BBM - 978 1 349 19852 8/1
BBM - 978 1 349 19852 8/1
BBM - 978 1 349 19852 8/1
Introduction
The examination questions that follow are actual finals papers from
the Economics course within the B.Sc.Econ. honours degree. Each
paper represents assessment for a one-year course in Managerial
Economics which builds upon a previous course in Microeconomics.
Students are required to answer four questions in three hours.
I am grateful to the University of Wales for permission to
reproduce these papers. They have been included in an attempt to
overcome the artificiality of study questions tacked on to the end of
chapters. The questions are followed by some notes on answers to
guide the student. Remember that in economics examinations there
are no right (or wrong) answers- just answers that gets lots of marks
and those that don't!
Within Cardiff Business School, Managerial Economics is taught
in three courses, two undergraduate as part of the B .Sc.Econ degree
(according to specialism), and one postgraduate (within the M.B.A .
degree) . Papers are taken from the Economics course for conveni-
ence only.
1. 'The most we can say about the Demand Curve is that it slopes down
unless it slopes up.' Discuss.
332
Examination questions and answer notes 333
ECONOMICS 1986
Time allowed - 3 hours
Answer FOUR questions
1. Critically assess the view that an understanding of the principles of
'scientific' decision-making is fundamental to the success of a modern
economy.
Examination questions and answer notes 335
2. (i) Explain the concept of opportunity loss, and show that the
minimum opportunity loss is equal to the Expected Value of
Perfect Information.
(ii) The failure rate in a particular examination is estimated to be
40%. Construct a table showing the probabilities of 0, 1, 2 . . .5
students failing in a sample of five.
(iii) 150 graduate entrants are due to take their first professional
accounting exam at the Institute of Certifiable Accountants.
The probability distribution for the failure rate is estimated in
the following table :
Failure rate Probability
0.1 0.1
0.2 0.2
0.3 0.3
0.4 0.3
0.5 0.1
Each failing student is entitled to a £10 refund on professional
fees. The Institute's senior tutor is confident that she could
ensure a failure rate of 0.1 by holding an intensive revision
course, at a cost to the Institute of £300. Advise the Institute on
whether the revision course should take place.
A tutorial test of five students resulted in no failures. Use this
information to revise the failure rate probability distribution,
and hence reassess the revision course.
3. 'Despite being a small local shopkeeper I can always beat the price
that Woolworths charge for the same product. Woolworths must pay
rent on its store while I own my shop and have no rent to pay.'
Discuss.
4. A firm keeps a record of sales and prices over the past seven months,
resulting in the following table:
Price (£/ton) Sales (tons)
Nov. 1985 7.5 84.5
Dec. 8.0 82.0
Jan. 1986 8.0 84.0
Feb. 7.2 92.0
March 7.0 95 .0
April 8.0 92.0
May 8.5 91.5
Use these observations to estimate demand as a linear function of
both price and time. Utilise this function to estimate demand for the
following month, on the assumption that:
(a) price remains unchanged,
(b) price increases to £9/ton.
336 Managerial Economics
ECONOMICS 1987
ECONOMICS 1988
(a) Find the expected cost of overhaul that would make the risk-
neutral decision-maker indifferent between overhauling or not.
(b) The decision-maker decides to seek further information. Contact
with the machinery supplier suggests an overhaul is equally likely
to cost either £175 or £225, depending on the problems encoun-
tered. Moreover a sample run of 10 items is produced, resulting
in 2 defectives. Use this new information to re-assess the
overhauling decision.
(c) How would the decision be influenced by:
(i) the firm's precarious financial position;
(ii) the knowledge that the machinery is to be scrapped after
the next production run.
10. 'Opportunity cost is both subjective and speculative. As such the
concept of opportunity cost has no place in the scientific decision-
making process.' Discuss.
11. (a) Briefly explain the significance of the firm's cost of capital. What
are the factors determining that cost of capital, and how can that
cost be estimated?
(b) Given that debt finance is generally cheaper than equity finance,
explain why the firm is unlikely to use solely debt finance to fund
expansion.
(c) A commodity broker is contemplating the acquisition of a new
computer-driven management information system (MIS) . The
hardware for this would cost an initial £4 million, whilst software
and staff training would cost £1 million for each of the first two
years operation, and £200 000 per year thereafter. After six
years, the system would be due for replacement. However
scrapping the current (manual) system would save staff costs of
£1.5 million each year.
