieth Century
3.4.1 Transforming the base year from 1914 prices to 1990 prices for the period
1900-39 and 1950-60
becomes inevitable that a time-series data stretching over the twentieth century with one
base year be constructed. In this exercise, the year 1990 was selected as base year for
the entire twentieth century due to the availability of time-series data for the period
1960-95, provided in the Singapore System of National Accounts 1995 and 1996-2000
in the Asian Development Bank, Key Indicators of Developing Asian and Pacific
Countries, 2001. On the other hand, 1914 was selected as a base year for the period
from 1914 to 1990 prices for the period, 1900-39 and 1950-60 from 1914 prices, the
As is presented in Chapter 2, PFCE and GFCE were deflated by CPI. On the other
hand, other components of GDP were deflated differently. In the case of GCF,
change in stock was deflated by each deflator separately. Similar to this, merchandize
trade and service trade were deflated by their respective deflators. Nevertheless, official
database for the years 1960-2000 merely provides implicit deflators for each component
of GDP. Under these constraints of availability of deflator, it was decided to apply the
implicit deflators for GCF, EXGS and IMGS (See Tables 3.15 and 3.16).
160
Table 3.15
Conversion Ratio from 1914 price to 1990 price
for the period 1900-39 and 1950-60
For the new series in 1990 prices, the growth rates of each component of GDP,
namely, PFCE, GFCE, GCF, EXGS and IMGS for the years 1900-39 and 1950-60
correspond to the 1914 constant price series. However, the growth rates of GDP
components in 1990 prices are different from that of GDP series in 1914 prices.
For conducting the empirical investigation on the economic growth of Singapore for
the twentieth century in Chapter Four and Five, it is inevitable to use the time-series
161
Table 3.16
The Methodology for Deriving Deflators (1990=100) by Each Component of GDP,
1900-39 and 1950-2000
Private Final Consumption Government Final Consumption Gross Fixed Capital Formation Exports of Goods and Services Imports of Goods and Services
Expenditure Expenditure
1950 359.02 33.62 359.02 28.40 286.27 17.97 236.01 44.10 235.24 45.97 1950
1951 451.51 42.29 451.51 35.71 343.94 21.59 329.63 61.59 332.36 64.94 1951
1952 469.80 44.00 469.80 37.16 405.01 25.43 272.03 50.83 273.39 53.42 1952
1953 458.41 42.93 458.41 36.26 334.21 20.98 240.67 44.97 232.56 45.44 1953
1954 436.94 40.92 436.94 34.56 343.77 21.58 234.26 43.77 226.04 44.17 1954
1955 427.08 40.00 427.08 33.78 374.11 23.49 270.61 50.56 266.17 52.01 1955
1956 431.66 40.43 431.66 34.14 347.89 21.84 264.83 49.48 258.56 50.52 1956
1957 444.20 41.60 444.20 35.13 375.85 23.60 260.01 48.58 252.80 49.40 1957
1958 441.93 41.39 441.93 34.95 331.93 20.84 253.01 47.27 243.88 47.65 1958
1959 436.87 40.91 436.87 34.55 299.91 18.83 273.82 51.16 267.22 52.22 1959
1960 437.05 40.93 437.05 34.57 274.02 17.20 280.99 52.50 273.29 53.40 1960
1961 40.99 36.15 18.28 52.50 53.40 1961
1962 41.10 37.71 23.39 52.50 53.40 1962
1963 41.61 37.78 22.86 52.40 53.30 1963
1964 42.09 37.83 26.46 53.30 54.20 1964
1965 42.36 37.85 27.45 53.00 53.90 1965
1966 43.20 38.01 29.04 50.70 51.60 1966
1967 44.23 38.17 29.30 51.00 51.90 1967
1968 44.78 38.21 31.09 48.20 49.00 1968
1969 44.77 38.70 33.68 50.20 51.10 1969
1970 45.35 39.38 37.19 52.60 53.50 1970
1971 46.89 41.83 39.58 53.20 54.10 1971
1972 48.10 42.45 44.43 53.40 54.40 1972
1973 54.71 45.43 49.48 60.50 61.60 1973
1974 61.46 52.71 58.30 85.40 85.70 1974
1975 63.28 56.23 59.41 86.10 86.70 1975
1976 63.68 58.01 62.43 91.90 92.60 1976
1977 65.01 59.14 62.91 95.60 96.70 1977
1978 66.71 60.71 65.13 97.50 98.80 1978
1979 69.67 63.14 70.31 102.80 104.90 1979
1980 75.46 69.44 79.10 113.10 116.10 1980
1981 80.06 75.18 86.55 116.90 119.70 1981
1982 66.09 84.98 87.06 116.60 117.20 1982
1983 83.22 86.74 88.04 111.00 111.20 1983
1984 85.86 89.34 88.83 104.90 106.20 1984
1985 86.55 108.54 86.57 103.30 105.10 1985
1986 86.90 86.44 84.60 89.50 91.10 1986
1987 89.11 86.45 86.95 96.30 98.70 1987
1988 92.55 92.32 94.93 97.90 99.40 1988
1989 96.75 98.48 98.67 99.30 99.90 1989
1990 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 1990
1991 102.57 100.66 102.70 97.60 96.40 1991
1992 104.95 100.82 104.88 94.00 93.00 1992
1993 109.18 101.56 110.01 93.10 91.90 1993
1994 114.10 106.64 109.34 92.10 89.20 1994
1995 115.30 107.02 110.13 91.30 88.10 1995
1996 114.35 110.75 107.79 90.10 86.80 1996
1997 115.49 111.63 108.89 89.00 85.40 1997
1998 114.22 109.10 106.67 88.04 84.47 1998
1999 114.95 104.57 104.24 88.23 87.16 1999
2000 116.33 109.26 101.19 92.83 90.41 2000
162
3.4.2 Overall Patterns of Growth for the Twentieth Century
during the entire twentieth century from the view points of GDP growth and share of
3.4.2.1 Growth Rate of GDP and Its Component in the Twentieth Century
Singapore’s GDP growth rate has been high and remarkably consistent over a long
time period; the size of economy being measured simply in terms of real domestic
output. In 1939, real GDP (1990 prices) was 5.7 times its 1900 level. In 2000, real GDP
increased tremendously such that it was 33.8 times its 1950 level. The annual average
growth rate of GDP for the periods 1900-39 and 1950-2000 was 4.5% and 7.2%
respectively while the growth rate of real per-capita GDP for the same periods was
1.5% and 4.6%76 (See Table 3.17 and Figures 16 and 17). Both results reinforce the
historical fact that the overall growth rate of GDP during the post-World War II period
was significantly higher than that of the pre-World War II period. Table 3.17 gives
some indication of these growth rates for nine (9) decades. The most rapid growth of
real GDP and real per capita GDP was recorded in the 1960s and 1970s. Subsequently,
the growth rates were somewhat slightly lower after the 1980s. Each component of
Table 3.18 depicts the annual growth rates of both real GDP and its components and
it can be seen that many fluctuations were observed during the British colonial period
(up to 1957). Similarly, most of the negative growth rates for the twentieth century were
recorded during the British colonial period for the years 1930-32, 1938 and 1952
namely, -21% (1930) -23% (1931), -7% (1932), -11% (1938) and -19% (1952). In fact,
many countries faced a similar economic situation due to the world depression. On the
other hand, high growth rates of more than 20% were recorded for the years 1933 (23%),
76
The annual average growth rate was calculated based on the simple arithmetic average of yearly exponential growth rates.
163
1935 (22%), 1953 (24%) and 1956 (21%). On the other hand, real GDP has recorded
sustained and high growth rates during the period of self-government. For the years
1966-73, real GDP growth rates have constantly exceeded 10% exclusive of 1964 (-4%).
During this period, huge and significant foreign direct investment (FDI) into Singapore
was observed. For the period 1976-2000, real GDP growth rate was in the range of
6-11%, excluding the years 1985 (-2%) and 1998 (0.3%). During this period,
Singapore’s economy was boosted by the rapid expansion of the manufacturing and
financial and business services (Peebles, Gavin and Wilson, Peter, 2002:95).
Table 3.17
Singapore: Average Annual Growth Rate of Each Component of GDP and
Per-capita GDP at 1990 Prices, 1900-2000
164
Table 3.18
Singapore: Components of GDP, 1900-39 and 1950-2000 (1990 Prices)
Private Final Consumption Government Final Consumption Gross Capital Formation Net Exports of Goods Statistical GDP at Martket Prices
Expenditure in The Domestic Expenditure and Services Discrepancy
Market by Resident Households
165
Figure 3.16
Singapore: GDP at Current and Constant (1990 Prices), 1900-39 and 1950-2000
180,000
160,000 GDP (Current Prices)
140,000 GDP (1990 Prices)
Straits $ (millions)
120,000
100,000
80,000
60,000
40,000
20,000
-
1900
1905
1910
1915
1920
1925
1930
1935
1940
1954
1959
1964
1969
1974
1979
1984
1989
1994
1999
Year
Figure 3.17
Singapore: Per-capita GDP at Current and Constant (1990 Prices),
1900-39 and 1950-2000
45,000
40,000
Per-capita GDP (Current Prices)
35,000
Per-capita GDP (1990 Prices)
30,000
Straits $
25,000
20,000
15,000
10,000
5,000
-
1900
1905
1910
1915
1920
1925
1930
1935
1940
1954
1959
1964
1969
1974
1979
1984
1989
1994
1999
Year
166
3.4.2.2 Share of Each Component of GDP
Table 3.19 shows the 10-yearly average share of each component of GDP for the
period 1900-39 and 1950-2000 while Table 3.20 and Figure 3.18 present the annual
share of each component of GDP at current prices in Singapore for the same period.
Table 3.19
Singapore: Annual Average Share of Each Component to GDP at Current Prices,
1900-39 and 1950-2000
Figure 3.18
Singapore: Share of Each Component of GDP to GDP at Current Prices,
1900-39 and 1950-2000
120
100
80
60
% of GDP
40
20
0
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1951
1953
1955
1957
1959
1961
1963
1965
1967
1969
1971
1973
1975
1977
1979
1981
1983
1985
1987
1989
1991
1993
1995
1997
1999
-20
-40
-60
-80
Year
PFCE GFCE GFCF NETEX
Abbreviations:
PFCE Private Final Consumption Expenditure by resident households
GFCE Government Final Consumption Expenditure
GCF Gross Capital Formation
NETEX Net Exports of Goods and Services
167
Table 3.20
Singapore: Components of GDP, 1900-39 and 1950-2000 (Current Prices)
Private Final Consumption Government Final Consumption Gross Capital Formation Net Exports of Goods Statistical Discrepancy GDP at Martket Prices
Expenditure in The Domestic Expenditure and Services
Market by Resident Households
168
For the period 1900-39 and 1950-60, the 10-yearly average share of each component
of GDP was relatively stable though the annual data generally displayed significant
yearly changes.
In contrast to the British colonial period, structural changes were observed after the
expenditure by resident households (PFCE) showed drastic falls from about 89 per cent
of GDP in the 1960 to around 40 per cent at the end of the 20th century.
On the other hand, the share of government final consumption expenditure (GFCE)
to GDP remained fairly constant. The annual share of gross capital formation (GCF) to
GDP, however, has gradually increased after independence from 20% to 40% within the
20-year period (1971-90) though it declined slightly during the 1990s. The most
remarkable change was observed in the net exports of goods and services. Net exports
were in the negative territory up to 1985. This situation dramatically reversed after 1985
when net exports began to predominate in the positive territory. By 2000, the share of
There are a number of plausible explanatory factors for this incredible change which
occurred during the last four decades in the structure of GDP. A large fall of PFCE can
be explained by the remarkable increase in Gross Domestic Savings (GDS) over this
long period77 (Peebles and Wilson, 2002: 78 and Ghesquiere, 2007: 165). This increase
of saving rate can be attributed to “forced saving” due to the compulsory public
financing domestic investments and lending abroad. The continuous reduction of the
77
Disposable income is equal to income (output) plus net transfers less taxes. Disposable income, in turn, is allocated to
consumption and saving. Therefore, increases of the weight on saving will lead the fall of share of PFCE against GDP.
78
The Central Provident Fund (CPF) was established by law in 1953 under the colonial administration and started operations in
July 1955. It was initially intended as a fully-funded pension plan for civil servants but has been expanded in coverage and scope
immensely under the PAP government and has become an important part of social and economic policy and has been used for
macroeconomic purposes. Employers and employees both contribute to the member’s account at rates that have changed
significantly over time. All employees are required to be members while permanent residents can be members. The self-employed
can contribute to this fund. The scheme implies no transfers between economic classes and is not redistributive or aimed at reducing
income inequality. It does not guarantee any minimum pension on retirement.
169
share of PFCE has led to a parallel increase in the share of GCF. This structure,
however, experienced significant changes in 1985. Since then, gross national savings
have exceeded domestic investments and this has led to large positive current account
balances.79
Figure 3.19
Singapore: Saving and Investment as ratio of GNP and Current Account Balance,
1960-2000
60 40,000
35,000
50
30,000
40 25,000
S'pore $ millions
20,000
30
% to GNP
15,000
20
10,000
10 5,000
0
0
1960
1962
1964
1966
1968
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
-5,000
-10 -10,000
Source: Figure was created based on Table released by Peebles, Gavin and Wilson, Peter (2002: 274-275)
79
The excess of saving over investment (S – I) in the private sector is equal to the government budget deficit (Government
purchases of goods and services (G) plus government transfer payments (TR) minus government revenue (TA)) plus the trade
surplus (NEXGS); S - I = (G + TR – TA) + NEXGS. In the case of Singapore, the government budget has been in the surplus
situation for many years. Thus, it is inevitable to conclude that when savings exceed investments, net exports of goods and services
would be in the positive territory.
170
CHAPTER FOUR
4.1 Introduction
It will be recalled that the methodology employed for the construction of GDP
estimates for the Colony of Singapore for the period 1900-39 and 1950-60 was
economic database stretching over the last hundred years,80 covering the British colonial
era and the more recent period of self-government, enabled us to undertake a long-term
This chapter is devoted to examining economic instability and its impact on the
economic growth of Singapore during the twentieth century. In this study, economic
instability is defined as the short-term fluctuations of real GDP after adjusting for trend
(Nazrin, 2000, Dawe, 1996). As observed in Chapter Three, the salient feature of
often described as a ‘very open re-export economy’ due to her heavy reliance on
imported intermediate inputs as well as entrepôt exports (Huff, 1994, Lloyd and
Sandilands, 1986, Peebles and Wilson, 1996 and 2002). Basically, this nature of
essentially unchanged until today. Given this scenario, Singapore has been
80
This study does not include 1940-49 due to the absence of historical GDP estimates.
171
Nevertheless, Singapore has experienced two major changes in the twentieth century.
The first involved the shifting of trade dependence from the re-export of primary
management which was dictated by the principle of laissez-faire under the British
Against this historical backdrop, this chapter focuses on answering three basic
questions relating to the issue of economic instability and its concomitant effect on
economic growth. The first question seeks to examine the pattern of volatility of real
GDP and its components over the century. The second attempt is to identify the
explanatory variables which could statistically explain the sources of real GDP volatility.
Thirdly, this study examines the effect of export instability and other relevant
explanatory variables on the economic growth of Singapore. For all of the above
questions, attention was focused particularly on whether there were any notable
economic growth for the two periods, namely the British colonial era and the period of
self-government.
This chapter is organized as follows. Section 4.2 conducts a literature review on the
studies relating to (i) the extent of volatility of GDP and its components (ii) the source
of real GDP volatility, (iii) the effect of export instability on economic growth and (iv)
the studies on Singapore relating to this topic. Section 4.3 outlines the definition of
economic instability and examines the extent of economic instability of Singapore’s real
GDP and its components, namely private final consumption expenditure, government
final consumption expenditure, gross capital formation, exports of goods and services
and imports of goods and services. Section 4.4 conducts two types of econometric tests,
namely the sources of output volatility and the effect of export instability on economic
172
growth. Based on the results of econometric tests, international comparisons would be
made in Section 4.5. Finally, Section 4.6 provides some concluding remarks.
To-date, many studies have been conducted touching on the issues of economic
instability based on the various empirical econometric tests with different time-series
framework undertaken for both developed and developing countries. One of the
academic questions relating to this subject was the declining degree of real GDP
volatility over time. Christina Romer (1986, 1989), Sheffrin (1988) and Nathan Balke
and Robert J. Gordon (1989) observed the fact that real GDP volatility in the United
States after World War II has been smaller than that prior to World War I and discussed
that a diminution of volatility was the reflection of institutional developments and the
David K., Kehoe, Patrick J. (1992) compared output volatility prior to World War I (the
pre-war period 1870-1914), between the wars (the inter-war period 1919-39) and the
statistical data of ten countries, namely Australia, Canada, Denmark, Germany, Italy,
Japan, Norway, Sweden, United Kingdom and United States. This study also found that
real GDP volatilities during the pre-World War I period were generally larger than those
of the post World War II period, the extent of the differences varying across countries.
The changes in real GDP variability over time are that the inter-war era experienced
much larger fluctuations than the other two periods although the extent of this higher
volatility again varies from country to country. High volatilities were experienced
during a brief depression in the early 1920s and the Great Depressions of the 1930s
173
Similar exercises were conducted by Bergman, U.Michael, Bordo, Michael D. and
Jonung, Lars (1998) and Basu, S and Taylor, Alan (1999) by extending the number of
Japan, Netherlands, Norway, Spain, Sweden, United Kingdom and United States). The
time periods were decided based on the four distinct international monetary regimes,
namely the Classical Gold Standard period (1870-1914), inter-war period (1919-39),
Bretton Woods era (1945-71) and Floating Exchange Rate era (1970s to present). Their
empirical tests find convergence with the observations made in the works of Backus and
Patrick J. (1992). Volatility was considerably higher during the inter-war years than
during the pre-World War I and the post-World War II periods (See Figure 4.1).
Figure 4.1
Standard Deviations of Output (Real GDP) Volatility during Different Monetary
Regimes
0.09
0.08
0.07
Standard Deviation
0.06
0.05
0.04
0.03
0.02
0.01
0.00
United Kingdom
Belgium
Germany
Japan
Denmark
France
Canada
United States
Netherlands
Italy
Finland
Norway
Sweden
In addition to real GDP volatilities, Backus and Patrick (1992) examined volatilities
net exports. Some stylized facts were observed. Firstly, consumption expenditures have
exhibits little regularities with its volatility relative to output ranging from 0.81 in inter-
174
war Sweden to 8.72 in inter-war Britain to 9.49 in pre-war Japan.81 Thirdly, volatilities
of investment (gross capital formation) has generally varied, with the level of standard
deviation being two to four times larger than output. Fourthly, volatilities of net
the cross-correlations between volatilities of each major component and real GDP. As
GDP ranges from 0.41 in pre-war United Kingdom to 0.91 in the pre-war United States.
Similarly, cross-correlations between investment volatility and that of real GDP is also
relatively high. On the other hand, cross-correlations between government spending and
are positive and eight are negative. In the case of net exports, in two-thirds of the cases
the cross-correlations were negative and often strongly so. In the remaining cases, the
available for developing countries due to the dearth of long-term time-series data which
stretch over the entire twentieth century. This study hopes to bridge the gap by
providing a case study of a developing country like Singapore (See Section 4.3).
Empirical tests on the output volatility after World War II have been more widely
examined for both developed and developing countries. Blanchard and Simon (2001)
measured output volatility in USA, United Kingdom, Canada, France, Germany, Italy
and Japan since the first quarter of 1952. It was noted that volatility increased from the
late 1960s to the mid-1980s, and this was followed by a sharp decline since the second
half of the 1980s for all six countries. A similar pattern was observed from the exercise
81
This large difference was partly due to the expansion of military spending during the Russo-Japanese War.
82
Volatilities of net exports were measured as the ratio of current value net exports to nominal output.
175
Figure 4.2
Standard Deviations of Volatilities of Major Components of GDP Relative to Output (Real GDP) for Pre War, Inter-war and Post War Period
3.5 10
9
3.0
8
2.5 7
6
2.0
5
1.5 4
1.0 3
2
0.5
1
10 4.0
9 3.5
8
3.0
7
2.5
6
5 2.0
4 1.5
3
1.0
2
0.5
1
Standard Deviations Relative to Output
176
Figure 4.3
Cross-Correlations between Volatilities of Each Major Component and Output (Real GDP)
CONSUMPTION GOVERNMENT PURCHASES
1.00 1.00
0.90 0.80
0.80 0.60
0.70
0.40
0.60
0.20
0.50
0.00
0.40
Australia Canada Denmark Italy Japan Norway Sweden United United
0.30 -0.20 Kingdom States
0.20 -0.40
1.00 1.00
0.80
0.80
0.60
0.60 0.40
0.20
0.40 0.00
Australia Canada Denmark Italy Japan Norway Sweden United United
-0.20 Kingdom States
0.20
-0.40
-0.60
0.00
Australia Canada Denmark Italy Japan Norway Sweden United United -0.80
Kingdom States
-0.20 -1.00
177
Table 4.1
Standard deviations of annual real GDP growth (GDP % Growth Volatility)
Most of the trend decrease in output volatility can be traced to a decrease in the
countries, a similar exercise applied for developing countries yielded different results. A
study by Agénor, McDermott and Prasad (2000) found that output volatility of
developing countries83 were, on average, much higher than the level typically observed
in industrial countries for the period 1978 (1st quarter) to 1995 (4th quarter). Similarly,
studies by De Ferranti et al (2000) and, Singh and Fagernäs (2006) show that there are
countries for the period 1960-2004. As presented in Table 4.2, evidence suggests that
volatility has declined over the last two decades in South Asia and less so, in the East
Asia region as a whole. Among the latter country group, volatility has clearly declined
for China, but whether this is the case for the other countries is not clear. To the best of
my knowledge, there are, unfortunately, no previous studies which dealt with the issue
of economic instability during the British colonial period and the period of self-
government. This was plausibly due to the absence of long-term time series economic
data. This study, therefore, represents the first of its kind devoted specifically to
examining the extent of instability of GDP and its components for Singapore during the
twentieth century.
83
Those countries are Chile, Colombia, India, South Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Nigeria, Philippines, Tunisia, Turkey and Uruguay.
178
Table 4.2
Real GDP growth volatility (Standard Deviations and Mean of Growth)
1960-71 1972-81 1982-91 1992-2004 1992-2004
St.Dev 2.6 3.6 1.8 1.3
South Asia
Mean 4.0 3.6 5.2 5.7
St.Dev 7.4 2.0 1.5 2.5 1.7
East Asia & Pacific
Mean 4.9 6.5 7.7 7.9 8.6
St.Dev 1.8 2.2 2.4 2.2
Latin America & Caribbean
Mean 5.4 5.1 1.6 2.8
St.Dev 5.5 3.3 1.1
Middle East & North Africa
Mean 3.8 3.7 3.8
St.Dev 2.0 1.9 1.5 1.7
Sub-Saharan Africa
Mean 5.1 3.2 1.7 2.9
patterns of output volatilities in the long-term perspective. On the other hand, the results
for developing countries were rather mixed. With regards to this, many studies have
attempted to seek the possible explanatory factors (source) for the decline of real GDP
volatility mainly in developed countries. Cecchetti, Stephen et al. (2006) surveyed the
evidence and competing explanations and found support for the view in decline in the
degree of volatility in the post-World War II period due to a number of reasons, namely
1999, McConnell and Perez-Quiros, 2000, Kahn, McConnel and Perez-Quiros, 2002
and Kent, Christopher et al. 2005), (ii) better monetary policy (eg. inflation control)
(Clarida, Gali and Gertler, 2000, Blanchard and Simon, 2001, Martin and Rowthorn,
2004 and Kent, Christopher et al., 2005), (iii) financial innovation in risk sharing
(Dynan, Elmendorf and Sichel, 2006), (iv) increased international commercial openness
(Barrell and Gottschalk, 2004 and (v) luck in the form of smaller shocks (Stock and
Watson, 1988, 1999 and Ahmed and Wilson, 2004). The first four factors emphasized
the government’s role in reducing the adverse effects on the economy arising from
exogenous shocks. The fifth factor, however, may have led to a decline in the
179
magnitude of the shocks globally over this period, regardless of any effect from the first
four factors. Based on this hypothesis, Cecchetti et al. (2006) conducted output
volatility panel regression tests which showed that financial development, as measured
by the importance of bank lending, is linked to real economic stability. Beyond the
importance of financial development, this study provided evidence in favors of the view
that improved inventory control policies played an important role in bringing about
ratio of imports plus exports to GDP, does not appear to be associated with more stable
growth.
econometric analysis of India, where real GDP volatility has declined over the past two
decades. In their analysis of real GDP volatility, the following factors were regarded as
(change in CPI , gross fiscal deficit as a share of GDP(%)), external shocks (terms of
trade, percentage change), the structure of the economy (eg. share of agriculture in
GDP(%)), GDP growth rate in the past year and past experiences of real GDP volatility.
Their regression results show that the move away from agriculture has stabilized the
economy while increased financial depth and more favorable developments in terms of
share of Gross Value Added of each sector of GDP are not generally available.
Therefore, econometric tests based on only those variables for which data was available
180
4.2.3 The Effect of Economic Instability to Economic Growth
How economic instability affects economic growth has been an issue of research,
initiated by the work of Ramey, Garey and Ramey, Valerie A. (1994) who found that
countries with large fluctuations in growth rates were inclined to have lower average
growth rates. Many studies were conducted to identify the determinant variables relating
to this issue; their focus being particularly with the effect of export instability on
economic growth for both developed and developing nations. These studies found all
three possible kinds of relationships between export instability and economic growth,
Studies by McBean (1966) and Knudsen and Parnes (1975) found a positive
relationship between the two variables. Their study argues that uncertainty of export
earnings can lead to reduction in consumption and in turn, an increase in savings and
investments and thus economic growth. The conventional measure of export instability,
on the other hand, leads to an opposite conclusion that export instability has a negative
impact on economic growth (Glezakos, 1973, Voivodas, 1974, Moran, 1983, Feder,
1984, Lim David, 1974, 1976, Knudsen, 1975, Rangarajan and Sundararajan, 1976,
Ozler and Harrigan, 1988, Dawe, 1996, Sinha, 1999, Abraha, 2004, Dupasquier and
Patrick, 2006).
A study by Sinha (1999) examined the relationship between export instability and
investment and economic growth in nine Asian countries using time series data (around
1950-97). A negative relationship between export instability and economic growth was
found in the case of Japan, Malaysia, the Philippines and Sri Lanka while on the other
hand a positive relationship was found for South Korea, Myanmar, Pakistan and
Thailand. India, however, displayed mixed results. In the case of domestic investments,
economic growth in most cases was found to be positively associated with it.
181
The results from previous studies on export instability and economic growth rate are
very far from conclusive. However, what is clear is the tendency that export instability
is higher for developing countries than for developed countries (Mullor Sebastian, 1988).
The work by Love (1977, 1987 and 1992) is one of the few studies which examines the
causal relationship between export instability and income instability. His time series
analysis found that developing countries which rely on the export of primary goods,
which are subject to more fluctuations, experienced greater export instability than those
In the case of Singapore, Wilson (1994) investigates the export earnings instability
of Singapore for the years 1957-88 measured over two separate time periods: 1957-71
and 1972-88. He found that the pattern of the export instability index of the latter period
was even higher than that of first period. Nevertheless, no specific study on Singapore
has yet been made to cover the entire twentieth century. Therefore, this study attempts
to fill the gap in reviewing the long-term patterns of economic instability in a typically
Apart from “export instability”, other explanatory variables were also examined and
Westphal, Kim and Dahlman (1985) and Pack and Westphal (1986) examined the
relationship between for the annual growth rate of exports as a proportion of GDP and
the economic growth for Korea. Their study emphasizes that a high rate of growth of
it to compete world–wide and to produce products that are competitive in quality and
price. A growing export share provides the country with the foreign exchange to pay for
182
its imports particularly of capital goods that serve as an engine for further economic
growth.
particularly in the commodity producing colonies based on the experiences from 1870
to 1939 and assessed its impact on the economic performance of the sovereign
by Mendoza, Enrique (1994 and 1995) which included 40 industrial and developing
countries also showed that terms-of-trade volatility adversely affected economic growth.
Similar results were derived from the empirical test on developing countries (Bleaney,
from the poorest to the richest using data from the United Nations International
Comparison Project. This study found that countries with high equipment investment
grew extremely rapidly, even controlling for a number of other factors. This association
suggested a causal relationship: rapid growth went with high equipment investment, no
matter whether high investment was a consequence of high saving or of a low relative
statistically significant and robust cross-country partial correlation between the growth
183
4.2.3.5 Annual Growth Rate of Government Final Consumption Expenditure as a
Proportion of GDP
The annual growth rate of the ratio of real government final consumption
expenditure to real GDP was also tested as one of the possible determinant variables to
economic growth. Relating to this, Barro (1991) has argued that higher growth rate of
government final consumption spending lowers real GDP growth through the distorting
proposition.
Neoclassical growth theory states that the steady state growth rate of output equals
the sum of the growth rate of the labour force and the growth rate of exogenous
technological change. On the other hand, if a high population growth rate increases the
dependency ratio it will serve to retard economic growth (Simon, J.L, 1986). It could
also be argued that a cheap labour supply discourages automation and other productivity
enhancing measures.
Neoclassical growth theory predicts that in the transition to the steady state,
countries with lower capital-labour ratios and hence lower output per capita will grow at
a faster rate as a result of diminishing returns. Therefore, the lower the level of GDP per
explanatory variables for Malaya / Malaysia for the time periods 1895-1939 and 1947-
97. His regression results found that the coefficient of export instability for both periods
was negative and statistically significant while coefficient became smaller in the second
184
period. This implies that the problem of export instability becomes less as the structure
of the economy changed. Additionally, he pointed out that the role of government
with the reduced impact on economic growth. This study of Singapore also attempts to
Sachs and Warner (1995) identified Singapore as one of the most open economies in
the World. Nevertheless, “open economies” which refer to the degree of integration
with other countries, is different from the “dependence” on trade. Unlike other countries,
This standard way of presenting the account of net exports do not seem as crucial as
Demand = Supply
EX + C + G + I = GDP + IM
287+ 64 + 17 + 50 = 160 + 258
It can be seen that export demand is 4.5 times the amount of domestic private
consumption and 5.7 times the amount of investments. For the period 1992-2000, for
example, changes in the external demand (exports) accounted for over three-quarters of
the changes in real total demand, while changes in domestic demand only accounted for
185
A similar exercise was conducted for the twentieth century to examine whether
these relationships still held good. As is presented in Table 4.3, changes in external
demand (exports) accounted for 71.5% and 67.6% of the changes in real total demand
(1990 prices) for the pre-war and post-war periods respectively. In fact, throughout the
twentieth century, Singapore’s total demand was heavily determined by the changes in
external demand.
Table 4.3
Singapore: The Contribution of Domestic and External Demand to Growth in
Total Demand, 1900-2000 (1990 Prices)
Note: Figure was constructed based on the statistical database presented in Chapter 3. All variables are 1990 prices.
This is not surprising since Singapore’s share of external demand remain bigger than
its domestic demand. This situation is very different from that of other economies such
as Japan and USA where domestic demand is the prime mover in total demand. This
implies that any unforeseen shock in external demand may cause a serious impact to
to economic volatility as a result of two major factors. Firstly, there was the shift of
186
manufactured goods. Secondly, macroeconomic management which was dictated by the
(Huff, 1994). It is important to investigate whether these shifts have in any way affected
Table 4.4 shows percentage contributions of three major export commodities from
Singapore namely tin, rubber and petroleum as against total merchandize exports for the
1900-70. In the early twentieth century, tin accounted for the bulk of total merchandize
exports. This structure, however, experienced some major transitions after the
emergence of rubber in early 1910s and petroleum in the 1920s. By 1920, these three
major export commodities accounted for about 42% of total merchandize exports and
their share increased further to 69% in 1939. In the post World War II period, the
importance of tin dropped significantly. This is mainly because all major smelting work
in Singapore ceased when the Straits Trading Company transferred its operation to
Table 4.4
Singapore: Tin, Rubber and Petroleum Export Quantity Indices and Percentage
Contributions to Merchandize Exports, 1900-70
The changes in the export structure brought with it severe fluctuations in annual
export values, volume and percentage contribution to total merchandize exports of these
three major export commodities (See Figure 4.4). These rapid fluctuations were strongly
187
related to the change in the external demand for these commodities. The market price of
these commodities has experienced rapid fluctuations (See Figure 4.5). In particular,
rubber price experienced very large fluctuations throughout the period despite the
Figure 4.4
Singapore: Percentage Contributions of Tin, Rubber and Petroleum to
Merchandize Exports, 1900-70
60%
% to Merchandize Exports
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1940
1942
1944
1946
1948
1950
1952
1954
1956
1958
1960
1962
1964
1966
1968
1970
Ye ar
T in Rubber Petroleum
Figure 4.5
Singapore: Export Unit Value Indices (1914=100) of Rubber, Tin and Petroleum,
1900-70
1,200
600
400
200
-
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1940
1942
1944
1946
1948
1950
1952
1954
1956
1958
1960
1962
1964
1966
1968
1970
188
Table 4.5 shows the standard deviations of price and export volume of these three
major export commodities. In the case of tin, standard deviations of price were
relatively stable over time although export quantity had fallen significantly. In the case
of rubber, high standard deviations on price were recorded during the inter-war period.
On the other hand, export quantity of petroleum had experienced high standard
Table 4.5
Singapore: Standard Deviation of Prices and Export Volume of Rubber, Tin and
Petroleum, 1900-70
Tin Rubber Petroleum
Price Quantity Price Quantity Price Quantity
1900-1918 0.264 0.105 0.430 2.577 0.288 0.653
1919-1939 0.256 0.191 0.703 0.283 0.349 1.672
1950-1970 0.265 2.163 0.255 0.190 0.259 0.556
Source: Calculated based on Huff, W.G (1994)
With independence from the British in 1959, the ruling People’s Action Party (PAP)
ushered in the process of industrialization to diversify away from the “entrepôt base”
which inevitably placed constraints in the form of employment and more importantly
avoid high export earnings instability. For the period 1960-65, an import substitution
policy was initiated based on the expected integration with the Federation of Malaya.
Upon the inclusion of Singapore under the Federation of Malaysia in 1963, fiscal
concession was given to ‘pioneer’ industries for the establishment of a viable industrial
sector. However, when Singapore left the Federation of Malaysia in 1965, trade policies
were entirely changed from inward to outward orientation. Due to the limited size of the
domestic market and dearth of natural resources, the import substitution policy was no
longer valid for Singapore. The focus in trade policy therefore switched towards the
when the British government announced its intention to phase out its military bases in
the Republic by 1971, nearly one-fifth of Singapore’s GDP 84 was at stake. This
84
Lee Kuan Yew (2000: 49).
189
triggered the rapid development of export-oriented and labour-intensive industries. In
1968 the Economic Development Board, as part of the trade promotion exercise, was
reorganized and tax incentives were given to encourage export promotion and foreign
investment participation. The new strategy of export promotion combined with a lack of
priority.
The shift in the policy towards industrialization introduced in the 1960s initially
focused upon low-skill-intensive exports of textiles and garments and simple electrical
goods but moved towards capital-intensive petrol refining in the 1970s and to the
manufacture of more sophisticated electronic goods in the 1970s and 1980s. Although
petroleum refining and bunkering for ships and aircraft increased in importance in
1970s and 1980s, in value-added terms their contribution declined to 9.4 per cent by
2000. As presented in Table 4.6, a major expansion of domestic exports was observed
beginning in 1975. In other words, the importance of the entrepôt trade to the economy
measured by its contribution to GDP, seems to have hit a nadir in the mid-1970s
Table 4.6
Singapore: Dependence on Trade 1970 to 2000
Total Domestic Exports Entrepôt
Exports Total Oil Exports Domestic Exports Exports
less Oil Exports
Singapore $ (billions)
1970 82 32 19 13 50
1975 95 56 19 37 39
1980 171 107 59 48 64
1985 129 84 42 42 45
1990 141 93 26 67 48
1995 141 83 12 71 58
2000 149 85 14 71 64
Distribution (%)
1970 100.0 39.0 23.2 15.9 61.0
1975 100.0 58.9 20.0 38.9 41.1
1980 100.0 62.6 34.5 28.1 37.4
1985 100.0 65.1 32.6 32.6 34.9
1990 100.0 66.0 18.4 47.5 34.0
1995 100.0 58.9 8.5 50.4 41.1
2000 100.0 57.0 9.4 47.7 43.0
Source: Based on Wilson, Peter and Peebles, Gavin (2005)
190
In summary, it can be said that there was a significant shift of the trade structure,
This section firstly clarifies the definition of economic instability and investigates
representation of economic time series data consists of the trend component and a
characterized by a slow and smooth change over time. The cyclical component, on the
variables over relatively short periods of time. In the case of GDP, the study of
movements in the trend or secular component has been long viewed as falling within the
realm of growth theory. A cyclical fluctuation was a familiar topic of interest in the field
of business cycle theory. Theories of growth have been concerned with examining the
growth and technological change. Theories of business cycle, on the other hand, seek to
answer the question of why economies go through cycles of recession and recovery, or
boom and bust. Any theory of the business cycle makes two sorts of claims: what
shocks are most important in disturbing the economy and what economic structure is
In the case of economic instability, the attention was given to examine the
movements in the cyclical component of real GDP. Therefore, in this study, economic
191
instability is defined as the short-run fluctuations of real GDP after adjusting for trend.
It is measured by taking the absolute deviation of real GDP from its long-run trend.
1994, Nazrin, 2000, Singh and Fagernäs, 2006). In the final analysis, the choice of
time series was filtered by the Hodrick-Prescott method, which removes trend
movements from the data.85 The choice of this method is mainly because many previous
studies have applied it for empirical tests 86 (For example Backus and Patrick, 1992,
As is described in the literature review, one of the major questions in all historical
accounts of the evolution of the economic instability is whether the level of volatility
increases or decreases over time. One simple way to look at economic volatility is to
check the standard deviation of variables (Basu and Taylor, 1999). Figure 4.6 and Table
4.7 provides the degree of instability on log of real GDP and its components which was
step due to the fact that the result would be different depending on the selection of the
period. Alternatively, periodical frame for the pre-World War II was determined based
Michael D. and Jonung, Lars (1998) and Basu, Susanto and Taylor, Alan M (1999),
85
The Hodrick-Prescott filter, described by Hodrick, R and Prescott, E.C. (1980) and Kydland, F.E. and Prescott, E.C. (1982),
defines a trend {τt} for a series {yt} as the solution to the problem
T T −1
min
(τ i )
∑
t =1
( y t − τ ) 2
+ µ ∑
t = 2
[( τ t +1 − τ t ) − (τ t − τ t −1 )] 2
Fluctuations are defined as deviations from trend, yt - τt. We use µ=100 in all tables concerning fluctuations of variables. A
procedure for computing the trend was made based on Eview 4.1.
86
Bergman, U.Michael, Bordo, Michael D. and Jonung, Lars (1998) apply the Baxter-King (1995) band-pass filter to extract all
variations of a variable at business cycle frequencies. Love (1992) and Sinha (1999) define the measure of export instability as the
absolute value of the deviations of actual exports from a five-year moving average of exports. Singh and Fagernäs (2006) applied
the three-year moving average. Wilson (1994) selected the autocorrelation corrected exponential regression model.
192
namely Pre-World War I period (1900-13) and Inter-War Period (1914-39). For the
post World War II period (1950-2000), two sub-periods were set, namely 1950-74 and
1975-2000 based on the historical fact that Singapore’s economy had experienced a
transformation from entrepôt trade involving the export of primary commodities to one
Figure 4.6
Singapore: Trend GDP, Actual GDP and Percentage Deviation of GDP from
Trend, 1900-2000 (Trend obtained using HP filter)
14
12
10
Log of GDP
-
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1940
1942
1944
1946
1948
1950
1952
1954
1956
1958
1960
1962
1964
1966
1968
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
YEAR
ACTUAL TREND
5%
4%
3%
Deviations from Trend
2%
1%
0%
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1940
1942
1944
1946
1948
1950
1952
1954
1956
1958
1960
1962
1964
1966
1968
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
-1%
-2%
-3%
-4%
-5%
YEAR
Table 4.7
Singapore: A Comparison of the Standard Deviation of the GDP series
using Hodrick-Prescott Methods
Period Hodrick-Prescott
1900-1913 4.7
1914-1939 12.4
1950-1974 6.4
1975-2000 3.2
193
Based on these unit root test, now we examine the degree of volatility. From the
long-term perspective, the degree of real GDP instability for the period of inter-war
years (1914-39) was among the highest as compared with the other three periods.
During the pre-World War I period, the standard deviations of real GDP instability was
much smaller than that of the inter-war period and even slightly smaller than that of first
phase of post-war period (1950-74). The standard deviation of real GDP instability for
the last period (1975-2000) was among the lowest in the twentieth century. The small
standard deviation of real GDP for pre-World War I vis-à-vis that of inter-war period
observed for Singapore was consonant to that observed in other studies of industrialized
countries. Singapore’s standard deviation of pre-World War I period being even smaller
than post WWII periods, however, dissimilar to that observed in most of the
industrialized countries. One plausible reason for the low standard deviation prior to
World War I period for Singapore was the fact that role played by the export of primary
commodities such as rubber, which was in its infancy then, was not significant yet in
Subsequently, the extent of economic instability for GDP and its components,
consumption expenditure (Figure 4.8), gross capital formation (Figure 4.9), exports of
goods and services (Figure 4.10)87 and imports of goods and services (Figure 4.11) were
tested. Each of these variables was transformed to logarithms before filtering. Each
graphical presentation is divided into two panels. The upper panel plots the actual and
estimated trend values of the variable. The lower panel shows the percentage deviation
87
The time-series figures on imports and exports of goods and services for the period 1960-2000 were not provided in the official
statistical reports by the Department of Statistics, Singapore. However, the figures for both imports and exports of goods and
services in current prices (Singapore Dollars) were provided in the Penn-World Table Version 6.1. (Alan, Heston et al. 2002). The
figures on net exports on goods and services which are derived from Penn-World Table Version 6.1 were almost identical with
official time-series figures provided by Department of Statistics, Singapore. Based on this observation, the figures provided in Penn-
World Table Version 6.1 were deemed to be acceptable. Imports and exports of goods and services in 1990 prices were deflated by
implicit export and import unit value indices of goods and services (1990=100). These derived net exports of goods and services
figures in 1990 prices for the period 1960-2000 were, however, different from that given in official publications. In this exercise, we
aimed to identify the trend and deviations from trend. Therefore, this derived figure was then utilized for conducting this specific
analysis.