To finance the new investment the broker would use a combina-
tion of debt and equity capital in the ratio 1:3. The broker can
borrow at an interest rate of 10%, whilst interest paid can be set
against the corporation tax liability (currently taxed at 30%).
The broker is a listed company with a current share price of
£3 .00, and current dividend of 15 pence. Over the period the
share price is expected to grow at an annual rate of 6%.
Use the above information to evaluate investment in the new
MIS, finding the net present value and internal rate of return on
that investment.
What other factors should the decision-maker take into account?
342 Managerial Economics
Answer notes
The answer notes that follow are a brief guide to the relevant question, and
in no sense represent full or adequate answers to these questions.
The key to examination success is a series of carefully planned and
executed answers that provide the examiner with the information required.
It is essential that the student preparing for examinations practises
answering questions within the defined time limits. It is a sad experience
for an examiner to meet a paper where the student has only answered three
questions because of time, matched only by the experience of a paper
where five questions have been answered. Please read the preamble to the
questions, and understand what is required.
Economics 1985
1. Questions 1 and 2 are a 'spillover' from the previous year's course,
and should only be answered when all else fails.
2. Without attending the course, and participating in a business game, it
would be most unwise to answer this question.
4. This question requires a careful definition of uncertainty and explana-
tion of the techniques used to make decisions under uncertainty. It is
difficult to argue against the need to make probability estimates in the
face of uncertainty, but caution needs to be expressed about the
methods available. Expected profit requires definition and considera-
tion as a decision objective, pointing out the circumstances in which it
is appropriate (small sums of money or linear utility functions and
repetitive decisions) and evaluating alternative criteria. Refer to
Chapter4.
5. Explain the criteria of minimising expected cost, and apply it to this
problem. Calculate the expected cost with and without the revision
course. Note that 'equally likely' implies a probability of 0.5 to each,
so that the expected failure rate after the course is
(0.05 X 0.5) + (0.10 X 0.5) = 0.075.
Then calculate the likelihood of two fails in a sample of 10 using the
Binomial distribution and combine with the prior probabilities using
Bayes Theorem to find posterior probabilities. Use these posterior
probabilities to determine whether the course should run, using
expected cost or opportunity loss as the decision criteria.
List the assumptions made to answer the question, and assess their
relevance in these circumstances. Refer to Chapter 4.
6. Examine the methods available for demand estimation, comparing
and contrasting the explanatory and extrapolatory approaches. Dis-
cuss the decision about resources to be devoted to demand estima-
tion, primarily determined by the use to which forecasts are to be put.
Explain what is meant by forecast reliability, and how this can be
Examination questions and answer notes 343
Economics 1986
1. A question to be avoided if at all possible! If you must answer it,
explain what is meant by scientific decision-making, by expanding the
framework for decisions encountered in Chapter 1, and then provid-
ing a critique of this, noting the apparent ability of many decision-
makers to 'manage' outside this framework. Refer to Chapters 1
and4.
2. (a) Define opportunity loss (not opportunity cost!) and EVPI. If
opportunity loss is defined as the benefit forgone by not
making the best possible decision, and EVPI is the difference
between the best possible decision and the performance best
achieved without perfect information, it should be easy to show
min EOL = EVPI.
Note a simple example would help.
(b) this is a simple application of the Binomial distribution, with
P(X = x) = 5 Cx(0.4Y(0.6) 5 -x
(c) refer to Chapter 4, pages 85-9. Note the similarity!
3. This question involves the careful definition of implicit and explicit
costs, and is best answered by defining profit as the surplus over
opportunity cost. From an economic view there is little difference
between owning and renting the store, since opportunity costs are
likely to be similar. See Chapter 3.
4. The question involves estimating the parameters of the equation
D, = a+bP+ct
Given lots of time and some computational ability, a, band c can be
estimated by linear regression. In the absence of either, substitution
is an acceptable method if the relevant assumptions are made explicit.
Note that if November is assigned a time value of 1, December 2,
etc., then in April t = 8.
Then estimate elasticity using the arc formula:
!!lD P1 + P2
Ep=-·
!!lP D1 + D2
Sales revenue can be maximised either by finding the total revenue
function (when t = 8) and then differentiating and setting =0, or by
finding the price at which point elasticity = -1.
Note that the method used combines both explanatory and extrapola-
tory approaches and is liable to the problems inherent in each. See
Chapter 5.