194
of the cyclical component of the variable from its long run trend. For comparison, the
percentage deviation of the cyclical component of GDP from its long run trend is also
plotted in the lower panel of each diagram. The lower panel of each diagram shows that
the degree of economic instability of each component of GDP was different from that of
GDP. Generally, the degree of instability of PFCE was similar and its range was smaller
than that of GDP. On the other hand, the degree of instability for GFCE and GCF were
relatively larger than that of GDP. It is important to note here that deviations of GFCE
from the HP filtered trend somewhat moved in the opposite direction to that of GDP
during the world depression period (1930-32) and the short-term economic recession
period (1985-86). The degree of instability for GCF, EXGS and IMGS, however,
showed similar direction to that of GDP. Generally, the degree of instability was similar
to that of GDP. During periods of economic boom and recession, however, the degree
Figure 4.7
Singapore: Private Final Consumption Expenditure, Trend, Actual and
Percentage Deviation from Trend, 1900-2000 (1990 Prices)
12
Log Private Final Consumption Expenditure
10
-
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1940
1942
1944
1946
1948
1950
1952
1954
1956
1958
1960
1962
1964
1966
1968
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
YEAR
ACTUAL TREND
5%
4%
3%
Deviations from Trend
2%
1%
0%
1900
1902
1904
1906
1908
1910
1912
1914
1916
1918
1920
1922
1924
1926
1928
1930
1932
1934
1936
1938
1940
1942
1944
1946
1948
1950
1952
1954
1956
1958
1960
1962
1964
1966
1968
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
-1%
-2%
-3%
-4%
-5%
YEAR
PFCE GDP
195
Log Gross Capital Formation Deviations from Trend Log Government Final Consumption Expenditure
-
Deviations from Trend
2
4
6
8
10
12
2
4
6
8
10
12
-10%
-8%
-6%
-4%
-2%
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
12%
14%
-8%
-6%
-4%
-2%
0%
2%
4%
6%
1900
1900 1902 1900
1900
1902 1904 1902
1902
1904 1906 1904
1904
1906 1908 1906
1906
1908 1910 1908 1908
1910 1912 1910 1910
1912 1914 1912
1912
1914 1916 1914 1914
1916 1918 1916 1916
1918 1920 1918 1918
1920 1922 1920 1920
1922 1924 1922 1922
1924 1926 1924 1924
1926 1928 1926 1926
1928 1930 1928 1928
1930 1932 1930 1930
1932 1934 1932 1932
1934 1936 1934 1934
GCF
ACTUAL
1948 1948 1948
1950
1950
ACTUAL
1950
GFCE
YEAR
1952 1950
YEAR
YEAR
1952 1952
YEAR
1954 1952
1954
Figure 4.9
Figure 4.8
1954 1954
1956
GDP
1956 1956 1956
1958
TREND
1958
GDP
1958 1958
1960 1960
TREND
1960 1960
1962 1962 1962
1964 1962
1964 1964 1964
1966 1966 1966
1968 1966
1968 1968 1968
1970 1970 1970
1970
1972 1972 1972
1972
1974 1974 1974
1974
1976 1976 1976
1976
1978 1978 1978
1978
1980 1980 1980
1980
1982 1982 1982 1982
1984 1984 1984 1984
1986 1986
Singapore: Gross Capital Formation, Trend, Actual and
1986 1986
Percentage Deviation from Trend, 1900-2000 (1990 Prices)
Percentage Deviation from Trend, 1900-2000 (1990 Prices)
2000 2000
196
Deviations from Trend Log Imports of Goods and Services Deviations from Trend Log Exports of Goods and Services
-
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
-6%
-4%
-2%
0%
2%
4%
6%
-6%
-4%
-2%
0%
2%
4%
6%
1900 1900 1900 1900
1902 1902 1902 1902
1904 1904 1904 1904
1906 1906 1906 1906
1908 1908 1908 1908
1910 1910 1910 1910
1912 1912 1912 1912
1914 1914 1914 1914
1916 1916 1916 1916
1918 1918 1918 1918
1920 1920 1920 1920
1922 1922 1922 1922
1924 1924 1924 1924
1926 1926 1926 1926
1928 1928 1928 1928
1930 1930 1930 1930
1932 1932 1932 1932
1934 1934 1934 1934
1936
IMGS
1948 1948 1948 1948
ACTUAL
EXGS
ACTUAL
1950 1950 1950 1950
YEAR
YEAR
YEAR
YEAR
1952 1952 1952 1952
1954 1954 1954 1954
GDP
1956 1956
Figure 4.11
Figure 4.10
1956 1956
GDP
1958 1958 1958 1958
TREND
TREND
1960 1960 1960 1960
1962 1962 1962 1962
1964 1964 1964 1964
1966 1966 1966 1966
1968 1968 1968 1968
1970 1970 1970 1970
1972 1972 1972 1972
1974 1974 1974 1974
1976 1976 1976 1976
1978 1978 1978 1978
1980 1980 1980 1980
1982 1982 1982 1982
1984 1984 1984 1984
1986 1986 1986 1986
1988 1988 1988 1988
Percentage Deviation from Trend, 1900-2000 (1990 Prices)
Percentage Deviation from Trend, 1900-2000 (1990 Prices)
197
Table 4.8 shows the instability indicators of each component of GDP which is
derived from the standard deviation of the cyclical fluctuations from trend. As is
mentioned above, one of the objectives of this study is to compare the degree of
economic instability between the pre-World War II and post-World War II periods. The
following observations can be made. The highest instability for all components of GDP
was recorded during the inter-war period, while the petroleum swung the other way with
the lowest degree of instability being observed during the last quarter of the twentieth
century (1975-2000) for GDP, GFCE and GCF. On the other hand, the degree of
instability for PFCE, EXGS and IMGS was recorded at its lowest in the pre-World War
I period. Another important observation was that GDP and its components experienced
an increase in the economic instability during the inter-war period (1914-39) compared
to the pre-World War I period (1900-13). Subsequently, the degree of instability has
constantly dampened in the third quarter (1950-74) and fourth quarter (1975-2000) of
Table 4.8
Singapore: Instability Indicators of GDP and the Aggregate Demand Components,
1900-2000 at 1990 prices and Relative Instability Indicators of the Each
Component of GDP (1914-39=100)
198
Table 4.9 shows instability indicators of each component of GDP in relation to that
of GDP. It was found that the relative instability indicator of private final consumption
spending was less volatile than GDP before the war, but surprisingly more volatile than
GDP for the period 1975-2000. The other components of GDP experienced greater
instability in the British colonial period. Among these, gross domestic capital formation
showed the highest volatility. Throughout the period, the relative instability indicator of
gross capital formation to GDP was generally three times higher. There was a reduction
Table 4.9
Singapore: Relative Instability Indicators of the Aggregate Demand Components,
1900-2000 (1990 Prices)
Period GDP Private Final Government Gross Capital Exports of Imports of
Consumption Final Formation Goods and Goods and
Expenditure Consumption Services Services
Expenditure
In addition to the two above observations, Table 4.10 provides the results of cross
correlations between volatilities of each component of GDP and GDP itself for selected
time periods. PFCE and GDP showed relatively strong (0.70) and positive cross
correlations for the all period. A similar phenomenon was observed between GCF and
GDP save for the period 1900-13. In the case of GFCE, cross-correlations of volatility
have been weak and negative throughout the period, with the exception for the period
1950-74 which recorded a positive relationship (0.60). On the other hands, cross-
correlations of volatilities between net exports and GDP were somewhat different. Prior
to World War II, correlations for this component were positive but during the later half
199
of twentieth century, a reverse situation was observed with these correlation values
Table 4.10
Singapore: Cross-Correlations between Volatilities of Each Component of GDP
and GDP, 1900-2000 (1990 Prices)
Note:
Volatility of Net exports of goods and services were measured without converting to natural logarithm term due to the fact that
original net exports of goods and services were minus (-) for most of the twentieth century.
As seen earlier, Singapore has experienced a decline of real GDP volatility over
time. This section is devoted to empirically investigate what economic variables caused
the decline of real GDP volatilities. In this exercise, five types of hypothesis were
experimented based on the empirical exercise made by Singh and Fagernäs (2006).
Firstly, it has been argued that improvement of government’s ability help to reduce the
volatility of output due to the greater knowledge of the economy by policy makers and
their ability to anticipate how to cope with economic shocks. Government budget deficit
as a share of GDP are used to reflect the government’s policy choices. Secondly, it is
often argued somewhat counter-intuitively, that trade openness should not lead to
greater but to lower volatility. Thirdly, the role of shocks such as changes in terms of
trade with respect to output volatility will also be considered. Fourthly, the real GDP
growth rate in the previous year may itself affect volatility of the current year. It is
significant to see how GDP growth rate is associated with real GDP volatility. Fifthly,
200
past experiences of volatility itself has caused volatility in the subsequent period. Based
on these premises, the following independent variables (Figure 4.12) have been selected
Figure 4.12
Explanatory Variables for Regression
GDP%(-1) Percentage growth of Real GDP with one year time lag
The volatility of real GDP growth over the period was measured using the standard
deviation. However, for the purposes of econometric time series analysis, an annual
measure is required (Singh and Fagernäs, 2006:17). The precise volatility measure used
in this regression test is based on the recursive estimation used in the following equation.
yt = α + β1yt-1 +β2yt-2 + γ t + εt
Time-series data on Terms of Trade was derived by utilizing export and import unit
root test to examine whether dependent and explanatory variables are trend stationary or
difference stationary. As is applied above, two types of Unit Root Tests, namely ADF
and PP tests were conducted for the period 1900-39 and 1950-2000, respectively. The
results (Table 4.11 [A]-[E]) show that the time series of [A] growth rate of real GDP,
[B] volatility of GDP, [C] share of Government deficit to GDP (1900-39), [D] share of
trade to GDP and [E] annual percentage change of terms of trade are all integrated of
201
order zero, I (0), therefore, regarded as trend stationary. [C] share of government deficit
to GDP (%) for the period 1950-2000 (ADF test) are, however, integrated of order one,
I (1) since only its first difference and second difference are stationary. This means that
the null hypothesis of a unit root test cannot be rejected. Nevertheless, the PP test
showed integrated of order zero, I (0). As is discussed above, the result of PP test should
be given priority over the results from the ADF test. The time series regression will then
Table 4.11
Results of Unit Root Tests (1990 Prices)
[A] Results of Unit Root Tests on Growth of Gross Domestic Product (%)
Period Levels trend lags1 First Difference trend lags1 Second Difference trend lags1 Order
1900-1939 -6.731829*** Yes 0 -11.01591*** Yes 0 -4.990693*** Yes 6 I(0)
ADF
1950-2000 -6.236542*** Yes 0 -12.07564*** Yes 0 -5.776294*** Yes 5 I(0)
Period Levels trend 2 First Difference trend 2 Second Difference trend 2 Order
Bandwidth Bandwidth Bandwidth
1900-1939 -7.637953*** Yes 9 -30.44674*** Yes 20 -43.66058*** Yes 13 I(0)
PP
1950-2000 -6.223109*** Yes 3 -14.62394*** Yes 5 -27.74062*** Yes 7 I(0)
[B] Results of Unit Root Tests on Volatility of Real GDP growth (%)
Period Levels trend lags1 First Difference trend lags1 Second Difference trend lags1 Order
Period Levels trend Bandwidth2 First Difference trend Bandwidth2 Second Difference trend Bandwidth2 Order
Period Levels trend 2 First Difference trend 2 Second Difference trend 2 Order
Bandwidth Bandwidth Bandwidth
1900-1939 -5.573827*** Yes 3 -32.00959*** Yes 37 -59.46962*** Yes 33 I(0)
PP
1950-2000 -3.446567* Yes 3 -13.2647*** Yes 2 -21.67567*** Yes 0 I(0)
[D] Results of Unit Root Tests on Share of Trade to GDP
Period Levels trend lags1 First Difference trend lags1 Second Difference trend lags1 Order
1900-1939 -6.213849*** Yes 0 -7.860096*** Yes 1 -8.80479*** Yes 2 I(0)
ADF
1950-2000 -7.990837*** Yes 0 -9.750357*** Yes 1 -13.38367*** Yes 1 I(0)
Period Levels trend 2 First Difference trend 2 Second Difference trend 2 Order
Bandwidth Bandwidth Bandwidth
1900-1939 -6.406631*** Yes 5 -33.03873*** Yes 35 -47.65318*** Yes 35 I(0)
PP
1950-2000 -7.990837*** Yes 0 -20.17221*** Yes 6 -24.87343*** Yes 3 I(0)
[E] Results of Unit Root Tests on Terms of Trade (TOT)
Period Levels trend lags1 First Difference trend lags1 Second Difference trend lags1 Order
1900-1939 -9.095181*** Yes 0 -8.51861*** Yes 1 -5.678672*** Yes 4 I(0)
ADF
1950-2000 -7.101295*** Yes 0 -10.73563*** Yes 1 -5.969188*** Yes 7 I(0)
Period Levels trend Bandwidth2 First Difference trend Bandwidth2 Second Difference trend Bandwidth2 Order
1900-1939 -10.97895*** Yes 6 -52.44527*** Yes 28 -28.0582*** Yes 3 I(0)
PP
1950-2000 -7.253854*** Yes 5 -27.05399*** Yes 32 -32.20052*** Yes 41 I(0)
Notes:
1. Automatic selection of lag were determined by Schwartz Info Criterion
2. Bandwidth was determined based on the Newey-West using Bartlett kernel
(***,** ,*) denotes significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively.
I(0) = stationary, I(1) = unit root
202
4.4.1.2 Regression Results
The selection of the period for this regression analysis was made based on the
historical experience that Singapore has undergone in terms of two types of different
government and self-government after the independence (1965). Due to the dearth of
time-series data of 1940s, it was not possible to set the two different periods.
Alternatively, three different periods of 1900-39, 1950-2000 and 1965-2000 were tested
for regression analysis. The first two periods were selected to see whether there were
any significant similarities or differences. The selection of the third period (1965-2000)
was, however, set to see whether there were any similar features as compared with
previous period.
Table 4.12 shows the results of the regression analysis for the three specific periods,
with volatility of real GDP being used as dependent variable. From these regression
results, one feature was identified in Singapore’s economy. Contrary to findings made
in studies for other countries, the coefficient of explanatory variables such as the share
of government budget deficit to GDP, percentage changes of terms of trade and share of
trade (exports and imports of goods and services) to GDP are not consistent by period
and statistically not significant for all the periods. For the years 1965-2000, the
coefficient of previous year’s volatility of real GDP growth and one year lagged real
negligible. In short, these regression results reveal that there are no plausible
explanatory variables which can statistically explain the sources of output growth
volatility in Singapore for both during the British colonial period as well as in the period
of self-government.
203
Table 4.12
Singapore: Source of Real GDP Volatility by Specific Periods
Dependent Variable= Real GDP Volatility
1900-1939 1950-2000 1965-2000
Explanatory Variables
[1] [2] [5]
CONSTANT -0.08 4.63 12.16
(-0.03) (1.43) (2.49)**
VOL(-1) -0.06 0.58 1.86
(-0.13) (1.26) (3.07)***
GDP%(-1) 0.08 -0.61 -1.41
(0.19) (-1.41) (-2.37)**
SBY(-1) -0.23 -0.04 0.16
(-0.57) (-0.29) (1.64)
TOT(-1) -0.47 -0.12 0.10
(-0.68) (-0.18) (0.15)
TRADE/GDP(-1) 0.70 0.36 -0.65
(0.41) (0.24) (-0.35)
Regression tests were run with the growth rate of real GDP per capita as the
dependent variable. The primary interest of this regression exercise was to study the
effect of export instability on economic growth. In line with the works of Kormendi and
Meguire (1985), Dawe (1993) and Nazrin (2000), other plausible explanatory variables
were also included in the effect to improve the specification of the model and increase
the explanatory power of the regression (See Figure 4.13). The final choice of
of data availability. Generally, the explanatory variables selected were very similar to
that as used in the study by Nazrin (2000). Data for the 1900-39 and 1950-59 periods
represent my own estimates, whereas those for the more recent years were obtained
204
from official publication releases entitled System of National Account 1995 Singapore
Figure 4.13
Explanatory Variables for Regression
Dependent Variable: Real Per-capita GDP growth (%)
Independent Variables
MACHIN Change in share of Investment on Machinery and Equipment to
GDP
CONSTRUC Change in share of Investment on Construction to GDP
POP Population Growth (%)
GDPC GDP Per-capita
EXIN Export Instability Indicator
GREXSHAR Growth rate of exports as a proportion of GDP
GCSHAR Growth rate of Government Final Consumption Expenditure as a
proportion of GDP
tests (Augmented Dickey Fuller test and Phillips-Perron test) have been applied for both
dependent and independent variables (See Table 4.13). ADF and PP unit root test results
showed that the time-series appear to be stationary in their levels for (A) Real Per-capita
GDP growth, (C) CONSTRUC, (F) EXIN, (G) GREXSHAR and (H) GCSHAR i.e.,
they are all integrated of order zero, I (0). On the other hand, unit root test on MACHIN
POP, and GDPC were stationary in first differences rather than in levels. Therefore,
MACHIN, POP and GDPC are difference stationary and integrated of order one. The
time series regression should include only stationary variables. Therefore, alternatively,
first difference of MACHIN, POP and GDPC are applied for the regression.
205
Table 4.13
Results of Unit Root Tests (1990 Prices)
[A] Results of Unit Root Tests on Real Per-capita GDP growth (%)
Period Levels trend lags1 First Difference trend lags1 Second Difference trend lags1 Order
1900-1939 -7.537025*** Yes 0 -6.975864*** Yes 2 -5.148174*** Yes 7 I(0)
ADF
1950-2000 -7.727637*** Yes 0 -5.015317*** Yes 2 -6.112558*** Yes 5 I(0)
Period Levels trend 2 First Difference trend 2 Second Difference trend 2 Order
Bandwidth Bandwidth Bandwidth
1900-1939 -18.62838*** Yes 37 -31.28876*** Yes 15 -40.69998*** Yes 12 I(0)
PP
1950-2000 -7.68677*** Yes 4 -15.80769*** Yes 1 -23.3652*** Yes 1 I(0)
Period Levels trend Bandwidth2 First Difference trend Bandwidth2 Second Difference trend Bandwidth2 Order
1900-1939 -3.127443 Yes 2 -7.42359*** Yes 12 -23.10612*** Yes 10 I(1)
PP
1950-2000 -1.729622 Yes 3 -6.61815*** Yes 3 -20.33456*** Yes 7 I(1)
Period Levels trend Bandwidth2 First Difference trend Bandwidth2 Second Difference trend Bandwidth2 Order
1900-1939 -3.206648* Yes 4 -8.097467*** Yes 3 -26.10839*** Yes 14 I(0)
PP
1950-2000 -2.642867 Yes 0 -5.994391*** Yes 6 -23.48653*** Yes 12 I(1)
Period Levels trend Bandwidth2 First Difference trend Bandwidth2 Second Difference trend Bandwidth2 Order
1900-1939 -3.07816 Yes 3 -4.985655*** Yes 3 -8.249593*** Yes 4 I(1)
PP
1950-2000 -2.794071 Yes 0 -8.699432*** Yes 6 -20.42238*** Yes 11 I(1)
Period Levels trend 2 First Difference trend 2 Second Difference trend 2 Order
Bandwidth Bandwidth Bandwidth
1900-1939 -3.167221 Yes 5 -20.17437*** Yes 2 -30.77797*** Yes 14 I(1)
PP
1950-2000 -0.374226 Yes 11 -7.490135*** Yes 9 -16.75087*** Yes 18 I(1)
Period Levels trend Bandwidth2 First Difference trend Bandwidth2 Second Difference trend Bandwidth2 Order
1900-1939 -4.029493*** Yes 1 -8.550944*** Yes 36 -23.75345*** Yes 6 I(0)
PP
1950-2000 -4.27237*** Yes 3 -10.40277*** Yes 47 -21.30501*** Yes 9 I(0)
Period Levels trend Bandwidth2 First Difference trend Bandwidth2 Second Difference trend Bandwidth2 Order
1900-1939 -5.987733*** Yes 2 -35.99585*** Yes 36 -64.53198*** Yes 35 I(0)
PP
1950-2000 -7.27847*** Yes 2 -45.85592*** Yes 47 -24.87374*** Yes 11 I(0)
206
[H] Results of Unit Root Tests on GCSHAR
Period Levels trend lags1 First Difference trend lags1 Second Difference trend lags1 Order
1900-1939 -6.148656*** Yes 0 -6.949908*** Yes 1 -6.953464*** Yes 2 I(0)
ADF
1950-2000 -7.364163*** Yes 0 -8.393242*** Yes 1 -6.99744*** Yes 3 I(0)
Period Levels trend Bandwidth2 First Difference trend Bandwidth2 Second Difference trend Bandwidth2 Order
1900-1939 -6.148953*** Yes 2 -37.27765*** Yes 36 -66.66384*** Yes 35 I(0)
PP
1950-2000 -7.398835*** Yes 3 -47.19874*** Yes 47 -28.69676*** Yes 14 I(0)
Notes:
1 Automatic selection of lag based on the Schwartz Info Criterion
2 Bandwidth was determined based on the Newey-West using Bartlett kernel
(***,** ,*) denotes significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively.
I(0) = stationary, I(1) = unit root
The estimating time span was from 1900 to 2000 covering three periods, namely
1900-39, 1950-2000 and 1975-2000. The first two periods were identified to see the
overall picture of the pre-World War II period vis-à-vis the post-World War II era.
Additionally, one specific period of 1975-2000 was studied to empirically test the effect
of changes in the export structure shifting from the dominance of entrepôt based
primary commodity export to the export of domestic manufactured goods since the
middle of 1970s. In this exercise, the export instability index measured by one-year
The results of regression tests are presented in Table 4.14. Importantly, the
coefficient of export instability of first-year lag was negative and statistically significant
at the 5 per cent level for the period 1900-39 and 10 per cent level for the periods 1950-
2000 and 1975-2000. The coefficient of export instability for the period 1900-39 was -
37.81. This negative coefficient figure, however, reduced slightly to the level of -28.16
for the period 1950-2000. It is crucial to note here that negative coefficient on export
instability for the period 1975-2000 has even scaled down to –10.07. The result of this
econometric regression test has clearly found the phenomenon that the effect of export
88
Several time lags were attempted for regression test such as 2-3 years time lags and combinations of one and two year lags.
However, all regression results were insignificant. Additionally, the explanatory variables of D(MACHIN), D(POP) and
D(GDPC)(-1) were omitted in this regression analysis on the ground that inclusion of these variable would lead to weak F-statistics
results and apart from serial-correlation.
207
instability to real per-capita GDP growth became smaller once Singapore trade structure
The rate of growth in the export ratio to GDP shows a small negative coefficient of
(-0.001) for the period 1900-39 but not significant. Subsequently, for the period 1950-
2000, the coefficient of this variable turned positive (0.001) but was statistically not
significant. For the period 1975-2000, the coefficient has slightly increased up to the
level of 0.004 and is statistically significant for this period at the 1% level. This
regression result shows that a high rate of growth of exports was not an important
Table 4.14
Singapore: Regression Results with the Rate of Growth of Real GDP Per Capita
as the Dependent Variable, 1900-39,1950-2000, and 1975-2000
Estimation Period
Explanatory Variables 1900-1939 1950-2000 1975-2000
[1] [2] [4]
CONSTANT 7.92 4.50 5.92
(1.31) (4.87)*** (14.12)***
CONSTRUC -0.35
(-1.00)
EXIN (-1) -37.81 -28.16 -10.07
(-1.89)* (-2.30)** (-2.03)**
GREXSHAR -0.001 0.001 0.004
(-0.57) (1.56) (4.65)***
GCSHAR 0.0001 0.001 0.007
(0.54) (1.27) (4.30)***
208
In the case of coefficient of change with respect to the share of Government Final
statistically not significant, was recorded for the period 1900-39. During the entire post-
World War II period in the 20th century, the coefficient became slightly higher, that is to
0.001 for the period 1950-2000. For the period 1975-2000, the coefficient in fact
increased from 0.001 to 0.007 and was statistically significant at 1% level. It goes
without saying that the coefficient of this explanatory variable was very small and even
negligible. This regression result implies that the high growth rate of Government Final
Consumption Expenditure did not have any significant impact on the real per-capita
GDP growth. This results differed from that obtained by a study by Barro (1991).
Based on the above results, it may be possible to draw several observations on the
century as follows.
Firstly, the regression results show that export instability negatively impacted on the
economic growth for both periods. Nevertheless, the negative coefficient value for the
export instability became remarkably small for the Post World War II period due to the
Other than export instability, remarkable changes were identified between pre
World War II and the period thereafter. In the case of 1975-2000, the coefficient of
proportion of GDP were positive and statistically significant though the coefficients
209
4.5 International Comparison
related econometric tests, this study found some unique features of Singapore’s
Firstly, the extent of real GDP volatilities observed for Singapore was similar to that
among the highest during the twentieth century. Nevertheless, the extent of economic
instability of real GDP during the pre-World War I period was much smaller than that
of the inter-war period and even slightly smaller than that of first phase of post-war
period (1950-74). This picture was somewhat dissimilar to that observed in most of the
industrialized countries. One plausible reason for the low standard deviation prior to
World War I period for Singapore was the fact that the role played by the export of
primary commodities such as rubber, which was in its infancy then, was not significant
On the contrary, output volatilities of other developing countries such as the Latin
American countries during the post 1960 period have increased and the economic
growth rates were rather unimpressive. On the other hand, there has been little change in
Africa.
The similarities with industrialized nations can be explained by the fact that
countries which were the major destinations of Singapore’s major export commodities
such as rubber, tin and petroleum. With respect to the relative economic instability
indicators of each component to GDP, the phenomenon observed for PFCE, GFCE and
89
The study of Backus and Kehoe (1992) did not provide the standard deviations of volatilities of export and imports of goods and
services relative to real GDP. Instead, standard deviations of volatilities of net exports of goods and services relative to real GDP
were presented. However, my study could not obtain the volatility indicator due to the problem of deriving figures in natural
logarithm term.
210
In terms of cross-correlations between volatilities of each component of GDP and
GDP in Singapore, PFCE and GCF recorded relatively constant and high cross-
real GDP, however, exhibit some irregularity. In the case of Singapore, exclusive of
first phase of post-WWII period, cross-correlation was negative and weak. In the case of
net exports, in two-thirds of the cases the cross-correlations were negative and often
strongly so. In Singapore, cross-correlations of net exports during the pre-WWII period
were somewhat positive but turned to negative in the latter half of the twentieth century.
Singapore’s figures remain high throughout the twentieth century while many
Fagernäs (2006) show that output volatility is persistent as it depends positively and
budget deficit are statistically not significant. In the case of Singapore, a similar
growth applied a similar econometric exercise as used by Nazrin (2000) for Malaya /
Malaysia. Regression results of both Malaya and Singapore showed negative effects of
export instability towards economic growth. This result is not surprising in the sense
that both economies were strongly reliant on the exports of primary commodities in the
early half of the century. In line with the diversification of the economic structure, the
negative coefficient values have declined for both Singapore and Malaya/Malaysia.
211
4.6 Concluding Remarks
This chapter examines the extent, causes and consequences of economic instability
in Singapore during the twentieth century. Not unlike industrialized nations, the degree
of economic instability experienced by Singapore has dampened in the post World War
II period as compared with that of the pre World War II years. Most notably, highest
real GDP instability was recorded during the inter-war period though other periods also
recorded a certain degree of real GDP volatility. Among GDP components, a relative
volatile than that of GDP. On the other hand, the relative instability indicator of gross
capital formation to GDP was almost three times. When we look at the relative
instability indicator of each component, PFCE, GFCE and GCF showed significant
reduction of instability particularly during the last quarter of the twentieth century.
Nevertheless, the degree of instability of exports and imports of goods and services did
not change overtime. In fact, instability of trade export earnings has the most significant
impact on real GDP growth. The instability of the export sector has, in turn, been
influenced by the extreme volatility of export commodities during the British colonial
era. Nevertheless, diversification of trade in Singapore was initiated during the period of
self-government since the mid-1970s. This study attempts to undertake two kinds of
empirical tests, namely sources of output volatility and the effect of export instability on
economic growth. The following features were observed from this empirical exercise.
Firstly, contrary to findings made in other studies, the major sources of output
deficit to GDP, changes in trade as a share of GDP (%) and changes in terms of trade
with one year time lag were not statistically significant. Secondly, export instability was
seen to reduce economic growth for both periods. The coefficient of export instability
has reduced over time. Importantly, the negative coefficient on export instability for the
212
period 1975-2000 has even scaled down significantly. The result of this econometric
regression test has clearly found the phenomenon that the effect of export instability to
real per-capita GDP growth became smaller once Singapore’s trade structure
213
CHAPTER FIVE
5.1 Introduction
Chapter Four earlier examined the relationship between economic instability and
economic growth of Singapore in the twentieth century based on the fact that her
shocks.
remained small during the twentieth century.90 The average share of real total general
government expenditure to GDP (1990 prices) in Singapore for the period 1900-39 and
1950-2000 was 17.0% and 18.0% respectively while that of industrialized nations
finance structure and empirically investigate the relationship between government fiscal
behavior and economic growth in Singapore in the twentieth century. This research is
growth in Singapore might have experienced a significant shift due to the administrative
changes brought about in the process of transition from British colonial rule to one of
self-government.
In Chapter Four, two types of econometric tests were conducted relating to the issues
government fiscal behavior was selected as one of the explanatory variables. Firstly, the
90
This study does not include 1940-49 due to the absence of historical GDP estimates.
214
share of government budget surplus to GDP was tested as to whether this was a possible
source of real output volatility. Secondly, the effect of annual growth rate of government
growth was tested to examine whether a higher growth rate of GFCE lowers real GDP
growth through the distorting effects resulting from taxation or government expenditure
programs. The results of both empirical tests, however, were statistically not significant
for the British colonial period as well as the period of self government.
This chapter will investigate in depth the relationship between government fiscal
behaviors and economic growth in Singapore. Firstly, this chapter attempts to identify
the characteristics of colonial government fiscal behavior as against that during the
allocation and budget deficit/surplus management. Secondly, this study aims to conduct
empirical econometric tests using time-series data stretching over the better part of the
twentieth century. The validity of Wagner’s Law was tested to establish whether
similarities or differences that existed between the period of British colonial rule and the
assessed using the unit root tests. Secondly, the hypothesis of a long-run relationship
between government expenditure and real GDP is tested using Johansen maximum
likelihood technique. Thirdly, the Granger causality test is utilized to examine the short-
run direction of causality between GDP and government expenditure in the context of
Wagner’s Law.
The structure of this essay is arranged as follows. Section 5.2 outlines the literature
215
review on [i] the characteristics of colonial government finance behavior and [ii]
similarities or differences between the colonial period and the period of self-government.
In Section 5.4, the framework and the methodologies for econometric tests are
described in general. The econometric results and analyses are presented in Section 5.5.
changes in attitudes towards the role of the state in the economy. The study by Tanzi and
economy in industrialized countries during the twentieth century and found that growth
institutional differences. Tanzi and Schuknecht (2000) pointed out that the role of the
state in the economy has experienced four major transitions in the twentieth century,
namely (1) the period up to World War I, (2) the interwar period, (3) the period until
Initially, the laissez-faire attitude occupied a position of predominance while the role
of government in economic life was minimal. In fact, the onset of the World War I
expenses. Subsequently, the Great Depressions in late 1920s and early 1930s
216
experienced world-wide was regarded as a monumental failure of the market economy
and this had led to the expansion of government involvement in the nation’s economy.
The most notable expansion of government involvement in the economy was recorded
for the years 1960 and 1980. As is presented in Table 5.1, the percentage share of real
general government expenditure to real GDP for selected years generally showed rapid
growth for the period 1960-80 and remained relatively stable. In 1980s, skepticism
about the proper role of state in allocation of resources, stabilization and income
distribution emerged (Buchanan, 1975, Premchand, 1983). Some critics also started to
question the practical implementation of these policies. As deficits and public debt rose,
many economists argued that government had grown much beyond its justified role,
Table 5.1
Percentage Share of Real General Government Expenditure to Real GDP for
Selected Years, 1870-1996 (1990 prices)
The 1990s have seen much interest in budgetary institutions and in fiscal rules to
prioritize and improve the efficiency of public spending and to make government live
within its means. Many countries, and especially the industrial countries, have
217
introduced important reforms that have helped to make fiscal policy sounder.
Government began to focus on public spending on essential tasks and provide basic
services in the most cost-effective ways. Unlike the previous period, these approaches
are in fact aimed at reducing the size of public spending. Nevertheless, as presented in
Table 5.1, few countries managed to reduce the government expenditure share to GDP.
This implies that reduction of government expenditure is not an easy task as compared
Unlike statements of Tanzi and Schuknecht (2000), the share of real general
government expenditure to real GDP in Singapore remained small and stable over time
major difference between Singapore and other industrialized countries was the fact that
Singapore was formerly governed by the British colonial authority. In fact, the
established and implemented by the colonial authority. The small share of government
expenditure to GDP should also be treated as one of the features of the colonial
government’s fiscal behavior in Singapore. While the characteristic of the small share of
During the period of self-government the budgetary process and actual implementation
of government fiscal behavior was determined in line with its owns needs as opposed to
the interest of the colonial government which paid more attentions to the benefits of
home country (Britain). One may be interested to know whether there are any common
features in the government fiscal behavior during the two periods, that is the British
In the following sections, this study would like to highlight the two key terms which
218
balanced budget structure (5.2.1.2)” and “weakness of colonial government
One of the characteristics of fiscal principle of the colony was to self-support and
have a balanced budget, i.e. “living within means”, such that there was no need for the
exchequer of the home country to subsidize the Colony (Tan, Shu-hung, 1997). There
are many criteria in assessing whether the budgetary performance achieved the
objectives of this fiscal philosophy. The most important one is the actual surplus/deficit
Huff (2003b) has compiled the balance of government finance in Burma, Indochina,
Thailand, British Malaya, Indonesia and Philippines and elaborated that the colonial
near zero.
In the case of Hong Kong, for example, the philosophy and management of fiscal
system was governed by the financial procedures stipulated in the colonial regulations.
These financial procedures controlled the scope and scale of public expenditure and the
Sugimoto (1997 and 2007a) examined the British colonial financial administration in
the state of Johore for the period 1910-40. This study established that during the thirty-
year period of British colonial administration, the central concern was the creation and
investments in the British Empire. For the period 1914-40, total accumulated
government financial assets had increased from $2 million to $41 million and almost
the entire assets were allocated for portfolio government financial investment. It was
219
almost double the total annual government expenditure.
As a matter of fact, this government finance structure was strongly linked with the
financial situation of the government of the United Kingdom. It will be noted that the
United Kingdom faced serious government debt after World War I which in part could
be attributed to the expansion of government expenditure and also due to the problems
For the year 1913, percentage of gross public debt to GDP in UK was at 30.4%.
However, the share to GDP dramatically increased to 132% and 188.1% in 1920 and
It does not mean that all colonies could afford to maintain the “living within means”
fiscal principle. In fact, many colonies faced serious government finance deficit as a
result of a weak revenue base compounded with the demand for extraordinary
expenditure such as defense (Da Costa, 2007). For example, British India borrowed
quite heavily to finance its expenditure, both in the London money market and also in
India. These borrowings peaked at the time of the World Wars (Roy, 2000:229).
budget. In line with this, colonial countries by nature needed to conduct prudent
government finance management. How did they realize such financial management? In
fact, it was strongly related to the budgetary process. In any country, there are at least
two stages before the actual implementation of government finance administration. First
comes the formulation phase which involves making advance estimates of revenue and
expenditure. This is entirely the responsibility of the executive arm of the government.
The second stage involves seeking legislative approval to the executive’s proposals. In
most cases, parliament has been entrusted with matters relating to taxation vis-à-vis tax
decisions and spending policies. This being the case, the crucial causal force for
determining the budget was the voter under democratic parliamentary systems which
220
stimulated citizens-participation in their choice of government. The budgetary process
during the colonial period, however, differed from that practiced during the period of
self-government. In practice, the colonial budget was institutionalized to meet the needs
and interests of the suzerain power. For example, the budgetary system of the Colony of
Straits Settlements was formulated by the Treasury of the Colony of Straits Settlements
at the first stage phase. Subsequently, authorization of the budget was discussed by the
legislative council members and executive council members who were appointed by the
Figure 5.1
Members of Legislative Council and Executive Council
Members of Legislative Council Members of Executive Council
Governor as President Governor as President
Ex-officio members (11) General officer Commanding the Troops,
Official members (2) Malaya (1)
Elected Unofficial members (2 since The Colonial Secretary, Penang, Malacca (2)
1924) Resident Councilor, Penang, Malacca (2)
11 Nominated Unofficial members (11) Attorney-General (1)
(Nominated Unofficial Members are Treasurer (1)
subject to the confirmation or Official member (2)
disallowance of His Majesty the King) Unofficial member (3)
( ) number of people.
Sources: Malayan Year Book 1939 and Mills, Lennox A (1942).
The legal power of the governor, the advisory role of the two councils, and the
ultimate control of the colonial office in London was essentially the set-up applied for
the colonies. On the other hand, the colonial authority did not permit resident
91 Nevertheless, constitutional theory and actual practice was incongruent. In reality, the Governor was a limited monarch (Mills
1942). His policy was influenced by local public opinion and the press, and one of his most cherished ambitions was that he shall
not provide ammunition for any questions in the House of Commons in Britain. In other words, the Governor has to plan and
implement the budget to meet the request of the colonial office in UK by observing response from the local populace. After World
War II, the situation changed slightly. The first election for the Legislative Council was held in 1948. The Legislative Council
comprised nine elected unofficial members, four nominated unofficial members, five nominated officials and four ex-officials.
Nevertheless, the electorate numbered only 22,000 since voting was confined to only registered voters and registration was
voluntary and not mandatory. It was a far cry from the budgetary system established in western countries. After the formation of
self-government, authorization of budget changed due to the creation of a democratic parliamentary system. Regular parliamentary
elections chose the political party and led to increasing power and say of the citizens.
221
5.2.1.3 Weakness of Colonial Government Macroeconomic Management
the emergence of the role of government became clearer with the onset of the Great
during the Great Depressions. It was market failure that clearly justified government
intervention. For example, United States introduced major public expenditure programs
with the New Deal, and other governments authorized higher spending on the
unemployed and on public works partly to create employment. As a matter of fact, the
depression was transmitted from the advanced industrial economies to Southeast Asia
through a sharp fall in demand for many of the region’s major primary commodities
such as rubber and tin which were exported to western countries. Singapore was one of
the few economies which underwent a macroeconomic shock more severe than that
In this regards, it is significant to see whether the colonial government authority had
inflation, (iii) a high, but sustainable rate of economic growth and (iv) keeping the
namely fiscal policy and monetary policy. Fiscal policy comprises government spending
hand, monetary policy is the process by which the government, central bank or
monetary authority manages the supply of money or by trading in the foreign exchange
222
policy or a contractionary policy. Expansionary policy is traditionally used to combat
there are some previous literatures explaining the government involvement in the
Huff (2001) conducted a study on the impact of the Great Depressions to the colonial
employment during the Great Depression. In fact, little new public works expenditure
creating new job opportunities, the British colonial authority resorted to repatriation to
regulate the size of the workforce (Kratoska, 2000 and Huff, 2001).
Booth, Anne (2002) also pointed out that most Southeast Asian colonies ran
considerable budget deficits in the early 1930s. This hardly reflected a conversion to
Keynesian economics on the part of colonial officials, but rather an inability to reduce
In terms of monetary policy, the colonial currency board system can be viewed as
minimal government involvement. Because colonial currency boards offer no scope for
government regulation or intervention, they are the antithesis of a central bank (Huff,
2003a:127, Roy, 2000: 233). In other words, colonial monetary policy was particularly
223
inadequate in the task of stabilization of prices and outputs (Roy, 2000:237). Before
World War II, money supply in the Colony of Straits Settlements consisted chiefly of
base money, M0, issued by currency boards. During the period base money supply
payments.
The fact that exchange rate policies were formulated largely in the interests of the
metropolitan powers in the early decades of the twentieth century is hardly surprising
(Booth, Anne, 1990). Exchange rate policies were used to promote tight economic links
between the colonies and the metropolitan power, and especially to encourage the
5.2.1.4 Summary
Based on the literature review, it might be possible to summarize the main features
of the colonial government financial behavior as follows. Firstly, the major objective of
not to depend on the home country. To ensure this principle was met budgetary process
was handled by the people who represented the interests of the home country. Secondly,
as was done in western countries. The colonial government only passively reacted
against the unforeseen economic changes taking place. Relating to this issue, this study
will examine the relationship between the colonial government’s fiscal behavior and
economic growth in Section 5.4. Additionally, this study conducts the empirical
econometric analysis.
224
Over the past three decades, numerous empirical studies have been undertaken to seek
the relationship between government expenditure and economic growth. The main
expenditure and relative size of the government expenditure to GDP. Figure 5.2
Figure 5.2
Summary of Selected Empirical Studies on Government Expenditure and
Economic Growth
employed, periods chosen for the study. These differences in results obtained were
partially due to the differences in the set of conditioning variables and initial conditions
225
across studies leading to a lack of consensus in the results (Levine and Renelt, 1992)
and in part due to the ignorance of the implication of government budget constraint for
their regression (Helms, 1985, Mofidi and Stone, 1990; Kneller et al. 1999a and 1999b).
The defect of such empirical studies, however, is the statistical constraints that “cross-
sectional analysis can identify correlation but not causation between variables” (Hsieh
and Lai, 1994 and Wing, Yuk, 2005). In view of this, time series analysis is crucial to
In 1893, Adolph Wagner put forward his well-known proposition that there is a
(Henrekon, 1993). It is one of the economic theories that emphasize economic growth
as the fundamental determinant of government sector growth. Empirical tests of this law
have yielded results that differ considerably from one country to another (See Figure
5.3).
Wagner and Weber (1977) tested the hypothesis for 34 countries over the period
1950-72. The study by Abizadeh and Gray (1985) covered 55 countries over the period
1963-79 and their findings support the proposition in the cases of wealthier nations but
not for the poorest countries. Ram’s study (1986, 1987) covering the period 1960-80
and Serletis (1996) examined six European countries (France, Italy, Germany, Belgium,
the Netherlands and Luxemburg) over the period 1961-91 and found no evidence
supporting Wagner’s hypothesis for the countries studied. Ansari et al. (1997) studied
three African countries, namely Ghana, Kenya and South Africa, and also found little
expenditure for OECD, EU and G7 countries for the period 1950-2000. He found
226
evidence that lends support to Wagner’s law for EU countries only. However, his
findings suggested that for all countries in general, government expenditure increased
less than proportionately with accelerating economic growth and decreased more than
Figure 5.3
Summary of Selected Empirical Studies on Granger Causality Test
227
Historical Studies (Inclusive of Pre-WWII period)
Thornton, John (1999) Denmark, Germany, Unidirectional causality ran mainly from income to
Italy, Norway, Sweden, government expenditure. Considerable support for Wagner’s
UK (Mid 19th century to law.
1913)
Wing Yuk(2005) UK(1830-1993) RTGE → Real GDP
Abbreviations
RDG= Real Government Development Expenditure, ROG= Real Operating Government Expenditure
RTGE = Real Total Government Expenditure, RTPE = Real Total Public Expenditure
RTPCE = Real Total Public Consumption Expenditure
Notes: ← (→) indicates direction of causality running from the variable on the right (left) to the one on the left (right).
↔ indicates both direction of causality
~ indicates absence of causality
economic growth and certain components of public expenditure of the G7 countries for
the period 1960-93, yielded results to the contrary. Wagner’s Law was confirmed for all
seven countries, i.e., there were signs of long-run equilibrium relationships between
Wagner’s Law was confirmed for all three categories of government expenditure as
Besides these works, there are many country-specific studies. Gupta (1967), Bird
(1971), Ahsan et al.(1996) and Biswal et al. (1999) have studied Wagner’s Law for
Canada. Mann (1980), Nagarajan and Spears (1990), Murthy (1993), Ashworth (1994),
Hayo (1994) examined the validity of Wagner’s Law for Mexico. Ganti and Kalluri
(1978), Vatter and Walker (1986) and Yousefi and Abizadeh (1992) have studied the
applicability of this law for the USA; Pluta (1979) and Sun (1997) for Taiwan; Khan
(1990) for Pakistan; Gyles (1991) for the UK; Henrekson (1993) for Sweden;
Hondroyiannis and Papapetrou (1995) for Greece; Nomura (1995) for Japan, Tan, Eu
Chye (2003) for Malaysia and Singh (1996) for India. In general country-specific
studies, with few exceptions, have found support for Wagner’s proposition.
228
Most of the works focused on the post-World War II period. However, there are a
number of studies which tested the validity of Wagner’s law for the period prior to
World War II such as UK (Wing Yuk, 2005 and Oxley, 1994), USA (Islam, 2001) and
Mexico (Mann, Arthur J., 1980). The results obtained differed from country to country,
very much influenced by government expenditure and the periods chosen for the study.
Wagner’s law between the pre World War II period and the post World War II period. In
the case of Singapore, there was no empirical exercise made on the applicability of
finance behavior have mostly concentrated on the pattern of government revenue and
expenditure and hardly gave any attention to the relationship between government
expenditure and economic growth. Unlike other previous country-specific studies, this
paper focuses on seeking out any notable similarities or differences that existed during
the two periods, namely the period of British colonial rule and the period of self-
This section briefly observes the long-term structural changes of revenue raising,
prices for the twentieth century. 92 Prior to World War II, government revenue
experienced fluctuations over time. The most rapid revenue growth of 53% was
92
Revenue is composed of heterogeneous elements. Accordingly, the elements are classified according to different characteristics
depending on the type of revenue, namely, (1) taxes and (2) social contribution (3) grants and (4) other revenue. (IMF, 2001:47). In
this study, Government revenue refers to revenue collected from Colony of Singapore, Municipality of Singapore/ City Council of
Singapore for the period 1900-39 and 1950-60. Revenue from Trading Department was not included in this definition. After 1960,
revenue credited to the Consolidated Revenue Account was utilized.
229
recorded in 1920. It was due to the introduction of Income tax as a temporary measure
to compensate for the deficiencies of revenue raising capacity. After the termination of
this implementation in 1922, total revenue collection fell by 16% despite revenue being
Figure 5.4
Singapore: General Government Revenue at Current Prices,
1900-39 and 1950-2000
1900-39, 1950-60
350
300
250
Straits $ Millions
200
150
100
50
-
1900
1901
1902
1903
1904
1905
1906
1907
1908
1909
1910
1911
1912
1913
1914
1915
1916
1917
1918
1919
1920
1921
1922
1923
1924
1925
1926
1927
1928
1929
1930
1931
1932
1933
1934
1935
1936
1937
1938
1939
1950
1951
1952
1953
1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
1959
1960
Year
1963-2000
45,000
40,000
35,000
Straits $ / Singapore $ Millions
30,000
25,000
20,000
15,000
10,000
5,000
-
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
Year
Source:
1900-39, 1950-60: Constructed by Author.
1960-81: Department of Statistics, Singapore (1983).
1982: Estimated by Author.
1983-2000: Asia Development Bank (2001 and 2005).
230
Another reduction of revenue was observed in 1929. It was solely due to the reduction
Clear distinctions of the size of revenue can be observed between the pre-war and
the post-war periods. It is partially due to inflation but mainly because of the
earning has experienced a steep increase over time. However, a notable reduction of
revenue was recorded during the recession period, namely 1985-1986 and 1997-1998.
According to the study by Tanzi and Schuknecht (2000) on revenue structure, the
changes over the century. Initially, indirect taxes were the most crucial revenue source.
Nevertheless, narrow tax bases prevented the revenue raising capacity. After World War
II, income tax and social security contributions have become the most crucial revenue
ratio between direct and indirect tax revenue still prevailed. Additionally, social security
contributions started to be become an important revenue source. For the period 1960-
2000, revenue increases were largely derived from direct taxes and social security
contributions. In most of the western countries, personal income taxes came to be seen
as the best and fairest taxes. Personal income taxes were ideal instruments because they
could be progressive and thus contribute to the objective of income redistribution. These
direct taxes are more in conformity with the ability-to-pay principle and are more
befitting of a modern community, because they are generally levied at progressive rates
(Goode, 1984:89).
depends upon customs (export and import duties) and excise duties, poll tax,
231
commodity taxes and other indirect taxes for its sources of revenue. These indirect taxes
are regressive in nature and the tax burden falls heavily and unevenly on the poor
(Goode, Richard, 1984). A developed country relies more on income tax, profit tax,
property tax, estate duties, inheritance tax, and other direct taxes for its revenue.
bodies, namely the Colony of Singapore, Municipality / City Council and Rural Board.
As presented in Table 5.5, the Colony of Singapore accounts for between 72.1-90.0% of
total revenue while Municipality / City Council and Rural Board contributed about 8.5-
With elected self-government for all internal matters under the 1959 Constitution,
the ruling People's Action Party abolished the City Council and the Rural Board on the
ground that Singapore was too small to afford such differentiation in roles (Lee Soo Ann,
1974:68-69).
The British colonial authority needed to identify potential revenue sources for
Singapore which became part of its colonies in the early 19th century. Unlike other
British colonial territories which relied on export duties, Singapore as a free port relied
heavily on trade for its economic activities. Under these circumstances, the British
colonial authority could not impose any export duties as their revenue source.
Alternatively, the colonial authority needed to rely on the revenue collection from the
sales of opium / chandu (Trocki, Carl, 1990, Emerson, Rupert, 1969 and Lim Chong
Yah, 1967). As can be seen from Table 5.2, more than half of the entire revenue came
from this single revenue source during the 1900-20’s. Nevertheless, its reliance on
opium sales as a revenue source reduced gradually over the period. The revenue from
opium was paid into the “Opium Revenue Replacement Fund” for each year and the
money invested in securities abroad. More importantly, the British colonial authority
232
ceased to depend on opium revenue by abolishing the opium sales immediately after the
Table 5.2
Singapore: Revenue by Major Sources at the level of Colony of Singapore,
Municipality / City Council of Singapore and Rural Board at Current Prices,
1900-39 (Percentage)
Percentage of Total by Level
1907 1915 1920 1928 1933 1938 1952 1956
Colony of Singapore 72.1 77.8 84.4 72.9 74.7 72.7 90.0 85.9
Municipality / City Council of Singapore 27.9 20.5 14.8 26.0 23.9 25.3 8.5 12.4
Rural Board 1.7 0.8 1.1 1.4 2.0 1.5 1.7
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Sources:
Blue Book, Straits Settlements, various series, Financial Statement of Colony of Singapore, various series, Annual, Administration
Report of the Singapore Municipality, various series, Annual Administration Report of the City Council of Singapore,
Various series.
Notes:
(1) Others in the Colony of Singapore include Fees of Courts, Rents of Government Property, Land Sales, Postage Stamps and
Others, Overpayments recovered, Motor Cars and Drivers' Licenses etc.
(2) Net revenue earning from the sales of Opium was available for Straits Settlements as a whole for the period 1911-1930. The
distribution for Singapore for that period was derived based on the average distribution for the period 1931-39.
(3) Interest obtained from the Opium Revenue Replacement Fund for the period 1933-39 was also presented for Straits Settlements
as a whole. The distribution for Singapore was calculated based on the size of revenue earning from the sales of opium for the
relevant years.
(4) Rural Board was established in 1908.
Import duties increasing became an important revenue source over time. Import
duties that were imposed were that on petrol (1909) followed by tobacco (1916), which
233
became a crucial duty item. By the 1930s, the revenue derived from import duties
already exceeded that derived from the sales of opium. This expansion was achieved
through the increases of rate of duty. 93 In order to overcome this serious weak
tax during the 1920-1923. As no similar tax was imposed in the Federated Malay States
and Unfederated Malay States, commercial interests in the Straits Settlements argued
against the discriminatory treatment. The law was finally repealed (Lee Soo Ann,
1974:81).
Opium Revenue Replacement Fund, Sterling Security Fund and other loans had brought
After World War II, money collected in the way of import duties represented the
most important revenue source coinciding with the abolishment of revenue collection
from the sales of opium. Nevertheless, the government could not expect any further
increase in the size of revenue. Under such circumstances, the income tax bill was
finally introduced in 1947. “The Income Tax Ordinance of Singapore” was modeled
after that of the United Kingdom. Comparatively speaking, the Government imposed a
As Singapore was a free-enterprise and open economy, too progressive a rate would
hinder people’s incentive to work, save and invest. The company income tax was
applied to limited companies, public and private, but not to unincorporated firms such
as sole proprietors and partnerships because the profit of the latter is accrued to the
proprietors or partners and the personal income tax is applied to them accordingly. The
company income tax was at the flat rate of 40% on ‘taxable profit’. The revenue
structure, in fact, has changed rapidly within a relatively short historical time frame.
93
For instance, duty of petroleum with a flash point of 73° Fahrenheit was 5 cents per gallon when it was first imposed in 1909, and
this was increased to 10 cents in 1925 and raised further to 35 cents per gallon in 1931. The duty of Tobacco was 60 cents per pound
before 9 August 1921, raised to 80 cents after that date, raised further to $1.00 per pound in 1925 and raised further still to $1.10 in
1932 (Lim Chong Yah, 1967: 256).
234
In the case of the Municipality, increasing urbanization of Singapore led to increases
in revenue through the rates it levied on property and the services an urban centre
needed. The construction of respective revenue sources remains relatively stable over
time. The Rural Board which existed under the Municipal ordinance, with powers
similar to the Municipality / City Council similarly derived its revenue from the levying
of rates.
individual taxes remains the most crucial revenue sources for Singapore as presented in
Table 5.3. The size of revenue from income tax accounted for more or less half of the
total taxes by 1975. In line with the expansion of income taxes, revenue from selling,
leasing and renting of government assets such as land, facilities and motor-vehicle
related taxes also showed increases. On the other hand, the percentage contribution of
Table 5.3
Singapore: Revenue by Major Sources at Current Prices, 1960-2000
(Percentage)
1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000
Income Tax 24.4 20.7 20.8 36.0 33.2 28.1 37.5 35.4 43.2
Import Duty and Excise 33.1 29.8 23.6 12.9 11.7 9.2 10.0 6.4 5.7
Property Tax 3.2 12.2 9.0 9.8 9.7 11.1 8.5 6.6 4.8
Motor Vehicle Taxes 2.3 5.5 4.9 4.8 8.5 6.4 10.2 7.3 7.0
Stamp Duty 1.3 1.2 1.9 1.5 2.8 2.9 5.0 5.5 4.4
Goods and Services Tax 6.6 7.2
Others 8.0 6.9 10.6 5.1 5.5 5.6 9.3 10.3 9.0
Non-tax Revenue 27.7 23.7 29.2 29.9 28.6 36.6 19.6 21.8 18.7
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Sources:
1951 and 1956: Financial Statements of Colony of Singapore and Lee Soo Ann (1974:83).
1960-1995: Low, Linda (1998:111).
2000: Year Book of Statistics, Singapore, Various Series.
Notes:
(1) Others include Tax on betting, estate duty, other transfer receipt and other non-transfer receipt.
(2) Non-tax revenue includes Sales of Goods & Services from Current Operations, Reimbursements for Services & Sales of
Lands and Interest & Dividends Received.
new directions for its future economic prosperity. The committee report submitted in
235
1986 suggested new tax system. Firstly, suggestion was made to reduce corporate and
personal income taxes from 40% to 30% and subsequently 25%. It was mainly due to
the fact that Singapore government would like to attract foreign investment and foreign
talents. Additionally income tax also has a detrimental effort on savings and enterprise.
In response to this suggestion, the highest scale of company income tax rate and
individual tax rate has been brought down to 33%. Additionally, reduction of property
Secondly, the committee recommended structural tax system from direct to indirect
taxes as the main source of revenue. This is because the reduction in income tax revenue
introduction of indirect taxation on goods and services (GST). Needless to say, GST is
inherently regressive in nature since everybody pays the same tax rate regardless of the
income level. However, it was rationalized on the ground that broad based goods and
service tax would not create disincentive to corporations (regarding profitability) and
individuals (with regards to saving). Finally, on 1st April 1994, the government
Other than tax revenue, it must be highlight that the proportion of non-tax revenue is
relatively high in Singapore as compared with other countries. A few key items account
for the difference between Singapore and other countries. Firstly, revenue from the lease
of land is substantial, at about 7 per cent of GDP, since the government owns more than
80 per cent of the land in Singapore. Secondly, prudent investment of the large
accumulated stock of government assets has provided a substantial income stream to the
from relying on traditional revenue sources such as revenue from the sale of opium
during the colonial period to more diversified and modern revenue sources during the
236
period of self-government. Most notable among the changes was the shifting of the tax
burden from unevenly on the low-income group to all income group levels based on the
In the twentieth century, Singapore has experienced a long-term real GDP growth
rate (1990 prices) of 4.5% and 7.2% for the period 1900-39 and 1950-2000 respectively.
In real per-capita terms, a moderate growth rate of 1.5% was recorded for the period
1900-39. On the other hand, a higher growth rate of 4.6% has been attained for the
period 1950-2000. Hence, there are inter-temporal differences in terms of real growth
rate between these two distinct periods. As is presented in Table 5.4, the most
remarkable growth in terms of real GDP and per-capita real GDP was recorded during
1921-30 in the pre-World War II period and 1960-80 in the post-war period. A similar
final consumption expenditure and government fixed capital formation. It will not
escape notice that Government Fixed Capital Formation (GFCF) showed the highest
average growth during the period 1910-30. The average growth was even higher than
that in the post-independence period. It was mainly because of the government’s efforts
consumption expenditure (GFCE) generally remained stable for the entire century
exclusive of the 1960s. On the other hand, the share of government fixed capital
237
formation (GFCF) to GDP showed a gradual expansion from 1921 onwards reaching its
peak (11.6%) during the 1981-90 periods after which it declined to 7.6 % during the
next decade. In terms of size of real government expenditure to GDP, real total
government expenditure of Singapore for the years 1900-39 and 1950-2000 was 17.0%
and 18.0% respectively; this being remarkably low compared with other industrialized
nations as can be seen from the data shown on page 217. Both GFCE and GFCF also
have experienced gradual increases of their shares of GDP until 1990, after which a
Table 5.4
Singapore: Trend of Government Expenditures (period annual averages),
1900-2000 (1990 Prices)
Average % growth
Real Per- Real Per- Real Per- Real Per- Share of Share of Share of
GDP capita TGE capita GFCE capita GFCF capita TGE to GFCE to GFCF to
Real Real Real Real GDP (%) GDP (%) GDP (%)
GDP TGE GFCE GFCF
1900-1910 4.6 1.8 4.1 1.3 5.5 1.9 5.8 2.8 13.8 6.6 1.6
1911-1920 2.2 -1.0 11.7 8.2 2.7 -1.5 31.9 27.8 15.1 6.0 1.8
1921-1930 6.1 2.8 10.1 6.5 9.3 4.6 24.5 20.4 17.5 6.6 2.6
1931-1939 5.0 2.3 6.8 4.0 2.7 -0.2 3.7 0.9 21.5 7.3 3.1
1950-1960 5.1 0.3 6.8 1.8 6.4 -0.5 10.5 5.3 12.5 8.6 5.4
1961-1970 8.8 6.5 15.6 12.9 14.4 10.9 18.0 15.2 17.5 10.4 7.7
1971-1980 8.6 7.1 9.4 7.7 7.3 5.4 12.5 10.8 20.7 11.6 9.4
1981-1990 7.0 4.7 5.9 3.4 7.7 4.2 4.9 2.4 22.6 11.3 11.6
1991-2000 7.2 4.5 7.6 4.7 8.5 5.3 9.9 6.9 16.7 10.0 7.6
1900-1939 4.5 1.5 8.2 5.0 5.1 1.2 16.8 13.3 17.0 6.6 2.0
1950-2000 7.2 4.6 9.1 6.1 8.9 5.1 11.2 8.1 18.0 10.4 8.4
Sources:
[1900-39 and 1950-59] Sugimoto (2008), [1960-1995] Department of Statistics, Singapore (1996).
[1995-2000] Asian Development Bank (2001).
Abbreviations:
TGC= Total Government Expenditure, GFCE= Government Final Consumption Expenditure
GFCF= Government Fixed Capital Formation
maintenance of law and order, external security, and to the provision of limited
238
increases were observed in the area of social expenditure.94 As presented in Table 5.5,
the share of government expenditure on Law, order and defense, education, health,
pensions to GDP has gradually increased over the period. This was mainly due to the
increasing government obligations, or, seen from another side, of citizens’ entitlements
education has been regarded as a function of economic growth and equity, social
Table 5.5
Percentage Share of Government Social Expenditure to GDP
(Average of OECD Countries*)
Type of Expenditure About About 1913 About 1937 1960 1980 1993 1996
1870 1910 1930
Law, order and defense
4.1 3.7
expenditure
Education 0.6 1.3 2.1 3.5 5.8 6.1
Health 0.3 0.4 2.4 5.8 6.4
Pensions 0.4 1.9 4.5 8.4 9.6
Unemployment 1.3 0.3 0.9 1.6 2.7
Sources:
Law, order and defense expenditure: OECD (2007:195).
Education, Health, pensions, Unemployment: Constructed based on Tanzi and Schuknecht (2000:34, 38 , 41 and 43).
Notes:
Law, order and defense expenditure covers the police forces, intelligence services, prisons and other correctional facilities,
the judicial system, and ministries of internal affairs.
(*) refers to Australia. Austria, Belgium, Canada, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, New Zealand,
Norway, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom and United States.
defense, justice and police, (2) education, (3) health and (4) social security and welfare
against GDP in Singapore for the twentieth century. Several observations can be drawn.
Firstly, the government expenditure on defense, justice and police remained high
throughout the twentieth century despite some fluctuations being observed in the pre-
2004:241). However, this expenditure was considered essential to maintain peace and
94
This category includes education, health, pensions, unemployment benefits and other transfer programs.
239
order in Singapore. In 1964, expenditure for this category experienced a sudden drop
due to the historical fact that Singapore became a part of the Federation of Malaysia,
which bore to undertake expenditure for this purpose. After the attainment of
independence in 1965, the percentage share of defense remained high as during the pre-
1963 period. This implies that government expenditure on defense was one of the
indispensable areas for the establishment of internal and external security of Singapore.
Table 5.6
Singapore: Percentage Share of Expenditure to GDP by Major Objects
at Current Prices (%) Selected Years
Defense, Justice Education Health Social Security
and Police and Welfare
1900 1.2 0.3 0.5 0.3
1905 1.1 0.2 0.7 0.4
1910 3.1 0.2 0.5 0.3
1915 5.5 0.2 0.5 0.3
1920 3.3 0.2 0.4 0.3
1925 3.1 0.3 0.5 0.2
1930 2.9 0.4 0.6 0.2
1935 3.2 0.5 0.6 0.2
1952 1.2 1.3 0.7 0.7
1955 2.6 2.7 1.8 1.0
1960 1.6 2.7 1.5 1.0
1964 0.1 3.9 2.4 1.8
1970 5.7 5.4 1.4 1.0
1975 5.5 4.8 1.1 0.9
1980 5.2 4.1 0.9 0.9
1983 4.2 4.9 1.4 0.3
1990 5.1 4.3 1.0 0.5
1995 4.7 3.1 1.2 0.8
2000 4.8 4.0 1.0 0.7
Sources:
1900-39: Constructed by Author.
1950-60: Lee Soo Ann (1974).
1965-80: Department of Statistics, Singapore (1983).
1985-2000: Asian Development Bank (2001 and 2005).
was recorded at very low levels throughout the pre-World War II period. These
and are priority areas for the government. In this sense, it is clear that the British
colonial authority did not pay as much attention to these expenditure categories. The
post-war period saw the share of government expenditure on education increase steadily
240
over the years. However, government expenditure on health remained small even during
Singapore was much lower than that of other OECD countries. This is because the
healthcare system of Singapore differed from those in the United States and Western
Europe. The goal is to provide quality healthcare for all Singaporeans at minimal cost to
society by relying on a combination of public and private service delivery, but without a
ranked among the most successful in the world in terms of cost-effectiveness and
Thirdly, not unlike health expenditure, government outlays for social security and
welfare were very low throughout the century. It amounted, on average, to less than 1
percent of GDP in 1990-2001, compared with 13 percent in the typical OECD country.
individual and family, followed by the community through charity, with the state acting
support.96 Relating to this, the Central Provident Fund, which was put in place in 1955
played significant role. This compulsory savings scheme has relieved the budget for
In short, the share of government expenditure to GDP during both the British
show any expansion while those of other OECD countries experienced continuous
increases over the period. It is, however, essential to note that there are notable
95
Public pensions are limited to holders of political positions, the judiciary, and top civil servants and military officers (Ghesquiere,
2007:53).
96
If these are absent, the government provdes a social safety net as a last resort, but this is subject to stringent means-testing.
Government resists introducing entitlement programs, emphasizing instead retraining and incentives that foster job creation.
(Ghesquiere, 2007:54).
241
differences in the management of government expenditure between the British colonial
period and the period of self-government. The British colonial government, as is argued
above, always aimed to create a balanced or even a surplus budget structure so as not to
burden the colonial home government. Thus, the priority was not to foster the
improvement of the quality of government services and their effectiveness. On the other
department is required to specify its output and set performance targets as part of the
annual budgetary process. These targets are monitored and form the basis for evaluating
the performance of the departments. By doing so, the driving force of budgeting is
Putting together the revenue and expenditure side of the government sector and
added to it that for the statutory boards to arrive at the overall balance for the
government sector. Figure 5.5 shows the overall budget surplus / deficit of Singapore
for the twentieth century.97 Prior to 1920, the balance of surplus/deficit was relatively
negligible, except for a couple of years (1911 and 1919). However, substantial deficits
were recorded since 1925. During the Great Depression years of the 1930’s and the
years thereafter, Singapore recorded continuous budget deficits. This picture was
somewhat different from the other Malay states (Sugimoto, 1997 and 2007a) which
relied on revenue source from export duties. The reduction of revenue collected from
the sale of opium/chandu had a major contributory effect on the decline of revenue
raising capacity in Singapore and this led to the emergence of budget deficit despite
attempts by the Colonial government to seek alternative revenue sources in the form of
import duties, amongst the major being import duty from petrol. In line with this, it
97
Due to the lack of information on statutory boards, figures prior to 1960 only refer to the Colony and Municipality / City Council.
242
cannot be denied that the British colonial government in Singapore could no longer
maintain a balanced budget since the 1920s. This issue, however, need to be examined
from the wider scope. From the view point of the British colonial authority, Singapore
Malay States, Johore and Kedah had recorded continuous government budget surplus.
This is mainly because those states could receive export duties which were imposed on
primary commodities such as rubber, tin and etc. Instead, Singapore has served as
entrepot. During the period, the Colony of Straits Settlements issued loans and it was
purchased by other wealthy states of British Malaya.98 In this regards, Singapore have
played functional role. However, in the immediate post World War II period Singapore
recorded continuous budget surpluses over time. Lee Soo Ann (1974) found that the
British colonial budget management paid special attention to achieving budget surpluses
for the period 1948-60. In fact, there were significant differences between the budget
estimated and the actual expenditure and revenue figures. Naturally, this led to the
accumulation of budget surpluses and substantial amounts were allocated for foreign
asset holdings.99
Figure 5.5
Singapore: Budget Deficit (-)/ Surplus at Current Prices, 1900-1939, 1950-79 and
1980-2000
1900-39, 1951-60
80
60
40
Straits $ Millions
20
0
1900
1901
1902
1903
1904
1905
1906
1907
1908
1909
1910
1911
1912
1913
1914
1915
1916
1917
1918
1919
1920
1921
1922
1923
1924
1925
1926
1927
1928
1929
1930
1931
1932
1933
1934
1935
1936
1937
1938
1939
1950
1951
1952
1953
1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
1959
1960
-20
-40
Year
98
For example, The Straits Settlements’ 7 per cent Loan was issued on 26th April 1921 at the amount of $20,216,300 and wholly
purchased by Colonial governments of the territories of British Malaya, namely the Federated Malay States Government
($15,000,000), Johore Government ($800,000), Singapore Municipality ($3,500,000) and Penang Municipality ($916,300) (Annual
Report, Colony of Straits Settlements, 1921, pp.12-13).
99
A similar phenomenon was observed in the Malayan state of Johore prior to World War II (Sugimoto, 1997, 2007a).
243
1963-1979
350
300
250
200
100
50
0
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
-50
-100
-150
Year
Budget Deficit (-) or Surplus
1980-2000
25,000
20,000
Singapore $ Millions
15,000
10,000
5,000
0
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
-5,000
Year
Budget Deficit (-) or Surplus
Sources: [1900-39, 1950-60] Sugimoto (2008), [1960-2000] IMF Government Finance Statistics, Various Series.
Note: (1) Total Revenue = Total Revenue + Grant (2) Total Expenditure = Total Expenditure + Lending minus repayments.
This major transition was realized mainly due to the introduction of income tax and
its steady expansion as a major revenue source. Excluding the early years of the 1960s
and the year 1987, the government’s prudent budgetary practices resulted in budget
surpluses which have grown larger especially over the period 1990-2000. According to
the Jang and Nakabayashi (2005), the government budget surplus amounted to on
average 10.6 per cent of GDP during the 1990-2001 periods while a typical OECD
country for the same period recorded a budget deficit to the tune of -3.6%.
5.3.4 Summary
Based on the above observations, summarized below are the following main features
by the government to raise revenue and allocate expenditure had undergone major
structural changes between the pre-war and the post-war periods. In the pre-war period,
244
revenue collection was almost entirely based on the sales of opium/chandu since its free
port status precluded imposition of export duties, a privilege enjoyed by the Malay
States of British Malaya. For several years, the British colonial government attempted to
introduce income tax but failed to do so due to strong objections from its residents.
Initially, Singapore managed to sufficiently obtain revenue to meet the size of its
expenditure. Nevertheless, over the years, the Colony of Singapore faced a situation of
World War II due to the introduction of income tax and the complete abolition of
revenue derived from the sales of opium/chandu by the British colonial authority.
Within a short period of time, the size of revenue from income tax experienced an
since the 1950s. Importantly, this structure remained unchanged even after the
attainment of independence and its absolute amount of budget surplus increased over
basically conservative and prudent throughout the period despite the differing
underlying motives during the pre-war and post-war periods. In the pre-war period, one
of the major concerns of British colonial authority was to attain a balanced budget or
even budget surplus with a conservative spending tendency. In fact, large amounts of
accumulated government budget surpluses were funneled to the British homeland and
other British colonies in the form of portfolio financial investment. This principle,
however, could not be sustained since the mid-1920s mainly due to the complete
absence of earnings from export duty and partially due to the relative reduction of the
revenue earnings from the sales of opium. However, the situation reverted to the
245
original status in the post-war period. The British colonial government was again able to
successfully obtain budget surpluses for most of the years after the introduction of
income tax. After the formation of self-government, not only have budgetary surpluses
been chronic but they have grown larger and larger over the years. By conventional
wisdom, this budget operation should raise hackles of crowding-out and contractionary
effects. Nevertheless, these effects have been obviated in part by the government
recycling funds back into the economy. One way was been means of direct investment
education, training and health. Additionally, outside the domestic economy, investments
by the state in global assets and activities brought in more investment income as well as
secured a wider portfolio of investments. The point is that surpluses were productively
utilized rather than locked up to cause potential adverse deflationary effects (Low,
1998:148).
that government finance behavior under British colonial rule (particularly, prior to
WWII period) could not afford to focus on the economic growth of Singapore.
Maintaining the principle of “free port status” caused weakness in the revenue raising
colonial government fiscal behavior was somewhat different from the type of
government involvement experienced in the developed countries since the end of 1920s
as described by Tanzi and Schuknecht (2000). In fact, as pointed out by Booth (2002) on
the experiences in the Netherland Indies, the British colonial government’s policy in
Singapore also hardly reflected a conversion to Keynesian economics, but rather was a
revenues.
246
On the other hand, the self-government period was one which was geared for the
economic growth of Singapore. It is crucial to note here that the Singapore Government
expansion in the share of government expenditure to GDP during the period of the
intervention emerged in the 1980s due to the rising fiscal deficit and public debt.
Governments of the developed countries reformed their policy regimes towards less
state involvement and consequently led to cuts in public expenditure. However, many
developed countries faced difficulties due to the past commitments and resistance of
groups with strong entitlements on public spending (Tanzi and Schuknecht, 2000:20). In
this sense, the principle of a small-sized government in Singapore established during the
In the following section, this study conducts econometric tests to examine the
Singapore in the twentieth century and clarify whether we can find any notable
in which it was stated that public expenditure growth was a natural consequence of
economic growth. Later, his views were formulated as a law, often referred to as
“Wagner’s Law”. His main contribution in this field was that he tried to establish
generalisations about public expenditures, not from postulates about the logic of choice,
but rather by direct inference from historical evidence (Halicioğlu, 2003, Demirbas,
247
1999 and Henrekson, 1993). The interpretation of Wagner’s Law, however, seems to be
more controversial in a sense that several versions of the law have been introduced and
tested empirically since the 1960s. The most common functional forms of Wagner’s
where TGE, GFCE,GFCF and B refers to real total government expenditure, real
government final consumption expenditure, real government fixed capital formation and
government overall budget surplus respectively. The notation Y refers to real GDP. The
first version comprising equation (1) was originally employed by Peacock and Wiseman
(1961, 1968), Musgrave (1969), Goffiman and Mahar (1971), Chang (2002) and Huang
et al, (2006). This is the simplest of all the versions of Wagner’s hypothesis and has
been widely used in many studies concerning total government expenditure. The second
version (equation (2)) was used by Pryor (1969). Similarly, this study was with regards
Equations (1) through (3) may be perceived as the level version while (4)-(6) is the
relative versions of Wagner’s Law. Versions (4)-(6) represent the Musgrave and Mann’s
In addition to the six versions mentioned above, this study tests the share of overall
government budget surplus to GDP as in equation (7). This test is especially relevant
100
In fact, ambiguity exists as to whether the law refers to the relative share of government in an economy or merely to the absolute
size of the government (Islam, 2001).
248
since both the British colonial government and the self-government after independence
This study decides to empirically investigate all versions of Wagner’s Law for
stationarity (TS) or difference stationarity (DS) and the order of integration of the data.
In this regards, it is necessary to examine the time series properties of the variables
because of the implicit assumption that the data were stationary. However, recent
developments in time series analysis found that most macroeconomic time series have a
unit root (a stochastic trend) and this property is described as difference stationarity, so
that the first difference of a time series is stationary (Nelson and Plosser, 1982). Hence,
for stage 1, the non-stationary property of the series must be examined first.
To test the stationarity of the time-series data, Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test
and the Philipps-Perron (PP) regression test are attempted.101 If the variables are found
to be non-stationary in their levels, then one needs to apply the cointegration test that is
discussed below. In other words, the cointegration test is carried out only on the first-
Once unit root was confirmed for a data series, the question is whether there exits
some long-run equilibrium relationship among variables. Step 2 tests this issue which is
was first introduced by Granger (1981). From the statistical point of view, a long-term
relationship means that the variables move together over time so that short-term
disturbances from the long-term trend will be corrected (Manning and Andrianacos,
101
The equation and methodology for both ADF and PP tests were described earlier in detail in Chapters 3 and 4. Therefore,
description regarding this is not discussed in this chapter to avoid duplicity.
249
1993). A lack of cointegration suggests that such variables have no long-run
relationship: in principal they can wander arbitrarily far away from each other (Dickey
et al., 1991). 102 If cointegration exists between the two variables, there can be no
systematic divergence between the variables from some long run equilibrium
Cointegration tests in this study are conducted using the method developed by
Johansen (1988) and Johansen and Juselius (1990). This procedure is regarded as the
most reliable test for cointegration and avoids the problems with the Engle and
Johansen method applies the maximal likelihood procedure to determine the presence of
t= 1,2,….,T
where Yt =[Real GDP and government expenditure] and εt is i.i.d. N(0,Σ). By taking
Where
Γi = − I + A1 + A2 + ... + Ai ,
For i=1,2,…, k-1, and Π = I − A1 − A2 − ... − Ak . The П matrix conveys information about
the long-run relationship between Yt variables (Real GDP and government expenditure),
and the rank of П is the number of linearly independent and stationary linear
102
Many early researchers who looked at Wagner’s Law ignored the stationarity requirement of the variables. However, the
standard regression techniques are invalid when applied to non-stationary variables.
250
combination of real GDP and government spending. Thus, testing for cointegration
involves testing for the rank of П matrix r by examining whether the eigenvalues of П
are significantly different from zero. Three possible conditions exists: (a) the П matrix
has full column rank, implying that the Yt was stationary in level to begin with; (b) the
П matrix has zero rank, in which case the system is a traditional first-differenced VAR;
and (c) the П matrix has rank r such that 0<r<2, implying that there exist r linear
can be decomposed into two 2 x r matrices, α and β, such that П =αβ΄. The vectors of β
represent the r linear cointegrating relationships such that β΄Yt is stationary. By testing
the significance of the β-coefficients, whether the variables entering the cointegrating
relationship significantly will be known. The loading matrix α represents the error-
Johansen (1988) and Johansen and Juselius (1990) propose two test statistics for
testing the number of cointegrating vectors (or the rank of П): the trace (Tr) and the
maximum eigenvalue (L-max) statistics. The likelihood ratio statistic for the trace test is
p−2
Tr = −T ∑ ln(1 − λˆi )
i = r +1
are the estimated p – r smallest eigenvalues. The null hypothesis to be tested is that
there are at most r cointegrating vectors. That is, the number of cointegrating vectors is
less than or equal to r, where r is 0 or 1 (in this study). In each case, the null hypothesis
L-max = -T ln(1-λˆr+1)
In this test, the null hypothesis of r cointegrating vectors is tested against the
the alternative that r = 1, r=1 against the alternative r=2, and so forth. Is is well known
the cointegration tests are very sensitive to the choice of lag length. Here, the Schwartz
251
Criterion (SC) is used to select the number of lags required in the cointegration test. The
y ' M 1 y K1 ln T
SC = ln +
T T
Finally, Step 3 carries out Granger-type causality tests augmented with the error-
Step 2. Engle and Granger (1987) show that if two nonstationary variables are
Therefore it is necessary to conduct cointegration test before running the causality test.
equations below:
n n
∆ ln Gt = αo + ∑α
i =1
1i ∆ ln Gt −i + ∑ α 2i ∆ ln Yt −i + α 3 z t −1 + η 0t
i =1
n n
∆ ln Yt = βo + ∑β
i =1
1i ∆ ln Gt −i + ∑ β 2i ∆ ln Yt −i + β 3 zt −1 + η 0t
i =1
where ∆ is the difference operator, z is the estimated cointegrating vector. Y can be said
Granger causes G.
approach may be relied upon to study their lead-lag relationships that involve the
n n
∆ ln Gt = αo + ∑α1i ∆ ln Gt −i +∑α 2i ∆ ln Yt −i + η 0t
i =1 i =1
252
n n
∆ ln Yt = βo + ∑β
i =1
1i ∆ ln Gt −i + ∑ β 2i ∆ ln Yt −i + η 0t
i =1
Y would be said to Granger cause G if α2i’s are jointly significantly different from zero
while the converse holds if β1i’s have such joint significance. Bi-directional causality
5.4.2 Data
For conducting this empirical analysis, various time-series data are required. For
consistency purposes, the time-series data which stretches over the twentieth century
In the case of GDP and government final consumption expenditure (GFCE), the
figures presented in Chapter Three were utilized. Figures on government fixed capital
formation (GFCF) was estimated based on official publications such as the Blue Book,
on Singapore Municipality for the period 1900-39. For the period 1950-60, Financial
provided in the government expenditure account were not detailed enough, a case in
point being that of public works. If the works were contracted out to the private
contractors, it is necessary to take into account the additional, not declared value for the
computation. On the other hand, in case where public works are internally implemented,
we should take this given figure as own fixed capital formation (Please see Appendix
Figure 1). Due to absence of detailed accounts, this figure has been treated as
For deflating purposes, these government fixed capital formation was classified into
fixed capital formation comprising (a) construction and (b) machinery and equipment
and transport. These respective figures were then firstly deflated to 1914 prices by
253
utilizing the price indices of cement for construction and the UK price indices on
Account 1995 and Yearbook of Statistics, Singapore were utilized to obtain the
information on government fixed capital formation for the period 1960-2000. Implicit
deflators of government fixed capital formation (1990=100) for the 1960-2000 were
then connected with the implicit deflators for 1900-39 and 1950-60 to obtain the long-
In the case of total government expenditure for the period 1900-39 and 1950-60, the
same sources stated above were again utilized. For deriving the constant prices (1914
prices), total government expenditure was then deflated by the major classification of
expenditure, [3] fixed capital formation pertaining to construction, [4] fixed capital
formation on machinery, equipment and transport and [5] transfer and others. Each
above items were deflated by CPI with the exception of [4] which used the UK price
indices on Machinery and Plant. Subsequently, data on total government expenditure for
the period 1960-2000 in current and 1990 prices were compiled from the Singapore
International Financial Statistics, 2006. For the conversion of 1914 prices to 1990
prices for the period 1900-39 and 1950-1960, a methodology similar to that as described
Because cointegration test requires the use of non-stationary variables and error-
correction equations require the use of stationary variables, each data series is first
254
examined for the probable order of difference stationarity. Table 5.7 reports the result of
non-stationary tests for real GDP (LY), real total government expenditure (LTGE), real
formation (LGFCF), the share of real total government expenditure to real GDP
(LSTGY), the share of real government final consumption expenditure to real GDP
(LSGFCEY), real total government fixed capital formation to real GDP (LSGFCFY)
and share of government budget deficit surplus to current GDP (SBY) for the following
For the period 1900-39, the ADF test showed mixed results. The variables for LY,
LTG, LGFCE, LGCF and LSGFCEY were non-stationarity (unit root) in levels but
stationary in first differences, that is, they are integrated of order one (I(1)). On the other
hand, non-stationarity for the level can be rejected for LSTGY, LGFCFY and SBY. Thus,
those variables were integrated of order zero (I(0)). In the case PP test, the non-
stationarity of LSGFCEY at the level can be rejected at the significance level of 5%.