5. Explain the short- and long-run cost function C = f(Q), and note the
limitations of each (e.g. dimensions of output). Consider the com-
Examination questions and answer notes 345
Economics 1987
1. A question about the basic philosophy of scientific decision-making,
to be answered only as a last resort! If you must answer the question,
do so analytically, by expounding a scientific framework for deci-
sions, and then examining the circumstances in which that framework
may (or may not) improve the decision process. See Chapters 1 and 4.
2. Explain the profit maximisation hypothesis, and briefly outline the
price/output decision model with profit as the objective. List the
theoretical arguments against this, including informational difficul-
ties, the weakening of competition and the divorce of ownership and
control. Finally explain the empirical evidence: do firms maximise
profits, either by accident (as if) or by design? This question is not an
opportunity to parade a summary of alternative models.
3. This question is a relatively simple application of the 'Newsboy
346 Managerial Economics
Problem', with one or two little twists. Part (a) is answered by using
the formula:
Answering part (b) requires that differing price and income values be
used with the elasticity estimates to estimate sales revenue under
different conditions.
The answers (i) to (iii) generate enough information to set up
simultaneous equations that can be used to answer (iv).
8. Explain what is meant by the discounting approach to investment
appraisal, and contrast this to more ad hoc methods such as payback.
Show that there may be circumstances where information is inade-
quate for discounting, and where other methods more adequately reflect
the firm's objectives. Finally discuss the empirical evidence (which
seems to point to the use of other methods in smaller companies, but
that discounting is increasingly used by large corporations).
9. This question is a spillover from the previous course, although
Chapter 8 might help towards an answer.
10. A difficult question that asks you to judge the effects of advertising in
shifting the demand curve. Whether adverts are persuasive or in-
formative is a matter of psychological judgement: whether advertising
shifts the demand curve is a matter of empirical observation. The
determination of an optimal advertising budget requires a compari-
son of the costs and benefits of advertising that may proceed in a
number of ways, from marginalism through the Dorfman-Steiner
theorem to an informational approach.
11. Another spillover from microeconomics, although Chapter 7 may
help. Basically the answer involves the factors that determine costs,
and the relation of these particular circumstances to the general
theory. The net effects depend on whether the increase in labour
productivity outweighs the increase in wages, together with any
substitution effects.
Economics 1988
1,2. Both ofthese questions reflect the earlier (microeconomics) course, and
should only be answered when all else proves impossible.
3. The evidence that very good decisions are made by some people with
no reference to any decision model is not a refutation of that model.
Bad decisions are also made by not using any decision model, or by
using a model badly. The issue is really whether using a relevant
decision model in a consistent and sensible way leads to decisions that
are, on average, better than the alternatives. In the absence of
reliable data, this remains a matter of belief rather than fact, although
it is interesting that talking through the decision process with
managers often reveals a process that is consistent with the decision
model i.e. objectives are stated, alternatives considered, etc., even
though this process is more implicit than explicit.
348 Managerial Economics
Chapter 1
1. S. Hull and P. Blyton (1985) 'The Practice of Decision-making- Some
Evidence', Managerial and Decision Economics, December.
2. The same approach appears in the literature in a variety of guises. One
interesting (and often humorous) introduction is J. D. Bransford and
B.S. Stein (1984) The Ideal Problem Solver (New York: W. H.
Freeman).
Chapter 2
1. This is actually a necessary but not sufficient condition for maximum
profit. Certain conditions about the nature of the cost and revenue
functions must also be satisfied.
2. For the mathematically initiated,
TC
AC = Q so that TC = AC X Q
MC= dTC/dQ
Therefore
MC = AC . dQ/dQ+ Q. dAC/dQ
MC=AC+Q. dAC/dQ
Now dAC/dQ is just the rate of change of average cost. If AC is falling,
Q. dACidQ is negative, and MC<AC.
3. A linear equation is of the form y =ax+ b, and a and bare constants.
This equation describes a straight line when plotted, with intercept b
and slope a.
4. Unless the slope of the constraint coincides with the slope of the
objective function, in which case the appropriate corner solution must
be as profitable as any point along the constraint.
5. Readers with a burning desire to follow the Simplex method can find it
explained in chapter 12 of J. Gough and S. Hill (1979) Fundamentals of
Managerial Economics (London: Macmillan).
350
Notes and References 351
Chapter3
1. Joel Dean (1951) Managerial Economics (Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
Prentice-Hall), p. 3.