Based on these results, integrated of order one, I(1) was assigned for LY, LTG, LGFCE
and LGFCF for the period 1900-39. For the period 1950-2000, in turn, all variables
were non-stationary at all levels. In contrast, when the data are differenced, non-
stationarity can be rejected for all data series. This unit-root test (ADF and PP test)
indicates that all the data series for the period 1950-2000 are integrated of order one (I
(1)).
255
Table 5.7
Unit Root (Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test and Phillips-Perron Test)
Test for Stationary
1900-39
1950-2000
256
Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test (Constant)
Levels lags1 First Difference lags1 Second Difference lags1 Order
[A] LY 0.753408 1 -8.344712*** 0 -14.64466*** 0 I(1)
[B] LTG -1.458986 0 -6.971704*** 0 -13.18521*** 0 I(1)
[C] LGFCE -0.694785 0 -6.238491*** 0 -11.38402*** 0 I(1)
[D] LGCF -1.785802 0 -10.65997*** 0 -16.63653*** 0 I(1)
[E] LSTGY -1.605284 1 -9.324743*** 0 -14.9659*** 0 I(1)
[F] LSGFCEY -2.305553 6 -7.965965*** 0 -14.06737*** 0 I(1)
[G] LSGCFY -2.724488* 0 -10.46779*** 0 -16.64528*** 0 I(0)
[H]SBY -0.652582 1 -13.70274*** 0 -11.24676*** 1 I(1)
Phillips-Perron Test (Constant and Trend)
Levels Bandwidth2 First Difference Bandwidth2 Second Difference Bandwidth2 Order
[A] LY -3.227707* 4 -8.382089*** 4 -15.47021*** 1 I(0)
[B] LTG -1.326666 1 -6.995509*** 2 -45.31031*** 36 I(1)
[C] LGFCE -1.845273 1 -6.260416*** 0 -33.05377*** 31 I(1)
[D] LGCF -2.552074 4 -13.64865*** 8 -54.50292*** 18 I(1)
[E] LSTGY -2.374247 1 -9.169686*** 3 -53.19499*** 31 I(1)
[F] LSGFCEY -2.914305 0 -8.214355*** 1 -37.5317*** 28 I(1)
[G] LSGCFY -2.600917 5 -11.55729*** 6 -50.39451*** 17 I(1)
[H]SBY -3.467982* 3 -13.17839*** 2 -21.78444*** 0 I(0)
Phillips-Perron Test (Constant)
Levels Bandwidth2 First Difference Bandwidth2 Second Difference Bandwidth2 Order
[A] LY 0.818733 4 -8.318235*** 4 -14.64466*** 0 I(1)
[B] LTG -1.450364 3 -6.968625*** 2 -16.07731*** 3 I(1)
[C] LGFCE -0.677723 3 -6.238491*** 0 -13.44321*** 3 I(1)
[D] LGCF -1.958535 3 -11.01277*** 5 -55.21298*** 18 I(1)
[E] LSTGY -2.878653* 1 -9.065948*** 2 -19.63955*** 3 I(0)
[F] LSGFCEY -3.186071** 0 -7.94208*** 1 -29.23749*** 20 I(0)
[G] LSGCFY -2.687726* 11 -10.48893*** 4 -50.93432*** 17 I(0)
[H]SBY -1.806544 3 -12.70184*** 5 -22.0251*** 0 I(1)
Notes:
1 Automatic selection of lag based on the Schwartz Info Criterion
2 Bandwidth was determined based on the Newey-West using Bartlett kernel
All variables are in natural logs exclusive of share of budget deficit to GDP.
(***,** ,*) denotes significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively.
I(0) = stationary, I(1) = unit root.
Since a difference stationary on relevant variables has been identified for both
periods, the next question seeks to answer whether there are any long-run equilibrium
relationship between real government expenditure and real GDP growth. Regarding the
Johansen method, a VAR model was first fitted to the data to find an appropriate lag
structure. The Schwartx Criterion (SC) likelihood ratio test suggest two lags for most of
the VAR models examined for different versions of Wagner’s hypothesis models based
As presented in Table 5.8, the results of Max-Eigen test and Trace test show that the
null hypotheses of no cointegration between (1) LTG and LYSBY, (2) LGFCE and LY
were rejected at 5% levels of significance respectively for the period 1900-39. For the
rest of the versions, the null hypothesis of no cointegration can not be rejected. For the
257
period 1950-2000, the results of Max-Eigen test and Trace test presented that the null
Table 5.8
Johansen Maximum Likelihood Procedure Cointegration LR test based on the
Max-Eigen Test and Trace Test of the Stochastic Matrix,
1900-39
Critical Critical The Critical Critical
Max-
Eigenvalues Value Value Trace Value Value
Eigen Test
(λ) (λmax) (λmax) Test (λtrace) (λtrace)
(λmax)
(5%) (1%) (λtrace) (5%) (1%)
(1) LTG and LY (VAR lag=2)
H0:r=0 0.356107 16.24* 14.07 18.63 16.53* 15.41 20.04
H0:r≤1 0.006578 0.24 3.76 6.65 0.24 3.76 6.65
(2)LGFCE and LY (VAR lag=2)
H0:r=0 0.342847 15.53* 14.07 18.63 15.53* 15.41 20.04
H0:r≤1 0.0000014 0.0001 3.76 6.65 0.0001 3.76 6.65
(3) LGFCF and LY (Var Lag=2)
H0:r=0 0.180713 7.37 14.07 18.63 7.42 15.41 20.04
H0:r≤1 0.001134 0.04 3.76 6.65 0.04 3.76 6.65
1950-2000
Max- Critical Critical The Critical Critical
Eigenvalues Eigen Value Value Trace Value Value
(λ) Test (λmax) (λmax) Test (λtrace) (λtrace)
(λmax) (5%) (1%) (λtrace) (5%) (1%)
(1) LTG and LY (VAR lag=2)
H0:r=0 0.130486 6.57 14.07 18.63 6.60 15.41 20.04
H0:r≤1 0.000628 0.03 3.76 6.65 0.03 3.76 6.65
(2)LGFCE and LY (VAR lag=2)
H0:r=0 0.208156 11.20 14.07 18.63 11.27 15.41 20.04
H0:r≤1 0.001325 0.06 3.76 6.65 0.06 3.76 6.65
(3) LGFCF and LY (Var Lag=2)
H0:r=0 0.149644 7.62 14.07 18.63 8.03 15.41 20.04
H0:r≤1 0.008777 0.41 3.76 6.65 0.41 3.76 6.65
(4)LSTGY and LY (VAR lag=2)
H0:r=0 0.130486 6.57 14.07 18.63 6.60 15.41 20.04
H0:r≤1 0.000628 0.03 3.76 6.65 0.03 3.76 6.65
(5)LSGFCEY and LY (VAR lag=2)
H0:r=0 0.208156 11.20 14.07 18.63 6.60 15.41 20.04
H0:r≤1 0.001325 0.06 3.76 6.65 0.03 3.76 6.65
(6)LSGFCFY and LY (VAR lag=2)
H0:r=0 0.149644 7.62 14.07 18.63 8.03 15.41 20.04
H0:r≤1 0.008777 0.41 3.76 6.65 0.41 3.76 6.65
(7)SBY and LY (VAR lag=2)
H0:r=0 0.540674 14.18* 14.07 18.63 14.29 15.41 20.04
H0:r≤1 0.200965 0.11 3.76 6.65 0.11 3.76 6.65
Notes: (λmax) is the maximal eigenvalue test statistic for at most r cointegrating vectors against the alternative of r + 1
cointegrating vectors; (λtrace) is the stochastic matrix trace test for at most r cointegrating vectors. * indicates significance at
the 95% level.
258
5.5.3 Granger Causality Tests
After obtaining the results from the cointegration tests, the procedure adopted is as
follows. When the variables are not cointegrated, the causality tests are conducted by
running the standard Granger regressions (as indicated in p.252 without the error
correction terms). However, if the cointegration hypothesis is not rejected the standard
p.252) can be applied to these time series for determining Granger causality.
The difficulty in fitting these models revolves around determining the appropriate
lag lengths. Both lags are frequently chosen to have the same value, and lag lengths of 1,
2, 3 and 4 are usually used. There are several criteria to determine “optimum” lag
lengths, such as Akaike’s information criterion, Akaike’s FPE and Schwarz criterion.
Following Afxentiou and Serletis (1992), this study have chosen four different
tested using F-statistics. The results of F-tests for the periods, 1900-39 and 1950-2000
Table 5.9
The Results of Granger Causality tests, 1900-39 and 1950-2000
1900-39
F Values Direction(s)
1 lag 2 lags 3 lags 4 lags
LY does not Granger Cause LTG 8.24 4.06 2.86 1.31 LY→LTG
1
LTG does not Granger Cause LY 3.40 2.90 2.64 1.51
LY does not Granger Cause LGFCE 8.36 5.03 3.69 3.70 LY→LGFCE
2
LGFCE does not Granger Cause LY 1.88 0.87 1.14 1.12
LY does not Granger Cause LGFCF 11.11 3.78 2.26 1.23 LY→LGCF
3
LGFCF does not Granger Cause LY 0.88 0.40 0.39 0.41
LY does not Granger Cause LSTGY 3.17 2.40 1.84 1.08
4 LY~LSTGY
LSTGY does not Granger Cause LY 3.41 2.90 2.64 1.51
LY does not Granger Cause LSGFCEY 0.00 0.03 0.41 2.42
5 LY~LGFCEY
LSGFCEY does not Granger Cause LY 1.89 0.88 1.15 1.12
LY does not Granger Cause LSGFCFY 3.41 1.60 1.09 0.58
6 LY~LGFCFY
LSGFCFY does not Granger Cause LY 0.89 0.40 0.39 0.42
Y does not Granger Cause SBY 10.53 5.69 3.92 3.23 Y→SBY
7
SBY does not Granger Cause Y 0.18 0.68 0.65 0.11
259
1950-2000
F Values Direction(s)
1 lag 2 lags 3 lags 4 lags
LY does not Granger Cause LTG 2.07 2.99 1.73 2.64
1
LTG does not Granger Cause LY 4.33 0.72 1.93 3.69 LY←LTG
LY does not Granger Cause LGFCE 0.34 1.16 2.37 1.77
2
LGFCE does not Granger Cause LY 9.23 5.44 0.64 1.43 LY←LGFCE
LY does not Granger Cause LGFCF 3.36 0.34 0.67 1.09
3 LY~LGFCF
LGFCF does not Granger Cause LY 2.02 1.61 2.65 1.47
LY does not Granger Cause LSTGY 0.02 2.44 1.38 1.08
4
LSTGY does not Granger Cause LY 4.33 0.72 1.93 3.69 LY←LSTGY
LY does not Granger Cause LSGFCEY 0.10 1.73 2.49 1.12
5
LSGFCEY does not Granger Cause LY 9.23 5.44 0.93 1.43 LY←LSGCY
LY does not Granger Cause LSGFCFY 0.84 0.05 0.46 0.83
6 LY~LSGFCEY
LSGFCFY does not Granger Cause LY 2.02 1.61 2.65 1.47
Y does not Granger Cause SBY 17.95 7.08 8.19 6.25 Y→SBY
7
SBY does not Granger Cause Y 0.09 0.17 0.94 1.01
Notes:
→ indicates direction of causality running from the variable on the left to the one on the right.
← indicates the reverse.
~ indicates absence of causality
The related F-critical values at 5% significance level are (4.11), (3.30), (2.92) and (2.73) respectively.
In the tests, causality is hypothesized to run from Y to the dependent variable, which
takes three different forms; TGE, GFCE and GFCF for the period 1900-39 and seven
different forms; TGE, GFCE, GFCF, STGY SGFCEY, SGFCFY and SBY for the period
1950-2000 respectively. In other words, the hypothesis that the change in GDP causes a
In respect of the pre-war period, the growth of real GDP caused the growth of Total
Fixed Capital Formation and share of Government deficit to GDP. These results indicate
that unidirectional causality ran mainly from economic growth to various components
of government expenditure (TGE, GFCE and GFCF), but not vice versa;- results
consistent with Wagner’s hypothesis. In the case of the post-war period, however, the
direction has reversed. Causality is observed from various components and types of
260
GDP and share of government final consumption expenditure to GDP were found to
This study examines the relationship between government fiscal behavior and
economic growth of Singapore for the twentieth century. This research is driven by the
significant shift due to the administrative changes from British colonial rule to that of
self-government. Firstly, this study conducts literature review and seeks the
general principle of government finance behavior during the colonial period was the
colonial master’s home country. To achieve this objective, the budgetary process was
authorized by the people who represented the interests of the home country. Under these
circumstances, the colonial government only undertook passive measures and did not
from the viewpoint of revenue raising, expenditure allocation and budget management
between the pre-WWII and post WWII period due to the abolishment of revenue from
the sales of chandu and introduction of income tax. Within a short period of time, the
conservative and prudent for the entire twentieth century. This is mainly due to the fact
that during both periods the aim was to obtain a budget surplus, the proceeds of which
were invested overseas in the form of portfolio financial investment though the motives
261
differed between the colonial and post-colonial periods.
Based on this recognition, focus was given to identify whether any notable
expenditure (GFCE), government fixed capital formation (GFCF) share of TGE, GFCE
and GFCF to GDP and share of government budget balance to GDP (SBY) in terms of
cointegration and Granger Causality test were initiated. Cointegration test results
provide the existence of long run equilibrium between (1) real GDP and real total
expenditure and real GDP (equation 2) in pre-war Singapore while post-war Singapore
recorded the cointegration of share of government budget balance to GDP and real GDP
(equation 7). Hence a sufficient condition for causality was proved. However, the result
of cointegration test could not establish any consistencies between the pre-WWII and
picture. In respect of the pre-war period, the growth of real GDP caused the growth of
TGE, GFCE and GFCF. Similar phenomenon was observed for share of real total
Additionally, the share of government budget surpluses to real GDP also depicted a
similar direction. Generally, this result somewhat appeared to obey Wagner’s Law. Thus,
it was economic growth that nurtured the expansion of government expenditure in the
pre-war period.
On the other hand, in the case of the post-war period, the direction and magnitude
was the reverse. The growth of total government expenditure, government final
government final consumption expenditure to GDP were found to cause the growth of
262
real GDP. The policy of the post-independence government of Singapore was to foster
This may be based on the conviction that increasing government expenditure could help
sustain economic growth. The need to spend to enhance the underlying productive
capacity of the economy and preserve the sense of economic well-being of its
263
CHAPTER SIX
CONCLUSION
This study provides the estimates of the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of
Singapore for the periods 1900-39 and 1950-60, in both current and constant prices.
Subsequently, time-series data stretching over the twentieth century with one base year
(1990 prices) was constructed for the purpose of econometric analysis.103 Based on this
historical GDP series and relevant time-series data, two types of empirical
investigations on the long-term economic growth of Singapore were made, namely (i)
economic instability and economic growth and (ii) government fiscal behavior and
economic growth.
This chapter firstly reviews the significance of the construction of historical GDP
describes the major findings on the overall patterns of Singapore’s GDP and related
limitations of this study and the area of future research area are outlined.
Research on the long-term economic growth of Singapore has been hampered until
now by the absence of long-term statistical series on national accounts prior to 1956.
This explains why the existing literature on the economic development of Singapore
prior to independence has been confined merely to studies on specific sectors. This
phenomenon is not merely observed for Singapore. In fact, most of the former colonies
103
Time-series data on GDP and its components for both pre-war and post-war series were constructed based on the concept and
definitions of System of National Account 1968.
264
In western industrialized nations, however, the field of the construction of historical
GDP estimates has been regarded as one of the dynamic branches of economic history.
In fact, the construction of historical GDP estimates was closely associated with the
statistical data was scrutinized and recompiled in the form of national accounts and its
This existing research gap between developed and developing countries could
mainly be attributed to the lack of statistical information in the case of the latter. More
importantly, the absence of local experts who could initiate these types of exercises was
another major obstacle as commented by Simon Kuznets. The emergence of interest for
mid-1990s. In this regard, the Hitotsubashi University in Japan initiated the Asian
Historical Statistic Project (ASHSTAT). Another research project by H.R.H. Raja Dr.
Nazrin Shah in 1998 focused on the construction of historical GDP estimates of Malaya
for the period 1900-39. This research project of Malaya has, in the process, immensely
helped in the construction of a similar series for Singapore which was a part of British
Based on the constraints of data availability during the period under study, it was
decided to apply the expenditure approach rather than production and income
historical GDP estimates series of Singapore has in some measure helped to fill the
265
6.2 Major Findings
The estimate of long-term historical GDP series helped in the overview of the
average growth rates of GDP for the periods 1900-1939 and 1950-2000 were 4.4% and
7.2% while growth rates of real per-capita GDP for similar periods were 1.4% and 4.6%
respectively. Both results reinforce the historical fact that the overall growth rate of
GDP during the post-World War II period was significantly higher than that of the
pre-World War II period. Most notable negative growth rates during the twentieth
century were recorded during the world economic depression years of 1930-31, namely
-21% and -23% respectively. In the pre-independence period (1900-39, 1950-64) the
share of each component of GDP was relatively stable over time though there were
about 74 per cent of GDP in the 1960s to around 40 per cent at the end of the 20th
century.
A large fall of PFCE can be explained by the remarkable increase in Gross Domestic
Savings (GDS) over this long period (Peebles and Wilson, 2002: 78). This increase of
the saving rate can be attributed to “forced savings” due to the compulsory public
contribution system in the form of the Central Provident Fund (CPF). Increases in
savings provided the source for financing domestic investments as well as lending
abroad. On the other hand, the share of government final consumption expenditure
(GFCE) to GDP remained fairly constant over the period. Generally, the share of gross
increase from 20% to 40% within the 20-year period (1971-90). Thereafter, the share of
266
GCF, however, has somewhat declined slightly to around 35% during the post 1990
period.
The most remarkable change was observed in the net exports of goods and services.
From the beginning the twentieth century up till 1970s the figures on net exports of
goods and services were negative, that is imports of goods and services exceeded
exports for these years. However from 1985 onwards these figures on the net exports of
goods and services began to turn positive with exports of goods and services exceeding
imports of goods and services over the next 15 years. Healthy current account balances
structure was its high degree of openness to international trade. Inevitably, this
economic structure which strongly relied on the external economic environment led to
fluctuations of real GDP after adjusting for trend. This study attempts to deal with three
questions. Firstly, the focus of the study was to ascertain whether the degree of output
volatility had dampened over time. The second was to seek the explanatory variables
which could statistically explain real GDP volatility. The third aims to seek the effect of
Relating to the first question above, GDP and its components experienced increases
in economic instability from the pre-WWI period (1900-13) to the inter-war period
(1914-39). Subsequently, the degree of instability has constantly dampened in the third
quarter (1950-74) and fourth quarter (1975-2000) of the twentieth century. Nevertheless,
267
the degree of instability of exports and imports of goods and services has not fallen as
compared with other components of GDP. With regards to the second question, possible
Contrary to findings made in other studies, the major sources of output volatilities were
changes in trade as a share of GDP (%) and changes in terms of trade with one year time
lag were not statistically significant. Relating to third question of the effect of
economic instability to economic growth, econometric tests found that export instability
had a negative effect on economic growth both during the pre-war as well as the
post-war periods. However, it became less of a problem in the later half of twentieth
century as the structure of the economy became more diversified. Other than export
instability, the coefficients of annual growth rate of exports as a proportion of GDP and
GDP for the 1975-2000 turned positive and was statistically significant at 1% and 5%
levels respectively. However, the coefficient was very small and negligible.
This study examined the issue on government fiscal behavior and economic growth
of Singapore in the twentieth century. This research is driven by the hypothesis that
experienced a significant shift due to the administrative changes brought about in the
process of transition from British colonial rule to one of self-government. Firstly, this
study examines the nature the of Colonial government’s fiscal behavior from the
extending the information to cover the rest of the twentieth century. Significant changes
268
in government fiscal behavior were observed between the pre-WWII and post WWII
period due to the abolishment of revenue from the sale of opium and the subsequent
introduction of income tax. This transition impacted on the revenue raising capacity as
well as the size of government expenditure. Nevertheless, both the British colonial
or even a budget surplus structure. The proceeds of government budget surplus were
invested overseas in the form of portfolio financial investment though the motives
differed between the colonial and post-colonial periods. Subsequently, in this chapter,
the validity of Wagner’s Law was tested. The hypothesis of a long-run equilibrium
relationship between various government expenditure components and real GDP were
tested using Johansen maximum likelihood technique. For the period 1900-39,
long-term equilibrium relationships were found for (1) real GDP and total government
expenditure, (2) real GDP and government final consumption expenditure and (3) real
GDP and government fixed capital formation for the period 1900-39. For the period
1950-2000, long-term equilibrium relationship was found between real GDP and share
of budget surplus to GDP. The above results showed that there were no consistencies in
Subsequently, the Granger causality test was conducted between GDP and various
pre-WWII and post-WWII periods. In respect of the pre-war period, the growth of real
GDP caused the growth of total government expenditure, government final consumption
expenditure and gross fixed capital formation. A similar phenomenon was observed for
share of overall balance of budget to GDP. Generally, this result somewhat appeared to
obey Wagner’s Law. Thus, it was economic growth that nurtured the expansion of
government expenditure in the pre-war period. On the other hand, in the case of the
269
post-war period, the direction was the reverse. The growth of total government
were found to cause the growth of real GDP. The policy of the post-independence
government of Singapore was to foster high economic growth to facilitate meeting its
approaches used yield results which are close and not too dissimilar. One major
handicap of this study is that the alternative approaches, mainly the production and
because of the absence of statistical information required for their estimation. Unlike
wholesale and retail trade. Thus, it was impossible to trace various types of relevant
statistical information to conduct these estimates based on the available British Colonial
data series. Under these constraints, historical GDP estimates of Singapore were
confined to using only the expenditure approach and no other estimates were available
Notwithstanding the above constraints, the methodologies used in this study were
tested for their reliability from the viewpoint of annual growth and share of each
component of GDP. Consistency check was done for data generated by this study with
official figures available for certain overlapping years in particular 1959 and 1960.
Additionally, the estimation procedures used in the study yielded results that were in
conformity with economic events as contained in the official documents and records.
Finally, the historical GDP estimates of Singapore were compared with the figures
270
available for other countries for checks on patterns, levels and trends and were found to
be reasonable.
Future research in this area can include studies which cover several other aspects not
covered in this study. Firstly, the construction of historical GDP estimates can be
undertaken for Singapore by extending the period of estimates of GDP to cover the
earlier period 1870-1900. During this period, statistical data on government finance and
trade were fortunately available with Singapore being treated as a separate entity and
not treated as part of the Colony of Straits Settlements. It is significant to examine the
would be helpful to improve the reliability of historical GDP estimates. Thirdly, it might
be useful to construct estimates of purchasing power parity (PPP) converters for the
expenditure side of the GDP of Singapore vis-à-vis other countries such as Japan, UK
and United State etc for the pre-WWII period.104 These efforts will help to identify the
the study initiated by Abeysinghe, Tilak and Keen Meng Choy (2007) for the period
for the construction of historical GDP estimates of Singapore could be replicated for
104
The estimation of purchasing power parity (PPP) converters for expenditure side GDP of Singapore to Common Comparable
Unit (CCU) with proper base year requires a detailed matching of prices for many goods and services in private consumption,
capital formation and government expenditure. In the case of Asia, studies by Fukao, Kyoji et al. (2006) and Fukao Kyoji and Ma,
D (2006) provided estimates of purchasing power parity (PPP) converters for Japan, Korea, Taiwan and China with base year of
1933-34.
271
APPENDICES
272
Appendix 1
Singapore: Cost of Living Indices by Major Object of Consumption and
Consumption Standard, 1899-1914
No official cost of living indices were available throughout this period. Therefore,
information on market prices and import unit value index were utilized to estimate the
price indices for the period 1899-1914. The same classification of consumption
standards and major objects of consumption item was used for the period, 1914-39. The
following estimating procedures were applied for each major object of consumption.
Information on annual average of market price of food items was available in the
Blue Book, Straits Settlements for the period of 1899-1914. Twelve (12) food items
were available throughout the period. Each market price was then converted into price
indices (1914 =100). Unfortunately, weights within food items for the year 1914 were
not available. In view of this, the weights reported in the per-capita private final
Department, Colony of Singapore,1949 was compared and evaluated with the one
derived for the Malay and Chinese labour standard (1936) and Indian labour standards
(1933). These three sources provided us a guideline in arriving at what were deemed to
be the most likely weights of the food items, the results of which are presented in
273
Appendix Table 1
The Assigned Weights of Food by Item for the Construction of Food Price Indices
for All Standards
Items Quantity Weights for 1914
1 Rice, white per 133.3 lbs. 35.00%
2 Sugar, white per kati 2.00%
3 Salt per kati 2.00%
4 Beef per lb 4.50%
5 Mutton per lb 4.50%
6 Pork per kati 4.50%
7 Fish per kati 4.50%
8 Wheaten Flour per barrel of 196 lbs. 2.00%
9 Milk per quart 3.00%
10 Tea per lb. 1.00%
11 Coffee per 133.3 lbs. 1.00%
12 Others Food Index 36.00%
100.00%
Statistical information on imports unit value of tobacco in Singapore for the years
1899-1912 was available in the Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other
Possessions of The United Kingdom for the period 1900-01, Statistical Tables Relating
to the Colonial and Other Possessions and Protectorates for the period 1902-07 and
Possessions and Protectorates for the period 1908-12. Subsequently, the import unit
value indices derived from the Annual Report on Report of Trade and Customs,
Federated Malay States series were alternatively applied for the period 1913-14.
Tobacco and beverages price indices for the European Standard were constructed using
a two-step procedure. At first, the price indices of beverages were constructed based on
the simple arithmetic average of market price indices of wine, brandy and beer provided
in the Blue Book, Straits Settlements. Subsequently, weights of tobacco and beverages
was taken to be 0.85 and 0.15 respectively based on the European Standard as presented
274
3 Clothing Price Indices
No market or import unit value of clothing was available throughout the period.
Nevertheless, Singapore’s import unit value of textiles comprising dyed, cotton yarn,
gray cotton yarn, raw bleached cotton and silk piece goods was used for the period
1899-1912 based on the Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other
Possessions of The United Kingdom for the period 1900-01, Statistical Tables Relating
to the Colonial and Other Possessions and Protectorates for the period 1902-07 and
Possessions and Protectorates for the period 1908-12. Price indices (1914=100) were
then computed by using a simple arithmetic average. Due to the lack of figures for the
period 1913-14, import unit values of cotton piece goods for FMS were utilized for the
period 1912-14 and linked with that of Singapore, based on the conversion ratio of 1.10
in 1912.
For the period 1908-14, the Report created by the Commissions Appointed by the
Excellency The Governor of The Straits Settlements and The High Commissioner of The
Federated Malay States (1919) was utilized to compute the rent price indices for the
European standard. For the years 1900-07, however, no specific data was available to
estimate the price movements of rent of dwellings. There is no other option but to apply
the average growth rate of rental prices for the Asiatic and European Standards for the
period 1900-07 based on the average growth rate of 1908-14. The Asiatic standard was
then taken to represent the movement of rent for all labour standards. Owing to the
weakness of the underlying data, the computation of these indices is inevitably subject
to errors.
275
5 Servant Price Indices
The movement of the wage index of non-agricultural workers was found to move in
tandem with the Singapore’s cost-of-living index on servants from 1920-38. Taking into
account this close relationship in the movement of these two indices, it was assumed
that this relationship would also hold good for the period 1900-13 and the servants price
The price index for expenditure on clubs was based on the simple arithmetic
average prices of “food” and “tobacco and beverages” consumed by those of the
European Standard.
Appendix 2
Singapore: Cost of Living Indices by Major Object of Consumption and
Consumption Standard, 1914-39
The Average Prices, Declared Trade Values, Exchange, Currency and Cost of
living indices (1914=100) for the period 1914 and 1918-38 for the European, Eurasian
and Asiatic Clerical standards for various consumption categories such as food,
beverages and tobacco, clothing and rental. In addition, indices on servants and
transport were available for the Eurasian and European standards while the clubbing
index for the European standard only. However, official data on cost of living index for
the labour standard was not available. In view of this, the cost of living index of the
Asiatic clerical standard was applied to the Chinese, Malay and Indian labour standards.
The following computation procedures were undertaken to establish the price indices
for the missing years of 1915-17 and 1939 for each major object of consumption.
276
1 Food price indices for the period 1915-17 and 1939
For the construction of weighted food price indices for the Asiatic standard, the
following steps were taken. Firstly, information on the full meat diet of Malay and
Chinese labour standards in 1936 and that of Indian labourer’s specimen monthly
budget in 1933 were gathered to identify the appropriate weights for each food item for
each labour standard. Secondly, unit market price series for each expenditure item for
each standard was then constructed for the period 1914-39 based on the market price
data provided in the Blue Book, Straits Settlements. The unit market price series was
then converted to an index with base year 1914=100. Thirdly, using the weights on food
items and the relevant price index of each labour standard, the weighted price index for
each labour standard was then derived for the period 1914-39. The overall price index
was then calculated by taking into account the base weights (1914) of private final
consumption expenditure on food for each of the labour standards. This derived price
index on food for the year 1918 stood at 155.72 while the cost-of-living index on food
for the Asiatic Clerical standard was recorded at 140.40 for the year 1918 using 1914
=100. In the light of this, the price index estimate on food required some minor
adjustments. In order to bring it in line with the given cost-of-living index of food, an
adjustment factor of 0.9016 (140.40/155.72) was applied for the period 1915-17. The
food price index for the year 1939 was derived by applying the movement of the food
Data on the food index for European and Eurasian standards are available in respect
of 1914 and 1918-38. Hence in order to fill the 1915-17 and 1939 gaps in the data, it is
postulated that some relationship exists between the food index for the European and
Eurasian standards and the food index for Asiatic clerical standard for which data is
277
available throughout 1914-39. The Ordinary Least Squares estimate of the relationship
R2=0.9093
where ln = Natural Logarithm
EPSF = Food Index for European and Eurasian standards
ASF = Food Index for Asiatic clerical standard
T = Time trend
and figure in parentheses refer to the t-statistics
The above estimated equation could explain about 91% of the movements in the
food index for European and Eurasian standards and the estimated coefficients are all
The 1915-17 and 1939 figures of the food index for the European and Eurasian
standards were then derived by substituting the figures of the index for Asiatic clerical
standard and the value of the time trend variable for the corresponding years in the
above estimated equation and then taking the anti-logs of such derived figures.
2 Price Indices of “Tobacco” and “Beverages and Tobacco” for the period 1915-17
and 1939
2.1 Tobacco Price Indices for the Asiatic and Eurasian Standards, 1915-17
The price indices for tobacco were based on the import unit value of tobacco. The
import unit value was then converted into price indices with the 1914 as base year. The
price movements based on the import unit value were then compared with the price
movements as recorded by Singapore’s cost-of-living indices for tobacco for the period
1914 to 1918. It was noted that the import unit value index showed a price increase of
32.8% from 1914 to 1918 whereas the Singapore cost-of-living index showed a price
increase of 74.3% for the same period. In other words, the import unit value index for
1918 was only 76.2% of Singapore’s cost-of-living index. Based on this observation, it
is felt that the under-estimation for the years 1915, 1916 and 1917 would also be of the
278
same magnitude and thereafter applied a conversion factor (0.762) to ensure that the
import unit value price indices were in line with the Singapore cost-of-living index for
tobacco for the period 1915-17. The Singapore cost of living index for tobacco for the
year 1938 was available but not for 1939. The movement of tobacco price from 1938 to
1939 was solely based on the price movement of “unmanufactured tobacco” from 1938
to 1939.
The methodology adopted to determine the tobacco price indices for the European
Standard was similar to that for the Asiatic and Eurasian Standards. It was noted that
there were no separate tobacco indices for the European standard. Indices were only
available for beverages and tobacco. Therefore, a beverages and tobacco index was
constructed for the European Standard. The weights for expenditure on beverages
(85%) and tobacco (15%) were based on the European Standard as contained in the
survey of Household Expenditure of Singapore, 1930. The price index for beverages for
1914-18 were based on the simple arithmetic average of the import unit value of brandy,
gin, whisky and wine and for the years 1938 and on beer and ale, brandy and whisky for
1939. The weighted indices of beverages and tobacco were then computed. For the
period 1914-18, the Singapore cost-of-living indices showed that there was a 74.8%
increase in price from 1914 to 1918 whereas the import unit value index showed a price
increase of 114.46%. In other words, the indices computed based on the import unit
value overstated the Singapore cost-of-living indices increase by 22.7% for the year
1918. The 1915, 1916 and 1917 data was adjusted accordingly based on the import unit
value indices. For the price increase from 1938 to 1939, the weighted (tobacco and
279
3 Price Indices of Clothing for the period 1915-17 and 1939
Detailed statistics on prices of clothing (c.i.f. values or market prices) were not
available during this period. The only information available was the import unit value of
“sarongs and selendangs” and “woolen cloth”. It was not possible to assign the
appropriate weights for each of these items. It was necessary to obtain detailed
information on a number of clothing items to assign the proper weights for each of the
items. The latter information was also not available. Therefore, there is no other option
but to take the simple arithmetic average of the two groups of commodities to determine
the price movements of clothing. This approach is rather crude in nature and is,
therefore, subject to errors. It is noted that the price index from 1914 to 1918 had risen
from 100.00 to 129.13 based on the import unit value index whereas the Singapore cost-
of-living index for clothing showed that the price index had risen from 100.00 in 1914
to 189.80 in 1918. This meant that the import unit value index for 1918 was only 68%
of Singapore’s cost-of-living index in 1918. Based on this observation, it was felt that
the under-estimation for the year 1915, 1916 and 1917 would be of the same magnitude
and thereafter applied an adjustment factor of 0.68 to ensure that the import unit value
indices were in line with the Singapore cost-of-living indices for clothing for the period
1915-17. The Singapore cost-of-living indices for clothing for all standards were
identical from 1918-30. From 1931 and thereafter, the European standard prices on
clothing differed from the price movements of clothing of all other standards. However,
the price movement of clothing for all standards (except the European Standard from
1931 and thereafter) continued to be identical throughout the period 1918-38. The
estimates for clothing for the year 1939 were based on the simple arithmetic average of
the import unit value of silk piece goods, woolen cloth, cotton piece goods (dyed &
other) and cotton sarong. There was an 8.7% increase in cloth prices from 1938 to 1939.
280
It is then applied this price increase to the Singapore cost-of-living price indices for
There were no comprehensive housing censuses prior to World War I. No data was
available on the total number of dwellings by types of units (e.g. bungalows, semi-
detached, etc). Only scanty data was available on rental values of dwellings from 1908-
19 in Singapore in the urban areas. Information on the rental values in Singapore was
available ranging from $25 to $60 per month for 26 housing units. Based on this data, it
was assumed that the movements of the rental values of these types of units would
provide a fairly reliable movement in the price of rentals of dwellings of the Asiatic and
all labour standards in Malaya. This data was utilized to compute the rental of dwelling
indices from 1908-19 (1914=100). Figures on the Asiatic rental value indices of
dwellings were available from the Singapore cost-of-living indices for the years 1918
and 1919. A comparison was made with the Singapore rental price indices (cost of
living) with that of the data computed using the 26 sample dwellings from the
Commissions Appointed by the Excellency The Governor of The Straits Settlements and
The High Commissioner of The Federated Malay States (1919). The results are
Appendix Table 2
Price Indices on Rent for Asiatic Standard
1918 1919
Bucknill Report 117.40 130.60
Singapore Cost of Living Indices (rental of 120.00 130.00
dwellings)
The fact that the 1918 and 1919 rental indices from the two sources of data are
almost identical or close to each other, provides us the confidence that the indices
computed from the 26 housing units will also provide a fairly reasonable estimate of the
281
rental value of dwellings from 1908-17. Consequently, it was decided that for the
Asiatic Clerical and all labour standards, the rental indices computed in this manner
and The High Commissioner of The Federated Malay States (1919) listed down the
rental value price indices of 23 units of dwellings whose rentals ranged from S$65 a
month to S$ 170. Using the data set from the Bucknill report, it was noted that for the
years 1918 and 1919 when compared with the Singapore cost-of- living indices on
rentals, the estimates based on the 23 units of dwellings from the “Bucknill Report” far
exceeded the Singapore Cost-of-Living rental indices. This being the case, it was
decided that an alternative approach need to be taken to identify and compute the rental
of dwelling indices that would conform to the 1918 and 1919 cost-of-living Indices. The
seven selected housing units provided us a series in which the 1918 and 1919 data
conformed to the 1918 and 1919 cost-of-living indices data on rentals of dwellings in
Singapore. It was felt that this series for some reason or other provided us a probable
4.3 Price of rental value indices for the year 1939 for the different standards
The cost-of-living indices on rent by standards were not available for the year 1939.
Surrogate data had to be used to estimate the rent by standards for the year 1939. It was
felt that the change in the assessment values from 1938 to 1939 as contained in Average
Prices, Declared Trade Values, Exchange and Currency, Malaya, 1939 report would
provide a reasonable estimate of the changes in the rental values (price) from 1938 to
1939. For the European standard, the average of group III (rental price range: $100-
282
$350) was selected while that for the Eurasians, Asiatic Clerical and all labour standards,
the average of Group I (rental price range: less than $49) was taken.
Data for the servant price indices for the period 1915-17 and 1939 are rather weak.
An attempt was made to establish whether there was a relationship between the
non-agriculture (trades and Indian factory labour) and agriculture (Indian rubber estate
tappers) workers. It was noted that from 1920-29 the nominal wage rate of non-
agriculture workers and that of Singapore cost-of-living indices for servants remained
rather stable though the levels differed. In general, the nominal wage of non-agriculture
workers by and large moved in the same direction as the Singapore cost-of-living
indices of servants from 1920-38. Taking into account the stable relationship of
for the period 1915-17. The estimates done in this manner are admittedly subject to
errors. It was noted that the nominal wage rate indices of non-agriculture workers in
1937 and 1938 remained relatively stable. The Singapore cost-of-living indices of
servants also remained relatively stable in 1937 and 1938. The price indices in 1939 for
non-agricultural workers continued to remain as in 1937 and 1938 and it is therefore felt
that the Singapore cost-of-living servant indices would also remain the same in 1939 as
in 1938.
283
6 Transport price indices for Asiatic, Eurasian and European Standards
Per-capita transport and traveling allowances price indices (Straits Settlements) for
the European standard were computed based on the UK travel and vehicle consumer
price index for the period 1900-17 (Prest, A.R, 1954: 135). Surprisingly the price index
for this item was generally stable from 1900-16. Notable price increases were observed
in 1917, 1918 and 1919 as compared to 1914. It was then assumed that the transport
price index of UK would more or less portray the movements of transport price indices
of the European standard. However, for the year 1917, my educated guess is that the
UK indices overstates the actual price indices and therefore an adjustment factor had to
be introduced to smooth the price increase from 1917 to 1918. The price index of
Singapore for transport for 1918 to 1938 remained status quo. The 1939 price indices
were estimated based on the wholesale prices of petrol (London Chamber of Commerce
Journal).
7 Price Indices of Clubs for European Standard for the Period 1915-17 and 1939
The price indices for expenditure in clubs was based on the simple arithmetic
average of “food” and “beverages and tobacco” consumed by the European Standard. It
was noted that the “club” price index based on the import unit value showed a price
increase of 55.65% from 1914 to 1918 whereas the Singapore cost-of-living index
showed a price increase of 34% for the same period. In other words, the import unit
value index for 1918 overstated the price increase by 16.2%. Based on this observation,
it was felt that the over-estimation for the years 1915-17 would also be of the same
magnitude and consequently applied an adjustment factor of 1.162 to ensure that the
import unit value price indices were in line with the Singapore cost-of-living indices for
“clubbing” for the period 1915-17. The Singapore cost of living index for “clubbing”
for the year 1938 was available but not for 1939. The price index for “clubbing” was
284
solely based on the simple arithmetic average price movements of “food” and
Appendix 3
Singapore: Cost-of- Living Indices by Major Object of Consumption and
Consumption Standard, 1939 and 1947-60
indices by major object of consumption for the labour standards with the base year of
1947 and 1959 and other standards (Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical standard,
Malay Clerical standard and European standard) with the base year 1939 and 1947
respectively. For the labour standards, price data by major object of consumption was
not available for the reference years 1939 and 1948 while that for the other standards it
was not available for the year 1947. The missing year data for each of the consumer
The price data for Chinese and Indian labour standards for the year 1948 was based
on the given price movements by each major object of consumption of the Chinese,
Indian and Eurasian standards from 1948-49. The price indices for the same year,
Malay labour standard on the other hand, was based on the price movements of each
major object of consumption of the Malay clerical grades standard from 1948-49.
The price movements by major object of consumption for the year 1947 for all other
[a] The Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical standard price index was based on the
price movements of each major object of consumption of the Chinese labour standard
from 1947-48.
[b] The Malay clerical grades standard price index was based on the price movement of
each major object of consumption of the Malay labour standard from 1947-48.
285
[c] The European standard price index was based on the price movement of each major
The price index of transport and servants for the year 1947 for the “Chinese, Indian
and Eurasian Clerical” and “European” standards was based on the price movements of
petrol prices and non-agricultural wage indices from 1947-48. These estimates are,
In the case of European standard the price index for clubbing for the year 1947 was
based on the simple arithmetic average of “food and beverages” and “tobacco”. The
price indices for the Chinese and Indian labour standards in 1939 was based on the
derived price movements of the Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical Standard from
1939 to 1947 while that of the Malay labour standard was based on the price
movements of the Malay clerical grades standard for the same period. The different
base years data were then linked to derive price indices for the entire period 1939-60
286
Appendix Table 3
Singapore: Computation of Consumer Price Indices by Major Object of
Consumption (1914=100), 1899-1914
Chinese Labour Standard 0.479 81.12 38.88 81.97 39.28 82.91 39.73 85.51 40.98 85.51 40.98
Malay Labour Standard 0.130 81.12 10.55 81.97 10.65 82.91 10.78 85.51 11.11 85.51 11.11
Indian Labour Standard 0.058 81.12 4.73 81.97 4.78 82.91 4.84 85.51 4.99 85.51 4.99
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.095 81.12 7.73 81.97 7.82 82.91 7.90 85.51 8.15 85.51 8.15
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.012 81.12 0.99 81.97 1.00 82.91 1.01 85.51 1.04 85.51 1.04
European Standard 0.225 81.12 18.25 81.97 18.44 82.91 18.65 85.51 19.23 85.51 19.23
1.000 81.12 81.97 82.91 85.51 85.51
Chinese Labour Standard 0.304 68.18 20.70 71.97 21.85 68.67 20.85 76.48 23.22 85.38 25.92
Malay Labour Standard 0.107 68.18 7.32 71.97 7.72 68.67 7.37 76.48 8.21 85.38 9.16
Indian Labour Standard 0.064 68.18 4.35 71.97 4.59 68.67 4.38 76.48 4.88 85.38 5.45
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.035 68.18 2.41 71.97 2.54 68.67 2.43 76.48 2.70 85.38 3.02
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.004 68.18 0.27 71.97 0.29 68.67 0.28 76.48 0.31 85.38 0.34
European Standard 0.486 95.23 46.27 95.80 46.54 95.30 46.30 96.47 46.87 97.81 47.52
1.000 81.32 83.55 81.61 86.19 91.42
Chinese Labour Standard 0.289 76.31 22.04 78.94 22.81 84.45 24.40 86.79 25.07 92.79 26.81
Malay Labour Standard 0.083 76.31 6.31 78.94 6.53 84.45 6.98 86.79 7.18 92.79 7.67
Indian Labour Standard 0.028 76.31 2.10 78.94 2.17 84.45 2.33 86.79 2.39 92.79 2.55
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.081 76.31 6.19 78.94 6.40 84.45 6.85 86.79 7.04 92.79 7.53
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.009 76.31 0.70 78.94 0.73 84.45 0.78 86.79 0.80 92.79 0.86
European Standard 0.511 76.31 38.96 78.94 40.30 84.45 43.11 86.79 44.31 92.79 47.37
1.000 76.31 78.94 84.45 86.79 92.79
Chinese Labour Standard 0.181 69.37 12.58 71.08 12.89 72.84 13.21 74.63 13.53 76.48 13.87
Malay Labour Standard 0.041 69.37 2.81 71.08 2.88 72.84 2.95 74.63 3.03 76.48 3.10
Indian Labour Standard 0.028 69.37 1.97 71.08 2.02 72.84 2.07 74.63 2.12 76.48 2.18
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.165 69.37 11.41 71.08 11.70 72.84 11.98 74.63 12.28 76.48 12.58
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.019 69.37 1.30 71.08 1.33 72.84 1.36 74.63 1.40 76.48 1.43
European Standard 0.566 79.35 44.95 80.58 45.64 81.84 46.35 83.11 47.07 84.40 47.81
1.000 75.02 76.46 77.93 79.43 80.96
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.051 69.64 3.53 75.00 3.80 73.21 3.71 82.14 4.16 82.14 4.16
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.006 69.64 0.40 75.00 0.43 73.21 0.42 82.14 0.47 82.14 0.47
European Standard 0.944 69.64 65.71 75.00 70.77 73.21 69.08 82.14 77.51 82.14 77.51
1.000 69.64 75.00 73.21 82.14 82.14
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.165 109.66 18.08 107.87 17.78 107.44 17.71 107.23 17.67 107.34 17.69
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.019 109.66 2.05 107.87 2.02 107.44 2.01 107.23 2.01 107.34 2.01
European Standard 0.816 109.66 89.53 107.87 88.07 107.44 87.72 107.23 87.54 107.34 87.63
1.000 109.66 107.87 107.44 107.23 107.34
European Standard 1.000 88.18 88.18 88.88 88.88 89.10 89.10 90.99 90.99 91.66 91.66
88.18 88.88 89.10 90.99 91.66
Food 0.5429 81.12 44.04 81.97 44.50 82.91 45.01 85.51 46.42 85.51 46.42
Tobacco 0.0561 81.32 4.56 83.55 4.69 81.61 4.58 86.19 4.83 91.42 5.13
Clothing 0.1082 76.31 8.26 78.94 8.54 84.45 9.14 86.79 9.39 92.79 10.04
Rent 0.0594 75.02 4.46 76.46 4.54 77.93 4.63 79.43 4.72 80.96 4.81
Servant 0.1218 69.64 8.48 75.00 9.13 73.21 8.91 82.14 10.00 82.14 10.00
Transport 0.0739 109.66 8.11 107.87 7.98 107.44 7.94 107.23 7.93 107.34 7.94
Club 0.0377 88.18 3.33 88.88 3.35 89.10 3.36 90.99 3.43 91.66 3.46
1.0000 81.23 82.73 83.57 86.73 87.79
287
Appendix Table 3(Continued)
Singapore: Computation of Consumer Price Indices by Major Object of
Consumption (1914=100), 1899-1914
Chinese Labour Standard 0.479 87.28 41.83 90.18 43.21 87.80 42.07 85.69 41.06 87.02 41.70
Malay Labour Standard 0.130 87.28 11.35 90.18 11.72 87.80 11.41 85.69 11.14 87.02 11.31
Indian Labour Standard 0.058 87.28 5.09 90.18 5.26 87.80 5.12 85.69 5.00 87.02 5.08
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.095 87.28 8.32 90.18 8.60 87.80 8.37 85.69 8.17 87.02 8.30
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.012 87.28 1.06 90.18 1.10 87.80 1.07 85.69 1.04 87.02 1.06
European Standard 0.225 87.28 19.63 90.18 20.28 87.80 19.75 85.69 19.27 87.02 19.57
1.000 87.28 90.18 87.80 85.69 87.02
Chinese Labour Standard 0.304 77.75 23.61 81.96 24.89 76.51 23.23 82.79 25.14 83.64 25.40
Malay Labour Standard 0.107 77.75 8.34 81.96 8.80 76.51 8.21 82.79 8.89 83.64 8.98
Indian Labour Standard 0.064 77.75 4.96 81.96 5.23 76.51 4.88 82.79 5.29 83.64 5.34
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.035 77.75 2.75 81.96 2.90 76.51 2.70 82.79 2.93 83.64 2.96
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.004 77.75 0.31 81.96 0.33 76.51 0.31 82.79 0.33 83.64 0.34
European Standard 0.486 96.66 46.96 97.29 47.27 96.48 46.87 97.42 47.33 97.55 47.39
1.000 86.94 89.41 86.21 89.90 90.40
Chinese Labour Standard 0.289 90.19 26.06 87.98 25.42 84.42 24.39 82.99 23.98 86.31 24.93
Malay Labour Standard 0.083 90.19 7.46 87.98 7.28 84.42 6.98 82.99 6.86 86.31 7.14
Indian Labour Standard 0.028 90.19 2.48 87.98 2.42 84.42 2.32 82.99 2.29 86.31 2.38
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.081 90.19 7.32 87.98 7.14 84.42 6.85 82.99 6.73 86.31 7.00
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.009 90.19 0.83 87.98 0.81 84.42 0.78 82.99 0.77 86.31 0.80
European Standard 0.511 90.19 46.05 87.98 44.92 84.42 43.10 82.99 42.37 86.31 44.06
1.000 90.19 87.98 84.42 82.99 86.31
Chinese Labour Standard 0.181 78.36 14.21 80.30 14.56 82.28 14.92 84.31 15.29 86.39 15.66
Malay Labour Standard 0.041 78.36 3.18 80.30 3.26 82.28 3.34 84.31 3.42 86.39 3.50
Indian Labour Standard 0.028 78.36 2.23 80.30 2.29 82.28 2.34 84.31 2.40 86.39 2.46
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.165 78.36 12.89 80.30 13.21 82.28 13.54 84.31 13.87 86.39 14.21
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.019 78.36 1.47 80.30 1.50 82.28 1.54 84.31 1.58 86.39 1.62
European Standard 0.566 85.71 48.55 87.04 49.30 88.40 50.07 89.77 50.85 91.16 51.64
1.000 82.53 84.12 85.74 87.40 89.09
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.051 78.57 3.98 78.57 3.98 82.14 4.16 91.07 4.62 91.07 4.62
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.006 78.57 0.45 78.57 0.45 82.14 0.47 91.07 0.52 91.07 0.52
European Standard 0.944 78.57 74.14 78.57 74.14 82.14 77.51 91.07 85.93 91.07 85.93
1.000 78.57 78.57 82.14 91.07 91.07
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.165 107.23 17.67 107.12 17.66 107.23 17.67 105.07 17.32 104.64 17.25
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.019 107.23 2.01 107.12 2.01 107.23 2.01 105.07 1.97 104.64 1.96
European Standard 0.816 107.23 87.54 107.12 87.46 107.23 87.54 105.07 85.78 104.64 85.43
1.000 107.23 107.12 107.23 105.07 104.64
European Standard 1.000 91.97 91.97 93.74 93.74 92.14 92.14 91.55 91.55 92.28 92.28
91.97 93.74 92.14 91.55 92.28
Food 0.5429 87.28 47.39 90.18 48.96 87.80 47.67 85.69 46.52 87.02 47.24
Tobacco 0.0561 86.94 4.88 89.41 5.02 86.21 4.84 89.90 5.04 90.40 5.07
Clothing 0.1082 90.19 9.76 87.98 9.52 84.42 9.13 82.99 8.98 86.31 9.34
Rent 0.0594 82.53 4.90 84.12 5.00 85.74 5.09 87.40 5.19 89.09 5.29
Servant 0.1218 78.57 9.57 78.57 9.57 82.14 10.00 91.07 11.09 91.07 11.09
Transport 0.0739 107.23 7.93 107.12 7.92 107.23 7.93 105.07 7.77 104.64 7.74
Club 0.0377 91.97 3.47 93.74 3.54 92.14 3.48 91.55 3.45 92.28 3.48
1.0000 87.89 89.51 88.13 88.04 89.25
288
Appendix Table 3(Continued)
Singapore: Computation of Consumer Price Indices by Major Object of
Consumption (1914=100), 1899-1914
Chinese Labour Standard 0.479 85.83 41.13 87.09 41.74 102.81 49.27 105.84 50.72 105.09 50.36
Malay Labour Standard 0.130 85.83 11.16 87.09 11.32 102.81 13.36 105.84 13.76 105.09 13.66
Indian Labour Standard 0.058 85.83 5.01 87.09 5.08 102.81 6.00 105.84 6.17 105.09 6.13
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.095 85.83 8.18 87.09 8.30 102.81 9.80 105.84 10.09 105.09 10.02
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.012 85.83 1.05 87.09 1.06 102.81 1.25 105.84 1.29 105.09 1.28
European Standard 0.225 85.83 19.31 87.09 19.59 102.81 23.12 105.84 23.80 105.09 23.64
1.000 85.83 87.09 102.81 105.84 105.09
Chinese Labour Standard 0.304 79.39 24.11 83.12 25.24 79.72 24.21 80.65 24.49 98.50 29.91
Malay Labour Standard 0.107 79.39 8.52 83.12 8.92 79.72 8.56 80.65 8.66 98.50 10.57
Indian Labour Standard 0.064 79.39 5.07 83.12 5.31 79.72 5.09 80.65 5.15 98.50 6.29
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.035 79.39 2.81 83.12 2.94 79.72 2.82 80.65 2.85 98.50 3.48
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.004 79.39 0.32 83.12 0.33 79.72 0.32 80.65 0.32 98.50 0.40
European Standard 0.486 96.91 47.08 97.47 47.35 96.96 47.11 97.10 47.17 99.77 48.48
1.000 87.90 90.09 88.10 88.64 99.12
Chinese Labour Standard 0.289 76.42 22.08 84.38 24.38 84.03 24.28 83.07 24.00 99.53 28.75
Malay Labour Standard 0.083 76.42 6.32 84.38 6.98 84.03 6.95 83.07 6.87 99.53 8.23
Indian Labour Standard 0.028 76.42 2.10 84.38 2.32 84.03 2.31 83.07 2.29 99.53 2.74
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.081 76.42 6.20 84.38 6.84 84.03 6.82 83.07 6.74 99.53 8.07
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.009 76.42 0.70 84.38 0.78 84.03 0.77 83.07 0.77 99.53 0.92
European Standard 0.511 76.42 39.02 84.38 43.08 84.03 42.90 83.07 42.41 99.53 50.81
1.000 76.42 84.38 84.03 83.07 99.53
Chinese Labour Standard 0.181 85.66 15.53 84.93 15.40 85.66 15.53 86.39 15.66 96.23 17.45
Malay Labour Standard 0.041 85.66 3.48 84.93 3.45 85.66 3.48 86.39 3.50 96.23 3.90
Indian Labour Standard 0.028 85.66 2.44 84.93 2.42 85.66 2.44 86.39 2.46 96.23 2.74
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.165 85.66 14.09 84.93 13.97 85.66 14.09 86.39 14.21 96.23 15.83
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.019 85.66 1.60 84.93 1.59 85.66 1.60 86.39 1.62 96.23 1.80
European Standard 0.566 86.91 49.23 86.91 49.23 84.05 47.61 84.73 47.99 86.75 49.14
1.000 86.37 86.05 84.75 85.45 90.86
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.051 91.07 4.62 91.07 4.62 91.07 4.62 91.07 4.62 91.07 4.62
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.006 91.07 0.52 91.07 0.52 91.07 0.52 91.07 0.52 91.07 0.52
European Standard 0.944 91.07 85.93 91.07 85.93 91.07 85.93 91.07 85.93 91.07 85.93
1.000 91.07 91.07 91.07 91.07 91.07
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.165 103.67 17.09 103.24 17.02 102.91 16.96 103.02 16.98 99.46 16.39
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.019 103.67 1.94 103.24 1.93 102.91 1.93 103.02 1.93 99.46 1.86
European Standard 0.816 103.67 84.64 103.24 84.29 102.91 84.02 103.02 84.11 99.46 81.20
1.000 103.67 103.24 102.91 103.02 99.46
European Standard 1.000 91.37 91.37 92.28 92.28 99.88 99.88 101.47 101.47 102.43 102.43
91.37 92.28 99.88 101.47 102.43
Food 0.5429 85.83 46.60 87.09 47.28 102.81 55.82 105.84 57.46 105.09 57.05
Tobacco 0.0561 87.90 4.93 90.09 5.05 88.10 4.94 88.64 4.97 99.12 5.56
Clothing 0.1082 76.42 8.27 84.38 9.13 84.03 9.09 83.07 8.99 99.53 10.77
Rent 0.0594 86.37 5.13 86.05 5.11 84.75 5.03 85.45 5.08 90.86 5.40
Servant 0.1218 91.07 11.09 91.07 11.09 91.07 11.09 91.07 11.09 91.07 11.09
Transport 0.0739 103.67 7.66 103.24 7.63 102.91 7.61 103.02 7.62 99.46 7.35
Club 0.0377 91.37 3.45 92.28 3.48 99.88 3.77 101.47 3.83 102.43 3.86
1.0000 87.13 88.78 97.35 99.03 101.09
289
Appendix Table 4
Singapore: Computation of Consumer Price Indices by Major Object of
Consumption (1914=100), 1914-39
1914 1915 1916 1917 1918 1919 1920
Price Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index
Food Weight (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100)
Chinese Labour Standard 0.479 100.00 96.60 46.29 98.98 47.43 109.53 52.49 140.40 67.28 191.20 91.63 253.20 121.34
Malay Labour Standard 0.130 100.00 96.60 12.56 98.98 12.87 109.53 14.24 140.40 18.25 191.20 24.85 253.20 32.91
Indian Labour Standard 0.058 100.00 96.60 5.64 98.98 5.77 109.53 6.39 140.40 8.19 191.20 11.15 253.20 14.77
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.095 100.00 96.60 9.21 98.98 9.44 109.53 10.44 140.40 13.39 191.20 18.23 253.20 24.14
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.012 100.00 130.89 1.60 130.59 1.59 135.83 1.66 136.50 1.66 160.30 1.95 214.30 2.61
European Standard 0.225 100.00 130.89 29.44 130.59 29.37 135.83 30.55 136.50 30.70 160.30 36.05 214.30 48.20
1.000 100.00 104.73 106.47 115.77 139.48 183.87 243.98
Chinese Labour Standard 0.304 100.00 105.44 32.02 165.69 50.31 131.26 39.86 174.30 52.92 200.00 60.73 257.10 78.06
Malay Labour Standard 0.107 100.00 105.44 11.32 165.69 17.78 131.26 14.09 174.30 18.71 200.00 21.47 257.10 27.59
Indian Labour Standard 0.064 100.00 105.44 6.73 165.69 10.58 131.26 8.38 174.30 11.13 200.00 12.77 257.10 16.41
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.035 100.00 105.44 3.73 165.69 5.86 131.26 4.64 174.30 6.16 200.00 7.07 257.10 9.09
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.004 100.00 105.44 0.42 165.69 0.67 131.26 0.53 174.30 0.70 200.00 0.80 257.10 1.03
European Standard 0.486 100.00 77.42 37.61 104.40 50.72 124.22 60.35 174.80 84.93 204.10 99.16 214.70 104.31
1.000 100.00 91.83 135.91 127.84 174.54 201.99 236.50
Chinese Labour Standard 0.289 100.00 138.32 39.96 161.28 46.59 144.02 41.61 189.80 54.83 229.60 66.33 291.60 84.24
Malay Labour Standard 0.083 100.00 138.32 11.44 161.28 13.34 144.02 11.91 189.80 15.70 229.60 18.99 291.60 24.12
Indian Labour Standard 0.028 100.00 138.32 3.81 161.28 4.44 144.02 3.97 189.80 5.23 229.60 6.32 291.60 8.03
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.081 100.00 138.32 11.22 161.28 13.08 144.02 11.68 189.80 15.40 229.60 18.62 291.60 23.65
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.009 100.00 138.32 1.27 161.28 1.49 144.02 1.33 189.80 1.75 229.60 2.12 291.60 2.69
European Standard 0.511 100.00 138.32 70.61 161.28 82.34 144.02 73.52 189.80 96.90 229.60 117.22 291.60 148.87
1.000 100.00 138.32 161.28 144.02 189.80 229.60 291.60
Chinese Labour Standard 0.181 100.00 103.23 18.72 106.15 19.25 107.53 19.50 120.00 21.76 130.00 23.57 150.00 27.20
Malay Labour Standard 0.041 100.00 103.23 4.19 106.15 4.31 107.53 4.36 120.00 4.87 130.00 5.27 150.00 6.09
Indian Labour Standard 0.028 100.00 103.23 2.94 106.15 3.02 107.53 3.06 120.00 3.42 130.00 3.70 150.00 4.27
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.165 100.00 103.23 16.98 106.15 17.46 107.53 17.69 120.00 19.74 130.00 21.39 150.00 24.68
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.019 100.00 103.23 1.93 106.15 1.98 107.53 2.01 120.00 2.24 130.00 2.43 150.00 2.80
European Standard 0.566 100.00 98.02 55.52 99.61 56.42 98.27 55.66 110.00 62.31 121.00 68.54 169.00 95.73
1.000 100.00 100.28 102.44 102.29 114.34 124.90 160.76
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.051 100.00 103.82 5.26 103.82 5.26 113.09 5.73 116.80 5.92 116.80 5.92 155.50 7.88
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.006 100.00 103.82 0.60 103.82 0.60 113.09 0.65 116.80 0.67 116.80 0.67 155.50 0.90
European Standard 0.944 100.00 103.82 97.96 103.82 97.96 113.09 106.71 116.80 110.21 116.80 110.21 155.50 146.72
1.000 100.00 103.82 103.82 113.09 116.80 116.80 155.50
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.165 100.00 101.83 16.79 103.13 17.00 108.64 17.91 112.50 18.54 122.90 20.26 126.80 20.90
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.019 100.00 101.83 1.91 103.13 1.93 108.64 2.03 112.50 2.11 122.90 2.30 126.80 2.38
European Standard 0.816 100.00 101.83 83.14 103.13 84.20 108.64 88.70 112.50 91.85 122.90 100.34 126.80 103.52
1.000 100.00 101.83 103.13 108.64 112.50 122.90 126.80
European Standard 1.000 100.00 91.31 91.31 103.77 103.77 113.88 113.88 134.00 134.00 147.40 147.40 163.50 163.50
1.000 100.00 91.31 103.77 113.88 134.00 147.40 163.50
Food 0.543 100.00 104.73 56.86 106.47 57.81 115.77 62.85 139.48 75.72 183.87 99.83 243.98 132.46
Beverage and Tobacco 0.056 100.00 91.83 5.15 135.91 7.62 127.84 7.17 174.54 9.79 201.99 11.33 236.50 13.27
Clothing 0.108 100.00 138.32 14.96 161.28 17.45 144.02 15.58 189.80 20.53 229.60 24.84 291.60 31.55
Rent 0.059 100.00 100.28 5.96 102.44 6.09 102.29 6.08 114.34 6.79 124.90 7.42 160.76 9.55
Servant 0.122 100.00 103.82 12.64 103.82 12.64 113.09 13.77 116.80 14.22 116.80 14.22 155.50 18.93
Transport 0.074 100.00 101.83 7.53 103.13 7.62 108.64 8.03 112.50 8.32 122.90 9.09 126.80 9.37
Club 0.038 100.00 91.31 3.44 103.77 3.91 113.88 4.30 134.00 5.05 147.40 5.56 163.50 6.17
1.000 100.00 106.54 113.14 117.78 140.43 172.28 221.30
290
Appendix Table 4 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of Consumer Price Indices by Major Object of
Consumption (1914=100), 1914-39
1914 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926
Price Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index
Food Weight (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100)
Chinese Labour Standard 0.479 100.00 167.70 80.36 145.50 69.73 145.30 69.63 146.10 70.01 151.50 72.60 160.20 76.77
Malay Labour Standard 0.130 100.00 167.70 21.80 145.50 18.91 145.30 18.89 146.10 18.99 151.50 19.69 160.20 20.82
Indian Labour Standard 0.058 100.00 167.70 9.78 145.50 8.49 145.30 8.48 146.10 8.52 151.50 8.84 160.20 9.35
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.095 100.00 167.70 15.99 145.50 13.87 145.30 13.85 146.10 13.93 151.50 14.45 160.20 15.27
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.012 100.00 168.80 2.06 140.00 1.71 141.00 1.72 139.80 1.70 143.40 1.75 153.00 1.86
European Standard 0.225 100.00 168.80 37.97 140.00 31.49 141.00 31.71 139.80 31.44 143.40 32.25 153.00 34.41
1.000 100.00 167.96 144.20 144.28 144.61 149.58 158.49
Chinese Labour Standard 0.304 100.00 242.90 73.75 242.90 73.75 200.00 60.73 185.70 56.38 185.70 56.38 194.20 58.97
Malay Labour Standard 0.107 100.00 242.90 26.07 242.90 26.07 200.00 21.47 185.70 19.93 185.70 19.93 194.20 20.84
Indian Labour Standard 0.064 100.00 242.90 15.51 242.90 15.51 200.00 12.77 185.70 11.85 185.70 11.85 194.20 12.40
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.035 100.00 242.90 8.58 242.90 8.58 200.00 7.07 185.70 6.56 185.70 6.56 194.20 6.86
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.004 100.00 242.90 0.98 242.90 0.98 200.00 0.80 185.70 0.75 185.70 0.75 194.20 0.78
European Standard 0.486 100.00 231.20 112.33 223.70 108.68 203.20 98.72 192.10 93.33 186.70 90.71 181.30 88.08
1.000 100.00 237.22 233.57 201.55 188.81 186.19 187.93
Chinese Labour Standard 0.289 100.00 237.20 68.53 182.80 52.81 163.60 47.26 157.10 45.39 158.10 45.68 157.50 45.50
Malay Labour Standard 0.083 100.00 237.20 19.62 182.80 15.12 163.60 13.53 157.10 12.99 158.10 13.08 157.50 13.03
Indian Labour Standard 0.028 100.00 237.20 6.53 182.80 5.03 163.60 4.50 157.10 4.33 158.10 4.35 157.50 4.34
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.081 100.00 237.20 19.24 182.80 14.83 163.60 13.27 157.10 12.74 158.10 12.82 157.50 12.78
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.009 100.00 237.20 2.19 182.80 1.68 163.60 1.51 157.10 1.45 158.10 1.46 157.50 1.45
European Standard 0.511 100.00 237.20 121.10 182.80 93.32 163.60 83.52 157.10 80.20 158.10 80.71 157.50 80.41
1.000 100.00 237.20 182.80 163.60 157.10 158.10 157.50
Chinese Labour Standard 0.181 100.00 154.00 27.92 181.00 32.82 217.00 39.34 230.00 41.70 242.00 43.88 257.00 46.60
Malay Labour Standard 0.041 100.00 154.00 6.25 181.00 7.34 217.00 8.80 230.00 9.33 242.00 9.82 257.00 10.43
Indian Labour Standard 0.028 100.00 154.00 4.38 181.00 5.15 217.00 6.18 230.00 6.55 242.00 6.89 257.00 7.32
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.165 100.00 154.00 25.34 181.00 29.78 217.00 35.70 230.00 37.84 242.00 39.82 257.00 42.28
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.019 100.00 154.00 2.88 181.00 3.38 217.00 4.06 230.00 4.30 242.00 4.52 257.00 4.81
European Standard 0.566 100.00 179.00 101.39 191.00 108.19 204.00 115.55 208.00 117.82 213.00 120.65 220.00 124.61
1.000 100.00 168.16 186.66 209.64 217.54 225.57 236.04
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.051 100.00 155.50 7.88 155.50 7.88 155.50 7.88 155.50 7.88 155.50 7.88 155.50 7.88
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.006 100.00 155.50 0.90 155.50 0.90 155.50 0.90 155.50 0.90 155.50 0.90 155.50 0.90
European Standard 0.944 100.00 155.50 146.72 155.50 146.72 155.50 146.72 155.50 146.72 155.50 146.72 155.50 146.72
1.000 100.00 155.50 155.50 155.50 155.50 155.50 155.50
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.165 100.00 122.80 20.24 112.00 18.46 94.80 15.63 99.40 16.38 105.30 17.36 103.50 17.06
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.019 100.00 122.80 2.30 112.00 2.10 94.80 1.78 99.40 1.86 105.30 1.97 103.50 1.94
European Standard 0.816 100.00 122.80 100.26 112.00 91.44 94.80 77.40 99.40 81.15 105.30 85.97 103.50 84.50
1.000 100.00 122.80 112.00 94.80 99.40 105.30 103.50
European Standard 1.000 100.00 176.70 176.70 177.40 177.40 169.20 169.20 164.10 164.10 164.20 164.20 161.70 161.70
1.000 100.00 176.70 177.40 169.20 164.10 164.20 161.70
Food 0.543 100.00 167.96 91.19 144.20 78.29 144.28 78.33 144.61 78.51 149.58 81.21 158.49 86.05
Beverage and Tobacco 0.056 100.00 237.22 13.31 233.57 13.10 201.55 11.31 188.81 10.59 186.19 10.44 187.93 10.54
Clothing 0.108 100.00 237.20 25.66 182.80 19.78 163.60 17.70 157.10 17.00 158.10 17.10 157.50 17.04
Rent 0.059 100.00 168.16 9.99 186.66 11.09 209.64 12.45 217.54 12.92 225.57 13.40 236.04 14.02
Servant 0.122 100.00 155.50 18.93 155.50 18.93 155.50 18.93 155.50 18.93 155.50 18.93 155.50 18.93
Transport 0.074 100.00 122.80 9.08 112.00 8.28 94.80 7.01 99.40 7.35 105.30 7.78 103.50 7.65
Club 0.038 100.00 176.70 6.66 177.40 6.69 169.20 6.38 164.10 6.19 164.20 6.19 161.70 6.10
1.000 100.00 174.82 156.16 152.11 151.49 155.07 160.33
291
Appendix Table 4 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of Consumer Price Indices by Major Object of
Consumption (1914=100), 1914-39
1914 1927 1928 1929 1930 1931 1932
Price Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index
Food Weight (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100)
Chinese Labour Standard 0.479 100.00 154.80 74.18 151.20 72.46 149.70 71.74 140.20 67.19 103.00 49.36 86.50 41.45
Malay Labour Standard 0.130 100.00 154.80 20.12 151.20 19.65 149.70 19.46 140.20 18.22 103.00 13.39 86.50 11.24
Indian Labour Standard 0.058 100.00 154.80 9.03 151.20 8.82 149.70 8.73 140.20 8.18 103.00 6.01 86.50 5.05
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.095 100.00 154.80 14.76 151.20 14.42 149.70 14.27 140.20 13.37 103.00 9.82 86.50 8.25
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.012 100.00 155.00 1.89 149.40 1.82 141.40 1.72 132.00 1.61 109.70 1.34 97.80 1.19
European Standard 0.225 100.00 155.00 34.86 149.40 33.60 141.40 31.80 132.00 29.69 109.70 24.67 97.80 22.00
1.000 100.00 154.85 150.77 147.73 138.26 104.59 89.18
Chinese Labour Standard 0.304 100.00 185.70 56.38 185.70 56.38 185.70 56.38 171.40 52.04 171.40 52.04 165.70 50.31
Malay Labour Standard 0.107 100.00 185.70 19.93 185.70 19.93 185.70 19.93 171.40 18.40 171.40 18.40 165.70 17.78
Indian Labour Standard 0.064 100.00 185.70 11.85 185.70 11.85 185.70 11.85 171.40 10.94 171.40 10.94 165.70 10.58
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.035 100.00 185.70 6.56 185.70 6.56 185.70 6.56 171.40 6.06 171.40 6.06 165.70 5.86
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.004 100.00 185.70 0.75 185.70 0.75 185.70 0.75 171.40 0.69 171.40 0.69 165.70 0.67
European Standard 0.486 100.00 176.00 85.51 176.30 85.66 167.00 81.14 168.70 81.96 178.40 86.68 172.00 83.57
1.000 100.00 180.99 181.13 176.61 170.09 174.80 168.76
Chinese Labour Standard 0.289 100.00 155.40 44.90 151.90 43.88 141.00 40.74 139.80 40.39 133.20 38.48 110.00 31.78
Malay Labour Standard 0.083 100.00 155.40 12.85 151.90 12.56 141.00 11.66 139.80 11.56 133.20 11.02 110.00 9.10
Indian Labour Standard 0.028 100.00 155.40 4.28 151.90 4.18 141.00 3.88 139.80 3.85 133.20 3.67 110.00 3.03
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.081 100.00 155.40 12.61 151.90 12.32 141.00 11.44 139.80 11.34 133.20 10.80 110.00 8.92
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.009 100.00 155.40 1.43 151.90 1.40 141.00 1.30 139.80 1.29 133.20 1.23 110.00 1.01
European Standard 0.511 100.00 155.40 79.33 151.90 77.55 141.00 71.98 139.80 71.37 139.80 71.37 132.30 67.54
1.000 100.00 155.40 151.90 141.00 139.80 136.57 121.38
Chinese Labour Standard 0.181 100.00 284.00 51.49 312.00 56.57 314.50 57.02 289.70 52.53 247.40 44.86 200.40 36.33
Malay Labour Standard 0.041 100.00 284.00 11.52 312.00 12.66 314.50 12.76 289.70 11.75 247.40 10.04 200.40 8.13
Indian Labour Standard 0.028 100.00 284.00 8.09 312.00 8.88 314.50 8.95 289.70 8.25 247.40 7.04 200.40 5.71
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.165 100.00 284.00 46.73 312.00 51.33 314.50 51.75 289.70 47.66 247.40 40.71 200.40 32.97
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.019 100.00 284.00 5.31 312.00 5.83 314.50 5.88 289.70 5.42 247.40 4.63 200.40 3.75
European Standard 0.566 100.00 230.00 130.28 248.00 140.47 249.00 141.04 229.50 129.99 201.60 114.19 166.50 94.31
1.000 100.00 253.41 275.75 277.40 255.60 221.46 181.20
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.051 100.00 155.50 7.88 155.50 7.88 155.50 7.88 152.90 7.75 138.00 7.00 124.70 6.32
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.006 100.00 155.50 0.90 155.50 0.90 155.50 0.90 152.90 0.88 138.00 0.79 124.70 0.72
European Standard 0.944 100.00 155.50 146.72 155.50 146.72 155.50 146.72 152.90 144.27 138.00 130.21 124.70 117.66
1.000 100.00 155.50 155.50 155.50 152.90 138.00 124.70
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.165 100.00 94.20 15.53 93.10 15.35 89.70 14.79 85.50 14.09 96.20 15.86 89.00 14.67
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.019 100.00 94.20 1.76 93.10 1.74 89.70 1.68 85.50 1.60 96.20 1.80 89.00 1.67
European Standard 0.816 100.00 94.20 76.91 93.10 76.01 89.70 73.23 85.50 69.81 96.20 78.54 89.00 72.66
1.000 100.00 94.20 93.10 89.70 85.50 96.20 89.00
European Standard 1.000 100.00 159.50 159.50 159.50 159.50 155.30 155.30 156.10 156.10 160.50 160.50 160.10 160.10
1.000 100.00 159.50 159.50 155.30 156.10 160.50 160.10
Food 0.543 100.00 154.85 84.07 150.77 81.86 147.73 80.21 138.26 75.06 104.59 56.78 89.18 48.42
Beverage and Tobacco 0.056 100.00 180.99 10.15 181.13 10.16 176.61 9.91 170.09 9.54 174.80 9.81 168.76 9.47
Clothing 0.108 100.00 155.40 16.81 151.90 16.43 141.00 15.25 139.80 15.12 136.57 14.78 121.38 13.13
Rent 0.059 100.00 253.41 15.05 275.75 16.38 277.40 16.48 255.60 15.18 221.46 13.15 181.20 10.76
Servant 0.122 100.00 155.50 18.93 155.50 18.93 155.50 18.93 152.90 18.62 138.00 16.80 124.70 15.18
Transport 0.074 100.00 94.20 6.96 93.10 6.88 89.70 6.63 85.50 6.32 96.20 7.11 89.00 6.58
Club 0.038 100.00 159.50 6.02 159.50 6.02 155.30 5.86 156.10 5.89 160.50 6.05 160.10 6.04
1.000 100.00 158.00 156.66 153.27 145.73 124.49 109.58
292
Appendix Table 4 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of Consumer Price Indices by Major Object of
Consumption (1914=100), 1914-39
1914 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939
Price Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index
Food Weight (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100) (1914=100)
Chinese Labour Standard 0.479 100.00 78.80 37.76 83.40 39.97 93.90 45.00 91.00 43.61 101.50 48.64 93.70 44.90 92.83 44.48
Malay Labour Standard 0.130 100.00 78.80 10.24 83.40 10.84 93.90 12.21 91.00 11.83 101.50 13.19 93.70 12.18 92.83 12.07
Indian Labour Standard 0.058 100.00 78.80 4.60 83.40 4.87 93.90 5.48 91.00 5.31 101.50 5.92 93.70 5.47 92.83 5.42
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.095 100.00 78.80 7.51 83.40 7.95 93.90 8.95 91.00 8.68 101.50 9.68 93.70 8.93 92.83 8.85
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.012 100.00 93.80 1.14 96.10 1.17 97.20 1.18 96.10 1.17 102.60 1.25 96.20 1.17 88.53 1.08
European Standard 0.225 100.00 93.80 21.10 96.10 21.61 97.20 21.86 96.10 21.61 102.60 23.08 96.20 21.64 88.53 19.91
1.000 100.00 82.36 86.41 94.68 92.21 101.76 94.29 91.81
Chinese Labour Standard 0.304 100.00 142.90 43.39 142.90 43.39 128.60 39.05 128.60 39.05 128.60 39.05 128.60 39.05 144.68 43.93
Malay Labour Standard 0.107 100.00 142.90 15.34 142.90 15.34 128.60 13.80 128.60 13.80 128.60 13.80 128.60 13.80 144.68 15.53
Indian Labour Standard 0.064 100.00 142.90 9.12 142.90 9.12 128.60 8.21 128.60 8.21 128.60 8.21 128.60 8.21 144.68 9.24
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.035 100.00 142.90 5.05 142.90 5.05 128.60 4.54 128.60 4.54 128.60 4.54 128.60 4.54 144.68 5.11
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.004 100.00 142.90 0.57 142.90 0.57 128.60 0.52 128.60 0.52 128.60 0.52 128.60 0.52 144.68 0.58
European Standard 0.486 100.00 168.00 81.62 170.50 82.84 166.50 80.89 165.90 80.60 165.90 80.60 164.20 79.78 164.07 79.71
1.000 100.00 155.09 156.31 147.01 146.72 146.72 145.90 154.10
Chinese Labour Standard 0.289 100.00 106.90 30.88 99.50 28.75 99.70 28.80 98.30 28.40 105.80 30.57 108.10 31.23 117.50 33.95
Malay Labour Standard 0.083 100.00 106.90 8.84 99.50 8.23 99.70 8.25 98.30 8.13 105.80 8.75 108.10 8.94 117.50 9.72
Indian Labour Standard 0.028 100.00 106.90 2.94 99.50 2.74 99.70 2.75 98.30 2.71 105.80 2.91 108.10 2.98 117.50 3.24
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.081 100.00 106.90 8.67 99.50 8.07 99.70 8.09 98.30 7.97 105.80 8.58 108.10 8.77 117.50 9.53
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.009 100.00 106.90 0.99 99.50 0.92 99.70 0.92 98.30 0.91 105.80 0.98 108.10 1.00 117.50 1.08
European Standard 0.511 100.00 124.10 63.36 121.60 62.08 119.50 61.01 119.50 61.01 119.50 61.01 119.50 61.01 129.90 66.31
1.000 100.00 115.68 110.78 109.81 109.12 112.79 113.92 123.83
Chinese Labour Standard 0.181 100.00 175.60 31.84 175.60 31.84 175.60 31.84 175.60 31.84 177.70 32.22 188.90 34.25 207.65 37.65
Malay Labour Standard 0.041 100.00 175.60 7.12 175.60 7.12 175.60 7.12 175.60 7.12 177.70 7.21 188.90 7.66 207.65 8.42
Indian Labour Standard 0.028 100.00 175.60 5.00 175.60 5.00 175.60 5.00 175.60 5.00 177.70 5.06 188.90 5.38 207.65 5.91
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.165 100.00 175.60 28.89 175.60 28.89 175.60 28.89 175.60 28.89 177.70 29.24 188.90 31.08 207.65 34.16
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.019 100.00 175.60 3.28 175.60 3.28 175.60 3.28 175.60 3.28 177.70 3.32 188.90 3.53 207.65 3.88
European Standard 0.566 100.00 146.40 82.92 146.40 82.92 146.40 82.92 146.40 82.92 149.60 84.74 154.80 87.68 162.83 92.23
1.000 100.00 159.06 159.06 159.06 159.06 161.78 169.58 182.26
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.051 100.00 115.80 5.87 123.70 6.27 127.40 6.46 125.70 6.37 130.00 6.59 128.20 6.50 128.20 6.50
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.006 100.00 115.80 0.67 123.70 0.71 127.40 0.73 125.70 0.72 130.00 0.75 128.20 0.74 128.20 0.74
European Standard 0.944 100.00 115.80 109.26 123.70 116.72 127.40 120.21 125.70 118.60 130.00 122.66 128.20 120.96 128.20 120.96
1.000 100.00 115.80 123.70 127.40 125.70 130.00 128.20 128.20
Asiatic Clerical Standard 0.165 100.00 85.40 14.08 84.50 13.93 82.40 13.58 80.00 13.19 81.40 13.42 81.50 13.43 82.18 13.55
Eurasian Clerical Standard 0.019 100.00 85.40 1.60 84.50 1.58 82.40 1.54 80.00 1.50 81.40 1.52 81.50 1.53 82.18 1.54
European Standard 0.816 100.00 85.40 69.72 84.50 68.99 82.40 67.27 80.00 65.31 81.40 66.46 81.50 66.54 82.18 67.09
1.000 100.00 85.40 84.50 82.40 80.00 81.40 81.50 82.18
European Standard 1.000 100.00 158.40 158.40 159.50 159.50 157.70 157.70 157.40 157.40 157.70 157.70 159.40 159.40 152.87 152.87
1.000 100.00 158.40 159.50 157.70 157.40 157.70 159.40 152.87
Food 0.543 100.00 82.36 44.71 86.41 46.91 94.68 51.40 92.21 50.06 101.76 55.25 94.29 51.19 91.81 49.84
Beverage and Tobacco 0.056 100.00 155.09 8.70 156.31 8.77 147.01 8.25 146.72 8.23 146.72 8.23 145.90 8.18 154.10 8.64
Clothing 0.108 100.00 115.68 12.52 110.78 11.99 109.81 11.88 109.12 11.81 112.79 12.20 113.92 12.32 123.83 13.40
Rent 0.059 100.00 159.06 9.45 159.06 9.45 159.06 9.45 159.06 9.45 161.78 9.61 169.58 10.07 182.26 10.83
Servant 0.122 100.00 115.80 14.10 123.70 15.06 127.40 15.51 125.70 15.31 130.00 15.83 128.20 15.61 128.20 15.61
Transport 0.074 100.00 85.40 6.31 84.50 6.25 82.40 6.09 80.00 5.91 81.40 6.02 81.50 6.03 82.18 6.08
Club 0.038 100.00 158.40 5.97 159.50 6.02 157.70 5.95 157.40 5.94 157.70 5.95 159.40 6.01 152.87 5.77
1.000 100.00 101.76 104.44 108.53 106.70 113.08 109.42 110.16
293
Appendix Table 5
Singapore: Computation of Consumer Price Indices by Major Object of
Consumption (1949=100), 1939 and 1947-60
1949 1939 1947 1948 1949 1950
Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index Price Index Weighted Index
Food Weight (1949=100) (1949=100) (1949=100) (1949=100) (1949=100)
Chinese Labour Standard 0.5188 26.39 13.69 120.48 62.50 107.65 55.85 100.00 51.88 104.82 54.38
Malay Labour Standard 0.0657 24.63 1.62 104.17 6.84 109.61 7.20 100.00 6.57 109.38 7.18
Indian Labour Standard 0.0990 23.05 2.28 105.26 10.42 107.65 10.66 100.00 9.90 106.32 10.53
Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical 0.1277 26.39 3.37 120.48 15.39 107.65 13.75 100.00 12.77 112.66 14.39
Malay Clerical Grades Standard 0.0150 24.63 0.37 104.17 1.56 109.61 1.64 100.00 1.50 111.33 1.67
European Standard 0.1738 34.13 5.93 116.88 20.32 104.44 18.15 100.00 17.38 108.53 18.86
1.0000 27.26 117.03 107.25 100.00 107.01
Chinese Labour Standard 0.2879 37.74 10.86 116.28 33.48 94.72 27.27 100.00 28.79 104.65 30.13
Malay Labour Standard 0.0475 37.45 1.78 102.04 4.85 94.01 4.46 100.00 4.75 118.37 5.62
Indian Labour Standard 0.0513 42.68 2.19 116.28 5.96 94.72 4.86 100.00 5.13 104.65 5.36
Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical 0.0390 37.74 1.47 116.28 4.53 94.72 3.69 100.00 3.90 112.45 4.38
Malay Clerical Grades Standard 0.0044 37.45 0.16 102.04 0.45 94.01 0.41 100.00 0.44 111.61 0.49
European Standard 0.5700 35.84 20.43 121.00 68.98 98.57 56.19 100.00 57.00 106.09 60.48
1.0000 36.90 118.23 96.87 100.00 106.46
Chinese Labour Standard 0.2483 31.69 7.87 107.53 26.70 90.00 22.35 100.00 24.83 103.23 25.63
Malay Labour Standard 0.0259 32.03 0.83 107.53 2.79 99.36 2.58 100.00 2.59 103.23 2.68
Indian Labour Standard 0.0363 31.69 1.15 107.53 3.91 90.00 3.27 100.00 3.63 103.23 3.75
Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical 0.1139 31.69 3.61 107.53 12.25 90.00 10.25 100.00 11.39 103.23 11.76
Malay Clerical Grades Standard 0.0127 31.69 0.40 107.53 1.36 90.00 1.14 100.00 1.27 103.23 1.31
European Standard 0.5629 38.79 21.84 107.53 60.53 90.00 50.66 100.00 56.29 103.23 58.10
1.0000 35.70 107.53 90.24 100.00 103.23
Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical 0.1457 34.36 5.01 116.60 16.98 97.59 14.22 100.00 14.57 104.81 15.27
Malay Clerical Grades Standard 0.0162 34.72 0.56 116.57 1.89 97.57 1.58 100.00 1.62 105.21 1.70
European Standard 0.8382 40.82 34.21 113.13 94.82 94.69 79.37 100.00 83.82 103.67 86.89
1.0000 39.78 113.70 95.16 100.00 103.86
Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical 0.2422 51.28 12.42 123.76 29.97 103.59 25.09 100.00 24.22 105.13 25.46
Malay Clerical Grades Standard 0.0304 51.28 1.56 123.15 3.75 103.08 3.14 100.00 3.04 105.13 3.20
European Standard 0.7274 55.87 40.64 119.47 86.91 100.00 72.74 100.00 72.74 102.79 74.77
1.0000 54.62 120.62 100.96 100.00 103.43
European Standard 1.0000 34.97 34.97 96.92 96.92 101.57 101.57 100.00 100.00 107.34 107.34
0.3558 34.97 96.92 101.57 100.00 107.34
Food 0.49011243 27.26 13.36 117.03 57.36 107.25 52.56 100.00 49.01 107.01 52.45
Tobacco 0.09010465 36.90 3.32 118.23 10.65 96.87 8.73 100.00 9.01 106.46 9.59
Clothing 0.12456521 31.83 3.96 161.54 20.12 99.19 12.36 100.00 12.46 106.79 13.30
Rent 0.09482084 35.70 3.38 107.53 10.20 90.24 8.56 100.00 9.48 103.23 9.79
Servant 0.12216267 39.78 4.86 113.70 13.89 95.16 11.63 100.00 12.22 103.86 12.69
Transport 0.04617403 54.62 2.52 120.62 5.57 100.96 4.66 100.00 4.62 103.43 4.78
Club 0.03206017 34.97 1.12 96.92 3.11 101.57 3.26 100.00 3.21 107.34 3.44
1.00000 32.54 120.90 101.75 100.00 106.04
294
Appendix Table 5(Continued)
Singapore: Computation of Consumer Price Indices by Major Object of
Consumption (1949=100), 1939 and 1947-60
Chinese Labour Standard 0.5188 144.58 75.00 153.01 79.38 143.37 74.38 128.92 66.88 122.89 63.75
Malay Labour Standard 0.0657 141.67 9.30 144.79 9.51 140.63 9.23 127.08 8.34 122.92 8.07
Indian Labour Standard 0.0990 141.05 13.97 146.32 14.49 140.00 13.86 126.32 12.51 121.05 11.99
Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical 0.1277 143.27 18.30 146.44 18.70 141.42 18.06 126.91 16.21 119.79 15.30
Malay Clerical Grades Standard 0.0150 140.89 2.11 143.84 2.16 139.66 2.09 124.38 1.87 116.26 1.74
European Standard 0.1738 137.54 23.91 143.00 24.86 138.57 24.08 131.40 22.84 130.38 22.66
1.0000 142.59 149.09 141.72 128.65 123.52
Chinese Labour Standard 0.2879 136.05 39.17 137.21 39.50 139.53 40.17 146.51 42.18 145.35 41.85
Malay Labour Standard 0.0475 131.63 6.25 131.63 6.25 136.73 6.49 145.92 6.93 143.88 6.83
Indian Labour Standard 0.0513 136.05 6.97 137.21 7.03 139.53 7.15 146.51 7.51 145.35 7.45
Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical 0.0390 119.25 4.65 119.62 4.66 123.77 4.82 133.58 5.21 134.72 5.25
Malay Clerical Grades Standard 0.0044 118.35 0.52 118.73 0.52 122.85 0.54 132.58 0.58 133.71 0.58
European Standard 0.5700 111.83 63.74 114.34 65.17 115.41 65.79 118.28 67.42 118.28 67.42
1.0000 121.30 123.14 124.96 129.83 129.38
Chinese Labour Standard 0.3104 154.10 47.83 149.18 46.31 137.70 42.74 122.95 38.16 118.03 36.64
Malay Labour Standard 0.0415 148.51 6.16 144.55 5.99 129.70 5.38 116.83 4.84 113.86 4.72
Indian Labour Standard 0.0300 148.21 4.45 146.43 4.40 135.71 4.08 121.43 3.65 116.07 3.49
Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical 0.0694 117.63 8.16 111.22 7.71 98.72 6.85 94.87 6.58 93.91 6.51
Malay Clerical Grades Standard 0.0083 117.63 0.98 111.22 0.93 98.72 0.82 94.87 0.79 93.91 0.78
European Standard 0.5404 125.08 67.59 123.78 66.89 114.01 61.61 113.36 61.26 112.38 60.73
1.0000 135.18 132.23 121.48 115.28 112.87
Chinese Labour Standard 0.2483 125.81 31.24 133.33 33.11 140.86 34.97 144.09 35.78 141.94 35.24
Malay Labour Standard 0.0259 125.81 3.26 133.33 3.46 140.86 3.65 144.09 3.74 141.94 3.68
Indian Labour Standard 0.0363 125.81 4.57 133.33 4.84 140.86 5.12 144.09 5.23 141.94 5.16
Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical 0.1139 125.81 14.33 133.33 15.19 140.86 16.05 144.09 16.41 141.94 16.17
Malay Clerical Grades Standard 0.0127 125.81 1.59 133.33 1.69 140.86 1.78 144.09 1.82 141.94 1.80
European Standard 0.5629 125.81 70.81 133.33 75.05 140.86 79.29 144.09 81.10 141.94 79.89
1.0000 125.81 133.33 140.86 144.09 141.94
Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical 0.1457 127.84 18.62 146.39 21.32 154.98 22.57 154.98 22.57 154.30 22.47
Malay Clerical Grades Standard 0.0162 128.13 2.07 146.88 2.38 159.03 2.57 155.56 2.52 154.86 2.51
European Standard 0.8382 116.33 97.50 128.57 107.76 135.92 113.92 138.37 115.97 139.59 117.00
1.0000 118.19 131.46 139.07 141.07 141.98
Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical 0.2422 129.23 31.30 122.56 29.68 109.74 26.58 106.67 25.83 109.23 26.45
Malay Clerical Grades Standard 0.0304 129.23 3.93 122.56 3.73 109.74 3.34 106.67 3.24 109.23 3.32
European Standard 0.7274 110.06 80.06 111.17 80.87 111.17 80.87 110.06 80.06 110.61 80.46
1.0000 115.28 114.28 110.78 109.13 110.24
European Standard 1.0000 125.00 125.00 129.02 129.02 127.27 127.27 125.00 125.00 124.48 124.48
0.3558 125.00 129.02 127.27 125.00 124.48
Food 0.49011243 142.59 69.89 149.09 73.07 141.72 69.46 128.65 63.05 123.52 60.54
Tobacco 0.09010465 121.30 10.93 123.14 11.10 124.96 11.26 129.83 11.70 129.38 11.66
Clothing 0.12456521 135.18 16.84 132.23 16.47 121.48 15.13 115.28 14.36 112.87 14.06
Rent 0.09482084 125.81 11.93 133.33 12.64 140.86 13.36 144.09 13.66 141.94 13.46
Servant 0.12216267 118.19 14.44 131.46 16.06 139.07 16.99 141.07 17.23 141.98 17.34
Transport 0.04617403 115.28 5.32 114.28 5.28 110.78 5.12 109.13 5.04 110.24 5.09
Club 0.03206017 125.00 4.01 129.02 4.14 127.27 4.08 125.00 4.01 124.48 3.99
1.00000 133.35 138.75 135.39 129.05 126.14
295
Appendix Table 5(Continued)
Singapore: Computation of Consumer Price Indices by Major Object of
Consumption (1949=100), 1939 and 1947-60
Chinese Labour Standard 0.5188 122.89 63.75 128.92 66.88 126.51 65.63 121.69 63.13 121.69 63.13
Malay Labour Standard 0.0657 123.96 8.14 130.21 8.55 128.13 8.41 123.96 8.14 122.72 8.06
Indian Labour Standard 0.0990 124.21 12.30 131.58 13.03 127.37 12.61 123.16 12.20 121.93 12.07
Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical 0.1277 119.26 15.23 122.96 15.71 120.58 15.40 118.73 15.17 118.73 15.17
Malay Clerical Grades Standard 0.0150 116.75 1.75 120.94 1.81 118.97 1.78 116.50 1.75 116.50 1.75
European Standard 0.1738 132.76 23.08 136.52 23.73 137.20 23.85 139.25 24.20 139.25 24.20
1.0000 124.25 129.70 127.69 124.58 124.38
Chinese Labour Standard 0.2879 146.51 42.18 151.16 43.52 150.00 43.18 147.67 42.52 147.67 42.52
Malay Labour Standard 0.0475 144.90 6.88 145.92 6.93 145.92 6.93 144.90 6.88 143.45 6.81
Indian Labour Standard 0.0513 146.51 7.51 151.16 7.75 150.00 7.69 147.67 7.57 147.67 7.57
Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical 0.0390 134.72 5.25 135.09 5.26 135.85 5.29 135.85 5.29 135.85 5.29
Malay Clerical Grades Standard 0.0044 133.71 0.58 133.71 0.58 134.08 0.58 134.83 0.59 134.83 0.59
European Standard 0.5700 118.28 67.42 118.64 67.63 119.35 68.04 119.71 68.24 119.71 68.24
1.0000 129.83 131.67 131.72 131.09 131.02
Chinese Labour Standard 0.3104 116.39 36.13 116.39 36.13 113.11 35.11 108.20 33.58 109.28 33.92
Malay Labour Standard 0.0415 116.83 4.84 120.79 5.01 116.83 4.84 110.89 4.60 113.11 4.69
Indian Labour Standard 0.0300 119.64 3.59 132.14 3.97 128.57 3.86 128.57 3.86 131.14 3.94
Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical 0.0694 94.23 6.54 95.83 6.65 96.79 6.71 97.44 6.76 97.44 6.76
Malay Clerical Grades Standard 0.0083 93.91 0.78 95.83 0.80 96.79 0.81 97.44 0.81 97.44 0.81
European Standard 0.5404 112.38 60.73 114.33 61.79 115.96 62.67 115.64 62.49 115.64 62.49
1.0000 112.61 114.34 114.00 112.10 112.61
Chinese Labour Standard 0.2483 150.54 37.38 154.84 38.44 158.06 39.25 160.22 39.78 160.22 39.78
Malay Labour Standard 0.0259 150.54 3.90 154.84 4.01 158.06 4.10 160.22 4.15 160.22 4.15
Indian Labour Standard 0.0363 150.54 5.47 154.84 5.62 158.06 5.74 160.22 5.82 160.22 5.82
Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical 0.1139 150.54 17.15 154.84 17.64 158.06 18.01 160.22 18.25 160.22 18.25
Malay Clerical Grades Standard 0.0127 150.54 1.91 154.84 1.96 158.06 2.00 160.22 2.03 160.22 2.03
European Standard 0.5629 150.54 84.74 154.84 87.16 158.06 88.97 160.22 90.18 160.22 90.18
1.0000 150.54 154.84 158.06 160.22 160.22
Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical 0.1457 154.98 22.57 154.98 22.57 154.98 22.57 154.98 22.57 154.98 22.57
Malay Clerical Grades Standard 0.0162 155.56 2.52 155.56 2.52 155.56 2.52 155.56 2.52 155.56 2.52
European Standard 0.8382 140.00 117.34 140.00 117.34 140.00 117.34 140.00 117.34 140.00 117.34
1.0000 142.43 142.43 142.43 142.43 142.43
Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical 0.2422 107.69 26.08 108.21 26.20 108.72 26.33 107.69 26.08 108.77 26.34
Malay Clerical Grades Standard 0.0304 107.69 3.28 108.21 3.29 108.72 3.31 107.69 3.28 108.77 3.31
European Standard 0.7274 113.41 82.49 118.44 86.15 118.99 86.56 121.79 88.59 123.01 89.47
1.0000 111.85 115.65 116.19 117.95 119.12
European Standard 1.0000 125.70 125.70 127.80 127.80 128.50 128.50 129.72 129.72 131.02 131.02
0.3558 125.70 127.80 128.50 129.72 131.02
Food 0.49011243 124.25 60.90 129.70 63.57 127.69 62.58 124.58 61.06 124.38 60.96
Tobacco 0.09010465 129.83 11.70 131.67 11.86 131.72 11.87 131.09 11.81 131.02 11.81
Clothing 0.12456521 112.61 14.03 114.34 14.24 114.00 14.20 112.10 13.96 112.61 14.03
Rent 0.09482084 150.54 14.27 154.84 14.68 158.06 14.99 160.22 15.19 160.22 15.19
Servant 0.12216267 142.43 17.40 142.43 17.40 142.43 17.40 142.43 17.40 142.43 17.40
Transport 0.04617403 111.85 5.16 115.65 5.34 116.19 5.37 117.95 5.45 119.12 5.50
Club 0.03206017 125.70 4.03 127.80 4.10 128.50 4.12 129.72 4.16 131.02 4.20
1.00000 127.49 131.20 130.52 129.03 129.08
296
Appendix Table 6
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
European Standard –Food in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita European Total Real Private Food Price Total Private Final
Capita Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Private Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Food in the
Expenditure (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Food in the Domestic Market
in Real Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
Terms (1914 of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita European Total Real Private Food Price Total Private Final
Capita Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Private Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Food in the
Expenditure (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Food in the Domestic Market
in Real Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
Terms (1914 of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
297
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Eurasian Standard [1899-1939] Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical Standard
[1947-1960]– Food in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Eurasian Total Real Private Food Price Total Private Final
Capita Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Private Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Food in the
Expenditure (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Food in the Domestic Market
in Real Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
Terms (1914 of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Chinese, Total Real Private Food Price Total Private Final
Capita Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Indian and Final Indices Consumption
Private Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Eurasian Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Clerical Expenditure on Food in the
Expenditure (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Population Food in the Domestic Market
in Real Income Elasticities Standard Domestic Market (Current Prices)
Terms (1914 of Demand (Numbers) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
298
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Asiatic Clerical Standard [1899-1939] Malay Clerical Standard [1947-1960]– Food
in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Asiatic Total Real Private Food Price Total Private Final
Capita Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Clerical Final Indices Consumption
Private Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on Food in the
Expenditure (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Food in the Domestic Market
in Real Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
Terms (1914 of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Malay Total Real Private Food Price Total Private Final
Capita Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Clerical Final Indices Consumption
Private Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on Food in the
Expenditure (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Food in the Domestic Market
in Real Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
Terms (1914 of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
299
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Chinese Labour Standard – Food in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Chinese Total Real Private Food Price Total Private Final
Capita Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Labour Final Indices Consumption
Private Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on Food in the
Expenditure (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Food in the Domestic Market
in Real Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
Terms (1914 of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Chinese Total Real Private Food Price Total Private Final
Capita Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Labour Final Indices Consumption
Private Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on Food in the
Expenditure (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Food in the Domestic Market
in Real Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
Terms (1914 of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
300
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Malay Labour Standard – Food in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Malay Labour Total Real Private Food Price Total Private Final
Capita Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Private Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Food in the
Expenditure (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Food in the Domestic Market
in Real Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
Terms (1914 of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Malay Labour Total Real Private Food Price Total Private Final
Capita Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Private Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Food in the
Expenditure (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Food in the Domestic Market
in Real Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
Terms (1914 of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
301
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Indian Labour Standard – Food in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Indian Labour Total Real Private Food Price Total Private Final
Capita Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Private Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Food in the
Expenditure (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Food in the Domestic Market
in Real Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
Terms (1914 of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Indian Labour Total Real Private Food Price Total Private Final
Capita Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Private Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Food in the
Expenditure (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Food in the Domestic Market
in Real Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
Terms (1914 of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
302
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
European Standard –Beverages and Tobacco in Current and 1914 Prices,
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita European Total Real Private Beverage Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final and Tobacco Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption Price Indices Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on (1914=100) Beverages and
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Beverage and Tobacco in the
Real Terms Income Elasticities Tobacco in the Domestic Market
(1914 Prices) of Demand Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita European Total Real Private Beverage Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final and Tobacco Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption Price Indices Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on (1914=100) Beverages and
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Beverage and Tobacco in the
Real Terms Income Elasticities Tobacco in the Domestic Market
(1914 Prices) of Demand Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
303
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Eurasian Standard [1899-1939] Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical Standard
[1947-1960]– Beverages and Tobacco in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Eurasian Total Real Private Beverage Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final and Tobacco Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption Price Indices Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on (1914=100) Beverages and
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Beverage and Tobacco in the
Real Terms Income Elasticities Tobacco in the Domestic Market
(1914 Prices) of Demand Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Chinese, Total Real Private Beverage Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Indian and Final and Tobacco Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Eurasian Consumption Price Indices Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Clerical Expenditure on (1914=100) Beverages and
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Population Beverage and Tobacco in the
Real Terms Income Elasticities Standard Tobacco in the Domestic Market
(1914 Prices) of Demand (Numbers) Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
304
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Asiatic Clerical Standard [1899-1939] Malay Clerical Standard [1947-1960]–
Beverages and Tobacco in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Asiatic Total Real Private Beverage Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Clerical Final and Tobacco Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption Price Indices Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on (1914=100) Beverages and
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Beverage and Tobacco in the
Real Terms Income Elasticities Tobacco in the Domestic Market
(1914 Prices) of Demand Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Malay Total Real Private Beverage Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Clerical Final and Tobacco Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption Price Indices Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on (1914=100) Beverages and
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Beverage and Tobacco in the
Real Terms Income Elasticities Tobacco in the Domestic Market
(1914 Prices) of Demand Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
305
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Chinese Labour Standard – Beverages and Tobacco in Current and 1914 Prices,
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Chinese Total Real Private Beverage Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Labour Final and Tobacco Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption Price Indices Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on (1914=100) Beverages and
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Beverage and Tobacco in the
Real Terms Income Elasticities Tobacco in the Domestic Market
(1914 Prices) of Demand Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Chinese Total Real Private Beverage Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Labour Final and Tobacco Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption Price Indices Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on (1914=100) Beverages and
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Beverage and Tobacco in the
Real Terms Income Elasticities Tobacco in the Domestic Market
(1914 Prices) of Demand Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
306
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Malay Labour Standard – Beverages and Tobacco in Current and 1914 Prices,
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Malay Total Real Private Beverage Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Labour Final and Tobacco Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption Price Indices Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on (1914=100) Beverages and
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Beverage and Tobacco in the
Real Terms Income Elasticities Tobacco in the Domestic Market
(1914 Prices) of Demand Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Malay Total Real Private Beverage Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Labour Final and Tobacco Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption Price Indices Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on (1914=100) Beverages and
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Beverage and Tobacco in the
Real Terms Income Elasticities Tobacco in the Domestic Market
(1914 Prices) of Demand Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
307
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Indian Labour Standard – Beverages and Tobacco in Current and 1914 Prices,
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Indian Total Real Private Beverage Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Labour Final and Tobacco Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption Price Indices Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on (1914=100) Beverages and
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Beverage and Tobacco in the
Real Terms Income Elasticities Tobacco in the Domestic Market
(1914 Prices) of Demand Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Indian Total Real Private Beverage Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Labour Final and Tobacco Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption Price Indices Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on (1914=100) Beverages and
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Beverage and Tobacco in the
Real Terms Income Elasticities Tobacco in the Domestic Market
(1914 Prices) of Demand Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (Straits $)
308
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
European Standard –Clothing in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita European Total Real Private Clothing Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Clothing in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Clothing in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita European Total Real Private Clothing Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Clothing in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Clothing in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
309
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Eurasian Standard [1899-1939] Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical Standard
[1947-1960]–Clothing in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Eurasian Total Real Private Clothing Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Clothing in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Clothing in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Chinese, Total Real Private Clothing Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Indian and Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Eurasian Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Clerical Expenditure on Clothing in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Population Clothing in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Standard Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (Numbers) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
310
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Asiatic Clerical Standard [1899-1939] Malay Clerical Standard [1947-1960]–
Clothing in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Asiatic Total Real Private Clothing Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Clerical Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on Clothing in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Clothing in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Malay Total Real Private Clothing Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Clerical Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on Clothing in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Clothing in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
311
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Chinese Labour Standard –Clothing in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Chinese Total Real Private Clothing Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Labour Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on Clothing in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Clothing in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Chinese Total Real Private Clothing Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Labour Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on Clothing in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Clothing in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
312
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Malay Labour Standard –Clothing in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Malay Labour Total Real Private Clothing Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Clothing in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Clothing in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Malay Labour Total Real Private Clothing Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Clothing in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Clothing in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
313
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Indian Labour Standard –Clothing in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Indian Labour Total Real Private Clothing Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Clothing in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Clothing in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Indian Labour Total Real Private Clothing Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Clothing in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Clothing in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
314
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
European Standard –Rent in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita European Total Real Private Rent Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Rent in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Rent in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita European Total Real Private Rent Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Rent in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Rent in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
315
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Eurasian Standard [1899-1939] Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical Standard
[1947-1960]–Rent in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Eurasian Total Real Private Rent Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Rent in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Rent in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Chinese, Total Real Private Rent Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Indian and Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Eurasian Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Clerical Expenditure on Rent in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Population Rent in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Standard Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (Numbers) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
316
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Asiatic Clerical Standard [1899-1939] Malay Clerical Standard [1947-1960]–Rent
in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Asiatic Total Real Private Rent Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Clerical Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on Rent in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Rent in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Malay Total Real Private Rent Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Clerical Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on Rent in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Rent in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
317
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Chinese Labour Standard –Rent in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Chinese Total Real Private Rent Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Labour Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on Rent in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Rent in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Chinese Total Real Private Rent Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Labour Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on Rent in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Rent in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
318
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Malay Labour Standard –Rent in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Malay Labour Total Real Private Rent Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Rent in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Rent in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Malay Labour Total Real Private Rent Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Rent in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Rent in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
319
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Indian Labour Standard –Rent in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Indian Labour Total Real Private Rent Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Rent in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Rent in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Indian Labour Total Real Private Rent Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Rent in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Rent in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
320
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
European Standard –Servant in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita European Total Real Private Servant Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Servant in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Servant in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
STEP 4 STEP 5 STEP 6 STEP 7 STEP 8 STEP 9 STEP 10 STEP 11
[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7]=[5]x[6] [8] [9]=[7]x[8]/100
1899 116.03 384.73 13,667 5,258,236 69.64 3,661,986
1900 113.92 -1.814% -1.814% 377.75 13,566 5,124,542 75.00 3,843,406
1901 112.77 -1.008% -1.008% 373.94 13,911 5,201,793 73.21 3,808,456
1902 108.67 -3.637% -3.637% 360.34 14,310 5,156,672 82.14 4,235,837
1903 107.35 -1.214% -1.214% 355.97 14,720 5,239,718 82.14 4,304,054
1904 107.24 -0.106% -0.106% 355.59 15,141 5,383,876 78.57 4,230,188
1905 105.29 -1.816% -1.816% 349.13 15,575 5,437,920 78.57 4,272,652
1906 106.94 1.562% 1.562% 354.59 16,023 5,681,407 82.14 4,666,870
1907 107.05 0.102% 0.102% 354.95 16,483 5,850,629 91.07 5,328,251
1908 107.87 0.772% 0.772% 357.69 16,958 6,065,542 91.07 5,523,976
1909 110.50 2.437% 2.437% 366.41 17,445 6,392,082 91.07 5,821,360
1910 108.44 -1.861% -1.861% 359.59 17,946 6,453,095 91.07 5,876,926
1911 98.90 -8.802% -8.802% 327.94 18,503 6,067,692 91.07 5,525,934
1912 97.22 -1.696% -1.696% 322.38 19,118 6,163,108 91.07 5,612,830
1913 95.24 -2.036% -2.036% 315.81 19,750 6,237,336 91.07 5,680,431
1914 100.00 4.995% 4.995% 331.59 20,400 6,764,493 100.00 6,764,493
1915 93.86 -6.142% -6.142% 311.22 21,069 6,557,037 103.82 6,807,662
1916 88.38 -5.833% -5.833% 293.07 21,756 6,376,054 103.82 6,619,761
1917 100.72 13.954% 13.954% 333.96 22,464 7,502,043 113.09 8,484,215
1918 104.36 3.614% 3.614% 346.03 23,192 8,025,152 116.80 9,373,377
1919 92.87 -11.007% -11.007% 307.95 23,941 7,372,472 116.80 8,611,047
1920 89.13 -4.028% -4.028% 295.54 24,711 7,303,157 155.50 11,356,409
1921 112.82 26.583% 26.583% 374.11 27,757 10,384,029 155.50 16,147,166
1922 123.66 9.603% 9.603% 410.03 29,018 11,898,246 155.50 18,501,772
1923 126.94 2.658% 2.658% 420.93 30,082 12,662,326 155.50 19,689,916
1924 127.47 0.412% 0.412% 422.67 31,165 13,172,465 155.50 20,483,183
1925 124.53 -2.308% -2.308% 412.92 32,515 13,425,879 155.50 20,877,242
1926 120.44 -3.285% -3.285% 399.35 33,811 13,502,307 155.50 20,996,088
1927 127.57 5.925% 5.925% 423.01 35,143 14,865,972 155.50 23,116,586
1928 131.90 3.394% 3.394% 437.37 36,493 15,961,166 155.50 24,819,613
1929 131.51 -0.296% -0.296% 436.08 37,864 16,511,488 155.50 25,675,365
1930 428.52 129.23 -1.734% -1.734% 428.52 37,403 16,027,883 152.90 24,506,633
1931 115.38 -10.717% -10.717% 382.59 36,586 13,997,596 138.00 19,316,682
1932 122.09 5.817% 5.817% 404.85 35,489 14,367,695 124.70 17,916,516
1933 136.87 12.102% 12.102% 453.84 33,443 15,177,534 115.80 17,575,584
1934 130.38 -4.738% -4.738% 432.34 34,140 14,759,922 123.70 18,258,023
1935 137.02 5.092% 5.092% 454.35 37,200 16,901,906 127.40 21,533,029
1936 148.89 8.661% 8.661% 493.70 39,206 19,355,820 125.70 24,330,265
1937 150.08 0.798% 0.798% 497.64 42,347 21,073,265 130.00 27,395,245
1938 155.10 3.348% 3.348% 514.30 46,152 23,736,088 128.20 30,429,665
1939 154.06 -0.672% -0.672% 510.84 47,292 24,158,540 128.20 30,971,248
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita European Total Real Private Servant Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Servant in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Servant in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
321
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Eurasian Standard [1899-1939] Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical Standard
[1947-1960]–Servant in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Eurasian Total Real Private Servant Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Servant in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Servant in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Chinese, Total Real Private Servant Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Indian and Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Eurasian Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Clerical Expenditure on Servant in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Population Servant in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Standard Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (Numbers) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
322
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Asiatic Clerical Standard [1899-1939] Malay Clerical Standard [1947-1960]–
Servant in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Asiatic Total Real Private Servant Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Clerical Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on Servant in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Servant in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Malay Total Real Private Servant Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Clerical Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on Servant in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and (Numbers) Servant in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
323
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
European Standard –Transport in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita European Total Real Private Transport Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Transport in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Real Wages and Transport in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) Prices) (Straits $) (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita European Total Real Private Transport Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Transport in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Real Wages and Transport in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) Prices) (Straits $) (Straits $)
324
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Eurasian Standard [1899-1939] Chinese, Indian and Eurasian Clerical Standard
[1947-1960]–Transport in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Eurasian Total Real Private Transport Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Transport in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Real Wages and Transport in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
STEP 4 STEP 5 STEP 6 STEP 7 STEP 8 STEP 9 STEP 10 STEP 11
[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7]=[5]x[6] [8] [9]=[7]x[8]/100
1899 116.03 27.82 2,278 63,378 109.66 69,502
1900 113.92 -1.814% -1.814% 27.32 2,261 61,766 107.87 66,630
1901 112.77 -1.008% -1.008% 27.04 2,318 62,697 107.44 67,364
1902 108.67 -3.637% -3.637% 26.06 2,385 62,154 107.23 66,646
1903 107.35 -1.214% -1.214% 25.74 2,453 63,155 107.34 67,787
1904 107.24 -0.106% -0.106% 25.72 2,523 64,892 107.23 69,582
1905 105.29 -1.816% -1.816% 25.25 2,596 65,543 107.12 70,210
1906 106.94 1.562% 1.562% 25.64 2,670 68,478 107.23 73,428
1907 107.05 0.102% 0.102% 25.67 2,747 70,518 105.07 74,093
1908 107.87 0.772% 0.772% 25.87 2,826 73,108 104.64 76,499
1909 110.50 2.437% 2.437% 26.50 2,908 77,044 103.67 79,870
1910 108.44 -1.861% -1.861% 26.00 2,991 77,779 103.24 80,297
1911 98.90 -8.802% -8.802% 23.72 3,084 73,134 102.91 75,264
1912 97.22 -1.696% -1.696% 23.31 3,186 74,284 103.02 76,528
1913 95.24 -2.036% -2.036% 22.84 3,292 75,179 99.46 74,773
1914 100.00 4.995% 4.995% 23.98 3,400 81,533 100.00 81,533
1915 93.86 -6.142% -6.142% 22.51 3,511 79,032 101.83 80,479
1916 88.38 -5.833% -5.833% 21.19 3,626 76,851 103.13 79,256
1917 100.72 13.954% 13.954% 24.15 3,744 90,422 108.64 98,235
1918 104.36 3.614% 3.614% 25.02 3,865 96,727 112.50 108,818
1919 92.87 -11.007% -11.007% 22.27 3,990 88,861 122.90 109,210
1920 89.13 -4.028% -4.028% 21.37 4,118 88,025 126.80 111,616
1921 112.82 26.583% 26.583% 27.05 4,270 115,531 122.80 141,873
1922 123.66 9.603% 9.603% 29.65 4,464 132,378 112.00 148,264
1923 126.94 2.658% 2.658% 30.44 4,628 140,880 94.80 133,554
1924 127.47 0.412% 0.412% 30.57 4,795 146,555 99.40 145,676
1925 124.53 -2.308% -2.308% 29.86 5,002 149,375 105.30 157,292
1926 120.44 -3.285% -3.285% 28.88 5,202 150,225 103.50 155,483
1927 127.57 5.925% 5.925% 30.59 5,407 165,397 94.20 155,804
1928 131.90 3.394% 3.394% 31.63 5,614 177,582 93.10 165,329
1929 131.51 -0.296% -0.296% 31.54 5,825 183,705 89.70 164,783
1930 30.99 129.23 -1.734% -1.734% 30.99 5,754 178,324 85.50 152,467
1931 115.38 -10.717% -10.717% 27.67 2,814 77,868 96.20 74,909
1932 122.09 5.817% 5.817% 29.28 2,730 79,927 89.00 71,135
1933 136.87 12.102% 12.102% 32.82 2,573 84,432 85.40 72,105
1934 130.38 -4.738% -4.738% 31.27 2,626 82,109 84.50 69,382
1935 137.02 5.092% 5.092% 32.86 2,862 94,024 82.40 77,476
1936 148.89 8.661% 8.661% 35.70 3,016 107,675 80.00 86,140
1937 150.08 0.798% 0.798% 35.99 3,257 117,229 81.40 95,425
1938 155.10 3.348% 3.348% 37.19 3,550 132,042 81.50 107,615
1939 154.06 -0.672% -0.672% 36.94 3,638 134,393 82.18 110,441
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Chinese, Total Real Private Transport Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Indian and Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Eurasian Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Clerical Expenditure on Transport in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Real Wages and Population Transport in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Standard Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (Numbers) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
325
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
Asiatic Clerical Standard [1899-1939] Malay Clerical Standard [1947-1960]–
Transport in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Asiatic Total Real Private Transport Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Clerical Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on Transport in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Real Wages and (Numbers) Transport in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita Malay Total Real Private Transport Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Clerical Final Price Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Population Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based Standard Expenditure on Transport in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Real Wages and (Numbers) Transport in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
326
Appendix Table 6 (Continued)
Singapore: Computation of PFCE in the Domestic Market, 1900-39 and 1948-60,
European Standard –Club in Current and 1914 Prices, (Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita European Total Real Private Club Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Club in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Club in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
Year Annual Per Weighted Real Wage Changes in Changes in Real Per Capita European Total Real Private Club Price Total Private Final
Capita Private Indices of Real Wages Real Private Final Population Final Indices Consumption
Final Agriculture and Non- (%) Consumption Consumption Standard Consumption (1914=100) Expenditure on
Consumption agriculture Sectors (%) Expenditure based (Numbers) Expenditure on Club in the
Expenditure in (1914=100 ) on Rel Wages and Club in the Domestic Market
Real Terms Income Elasticities Domestic Market (Current Prices)
(1914 Prices) of Demand (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $) (1914 Prices) (Straits $)
(Straits $)
327
Appendix Table 7
Total Private Final Consumption Expenditure by ajor Object of Consumption and Standard in Constant Prices,
Singapore,1900-39 and 1947-1960
(Straits $)
Food Total Beverages & Tobacco
Year European Eurasian Asiatic Clerical Chinese Labour Malay Labour Indian Labour Total European Standard Eurasian Asiatic Clerical Chinese Labour Malay Labour Indian Labour Total
Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard
1899 5,439,107 294,754 2,365,451 10,676,299 3,102,431 1,353,955 23,231,996 1,237,123 10,389 88,304 634,748 240,359 142,574 2,353,498
1900 5,330,194 288,852 2,318,085 10,462,517 3,040,308 1,326,844 22,766,800 1,205,668 10,125 86,059 623,181 235,979 138,949 2,299,961
1901 5,427,068 294,102 2,360,215 10,652,668 3,095,564 1,350,958 23,180,574 1,223,844 10,277 87,356 635,151 240,512 141,044 2,338,184
1902 5,440,909 294,852 2,366,234 10,679,836 3,103,458 1,354,404 23,239,693 1,213,228 10,188 86,598 639,147 242,025 139,820 2,331,007
1903 5,548,916 300,705 2,413,206 10,891,840 3,165,065 1,381,290 23,701,021 1,232,766 10,352 87,993 652,633 247,132 142,072 2,372,949
1904 5,703,397 309,076 2,480,389 11,195,067 3,253,180 1,419,745 24,360,854 1,266,683 10,637 90,414 670,873 254,039 145,981 2,438,627
1905 5,792,605 313,911 2,519,186 11,370,172 3,304,063 1,441,951 24,741,887 1,279,398 10,744 91,322 682,620 258,487 147,446 2,470,016
1906 6,024,044 326,453 2,619,838 11,824,459 3,436,075 1,499,563 25,730,431 1,336,684 11,225 95,411 708,796 268,399 154,048 2,574,563
1907 6,201,579 336,074 2,697,047 12,172,938 3,537,340 1,543,757 26,488,733 1,376,497 11,559 98,252 729,611 276,281 158,636 2,650,837
1908 6,414,603 347,618 2,789,691 12,591,079 3,658,847 1,596,785 27,398,623 1,427,061 11,984 101,862 754,094 285,552 164,464 2,745,015
1909 6,711,682 363,717 2,918,889 13,174,207 3,828,299 1,670,737 28,667,532 1,503,887 12,629 107,345 787,127 298,060 173,318 2,882,366
1910 6,814,297 369,278 2,963,516 13,375,628 3,886,830 1,696,281 29,105,829 1,518,242 12,749 108,370 800,668 303,188 174,972 2,918,190
1911 6,592,851 357,277 2,968,406 13,093,203 3,551,601 1,641,156 28,204,494 1,427,567 11,988 105,494 791,114 279,638 164,522 2,780,323
1912 6,731,180 364,774 3,030,688 13,367,921 3,626,119 1,675,590 28,796,272 1,450,015 12,176 107,153 809,099 285,995 167,109 2,831,548
1913 6,854,720 371,468 3,086,311 13,613,267 3,692,671 1,706,343 29,324,781 1,467,479 12,323 108,444 825,651 291,845 169,122 2,874,864
1914 7,327,950 397,113 3,299,381 14,553,088 3,947,602 1,824,144 31,349,279 1,591,505 13,365 117,609 878,391 310,488 183,415 3,094,773
1915 7,242,660 392,491 3,260,980 14,383,705 3,901,656 1,802,913 30,984,406 1,542,697 12,955 114,002 873,739 308,843 177,790 3,030,026
1916 7,173,622 388,750 3,229,896 14,246,597 3,864,465 1,785,727 30,689,057 1,500,116 12,597 110,855 870,673 307,760 172,883 2,974,884
1917 8,130,391 440,599 3,660,677 16,146,711 4,379,881 2,023,895 34,782,154 1,765,031 14,822 130,432 974,253 344,372 203,414 3,432,324
1918 8,606,305 466,390 3,874,956 17,091,862 4,636,258 2,142,365 36,818,134 1,888,105 15,855 139,527 1,027,646 363,245 217,597 3,651,976
1919 8,199,725 444,356 3,691,895 16,284,408 4,417,232 2,041,155 35,078,771 1,734,547 14,566 128,179 990,775 350,212 199,900 3,418,179
1920 8,224,894 445,720 3,703,227 16,334,393 4,430,791 2,047,420 35,186,445 1,718,239 14,429 126,974 997,935 352,743 198,021 3,408,340
1921 10,957,825 548,144 5,692,752 20,188,023 4,166,847 2,877,603 44,431,195 2,443,086 18,938 208,314 1,205,725 324,295 297,027 4,497,385
1922 12,225,691 611,566 6,351,428 22,523,862 4,648,969 3,210,554 49,572,071 2,799,341 21,699 238,691 1,333,129 358,562 340,340 5,091,761
1923 12,909,727 645,784 6,706,794 23,784,087 4,909,082 3,390,186 52,345,661 2,979,109 23,093 254,019 1,404,044 377,635 362,196 5,400,096
1924 13,413,301 670,974 6,968,408 24,711,841 5,100,572 3,522,428 54,387,524 3,099,131 24,023 264,253 1,458,213 392,205 376,788 5,614,612
1925 13,768,225 688,728 7,152,797 25,365,732 5,235,537 3,615,634 55,826,654 3,158,753 24,485 269,336 1,500,309 403,527 384,037 5,740,447
1926 13,987,688 699,707 7,266,811 25,770,056 5,318,990 3,673,266 56,716,518 3,176,734 24,625 270,870 1,529,348 411,338 386,223 5,799,137
1927 15,141,927 757,445 7,866,456 27,896,556 5,757,904 3,976,378 61,396,665 3,497,568 27,111 298,226 1,646,128 442,747 425,230 6,337,010
1928 16,097,336 805,238 8,362,805 29,656,743 6,121,210 4,227,275 65,270,606 3,755,238 29,109 320,197 1,744,191 469,122 456,557 6,774,414
1929 16,667,209 833,744 8,658,862 30,706,641 6,337,911 4,376,928 67,581,294 3,884,714 30,112 331,237 1,806,475 485,874 472,298 7,010,712
1930 16,264,686 813,609 8,449,746 29,965,058 6,184,846 4,271,222 65,949,168 3,770,935 29,230 321,535 1,765,942 474,972 458,465 6,821,080
1931 14,715,907 368,067 7,645,132 28,232,001 4,304,542 4,347,565 59,613,214 3,293,262 12,764 280,806 1,683,084 334,402 450,439 6,054,758
1932 14,855,891 371,568 7,717,856 28,500,555 4,345,488 4,388,921 60,180,279 3,380,337 13,101 288,230 1,689,597 335,696 462,349 6,169,311
1933 15,185,011 379,800 7,888,838 29,131,961 4,441,759 4,486,154 61,513,524 3,570,870 13,840 304,476 1,707,761 339,305 488,409 6,424,663
1934 14,987,527 374,861 7,786,242 28,753,094 4,383,993 4,427,810 60,713,527 3,472,617 13,459 296,099 1,693,811 336,534 474,971 6,287,491
1935 16,913,087 423,022 8,786,599 32,447,220 4,947,238 4,996,684 68,513,850 3,976,569 15,412 339,069 1,902,031 377,904 543,899 7,154,884
1936 18,905,496 472,855 9,821,685 36,269,593 5,530,036 5,585,307 76,584,972 4,553,910 17,650 388,297 2,108,734 418,972 622,866 8,110,429
1937 20,534,128 513,590 10,667,783 39,394,071 6,006,426 6,066,459 83,182,457 4,957,979 19,216 422,751 2,288,577 454,704 678,132 8,821,359
1938 22,904,054 572,865 11,898,996 43,940,700 6,699,652 6,766,614 92,782,881 5,584,471 21,644 476,170 2,544,360 505,524 763,821 9,895,990
1939 23,359,018 584,244 12,135,356 44,813,534 6,832,733 6,901,025 94,625,911 5,683,862 22,029 484,644 2,596,653 515,914 777,416 10,080,519
European Malay Clerical Chinese, Indian, Chinese Labour Malay Labour Indian Labour Total European Standard Malay Clerical Chinese, Indian, Chinese Labour Malay Labour Indian Labour Total
Standard Standard Eurasian Clerical Standard Standard Standard Standard Eurasian Clerical Standard Standard Standard
Grades Standard Grades Standard
1947 18,255,364 1,536,486 14,880,415 48,347,790 6,119,372 9,228,276 98,367,703 9,042,300 66,009 594,080 3,664,934 604,470 652,519 14,624,311
1948 19,882,898 1,673,470 16,207,060 52,658,176 6,664,937 10,051,011 107,137,551 10,100,362 73,733 663,595 4,093,777 675,200 728,872 16,335,539
1949 23,439,406 1,972,808 19,106,061 62,077,288 7,857,112 11,848,863 126,301,538 12,600,687 91,985 827,866 5,107,184 842,345 909,302 20,379,370
1950 23,165,302 1,949,738 18,882,632 61,351,347 7,765,230 11,710,300 124,824,549 12,150,708 88,700 798,302 4,924,803 812,264 876,830 19,651,608
1951 22,381,866 1,883,799 18,244,033 59,276,484 7,502,615 11,314,265 120,603,062 11,329,303 82,704 744,336 4,591,879 757,354 817,555 18,323,131
1952 23,153,681 1,948,759 18,873,159 61,320,570 7,761,334 11,704,426 124,761,929 11,619,665 84,824 763,413 4,709,566 776,764 838,509 18,792,741
1953 27,435,948 2,309,182 22,363,745 72,661,792 9,196,791 13,869,156 147,836,614 14,403,412 105,145 946,305 5,837,846 962,855 1,039,392 23,294,955
1954 28,972,205 2,438,483 23,615,987 76,730,440 9,711,759 14,645,750 156,114,625 15,263,446 111,423 1,002,810 6,186,426 1,020,348 1,101,455 24,685,908
1955 29,873,146 2,514,312 24,350,367 79,116,505 10,013,763 15,101,185 160,969,277 15,641,213 114,181 1,027,629 6,339,539 1,045,601 1,128,715 25,296,880
1956 34,157,654 2,874,923 27,842,779 90,463,664 11,449,971 17,267,048 184,056,039 18,506,546 135,098 1,215,881 7,500,887 1,237,146 1,335,486 29,931,045
1957 34,395,185 1,929,943 38,420,248 82,742,576 12,810,660 17,387,123 187,685,735 18,260,581 88,868 1,644,063 6,722,752 1,356,338 1,317,737 29,390,339
1958 35,962,661 2,017,896 40,171,155 86,513,364 13,394,474 18,179,498 196,239,048 19,080,983 92,861 1,717,926 7,024,789 1,417,274 1,376,939 30,710,772
1959 34,937,265 1,960,360 39,025,764 84,046,628 13,012,560 17,661,150 190,643,727 17,949,441 87,354 1,616,050 6,608,204 1,333,227 1,295,284 28,889,559
1960 40,871,439 2,293,332 45,654,378 98,322,138 15,222,773 20,660,936 223,024,995 22,039,388 107,258 1,984,282 8,113,945 1,637,015 1,590,426 35,472,315
Total Private Final Consumption Expenditure by ajor Object of Consumption and Standard in Current Prices,
Singapore, 1900-39 and 1947-1960
(Straits $)
1899 4,412,406 239,115 1,918,941 8,661,010 2,516,807 1,098,379 18,846,658 1,006,048 8,448 71,810 516,187 195,464 115,943 1,913,901
1900 4,369,042 236,765 1,900,083 8,575,892 2,492,072 1,087,584 18,661,438 1,007,297 8,459 71,899 520,648 197,153 116,087 1,921,544
1901 4,499,325 243,826 1,956,742 8,831,623 2,566,385 1,120,016 19,217,917 998,791 8,387 71,292 518,353 196,284 115,107 1,908,216
1902 4,652,316 252,117 2,023,278 9,131,925 2,653,650 1,158,099 19,871,385 1,045,724 8,781 74,642 550,904 208,610 120,516 2,009,177
1903 4,744,669 257,121 2,063,442 9,313,202 2,706,328 1,181,089 20,265,850 1,126,968 9,464 80,441 596,623 225,922 129,879 2,169,297
1904 4,977,968 269,764 2,164,903 9,771,141 2,839,400 1,239,164 21,262,341 1,101,209 9,247 78,603 583,233 220,852 126,910 2,120,055
1905 5,223,634 283,077 2,271,742 10,253,353 2,979,527 1,300,318 22,311,651 1,143,900 9,606 81,650 610,325 231,111 131,830 2,208,422
1906 5,289,017 286,620 2,300,177 10,381,691 3,016,820 1,316,593 22,590,920 1,152,353 9,677 82,253 611,052 231,386 132,805 2,219,527
1907 5,313,974 287,973 2,311,031 10,430,678 3,031,056 1,322,806 22,697,516 1,237,471 10,392 88,329 655,920 248,376 142,614 2,383,102
1908 5,582,067 302,501 2,427,624 10,956,913 3,183,974 1,389,542 23,842,622 1,289,998 10,833 92,078 681,666 258,126 148,668 2,481,368
1909 5,760,682 312,181 2,505,303 11,307,512 3,285,855 1,434,005 24,605,538 1,321,965 11,101 94,360 691,910 262,005 152,352 2,533,693
1910 5,934,800 321,616 2,581,026 11,649,283 3,385,171 1,477,348 25,349,243 1,367,792 11,486 97,631 721,326 273,144 157,633 2,629,012
1911 6,778,183 367,321 3,051,851 13,461,266 3,651,440 1,687,291 28,997,351 1,257,645 10,561 92,937 696,949 246,353 144,939 2,449,384
1912 7,124,071 386,065 3,207,586 14,148,191 3,837,772 1,773,393 30,477,078 1,285,291 10,793 94,980 717,184 253,505 148,125 2,509,879
1913 7,203,681 390,379 3,243,430 14,306,294 3,880,658 1,793,210 30,817,653 1,454,517 12,214 107,486 818,358 289,267 167,628 2,849,470
1914 7,327,950 397,113 3,299,381 14,553,088 3,947,602 1,824,144 31,349,279 1,591,505 13,365 117,609 878,391 310,488 183,415 3,094,773
1915 7,585,155 411,052 3,415,187 15,063,889 4,086,160 1,888,170 32,449,613 1,416,584 11,896 104,682 802,313 283,596 163,256 2,782,327
1916 7,638,020 413,917 3,438,989 15,168,877 4,114,638 1,901,330 32,675,770 2,038,877 17,121 150,669 1,183,372 418,290 234,973 4,043,304
1917 9,412,300 510,068 4,237,852 18,692,545 5,070,452 2,343,001 40,266,218 2,256,424 18,948 166,745 1,245,490 440,247 260,045 4,387,899
1918 12,003,667 650,498 5,404,605 23,838,921 6,466,434 2,988,069 51,352,193 3,295,554 27,674 243,534 1,793,684 634,019 379,801 6,374,266
1919 15,077,106 817,053 6,788,409 29,942,678 8,122,110 3,753,139 64,500,495 3,503,645 29,422 258,912 2,001,285 707,401 403,783 6,904,447
1920 20,066,803 1,087,453 9,035,001 39,852,067 10,810,085 4,995,223 85,846,631 4,063,634 34,124 300,294 2,360,115 834,237 468,319 8,060,724
1921 18,404,853 920,667 9,561,594 33,907,970 6,998,671 4,833,245 74,627,000 5,795,380 44,923 494,153 2,860,168 769,279 704,595 10,668,498
1922 17,628,945 881,853 9,158,498 32,478,485 6,703,623 4,629,487 71,480,891 6,538,468 50,683 557,514 3,113,811 837,499 794,938 11,892,913
1923 18,626,209 931,739 9,676,592 34,315,783 7,082,845 4,891,375 75,524,543 6,004,534 46,544 511,987 2,829,917 761,142 730,023 10,884,148
1924 19,396,465 970,270 10,076,751 35,734,856 7,375,744 5,093,650 78,647,736 5,851,452 45,358 498,934 2,753,243 740,520 711,412 10,600,918
1925 20,594,430 1,030,196 10,699,112 37,941,912 7,831,285 5,408,244 83,505,179 5,881,150 45,588 501,466 2,793,363 751,310 715,022 10,687,900
1926 22,169,479 1,108,985 11,517,373 40,843,686 8,430,216 5,821,863 89,891,602 5,970,117 46,277 509,052 2,874,142 773,037 725,839 10,898,465
1927 23,446,884 1,172,884 12,181,004 43,197,098 8,915,965 6,157,319 95,071,153 6,330,153 49,068 539,751 2,979,282 801,316 769,611 11,469,181
1928 24,270,469 1,214,082 12,608,868 44,714,421 9,229,144 6,373,598 98,410,583 6,801,976 52,726 579,982 3,159,306 849,736 826,975 12,270,701
1929 24,622,799 1,231,707 12,791,909 45,363,531 9,363,121 6,466,122 99,839,190 6,860,973 53,183 585,013 3,190,499 858,125 834,148 12,381,941
1930 22,486,856 1,124,861 11,682,255 41,428,401 8,550,903 5,905,208 91,178,483 6,413,916 49,718 546,894 3,003,659 807,872 779,795 11,601,853
1931 15,391,167 384,956 7,995,939 29,527,465 4,502,062 4,547,059 62,348,648 5,756,654 22,311 490,851 2,942,047 584,539 787,372 10,583,774
1932 13,248,386 331,362 6,882,733 25,416,607 3,875,278 3,914,011 53,668,377 5,704,685 22,110 486,420 2,851,379 566,524 780,264 10,411,382
1933 12,505,866 312,791 6,496,983 23,992,107 3,658,084 3,694,646 50,660,477 5,538,235 21,465 472,227 2,648,650 526,245 757,498 9,964,319
1934 12,950,916 323,922 6,728,193 24,845,921 3,788,265 3,826,128 52,463,346 5,428,029 21,038 462,830 2,647,587 526,034 742,424 9,827,942
1935 16,013,727 400,528 8,319,369 30,721,827 4,684,166 4,730,984 64,870,600 5,846,102 22,658 498,478 2,796,246 555,570 799,606 10,518,660
1936 17,432,618 436,016 9,056,503 33,443,923 5,099,205 5,150,171 70,618,437 6,681,596 25,896 569,718 3,093,981 614,725 913,882 11,899,799
1937 20,895,697 522,633 10,855,624 40,087,730 6,112,188 6,173,279 84,647,151 7,274,456 28,194 620,269 3,357,850 667,152 994,971 12,942,892
1938 21,596,868 540,170 11,219,893 41,432,906 6,317,288 6,380,428 87,487,553 8,147,533 31,578 694,713 3,712,126 737,541 1,114,387 14,437,878
1939 21,445,527 536,385 11,141,269 41,142,562 6,273,019 6,335,717 86,874,479 8,758,684 33,947 746,824 4,001,375 795,010 1,197,978 15,533,818
European Malay Clerical Chinese, Indian, Chinese Labour Malay Labour Indian Labour Total European Standard Malay Clerical Chinese, Indian, Chinese Labour Malay Labour Indian Labour Total
Standard Standard Eurasian Clerical Standard Standard Standard Standard Eurasian Clerical Standard Standard Standard
Grades Standard Grades Standard
1947 71,954,987 6,056,184 58,652,354 190,566,709 24,119,997 36,373,992 387,724,223 44,652,793 325,966 2,933,692 18,098,222 2,985,000 3,222,275 72,217,948
1948 71,818,963 6,044,736 58,541,478 190,206,461 24,074,400 36,305,230 386,991,268 40,866,858 298,328 2,684,956 16,563,744 2,731,914 2,949,071 66,094,871
1949 78,941,707 6,644,231 64,347,408 209,070,446 26,462,012 39,905,851 425,371,655 52,628,319 384,187 3,457,684 21,330,782 3,518,157 3,797,812 85,116,942
1950 83,489,050 7,026,964 68,054,065 221,113,702 27,986,325 42,204,580 449,874,685 54,026,729 394,396 3,549,560 21,897,571 3,611,639 3,898,726 87,378,621
1951 107,486,516 9,046,742 87,615,014 284,668,964 36,030,503 54,335,548 579,183,286 57,396,914 418,998 3,770,982 23,263,541 3,836,933 4,141,928 92,829,296
1952 116,261,314 9,785,284 94,767,577 307,908,275 38,971,899 58,771,299 626,465,648 59,761,353 436,258 3,926,325 24,221,871 3,994,994 4,312,553 96,653,355
1953 130,950,539 11,021,621 106,741,141 346,811,448 43,895,867 66,196,855 705,617,470 75,175,582 548,782 4,939,041 30,469,411 5,025,422 5,424,888 121,583,127
1954 125,527,001 10,565,142 102,320,276 332,447,666 42,077,846 63,455,200 676,393,132 82,763,618 604,175 5,437,576 33,544,918 5,532,675 5,972,463 133,855,426
1955 124,269,457 10,459,300 101,295,220 329,117,168 41,656,305 62,819,499 669,616,949 84,523,091 617,019 5,553,173 34,258,050 5,650,294 6,099,432 136,701,060
1956 142,939,681 12,030,703 116,513,798 378,563,678 47,914,742 72,257,490 770,220,091 100,349,254 732,550 6,592,953 40,672,552 6,708,259 7,241,494 162,297,063
1957 150,249,636 8,430,637 167,832,451 361,447,159 55,961,232 75,952,748 819,873,862 100,422,640 488,724 9,041,395 36,971,252 7,459,072 7,246,790 161,629,873
1958 154,652,705 8,677,697 172,750,785 372,039,375 57,601,177 78,178,545 843,900,284 104,970,472 510,857 9,450,852 38,645,566 7,796,871 7,574,974 168,949,592
1959 146,586,615 8,225,101 163,740,769 352,635,234 54,596,921 74,101,053 799,885,694 98,273,495 478,265 8,847,900 36,180,030 7,299,441 7,091,701 158,170,832
1960 171,204,779 9,606,448 191,239,850 411,857,778 63,766,080 86,545,791 934,220,726 120,602,695 586,934 10,858,275 44,400,671 8,957,982 8,703,041 194,109,598
328
Appendix Table 7 (Continued)
Total Private Final Consumption Expenditure by ajor Object of Consumption and Standard in Constant Prices,
Singapore,1900-39 and 1947-1960
(Straits $)
Clothing Rent
Year European Standard Eurasian Standard Asiatic Clerical Chinese Labour Malay Labour Indian Labour Total European Eurasian Asiatic Clerical Chinese Labour Malay Labour Indian Labour Total
Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard
1899 2,527,895 45,643 387,962 1,197,216 367,190 118,954 4,644,859 1,398,722 58,280 495,381 484,243 116,071 82,366 2,635,062
1900 2,463,621 44,482 378,097 1,175,398 360,499 115,929 4,538,027 1,368,195 57,008 484,569 473,674 113,538 80,568 2,577,553
1901 2,500,760 45,153 383,797 1,197,975 367,423 117,677 4,612,785 1,391,648 57,985 492,875 481,794 115,484 81,949 2,621,735
1902 2,479,068 44,761 380,468 1,205,513 369,735 116,656 4,596,200 1,389,990 57,916 492,288 481,220 115,347 81,852 2,618,613
1903 2,518,992 45,482 386,595 1,230,948 377,536 118,535 4,678,089 1,415,847 58,994 501,446 490,172 117,493 83,374 2,667,324
1904 2,588,296 46,733 397,232 1,265,352 388,088 121,796 4,807,497 1,455,109 60,630 515,351 503,764 120,751 85,686 2,741,291
1905 2,614,278 47,202 401,219 1,287,507 394,883 123,019 4,868,108 1,475,151 61,465 522,449 510,703 122,414 86,867 2,779,049
1906 2,731,334 49,316 419,184 1,336,879 410,025 128,527 5,075,265 1,536,461 64,019 544,163 531,929 127,502 90,477 2,894,550
1907 2,812,687 50,785 431,669 1,376,138 422,066 132,355 5,225,701 1,581,902 65,913 560,257 547,661 131,273 93,153 2,980,158
1908 2,916,007 52,650 447,526 1,422,316 436,229 137,217 5,411,945 1,637,498 68,229 579,947 566,908 135,886 96,427 3,084,894
1909 3,072,991 55,485 471,619 1,484,621 455,338 144,604 5,684,657 1,717,441 71,560 608,260 594,585 142,520 101,134 3,235,500
1910 3,102,323 56,014 476,120 1,510,162 463,172 145,984 5,753,775 1,740,410 72,517 616,395 602,537 144,426 102,487 3,278,773
1911 2,917,040 52,669 463,485 1,492,141 427,194 137,266 5,489,796 1,668,057 69,502 611,621 584,282 130,732 98,226 3,162,420
1912 2,962,911 53,497 470,774 1,526,064 436,906 139,424 5,589,576 1,700,133 70,839 623,382 595,517 133,246 100,115 3,223,231
1913 2,998,597 54,141 476,444 1,557,281 445,844 141,103 5,673,410 1,727,760 71,990 633,512 605,194 135,411 101,742 3,275,610
1914 3,252,027 58,717 516,711 1,656,756 474,323 153,029 6,111,564 1,855,955 77,331 680,517 650,098 145,458 109,291 3,518,650
1915 3,152,293 56,916 500,864 1,647,983 471,811 148,336 5,978,203 1,822,581 75,941 668,280 638,408 142,842 107,325 3,455,377
1916 3,065,285 55,345 487,040 1,642,200 470,155 144,242 5,864,267 1,794,230 74,760 657,884 628,477 140,620 105,656 3,401,628
1917 3,606,604 65,119 573,049 1,837,565 526,088 169,714 6,778,139 2,059,383 85,808 755,107 721,354 161,402 121,270 3,904,324
1918 3,858,088 69,660 613,007 1,938,270 554,919 181,548 7,215,494 2,187,614 91,151 802,125 766,270 171,451 128,821 4,147,432
1919 3,544,313 63,995 563,152 1,868,726 535,009 166,783 6,741,977 2,059,410 85,809 755,117 721,364 161,404 121,271 3,904,374
1920 3,510,990 63,393 557,857 1,882,231 538,875 165,215 6,718,560 2,057,170 85,715 754,296 720,579 161,228 121,140 3,900,127
1921 4,992,118 83,202 915,222 2,274,151 495,416 247,819 9,007,927 2,802,144 107,775 1,185,522 910,539 155,022 174,075 5,335,077
1922 5,720,077 95,335 1,048,681 2,514,449 547,764 283,956 10,210,261 3,154,495 121,327 1,334,594 1,025,033 174,515 195,964 6,005,927
1923 6,087,408 101,457 1,116,025 2,648,205 576,903 302,191 10,832,188 3,339,684 128,449 1,412,943 1,085,209 184,760 207,468 6,358,513
1924 6,332,657 105,544 1,160,987 2,750,374 599,160 314,366 11,263,088 3,471,381 133,515 1,468,661 1,128,004 192,046 215,649 6,609,256
1925 6,454,486 107,575 1,183,322 2,829,772 616,456 320,414 11,512,025 3,554,879 136,726 1,503,987 1,155,136 196,665 220,836 6,768,230
1926 6,491,229 108,187 1,190,059 2,884,543 628,388 322,238 11,624,644 3,599,400 138,438 1,522,823 1,169,603 199,128 223,602 6,852,995
1927 7,146,810 119,113 1,310,248 3,104,805 676,372 354,782 12,712,131 3,918,585 150,715 1,657,863 1,273,320 216,786 243,430 7,460,699
1928 7,673,324 127,889 1,406,776 3,289,765 716,664 380,919 13,595,337 4,179,648 160,756 1,768,312 1,358,150 231,229 259,648 7,957,744
1929 7,937,891 132,298 1,455,280 3,407,240 742,256 394,053 14,069,019 4,326,329 166,397 1,830,370 1,405,813 239,344 268,760 8,237,013
1930 7,705,398 128,423 1,412,656 3,330,790 725,601 382,512 13,685,380 4,214,435 162,094 1,783,030 1,369,454 233,154 261,809 8,023,976
1931 6,729,338 56,078 1,233,712 3,174,509 510,857 375,815 12,080,310 3,768,943 72,480 1,594,553 1,275,302 160,391 263,401 7,135,068
1932 6,907,263 57,561 1,266,332 3,186,794 512,834 385,752 12,316,535 3,826,061 73,578 1,618,718 1,294,629 162,821 267,393 7,243,200
1933 7,296,593 60,805 1,337,709 3,221,054 518,347 407,495 12,842,002 3,954,455 76,047 1,673,039 1,338,074 168,285 276,366 7,486,266
1934 7,095,826 59,132 1,300,901 3,194,742 514,113 396,283 12,560,997 3,883,900 74,690 1,643,189 1,314,200 165,283 271,435 7,352,698
1935 8,125,584 67,713 1,489,690 3,587,470 577,312 453,792 14,301,562 4,404,442 84,701 1,863,418 1,490,336 187,435 307,815 8,338,147
1936 9,305,302 77,544 1,705,972 3,977,339 640,052 519,676 16,225,885 4,963,500 95,452 2,099,942 1,679,505 211,226 346,886 9,396,511
1937 10,130,963 84,425 1,857,343 4,316,545 694,638 565,787 17,649,701 5,395,361 103,757 2,282,653 1,825,635 229,604 377,067 10,214,077
1938 11,411,114 95,093 2,092,038 4,798,985 772,275 637,280 19,806,784 6,037,748 116,111 2,554,432 2,043,000 256,942 421,962 11,430,193
1939 11,614,208 96,785 2,129,271 4,897,616 788,147 648,622 20,174,650 6,153,523 118,337 2,603,414 2,082,175 261,869 430,053 11,649,370
European Standard Malay Clerical Chinese, Indian, Chinese Labour Malay Labour Indian Labour Total European Malay Clerical Chinese, Indian, Chinese Labour Malay Labour Indian Labour Total
Standard Eurasian Clerical Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Eurasian Clerical Standard Standard Standard
Grades Standard Grades Standard
1947 12,729,149 188,357 1,737,312 6,546,285 874,505 633,385 22,708,993 7,661,571 172,288 1,550,592 2,872,240 299,869 420,183 12,976,743
1948 14,218,619 203,400 1,940,600 7,069,120 944,349 683,972 25,060,060 8,415,776 189,248 1,703,232 3,154,983 329,388 461,546 14,254,174
1949 17,738,411 235,127 2,420,991 8,171,768 1,091,650 790,658 30,448,605 10,113,781 227,432 2,046,884 3,791,547 395,847 554,669 17,130,160
1950 17,104,959 234,260 2,334,536 8,141,626 1,087,623 787,742 29,690,745 9,914,543 222,951 2,006,561 3,716,855 388,049 543,743 16,792,701
1951 15,948,640 228,975 2,176,718 7,957,961 1,063,088 769,971 28,145,354 9,467,595 212,901 1,916,105 3,549,299 370,556 519,231 16,035,686
1952 16,357,393 237,547 2,232,506 8,255,871 1,102,885 798,796 28,984,997 9,766,131 219,614 1,976,524 3,661,217 382,240 535,603 16,541,329
1953 20,276,166 277,156 2,767,352 9,632,474 1,286,783 931,989 35,171,919 11,750,190 264,230 2,378,069 4,405,019 459,895 644,415 19,901,819
1954 21,486,865 292,332 2,932,591 10,159,906 1,357,241 983,020 37,211,956 12,422,689 279,353 2,514,173 4,657,132 486,216 681,297 21,040,860
1955 22,018,661 302,041 3,005,173 10,497,341 1,402,318 1,015,669 38,241,202 12,782,712 287,449 2,587,037 4,792,100 500,307 701,041 21,650,647
1956 26,052,286 341,357 3,555,694 11,863,753 1,584,855 1,147,876 44,545,819 14,785,499 332,486 2,992,372 5,542,923 578,695 810,880 25,042,856
1957 25,706,033 230,689 4,807,857 10,923,900 1,785,079 1,163,604 44,617,162 14,788,541 221,703 4,101,502 5,035,858 643,127 811,047 25,601,778
1958 26,860,940 241,252 5,023,862 11,424,079 1,866,813 1,216,883 46,633,828 15,459,313 231,759 4,287,536 5,264,272 672,298 847,834 26,763,010
1959 25,268,030 236,849 4,725,936 11,215,593 1,832,744 1,194,675 44,473,828 14,859,864 222,772 4,121,283 5,060,145 646,229 814,959 25,725,251
1960 31,025,587 272,499 5,802,785 12,903,726 2,108,603 1,374,494 53,487,692 17,671,171 264,918 4,900,980 6,017,464 768,487 969,139 30,592,159
Total Private Final Consumption Expenditure by ajor Object of Consumption and Standard in Current Prices,
Singapore, 1900-39 and 1947-1960
(Straits $)
Clothing Rent
Year European Standard Eurasian Standard Asiatic Clerical Chinese Labour Malay Labour Indian Labour Total European Eurasian Asiatic Clerical Chinese Labour Malay Labour Indian Labour Total
Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard
1899 1,928,921 34,828 296,036 913,540 280,186 90,768 3,544,279 1,049,375 43,724 371,654 363,298 87,081 61,794 1,976,925
1900 1,944,855 35,115 298,481 927,894 284,588 91,518 3,582,451 1,046,185 43,591 370,524 362,193 86,817 61,606 1,970,915
1901 2,111,789 38,130 324,101 1,011,641 310,274 99,373 3,895,308 1,084,573 45,191 384,120 375,483 90,002 63,867 2,043,236
1902 2,151,594 38,848 330,210 1,046,270 320,894 101,247 3,989,063 1,104,127 46,005 391,045 382,253 91,625 65,018 2,080,073
1903 2,337,290 42,201 358,709 1,142,156 350,303 109,985 4,340,644 1,146,330 47,764 405,992 396,864 95,127 67,503 2,159,579
1904 2,334,473 42,150 358,277 1,141,265 350,030 109,852 4,336,047 1,200,835 50,035 425,296 415,734 99,650 70,713 2,262,263
1905 2,300,023 41,528 352,990 1,132,739 347,415 108,231 4,282,927 1,240,873 51,703 439,476 429,595 102,973 73,071 2,337,691
1906 2,305,847 41,633 353,883 1,128,620 346,152 108,505 4,284,640 1,317,418 54,892 466,586 456,095 109,325 77,578 2,481,895
1907 2,334,320 42,147 358,253 1,142,092 350,283 109,845 4,336,941 1,382,617 57,609 489,677 478,667 114,735 81,418 2,604,723
1908 2,516,708 45,441 386,245 1,227,553 376,495 118,428 4,670,869 1,458,920 60,788 516,701 505,084 121,067 85,911 2,748,470
1909 2,348,477 42,403 360,426 1,134,594 347,984 110,511 4,344,395 1,483,334 61,806 525,347 513,536 123,093 87,348 2,794,464
1910 2,617,633 47,263 401,734 1,274,222 390,808 123,177 4,854,838 1,497,671 62,403 530,425 518,500 124,283 88,193 2,821,474
1911 2,451,054 44,255 389,445 1,253,777 358,952 115,338 4,612,821 1,413,662 58,903 518,343 495,173 110,794 83,246 2,680,120
1912 2,461,380 44,442 391,086 1,267,747 362,951 115,824 4,643,429 1,452,722 60,530 532,665 508,855 113,855 85,546 2,754,173
1913 2,984,482 53,886 474,201 1,549,951 443,745 140,439 5,646,705 1,569,881 65,412 575,623 549,893 123,037 92,445 2,976,292
1914 3,252,027 58,717 516,711 1,656,756 474,323 153,029 6,111,564 1,855,955 77,331 680,517 650,098 145,458 109,291 3,518,650
1915 4,360,216 78,726 692,790 2,279,471 652,604 205,177 8,268,983 1,827,636 76,151 670,133 640,178 143,239 107,623 3,464,960
1916 4,943,690 89,261 785,497 2,648,538 758,266 232,633 9,457,886 1,838,075 76,586 673,961 643,835 144,057 108,238 3,484,752
1917 5,194,086 93,782 825,283 2,646,386 757,650 244,416 9,761,603 2,106,508 87,771 772,386 737,861 165,095 124,045 3,993,667
1918 7,322,652 132,215 1,163,488 3,678,837 1,053,237 344,578 13,695,007 2,501,224 104,218 917,116 876,121 196,030 147,288 4,741,997
1919 8,137,742 146,931 1,292,997 4,290,595 1,228,381 382,934 15,479,580 2,572,247 107,177 943,157 900,999 201,597 151,471 4,876,648
1920 10,238,046 184,854 1,626,712 5,488,584 1,571,360 481,767 19,591,322 3,307,149 137,798 1,212,621 1,158,418 259,194 194,746 6,269,926
1921 11,841,303 197,355 2,170,906 5,394,285 1,175,127 587,826 21,366,802 4,712,102 181,235 1,993,582 1,531,168 260,686 292,725 8,971,498
1922 10,456,300 174,272 1,916,988 4,596,412 1,001,313 519,072 18,664,358 5,888,314 226,474 2,491,210 1,913,371 325,757 365,794 11,210,919
1923 9,958,999 165,983 1,825,816 4,332,463 943,813 494,385 17,721,459 7,001,195 269,277 2,962,044 2,274,994 387,324 434,928 13,329,763
1924 9,948,604 165,810 1,823,911 4,320,837 941,280 493,869 17,694,311 7,551,596 290,446 3,194,906 2,453,844 417,774 469,121 14,377,686
1925 10,204,542 170,076 1,870,833 4,473,869 974,618 506,574 18,200,511 8,018,871 308,418 3,392,599 2,605,682 443,625 498,149 15,267,344
1926 10,223,685 170,395 1,874,342 4,543,156 989,711 507,524 18,308,814 8,496,106 326,773 3,594,507 2,760,757 470,027 527,795 16,175,965
1927 11,106,142 185,102 2,036,126 4,824,867 1,051,081 551,331 19,754,651 9,930,205 381,931 4,201,241 3,226,758 549,365 616,885 18,906,384
1928 11,655,779 194,263 2,136,893 4,997,153 1,088,613 578,617 20,651,318 11,525,328 443,282 4,876,100 3,745,083 637,611 715,977 21,943,381
1929 11,192,426 186,540 2,051,945 4,804,209 1,046,581 555,615 19,837,316 12,001,198 461,585 5,077,430 3,899,714 663,938 745,539 22,849,404
1930 10,772,146 179,536 1,974,894 4,656,444 1,014,391 534,751 19,132,162 10,772,146 414,313 4,557,447 3,500,342 595,943 669,188 20,509,379
1931 9,190,219 76,585 1,684,873 4,335,409 697,674 513,249 16,498,009 8,346,614 160,512 3,531,260 2,824,254 355,197 583,322 15,801,159
1932 8,384,352 69,870 1,537,131 3,868,276 622,501 468,243 14,950,374 6,932,753 133,322 2,933,088 2,345,844 295,029 484,511 13,124,547
1933 8,440,766 70,340 1,547,474 3,726,145 599,628 471,394 14,855,747 6,289,972 120,961 2,661,142 2,128,345 267,675 439,589 11,907,684
1934 7,860,931 65,508 1,441,171 3,539,215 569,547 439,012 13,915,383 6,177,747 118,803 2,613,662 2,090,372 262,899 431,746 11,695,229
1935 8,922,564 74,355 1,635,803 3,939,339 633,937 498,301 15,704,299 7,005,723 134,725 2,963,960 2,370,535 298,135 489,611 13,262,689
1936 10,154,225 84,619 1,861,608 4,340,192 698,444 567,086 17,706,173 7,894,962 151,826 3,340,176 2,671,428 335,977 551,758 14,946,127
1937 11,427,130 95,226 2,094,974 4,868,808 783,511 638,174 19,907,823 8,728,801 167,862 3,692,954 2,953,575 371,462 610,032 16,524,686
1938 12,999,532 108,329 2,383,247 5,467,000 879,775 725,989 22,563,871 10,239,108 196,906 4,331,930 3,464,619 435,734 715,584 19,383,882
1939 14,381,984 119,850 2,636,697 6,064,765 975,970 803,195 24,982,460 11,215,586 215,684 4,745,056 3,795,031 477,289 783,827 21,232,473
European Standard Malay Clerical Chinese, Indian, Chinese Labour Malay Labour Indian Labour Total European Malay Clerical Chinese, Indian, Chinese Labour Malay Labour Indian Labour Total
Standard Eurasian Clerical Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Eurasian Clerical Standard Standard Standard
Grades Standard Grades Standard
1947 80,002,359 1,183,817 10,918,961 41,143,226 5,496,240 3,980,807 142,725,410 42,063,009 945,883 8,512,947 15,768,966 1,646,320 2,306,859 71,243,984
1948 54,870,439 784,933 7,488,881 27,280,126 3,644,297 2,639,485 96,708,161 38,776,736 871,984 7,847,853 14,536,978 1,517,697 2,126,630 65,677,877
1949 69,015,383 914,815 9,419,425 31,794,152 4,247,316 3,076,239 118,467,331 51,639,140 1,161,224 10,451,018 19,358,954 2,021,124 2,832,042 87,463,502
1950 71,069,104 973,321 9,699,723 33,827,502 4,518,948 3,272,975 123,361,573 52,254,829 1,175,069 10,575,625 19,589,769 2,045,221 2,865,808 88,506,322
1951 83,879,148 1,204,255 11,448,076 41,853,538 5,591,129 4,049,534 148,025,680 60,814,625 1,367,556 12,308,004 22,798,744 2,380,247 3,335,252 103,004,428
1952 84,153,642 1,222,103 11,485,540 42,473,861 5,673,997 4,109,553 149,118,696 66,485,468 1,495,078 13,455,701 24,924,681 2,602,200 3,646,258 112,609,386
1953 95,832,640 1,309,941 13,079,524 45,526,626 6,081,810 4,404,923 166,235,464 84,508,170 1,900,360 17,103,236 31,681,197 3,307,597 4,634,676 143,135,235
1954 96,377,177 1,311,224 13,153,844 45,571,240 6,087,770 4,409,239 166,910,495 91,390,893 2,055,133 18,496,200 34,261,455 3,576,983 5,012,145 154,792,809
1955 96,694,939 1,326,411 13,197,214 46,099,065 6,158,281 4,460,309 167,936,219 92,635,925 2,083,131 18,748,177 34,728,204 3,625,712 5,080,426 156,901,576
1956 114,148,908 1,495,664 15,579,383 51,981,406 6,944,091 5,029,454 195,178,906 113,644,003 2,555,546 22,999,910 42,603,905 4,447,955 6,232,571 192,483,889
1957 114,355,030 1,026,237 21,388,077 48,595,710 7,941,043 5,176,372 198,482,469 116,915,026 1,752,735 32,425,590 39,812,410 5,084,424 6,411,963 202,402,147
1958 119,143,258 1,070,087 22,283,630 50,672,165 8,280,357 5,397,554 206,847,051 124,764,207 1,870,406 34,602,508 42,485,247 5,425,770 6,842,435 215,990,572
1959 110,210,741 1,033,057 20,612,961 48,918,686 7,993,820 5,210,775 193,980,042 121,558,016 1,822,340 33,713,292 41,393,461 5,286,339 6,666,598 210,440,046
1960 135,932,938 1,193,904 25,423,841 56,535,315 9,238,457 6,022,092 234,346,547 144,555,328 2,167,105 40,091,441 49,224,605 6,286,450 7,927,838 250,252,768
329
Appendix Table 7 (Continued)
Total Private Final Consumption Expenditure by ajor Object of Consumption and Standard in
Constant Prices, Singapore, 1900-39 and 1947-1960
(Straits $)
Servant Transport Clubbing Total from
Year European Standard Eurasian Standard Asiatic Clerical Total European Eurasian Asiatic Clerical Total European Total Indirect
Standard Standard Standard Standard Standard Approach
1899 5,258,236 32,102 272,863 5,563,201 2,762,442 63,378 538,711 3,364,531 1,726,248 1,726,248 43,519,395
1900 5,124,542 31,285 265,926 5,421,753 2,692,205 61,766 525,014 3,278,985 1,682,357 1,682,357 42,565,436
1901 5,201,793 31,757 269,934 5,503,484 2,732,789 62,697 532,928 3,328,415 1,707,718 1,707,718 43,292,894
1902 5,156,672 31,482 267,593 5,455,746 2,709,085 62,154 528,305 3,299,543 1,692,905 1,692,905 43,233,707
1903 5,239,718 31,989 271,902 5,543,609 2,752,714 63,155 536,813 3,352,682 1,720,168 1,720,168 44,035,842
1904 5,383,876 32,869 279,383 5,696,128 2,828,448 64,892 551,583 3,444,922 1,767,494 1,767,494 45,256,813
1905 5,437,920 33,199 282,188 5,753,306 2,856,840 65,543 557,119 3,479,503 1,785,237 1,785,237 45,877,106
1906 5,681,407 34,685 294,823 6,010,915 2,984,757 68,478 582,065 3,635,300 1,865,172 1,865,172 47,786,197
1907 5,850,629 35,718 303,604 6,189,951 3,073,659 70,518 599,402 3,743,578 1,920,727 1,920,727 49,199,686
1908 6,065,542 37,030 314,756 6,417,329 3,186,564 73,108 621,420 3,881,092 1,991,281 1,991,281 50,930,179
1909 6,392,082 39,024 331,701 6,762,807 3,358,114 77,044 654,874 4,090,032 2,098,482 2,098,482 53,421,376
1910 6,453,095 39,396 334,868 6,827,359 3,390,168 77,779 661,125 4,129,072 2,118,513 2,118,513 54,131,509
1911 6,067,692 37,043 325,981 6,430,716 3,187,694 73,134 643,580 3,904,408 1,991,987 1,991,987 51,964,143
1912 6,163,108 37,626 331,107 6,531,840 3,237,821 74,284 653,701 3,965,806 2,023,312 2,023,312 52,961,585
1913 6,237,336 38,079 335,095 6,610,510 3,276,817 75,179 661,574 4,013,570 2,047,680 2,047,680 53,820,424
1914 6,764,493 41,297 363,416 7,169,206 3,553,762 81,533 717,488 4,352,783 2,220,743 2,220,743 57,816,998
1915 6,557,037 40,031 352,271 6,949,339 3,444,774 79,032 695,484 4,219,290 2,152,636 2,152,636 56,769,278
1916 6,376,054 38,926 342,547 6,757,527 3,349,694 76,851 676,287 4,102,832 2,093,221 2,093,221 55,883,416
1917 7,502,043 45,800 403,040 7,950,883 3,941,238 90,422 795,717 4,827,377 2,462,876 2,462,876 64,138,077
1918 8,025,152 48,994 431,144 8,505,289 4,216,056 96,727 851,202 5,163,985 2,634,610 2,634,610 68,136,920
1919 7,372,472 45,009 396,079 7,813,560 3,873,167 88,861 781,974 4,744,002 2,420,339 2,420,339 64,121,202
1920 7,303,157 44,586 392,355 7,740,098 3,836,752 88,025 774,622 4,699,399 2,397,583 2,397,583 64,050,554
1921 10,384,029 58,518 643,699 11,086,246 5,455,304 115,531 1,270,846 6,841,682 3,409,015 3,409,015 84,608,527
1922 11,898,246 67,051 737,564 12,702,861 6,250,806 132,378 1,456,163 7,839,348 3,906,123 3,906,123 95,328,352
1923 12,662,326 71,357 784,929 13,518,611 6,652,219 140,880 1,549,675 8,342,774 4,156,966 4,156,966 100,954,809
1924 13,172,465 74,232 816,552 14,063,248 6,920,224 146,555 1,612,108 8,678,887 4,324,442 4,324,442 104,941,058
1925 13,425,879 75,660 832,261 14,333,800 7,053,356 149,375 1,643,122 8,845,853 4,407,636 4,407,636 107,434,644
1926 13,502,307 76,091 836,998 14,415,397 7,093,508 150,225 1,652,476 8,896,209 4,432,727 4,432,727 108,737,627
1927 14,865,972 83,776 921,531 15,871,278 7,809,917 165,397 1,819,367 9,794,681 4,880,410 4,880,410 118,452,875
1928 15,961,166 89,947 989,421 17,040,534 8,385,282 177,582 1,953,402 10,516,267 5,239,956 5,239,956 126,394,859
1929 16,511,488 93,049 1,023,535 17,628,073 8,674,397 183,705 2,020,754 10,878,856 5,420,624 5,420,624 130,825,590
1930 16,027,883 90,323 993,557 17,111,764 8,420,333 178,324 1,961,568 10,560,225 5,261,859 5,261,859 127,413,452
1931 13,997,596 39,441 867,701 14,904,738 7,353,711 77,868 1,713,092 9,144,670 4,595,328 4,595,328 113,528,085
1932 14,367,695 40,484 890,643 15,298,822 7,548,144 79,927 1,758,386 9,386,457 4,716,829 4,716,829 115,311,434
1933 15,177,534 42,766 940,845 16,161,144 7,973,597 84,432 1,857,498 9,915,527 4,982,694 4,982,694 119,325,820
1934 14,759,922 41,589 914,957 15,716,468 7,754,203 82,109 1,806,389 9,642,700 4,845,595 4,845,595 117,119,474
1935 16,901,906 47,624 1,047,737 17,997,268 8,879,506 94,024 2,068,535 11,042,065 5,548,796 5,548,796 132,896,572
1936 19,355,820 54,539 1,199,854 20,610,212 10,168,682 107,675 2,368,856 12,645,213 6,354,401 6,354,401 149,927,623
1937 21,073,265 59,378 1,306,317 22,438,960 11,070,951 117,229 2,579,045 13,767,226 6,918,228 6,918,228 162,992,008
1938 23,736,088 66,881 1,471,383 25,274,352 12,469,879 132,042 2,904,934 15,506,855 7,792,417 7,792,417 182,489,473
1939 24,158,540 68,071 1,497,571 25,724,182 12,691,816 134,393 2,956,636 15,782,844 7,931,105 7,931,105 185,968,581
European Standard Malay Clerical Chinese, Indian, Total European Malay Clerical Chinese, Indian, Total European Total
Standard Eurasian Clerical Standard Standard Eurasian Clerical Standard
Total from
Grades Standard Grades Standard Indirect
Approach
1947 22,846,173 454,667 4,091,999 27,392,838 15,978,038 612,284 6,198,403 22,788,724 5,299,353 5,299,353 204,158,665
1948 25,519,462 507,868 4,570,814 30,598,144 17,847,669 683,928 6,923,694 25,455,291 5,919,444 5,919,444 224,760,204
1949 31,836,756 633,590 5,702,310 38,172,656 22,265,825 853,234 8,637,641 31,756,699 7,384,791 7,384,791 271,573,818
1950 30,699,842 610,964 5,498,676 36,809,482 21,470,696 822,764 8,329,185 30,622,644 7,121,074 7,121,074 265,512,804
1951 28,624,490 569,662 5,126,958 34,321,110 20,019,247 767,144 7,766,120 28,552,511 6,639,680 6,639,680 252,620,534
1952 29,358,116 584,262 5,258,359 35,200,737 20,532,327 786,805 7,965,161 29,284,293 6,809,850 6,809,850 260,375,877
1953 36,391,499 724,235 6,518,114 43,633,848 25,451,297 975,302 9,873,390 36,299,989 8,441,300 8,441,300 314,580,444
1954 38,564,451 767,479 6,907,313 46,239,244 26,971,005 1,033,538 10,462,934 38,467,477 8,945,334 8,945,334 332,705,404
1955 39,518,915 786,474 7,078,268 47,383,657 27,638,533 1,059,117 10,721,890 39,419,541 9,166,729 9,166,729 342,127,933
1956 46,758,431 930,549 8,374,945 56,063,925 32,701,669 1,253,138 12,686,046 46,640,853 10,845,993 10,845,993 397,126,531
1957 46,136,980 612,121 11,324,242 58,073,343 32,267,041 824,322 17,153,529 50,244,893 10,701,842 10,701,842 406,315,093
1958 48,209,797 639,622 11,833,011 60,682,431 33,716,717 861,357 17,924,193 52,502,267 11,182,649 11,182,649 424,714,005
1959 45,350,856 601,691 11,131,289 57,083,836 31,717,246 810,277 16,861,251 49,388,773 10,519,494 10,519,494 406,724,469
1960 55,684,472 738,792 13,667,657 70,090,921 38,944,316 994,906 20,703,245 60,642,467 12,916,459 12,916,459 486,227,008
Total Private Final Consumption Expenditure by ajor Object of Consumption and Standard in Current
Prices, Singapore, 1900-39 and 1947-1960
(Straits $)
330
Appendix Table 8
Singapore: Percentage Share of Expenditure Incurred in relation to Straits
Settlements by Class of Account and Department for the period 1900-09
Personal Emoluments Intermediate Construction Machinery & Transfers
Consumption Equipment
1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.9 2 3 4 9
1900 100% 100% 100%
1901 100% 100% 100%
1902 100% 100% 100%
1903 100% 100% 100%
1904 100% 100% 100%
Analyst
1905 100% 100% 100%
1906 100% 100% 100%
1907 100% 100% 100%
1908 100% 100% 100%
1909 78% 85% 74% 100%
78% 85% 0% 74% 100%
1900 72% 92% 71%
1901 57% 91% 81%
1902 70% 93% 76%
1903 71% 94% 73%
1904 69% 92% 80% 100%
Audit Department
1905 59% 95% 82% 0%
1906 68% 96% 91%
1907 69% 96% 82%
1908 65% 95% 83% 0%
1909 66% 87% 85%
67% 94% 92% 80% 80%
The percentage data was not taken into account for the computation of the expenditure
incurred by class of account
331
Appendix Table 8 (Continued)
Personal Emoluments Intermediate Construction Machinery & Transfers
Consumption Equipment
332
Appendix Table 9
Methodology Adopted to Identify the Share of Expenditure Assigned to Singapore
in Relation to Straits Settlements by Departments for the Period 1910-39
STEP 1 Step 1
Major Sub Code Actual SS Malacca Penang Singapore Singapore Penang + Sum Average %applied Major Sub Code
Distribution of
Code (Proper) Malacca to S'pore Code
Item A 1 1 1,000.00 500.00 500.00 50.00% 1 1 compensation of
Item B 2 100.00 20.00 30.00 50.00 50.00 13,796.14 2 employees (Major Code 1)
Item C 4 1 2,000.00 4 1
Item D 3 1 300.00 300.00 300.00 - 3 1
was based on the known
Item E 2 1,000.00 2 distribution of
Item F 2 100.00 20.00 30.00 50.00 50.00 17,165.04 2 intermediate consumption
Item G 2 100.00 20.00 30.00 50.00 50.00 9,616.47 2
Item H 2 100.00 20.00 30.00 50.00 50.00 7,187.00 2 (Major Code 2) for the
Item I 9 150.00 9 respective Settlements.
Item J 2 2,000.00 2
Item K 1 2 400.00 200.00 200.00 50.00% 1 2
Item L 4 1 50.00 20.00 10.00 20.00 20.00 30.00 4 1
STEP 2 Step 2
Major Sub Code Actual SS Malacca Penang Singapore Singapore Penang + Sum Average %applied Major Sub Code
Code (Proper) Malacca to S'pore Code
Distribution of
Item A 1 1 1,000.00 500.00 500.00 50.00% 1 1 intermediate consumption
Item B 2 100.00 20.00 30.00 50.00 50.00 13,796.14 2 (Major Code 2) was based
Item C 4 1 2,000.00 4 1
Item D 3 1 300.00 300.00 300.00 - 3 1 on the known distribution
Item E 2 1,000.00 500.00 500.00 50.00% 2 of intermediate
Item F 2 100.00 20.00 30.00 50.00 50.00 17,165.04 2 consumption (Major Code
Item G 2 100.00 20.00 30.00 50.00 50.00 9,616.47 2
Item H 2 100.00 20.00 30.00 50.00 50.00 7,187.00 2 2) for the respective
Item I 9 150.00 9 Settlements.
Item J 2 2,000.00 1,000.00 1,000.00 50.00% 2
Item K 1 2 400.00 200.00 200.00 50.00% 1 2
Item L 4 1 50.00 20.00 10.00 20.00 20.00 30.00 4 1
STEP 3 Step 3
Major Sub Code Actual SS Malacca Penang Singapore Singapore Penang + Sum Average %applied Major Sub Code
Code (Proper) Malacca to S'pore Code Distribution of Transport
Item A 1 1 1,000.00 500.00 500.00 50.00% 1 1 Equipment (Code 4.1) was
Item B 2 100.00 20.00 30.00 50.00 50.00 13,796.14 2
Item C 4 1 2,000.00 800.00 1,200.00 40.00% 4 1
based on the known
Item D 3 1 300.00 300.00 300.00 - 3 1 distribution of Transport
Item E 2 1,000.00 500.00 500.00 50.00% 2 Equipment (Code 4.1). The
Item F 2 100.00 20.00 30.00 50.00 50.00 50.00 2
Item G 2 100.00 20.00 30.00 50.00 50.00 50.00 2
same methodology was
Item H 2 100.00 20.00 30.00 50.00 50.00 50.00 2 applied for Major Codes
Item I 9 150.00 9 3,4 and 9.
Item J 2 2,000.00 1,000.00 1,000.00 50.00% 2
Item K 1 2 400.00 200.00 200.00 50.00% 1 2
Item L 4 1 50.00 20.00 10.00 20.00 20.00 30.00 4 1
STEP 4
Major Sub Code Actual SS Malacca Penang Singapore Singapore Penang + Sum Average %applied Major Sub Code
Step 4
Code (Proper) Malacca to S'pore Code In cases where the
Item A 1 1 1,000.00 500.00 500.00 50.00% 1 1 distribution of a particular
Item B 2 100.00 20.00 30.00 50.00 50.00 13,796.14 2
Item C 4 1 2,000.00 800.00 1,200.00 40.00% 4 1 code (other than Major
Item D 3 1 300.00 300.00 300.00 - 3 1 Code 2) was not known
Item E 2 1,000.00 500.00 500.00 50.00% 2 entirely for a particular
Item F 2 100.00 20.00 30.00 50.00 50.00 50.00 2
Item G 2 100.00 20.00 30.00 50.00 50.00 50.00 2 year by Department, the
Item H 2 100.00 20.00 30.00 50.00 50.00 50.00 2 distribution of Code 2 was
Item I 9 150.00 75.00 75.00 50.00% 9
utilized for the distribution
Item J 2 2,000.00 1,000.00 1,000.00 50.00% 2
Item K 1 2 400.00 200.00 200.00 50.00% 1 2 of share of expenditure for
Item L 4 1 50.00 20.00 10.00 20.00 20.00 30.00 4 1 all other codes.
333
Appendix Table 10
Percentage Share of Expenditure Incurred in Singapore in relation to Straits
Settlements by Class of Account and Department
Share of
Singapore
Agricultural Department 1919-1939 25%
Civil Services 1905,1921-1934 75%
Colonial Development Fund, Grants-in-aid 1931-1939 75%
Co-Operative Societies 1927-1939 25%
Director of supplies, S.S and F.M.S 1921 75%
Fisheries 1923-1939 25%
General Clerical Service 1927-1939 25%
Immigration 1934-1939 50%
Imports, Exports and Statistics 1922-1923 75%
Malayan Civil Service 1934-1935 25%
Malayan Establishments 1934-1937 25%
Museum and Library 1900-1939 100%
Pensions and Allowances 1910-1939 50%
Political Intelligence 1926-1929 25%
Printing 1910-1939 100%
Public Trustee 1939 50%
Straits Settlements Civil Services 1935-1939 75%
Subventions 1939 75%
Survey Department 1920-1939 50%
Survey Department: Meteorological branch 1937-1938 50%
Veterinary (Principal Veterinary Officer S.S & F.M.S) 1933 25%
War Expenditure 1914-1920 75%
334
Appendix Figure 1
Case 1: All Capitalized Construction work and Machinery and Equipment (M&E) was purchased from Private
Contractors
1 Compensation of Employees
Output of Producers of
2 Intermediate Consumption
Government Services
Repairs and Maintenance B
3 Consumption of Fixed Assets
1 Compensation of Employees
Output of Producers of
2 Intermediate Consumption
Government Services
Repairs and Maintenance D
3 Consumption of Fixed Assets
Case 2: Construction work and capital formation in Machinery and Equipment (M&E) was partially done by PWD
and the rest was purchased purchased from Private Contractors
1 Compensation of Employees
Output of Producers of
Output Capitalized B
2 Intermediate Consumption
Government Services
3 Consumption of Fixed Assets Repairs and Maintenance C
1 Compensation of Employees
Output of Producers of
Output Capitalized E
2 Intermediate Consumption
Government Services
3 Consumption of Fixed Assets Repairs and Maintenance F
335
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Annual Reports
336
____________, Johore, 1933.
Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions and Protectorates,
1902-07.
337
Statistical Tables Relating to the Colonial and Other Possessions of The United
Kingdom, 1899-1901.
Monthly Bulletins
Malayan Statistics Monthly Digest of Economic and Social Statistics Relating to the
Colony of Singapore and the Federation of Malaya, 1958-60.
Cavendish A. (1911). Report on the Census of Kedah and Perlis, 1911, Penang: The
Criterion Press Ltd.
Chua, S.C. (1957). Report On the Census of Population, 1957, Singapore: State of
Singapore.
Innes, J.R. (1901). Report on the Census of the Straits Settlements, 1901, Singapore:
Government Printing Office.
Marriot, Hayes (1912). Census Report of the Straits Settlements, 1911, Singapore:
Government Printing Office.
Nathan, J. E. (1922). The Census of British Malaya (The Straits Settlements, Federated
Malay States and Protected States of Johore, Kedah, Perlis, Kelantan, Trengganu and
Brunei), 1921, London: Waterloo & Sons Limited.
Vlieland, C.A. (1932). A Report On The 1931 Census and On Certain Problems of Vital
Statistics, British Malaya (The Colony of The Straits Settlements and the Malay States
under British Protection, namely The Federated Malay States of Perak, Selangor,
Negeri Sembilan and Pahang and the States of Johore, Kedah, Kelantan, Trengganu,
Perlis and Brunei), London: The Crown Agents For The Colonies.
Special Reports
338
Commission Appointed to Inquire into Matters Relating to the Use of Opium in the
Straits Settlements and the Federated Malay States and British Malaya Opium
Committee (1924). Proceedings of the British Malaya Opium Committee, Singapore:
Government Printing Office.
Department for Economic and Social Affairs, Statistics Division, United Nations (1999).
Studies in Methods, Handbook of National Accounting, Series F, No.77, A Systems
Approach to National Accounts Compilation, A Technical Report, New York: United
Nations.
Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Statistical Office of the United Nations
(1968). A System of National Accounts, (SNA68), Studies in Methods, Series F, No.2,
Rev.3, New York: United Nations.
Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Statistics Division, United Nations (1997).
Principles and Recommendations for Population and Housing Censuses, Revision 1,
Statistical Papers, Series M No. 67/Rev.1, New York: United Nations.
339
___________________, Singapore (2008). Import and Export Price Indices, January
2008, Singapore: Government Printing Office.
International Monetary Fund (2001). The Government Finance Statistics Manual, New
York: IMF.
Milles, J.I. (1931). Report of The Commission on The Temporary Allowances, Family
Budget 1930, Singapore: Government Printing Office.
OECD (2007). OECD Fact Book 2007: Economic, Environmental and Social Statistics,
Paris: OECD.
Abeysinghe, Tilak and Keen Meng Choy (2007). The Singapore Economy: An
Econometric Perspective (Routledge Studies in the Growth Economies of Asia),
London: Routledge.
340
Abizadeh,S. and Gray, J. (1985). “Wagner’s law: a pooled time-series, cross-section
comparison”, National Tax Journal, Vol. 38, pp. 209–218.
Abraha, Gebru Garred (2004). Export Instability and Economic Growth in Ethiopia,
Dakar: African Institute for Economic Development and Planning.
Ahsan, Syed M., Andy, C.C. Kwan and Balbir S. Sahni (1989). “Causality between
Government Consumption Expenditure and National Income: OECD Countries”, Public
Finance, Vol.2, pp.204-24.
Alan Heston, Robert Summers and Bettina Aten, (2002). Penn World Table Version 6.1,
Center for International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania (CICUP).
Alexander, W.R (1990). “Growth: Some Combined Cross-Sectional and Time Series
Evidence from OECD countries”, Applied Economics, Vol. 22, pp. 1197-1204.
Ansari, M.I., D.V.Gordon and Akuamoah, C. (1997). “Keynes versus Wagner: Public
Expenditure and National Income for Three African Countries”, Applied Economics,
Vol. 29, pp. 543-550.
Backus, David K and Patrick J. Kehoe (1992). “International Evidence on the Historical
Properties of Business Cycles”, The American Economic Review, Vol.82, No.4,
pp.864-888.
Barrell, Ray and Sylvia Gottschalk (2004). “The volatility of the output gap in the G7,”
National Institute of Economic and Social Research Discussion Paper No. 230.
341
Bauer, P.T. (1948). The Rubber Industry, A Study in Competition and Monopoly,
London: Longmans, Green and CO.
Bird, R.M. (1971). “Wagner’s Law of Expanding State Activity”, Public Finance, Vol.
26, pp.1-26.
Biswal, Bagala, Urvashi Dhawan and Hooi-Yean Lee (1999). “Testing Wagner versus
Keynes Using Disaggregated Public Expenditure Data for Canada”, Applied Economics,
Vol. 31, pp.1283-1291.
Blanchard, O. and Simon, J. (2001). “The long and large decline in U.S. output
volatility”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol.1, pp.135-164.
Blattman, Chiristopher, Hwang, Jason and Williamson, Jeffrey G. (2004). “The Impact
of The Terms of Trade on Economic Development in the Periphery, 1870-1939:
Volatility and Secular Change, NBER Working Paper, No.10600.
Bleaney, Michael, Greenaway, David (2001). “The impact of terms of trade and real
exchange rate volatility on investment and growth in sub-Saharan Africa, Journal of
Development Economics, pp.491-500.
Booth, Anne (1990). “The Evolution of Fiscal Policy and the Role of Government in the
Colonial Economy”, in Anne Booth, W. J. O’ Malley and Anna Weidemann (eds.),
Indonesian Economic History in the Dutch Colonial Era, Monograph Series 35, New
Haven: Yale University, Southeast Asian Studies.
342
___________________(1997a). “Anglo-German Productivity Differences, 1870-1990:
A Sectoral Analysis”, European Review of Economic History, Vol. 1, pp. 247-267.
Brown, Ian (1994). The British Merchant Community in Singapore and Japanese
Commercial Expansion in the 1930s IN Sugiyama, S and Guerrero, M.C. (eds.).
International Commercial Rivalry in Southeast Asia in the Interwar Period, New
Haven: Yale Centre for International and Area Studies, pp.111-132.
Buchanan, James M. (1975). The Limits of Liberty, Between Anarchy and Leviathan,
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Carrera, J, Feliz, M, Panigo, D. (1999). “Unit roots and cycles in the main
macroeconomic variables for Argentina”, XXXIV Reunión Annual de la Asociación
Argentina de Economía Política.
Carter, Susan B. et al (2006). Historical Statistics of the United States, Earliest Times to
the Present, Millennial Edition, Volume Three, Part C Economic Structure and
Performance, New York: Cambridge University Press.
Cecchetti, Stephen G., Flores-Lagunes, Alfonso and Krause, Stefan (2006). “Assessing
the Sources of Changes in the Volatility of Real Growth”, NBER Working paper,
No.11946.
Chiang, Hai Ding (1963). A History of Straits Settlements Foreign Trade, 1870-1915,
Singapore: National Museum, Singapore.
Chletsos, Michael and Charistos Kollias (1997). “Testing Wagner’s Law Using
Disaggregated Public Expenditure Data in the Case of Greece: 1958-93”, Applied
Economics, Vol. 29, pp. 371-377.
Clarida, Richard, Gali, Jordi and Gertler, Mark (2000). “Monetary policy rules and
macroeconomic stability: evidence and some theory, Quarterly Journal of Economics,
Vol. 115(1), pp.147-180.
Clark, Colin (1937). National Income and Outlay, London: Macmillan Press Ltd.
343
Courakis, Anthony S, Fatima Moura-Roque and George Tridimas (1993). “Public
Expenditure Growth in Greece and Portugal: Wagner’s Law and Beyond”, Applied
Economics, Vol. 25, pp.125-134.
Craft, N.F.R. (1984). “Economic Growth in France and Britain, 1830-1910: A Review
of the Evidence”, Journal of Economic History, Vol. 44, pp. 49-67.
___________(1988). “The Assessment: British Economic Growth over the Long Run”,
Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 4(1), pp. i-xxi.
__________(1997). “Economic Growth in East Asia and Western Europe Since 1950:
Implications for Living Standards Since 1950”, National Institute Economic Review,
Vol. 162, pp. 75-84.
Dawe, David C. (1996). “A New Look at the Effect of Export Instability on Investment
and Growth”, World Development, Vol. 24, pp. 1905-1914.
De Ferranti D., Perry, G., Gill, I and Serven, L. (2000). “Securing our future in a global
economy” World Bank Latin America and Caribbean Studies.
344
Demirbas, Safa (1999). “Cointegration Analysis-Causality Testing and Wagner’s Law:
The Case of Turkey, 1950-1990”, Annual Meeting of the European Public Choice
Society, Lisbon:
Dickey, D.A., Jansen, D.W. and Thornton, D.C. (1991). “ A Primer on Cointegration
with An Application to Money and Income”, Review Federal Reserve Bank of ST. Luis,
73(2), pp.58-78.
Dupasquier, Chantal and Patrick N. Osakwe (2006). “Trade Regimes, Liberalization and
Macroeconomic Instability in Africa, Department of Economics, Singapore Centre for
Applied and Policy Economics Working Paper Series, No.2006/04, National University
of Singapore.
Dynan, Elmendorf and Sichel (2006). “Can Financial Innovation Explain the Reduced
Volatility of Economic Activity?”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol.53, pp.123-150.
Edward, C.T. (1970). Public Finance in Malaya and Singapore, Canberra: ANU press.
Emerson, Rupert (1969). Malaysia: Study in Direct and Indirect Rule, 3rd ed., Kuala
Lumpur: University of Malaya Press.
Eng, P. Van Der (2002). “Halting progress: Indonesia’s development experience since
1880”, Itinerario, 26, No.3, pp.15-34.
Engle, R.F and C.W.J. Granger (1987). “Cointegration and Error Correction:
Representation, Estimation and Testing”, Econometrica, Vol. 55, pp. 251-276.
Feder, Gershon (1984). “On exports and economic growth”, Journal of Development
Economics, Vol.12, pp.241-250.
345
Figart, David M. (1925). The Plantation Rubber Industry In The Middle East,
Department of Commerce, Bureau of Foreign and Domestic Commerce, Washington:
Government Printing Office.
Fukao, K. and Ma, D. (2006). “Real GDP in Pre-War East Asia: A 1934-36 Benchmark
Purchasing Power Parity Comparison with the U.S.” Discussion Paper Series, No.132,
Hitotsubashi University Research Unit for Statistical Analysis in Social Sciences (A
COE Program), Tokyo: the Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University.
Fukao, K., Ma, D., and Yuan, T. (2006). “International Comparison in Historical
Perspective: Reconstructing the 1934-36 Benchmark Purchasing Power Parity for Japan,
Korea and Taiwan,” Discussion Paper Series A, no. 442, Tokyo: the Institute of
Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University.
Ganti, S. and Kalluri, B.R. (1978). “Wagner’s Law of Public Expenditures: Some
efficient results for the United States”, Public Finance, Vol. 34, pp.225-33.
Goffiman, Irving J. and Mahar, D.J. (1971). “The Growth of Public Expenditures in
Selected Developing Nations: Six Caribbean Countries 1940-65”, Public Finance, Vol.
23, pp.359-64.
Goh Keng Swee (1995). The Practice of Economic Growth, Singapore: Federal
Publications.
Granger, C.W. (1981). “Some Properties of Time Series Data and Their use in
Econometric Model Specification”, Journal of Econometrics, 16, pp.121-130.
Grist, D.H. (1950). An Outline of Malayan Agriculture, Malayan Planting Manual, No.2,
London: Grand City Press Limited.
Gyles, A.F. (1991). “A Time-domain Transfer Function Model of Wagner’s Law: the
Case of the United Kingdom Economy”, Applied Economics, Vol. 23, pp. 327-330.
346
Halicioğlu, Ferda (2003). “Testing Wagner’s law for Turkey, 1960-2000”, Review of
Middle East Economics and Finance, Vol.1. No.2, pp.129-140.
Haque, M. Emranul and Osborn, Denise R. (2007). “Public Expenditure and Economic
Growth: A Disaggregated Analysis for Developing Countries”, Manchester School, Vol.
75, No. 5, pp. 533-556.
Hayo, B. (1994). “No Further Evidence of Wagner’s Law for Mexico, Public Finance,
Vol. 49, pp.287-294.
Heikkinen, Sakari and Luiten van Zanden, Jan (eds.) (2004). Explorations in economic
growth, Essays in Measurement and Analysis, A Festschrift for Riitta Hjerppe on her
60th Birthday, Amsterdam: Aksant Academic Publishers.
Helms, L. (1985). “The Effect of State and Local Taxes on Economic Growth: A Time
Series-Cross Section Approach”, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 67 (3),
pp.574-582.
Hicks, George H. (eds.) (1993). Overseas Chinese Remittances from Southeast Asia,
1910-1940, Singapore: Select Books.
Hodrick, R. and Prescott, E.C. (1980). “Post-War U.S. Business Cycles: An Empirical
Investigation”, mimeo, Carnegie-Mellon University, Pittsburgh, P.A.
Hsieh, E. and Kon S. Lai (1994). “Government Spending and Economic Growth: The
G-7 Experience”, Applied Economics, Vol. 26, pp. 535-542.
Huang, Chiung-Ju (2006). “Testing Wagner’s Law Using Bounds Test and a New
Granger Non-Causality Test: Evidence for Taiwan”, The Journal of American Academy
of Business, Cambridge, Vol.8 (2), pp. 86-90.
Huff, W.G. (1993). “The development of the rubber market in pre-World War II
Singapore”, Journal of Southeast Asian Studies, 24(2), pp.285-306.
347
__________(1994). The Economic growth of Singapore, Trade and development in the
Twentieth Century, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
_________ (2003a). “Currency Boards and Chinese Banks in Malaya and the
Philippines before World War II”, Australian Economic History Review, Vol.43, No.2,
pp.125-139.
Huff, W.G. and Caggiano, Giovanni (2007). “Globalization, Immigration, and Lewisian
Elastic Labor in Pre–World War II Southeast Asia”, The Journal of Economic History,
Vol. 67, No. 1, pp. 33-68.
International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD) (1955). The Economic
Development of Malaya, Report of a Mission organized by the International Bank for
Reconstruction and Development (IBRD) at the request of The Government of the
Federation of Malaya, the Crown Colony of Singapore and the United Kingdom,
Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press.
Islam, Anisul, M. (2001). “Wagner’s Law Revisited: Cointegration and Exogeneity test
for the USA”, Applied Economics Letter, Vol. 8, pp. 509-515.
J.-P. Smits, E. Horlings and J. L. van Zanden (2000). Dutch GNP and Its Components,
1800-1913, Groningen: Groningen Growth and Development Centre, Monograph Series
No.5.
Jang, Byung K. and Nakabayashi, Sinichi (2005). “Some Issues in Medium-Term Fiscal
Policy” in Singapore- Selected Issues, IMF Country Report 05/140, Washington, DC:
International Monetary Fund (April).
Kahn, James A., Margaret Mary McConnell, and Gabriel Perez Quiros (2002). “On the
causes of the increased stability of the U.S. economy”, Economic Policy Review of the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Vol.8 (1), pp.183-206.
Kent, Christopher, Smith Kylie and Hollaway, James (2005). Declining Output
Volatility, What role for Structural Change? , Research Discussion Paper, 2005-08,
Economic Group, Reserve Bank of Australia.
348
Khan, A.H. (1990). “Wagner’s Law and the Developing Economy: A Time-Series
Evidence form Pakistan”, The Indian Journal of Economics, Vol. 38, pp.115-123.
Kneller, R. Bleany, M.F. and Germell, N. (1999a). “Growth, Public Policy and the
Government Budget Constraint: Evidence from OECD Countries”, Discussion Papers
in Economics, DP 98/14, University of Nottingham.
Kratoska, Paul H. (1990). The British Empire and the Southeast Asian Rice Crisis of
1919-1921, Modern Asian Studies, Vol.24, No.1, pp.115-146.
_____________ (2000). “Imperial Unity Versus Local Autonomy, British Malaya and
the Depression of the 1930s”, in Weathering The Storm, The Economies of Southeast
Asia in the 1930s Depression edited by Peter Boomgaard and Ian Brown, Singapore:
Institute of Southeast Asian Studies, pp.271-294.
Krause, Lawrence B., Koh Ai Tee and Lee (Tsao) Yuen (1987). The Singapore Economy
Reconsidered, Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.
Kremers, J.M., Erisccos, N.R. and Dolado, J.J. (1992). “The Power of Cointegration
Test”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 54, pp.325-346.
Kuznets, Simon (1934). “National Income, 1929-1932”, NBER Bulletin, No. 49,
pp.17-19.
Kydland, F.E. and Prescott, E.C. (1982). “Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations”,
Econometrica, 50, pp.1345-1370.
349
Lee, Kuan Yew (2000). From Third World To First, The Singapore Story: 1965-2000,
Singapore: Times Media Private Limited.
Lee, Sheng Yi (1990). The Monetary and Banking Development of Singapore and
Malaysia, 3rd ed., Singapore: Singapore University Press.
Lee, Soo Ann (1974). Economic Growth and the Public Sector in Malaya and
Singapore, 1948-1960, Singapore: Oxford University Press.
Lim Chong Yah (1967). Economic Development of Modern Malaya, Kuala Lumpur:
Oxford University Press.
_____________(2004). Southeast Asia The Long Road Ahead, 2nd ed., Singapore: World
Scientific.
Lim, David (1974). “Export Instability and Economic Development: The Example of
West Malaysia”, Oxford Economic Papers, Vol.54, No.2 (March), pp.78-92.
Lloyd, Peter J. and Roger J. Sandilands (1986). “The trade sector in a very open
re-export economy”, in Lim Chong-Yah and Peter Lloyd (eds.), Resources and Growth
in Singapore, Singapore: Oxford University Press.
Loh, Wei Leng (2005). Centering the Periphery: New Forays in Malaysian Economic
History, Kuala Lumpur: Inaugural Lecture, Faculty of Arts and Social Sciences,
University of Malaya.
Love, J. (1977). “The Decline in Export Instability?”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and
Statistics, Vol.39, No.4, pp.355-359.
______ (1992). “Export Instability and the Domestic Economy: Questions of Causality”,
Journal of Development Studies 28, July, pp.735-742.
350
Maddison, Angus (1998). Chinese Eeconomic performance in the long-run, Paris:
OECD.
Maede, J.r. and R.Stone (1941). “The Construction of Tables on National Income,
Expenditure, Savings and Investment”, Economic Journal, Jun-Sept, pp.216-233.
Mann, Arthur J. (1980). “Wagner’s Law: An Econometric Test for Mexico, 1925-1976”,
National Tax Journal, Vol. 33, pp. 189-201.
Martin, B. and Rowthorn, R. (2004). “Will stability last?”, UBS research paper, March.
Mendoza, Enrique (1994). “Terms-of-trade uncertainty and economic growth: are risk
indicators significant in growth regressions?”, International Finance Discussion Papers,
No. 491.
__________________ (1995). “The Terms of Trade, the Real Exchange Rate, and
Economic Fluctuations”, International Economic Review, Vol.36 (February),
pp.101-137.
Mizoguchi, Toshiyuki and Umemura, Mataji (eds.) (1988). Basic Economic Statistics of
Former Japanese Colonies 1895-1938, Estimates and Findings, Tokyo: Toyo Keizai
Shinposha.
Mofidi, A and Stone, J. (1990). “Do State and Local Taxes affect Economic Growth?”,
Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 72 (4), pp. 686-691.
351
Muhsam, H.V. (1960). “Population Estimates Based on Census Enumeration and
Coverage Check”, Population Studies, Vol.13, No.3, pp.278-281.
Musgrave, Richard A. (1969). Fiscal System, New Haven: Yale University Press.
Nagarajan, P. and Spears, A. (1990). “An Econometric Test of Wagner’s Law for
Mexico: A Re-examination, Public Finance, Vol. 45, pp.165-168.
Nathan Balke and Robert J. Gordon (1989). “The Estimation of Prewar Gross National
Product: Methodology and New Evidence, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 97(1),
pp.38-92.
Nelson, C and Plosser, C. (1982). “Trends and Random Walks in Macroeconomic Time
Series: Some Evidence and Implications”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 10, pp.
139-162.
Odaka, Konosuke (2007). “Exploring and Sharing Asian Economic History: An Interim
Report on the Asian Historical Statistics Database Project”, Discussion Paper Series,
No.227, Hitotsubashi University Research Unit for Statistical Analysis in Social
Sciences (A 21st-Century COE Program), Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi
University.
Ohkawa, K., Shinohara, Miyohei and Umemura, Mataji (eds.) (1974). Estimates of
Long-Term Economic Statistics of Japan since 1868, Vol. No. 1, National Income.
Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shinposha.
Oxley, Les (1994). “Cointegration, Causality and Wagner’s Law: A Test for Britain
1870-1913”, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 41 (3), pp. 286-298.
Ozler, Sule and Harrigan, James (1988). “Export Instability and Growth”, Department
of Economics Working Paper, No.486, University of California, Los Angeles.
Pack, H. and Westphal, L.E. (1986). “Industrial strategy and technological change:
theory versus reality”, Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 22(1), pp.87-128.
352
Peacock, A.T. and Wiseman, J. (1961). The growth of public expenditure in the United
Kingdom. London: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Peebles, Gavin and Peter Wilson (1996). The Singapore Economy, Cheltenham: Edward
Elgar.
Philips, P. C. B. and Perron, P. (1988). “Testing for a Unit Root in Time Series
Regression”, Biometrica, Vol. 75, pp.335-346.
Pluta, J.E. (1979). “Wagner’s Law, Public Sector Patterns, and Growth of Public
Enterprises in Taiwan”, Public Finance Quarterly, Vol. 7, pp.25-46.
Prest, A.R. and Adams, A.A. (1954). Consumers’ Expenditure in the United Kingdom,
1900-1919. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ram, Rati (1986). “Government Size and Economic Growth: A New Framework and
Some Evidence from Cross-Section and Time-Series Data”, American Economic
Review, Vol.76 (1), pp.191-203.
Ramey, Garey and Ramey, Valerie A. (1994). “Cross-Country Evidence on the Link
between Volatility and Growth”, American Economic Review, Vol.85 (5), pp.1138-1151.
Rapach, D. (2002). “Are Real GDP Levels Nonstationary? Evidence from Panel Data
Tests”, Southern Economic Journal, Vol.68, No.3, pp. 473-495.
353
Rouvray, Cristel de (2004). “Seeing the world through a National Accounting
Framework: economic history becomes quantitative” in Programme including New
Researchers Paper & Abstracts of the other Academic Papers, The Economic History
Society Annual Conference 2004, London: The Economic History Society, pp.157-164.
Roy, Tirthankar (2000), The Economic History of India, 1857-1947, New Delhi: Oxford
University Press.
Sachs, Jeffrey D. and Andrew Warner (1995). “Economic reform and the process of
global integration”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1.
Saw, Swee Hock, (1999). The Population of Singapore, Singapore: Institute of southeast
Asian Studies.
Sharom Ahmat (1965). “American trade with Singapore, 1819-1865”, Journal of the
Malaysian Branch Of the Royal Asiatic Society, 38(2):241-257.
Shimizu, Hiroshi and Hirakawa, Hitoshi (1999). Japan and Singapore in the World
Economy: Japan’s Economic Advance into Singapore, 1870-1965, London: Routledge.
Simon, J.L. (1986). Theory of Population and Economic Growth, New York: Blackwell.
Singh, Ajit and Fagernäs, Sonja (2006). “Globalisation, Instability and Economic
Insecurity”, Centre for Business Research, Working Paper, No.328, University of
Cambridge.
Singh, Balvir and Balbir S. Sahni (1984). “Causality between Public Expenditure and
National Income”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 66 (4), pp. 630-644.
Singh, G. (1996). “Wagner’s Law – A Time Series Evidence from the Indian Economy”,
The Indian Journal of Economics, Vol. 44, pp.349-359.
Sinha, Dipendra (1999). “Export Instability, Investment and Economic Growth in Asian
Countries: A Time Series Analysis”, Center Discussion paper, No. 799, Economic
Growth Center, Yale University.
Sosa-Escudero, W. (1997). “Testing for Unit Roots and Trend-Breaks in Argentine Real
GDP”, Económica, Vol. 43, pp.123-142.
Stock, James H. and mark W. Watson (1988). “Variable Trends in Economic Time
Series”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol.2, No.3, pp.147-174.
354
______________________________ (1999). “Business Cycle Fluctuations in US
macroeconomic Time Series”, in John b. Taylor and Michael Woodford (eds.),
Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol.1.A, Amsterdam: Elsevier B.V.
Straits Settlements and Federated Malay States (1909). Agricultural Bulletin, No.5,
Vol.8, Appendix B, pp.237-238.
Tan, Eu Chye (2003). “Does Wagner's law or the Keynesian paradigm hold in the case
of Malaysia?”, Thammasat Review, Vol. 8, No.1, pp.62-75.
Tan, Shu-hung (1997). “Budgetary guidelines and fiscal performance in Hong Kong”,
International Journal of Public Sector Management, Vol. 10, No. 7, pp. 547-571.
Tanzi, Vito and L. Schuknecht (2000). Public Spending in the 20th Century, A Global
Perspective, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Taylor, W.C. (1949). Local Government in Malaya, Alor Star: Kedah Government Press.
Thornton, John (1999). “Cointegration, Causality and Wagner’s Law in 19th Century
Europe”, Applied Economics Letters, Vol. 6, pp. 413-416.
Trocki, Carl, A. (1990). Opium and Empire: Chinese Society in Colonial Singapore,
1800-1910, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
355
Tsangyao Chang (2002). “An Economic Test of Wagner’s Law for Six Countries Based
on Cointegration and Error-Correction Modeling Techniques”, Applied Economics,
Vol.34, pp. 1157-1169.
Vatter, H.G. and Walker, J.F. (1986). “Real Public Sector Employment Growth,
Wagner’s Law, and Economic Growth in the United States”, Public Finance, Vol. 41,
pp.117-137.
Wagner, R.E. and Weber, W.E. (1977). “Wagner’s Law, Fiscal Institutions and the
Growth of Government”, National Tax Journal, Vol. 30, pp.59-68.
Westphal, L., Kim, L. and Dahlman, C. (1985). “Reflections on the republic of Korea’s
Acquisition of Technological Capability”, in N. Rosenberg and C. Frischtak (eds.),
International technology Transfer: Concepts, Measures and Comparisons, New York:
Praeger, pp. 167-221.
Wilson, Peter and Peebles, Gavin (2005). “Don’t Frighten the Horses- the Political
Economy of Singapore’s Foreign Exchange Rate Regime since 1981”, Singapore Centre
for Applied and Policy Economics (SCAPE) Working Paper No.2005/06.
Wing, Yuk (2005). “Government Size and Economic Growth: Time-Series Evidence for
the United Kingdom, 1830-1993”, Econometric Working Paper EWP0501, Department
of Economics, University of Victoria.
Wong Lin Ken (1978). “Singapore’s growth as an entrepot port 1819-1941”, Journal of
Southeast Asian Studies, 9(1), pp.50-85.
______________ (1991). Commercial Growth Before the Second World War, in Chew,
Ernest C.T. and Lee, Edwin (eds.), A History of Singapore, Singapore: Oxford
University Press, pp.41-65.
356
Yeoh, Brend S.A (1993). “Urban Sanitation, Health and Water Supply in Later
Nineteenth and Early Twentiedh Century Colonial Singapore”, South East Asia
Research, 1(2), pp.143-172.
_______________ (1996). Contesting Space: Power Relations and the Urban Built
Environment in Colonial Singapore, Kuala Lumpur: Oxford University Press.
Unpublished Sources
Choo, Eng Kang (1976). “The Singapore Trade Depression, 1920-22”, Academic
Exerciese, Department of History, National University of Singapore.
Hernaikh Singh Dhaliwal (1989). “Poverty in Singapore in the 1920s and 1930s”,
Academic exercise, Department of History, National University of Singapore.
Oshima, Harry T. (1956). “A Critique of the National Income Statistics Selected Asian
Countries”, Ph.D thesis, Columbia University.
357
Ruhana Padzil (1999). “Perbekalan Air Johor-Singapura” (Water Supply from State of
Johore to Singapore), M.A Thesis, Department of Southeast Asian Studies, Faculty of
Arts and Social Sciences, Kuala Lumpur, University of Malaya.
Teo, Mary Celine Kiew Ting (1962). “The Development of the Port of Singapore,
1819-1959”, Academic exercise, Department of Geography, University of Malaya.
Online Sources
National Institute of Health and Nutrition (NIHN), Japan (1995). Health and Nutrition
Information Infrastructure Database System. Available at:
http://health02.nutritio.net:8888/nns/owa/nns_index_e.nk1100 (accessed 6th January
2008).
Asian Development Bank (2001). Key Indicators of Developing Asian and Pacific
Countries. Available at:
http://www.adb.org/Documents/Books/Key_Indicators/2001/sin_ki2001.xls (accessed
6th January 2008).
Asian Development Bank (2005). Key Indicators of Developing Asian and Pacific
Countries. Available at:
http://www.adb.org/Documents/Books/Key_Indicators/2005/xls/SIN.xls (accessed 6th
January 2008).
CD-ROM
358