2. Ibid., p. 260.
3. The economist usually denotes profit by 1r (Greek pi). This is used in
preference to the more obvious notation P, because Pis reserved for
price.
4. The process of discounting is extended in Chapter 13.
5. The symbol I (capital Greek sigma) is used to denote the sum of an
n
expression. Thus I X; is the sum of all the x values from x 1 to Xn·
i=l
6. J. R. Hicks (1946) Value and Capital, 2nd edn (Oxford: OUP), p. 172.
7. The situation is analogous to student assignments. Students often
claim that their objective is to maximise marks. But maximum marks
would require continuous and concentrated effort over the assignment
period. Hence, a trade-off is made between marks and effort that is
unlikely to result in maximum possible marks.
8. The shape of these functions is examined in later chapters.
9. The profit maximising output was derived in Chapter 2 as the point
where MC =MR. Note that MCIMR are the slopes of TCITR respec-
tively, and that output Q satisfied this condition.
10. W. J . Baumol (1967) Business Behaviour, Value and Growth, revised
edn (New York: Harcourt, Brace and Wold) .
11. See A. Koutsoyiannis (1979) Modern Microeconomics, 2nd ed. (Len-
don: Macmillan), chapter 15.
12. R. L. Marriss (1963) 'A Model of the Managerial Enterprise', Quarter-
ly Journal of Economics, vol. 77, pp. 185-209.
13. 0. Williamson (1963) 'Managerial Discretion and Business Be-
haviour', American Economic Review, December; reprinted in M. Gil-
bert (ed.) (1973) The Modern Business Enterprise (London: Penguin) .
352 Managerial Economics
14. See, for example, G. H. Rice (1980) 'But How Do Managers Make
Decisions?', Management Decisions, vol. 18, part 4.
15. The progenitor of this approach was Herbert Simon. See especially
H. A. Simon (1955) 'A Behaviour Model of Rational Choice',
Quarterly Journal of Economics, February.
16. R. Cyert and J. March (1963) A Behavioural Theory of the Firm
(Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall).
17. This application is derived from S. P. Neun and R. E . Santerre (1986)
'Dominant Stockownership and Profitability', Managerial and Deci-
sion Economics, vol. 7 (3), pp. 207-10.
Chapter4
1. The source of Figure 4.1 is S. Hill (1986) 'Decision Making Under
Uncertainty - The Divergence Between Theory and Practice', in
S. Jones (ed), Modelling Uncertainty (Fulmer, Hilger).
2. This also assumes that previous stock was always sufficient to meet
demand. The sensible decision-maker would, in addition, use his
experience of any particular circumstances (such as a TV advertising
campaign) to adjust this probability estimate.
3. Given perfect predictive powers, if the probability estimates are cor-
rect, 25 per cent of the time demand of 20 would be predicted, 50 per
cent of the time demand of 30 would be predicted, etc.
4. Ira Horowitz (1972) An Introduction to Quantitative Business Analysis
(Tokyo: McGraw Hill), pp. 57-8.
5. Note also that for individual B, the marginal utility of money (8u/8£) is
decreasing.
6. Derived from D. Bunn and H. Thomas (1977) 'J. Sainsbury and the
Haul of Contraband Butter' , reprinted in G . Kaufman and H. Thomas
(eds) Modern Decision Analysis (Harmondsworth: Penguin), pp. 260-
8.
7. A Poisson distribution is described by the formula
p(X = x) = rre-xlx! where a is the mean and e the natural exponent
(= 2. 718), and is discussed more fully in Chapter 11.
8. Bunn and Thomas, 'J. Sainsbury and the Haul of Contraband Butter',
p. 267.
ChapterS
1. For a more comprehensive explanation, see D. Salvatore (1986) Mic-
roeconomics: Theory and Applications (New York: Macmillan),
pp. 108-23.
Notes and References 353
Chapter6
1. N. Chacholiades (1986) Microeconomics (New York: Macmillan),
p.173.
2. A curve is convex to the origin if the straight line between any two
points on the curve lie above that curve.
3. It is possible that the slope of the isocost may coincide with the slope of
the isoquant. However, even in this case, production at the corner point
will be at least as inexpensive as production anywhere along that
segment of the isoquant.
4. D. J. Pearl and J . L. Enos (1975) 'Engineering Production Functions
and Technological Progress', Journal of Industrial Economics, vol. 24,
September, pp. 55-72.
Chapter7
1. J. Dean (1951) Managerial Economics (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Pren-
tice-Hall), p. 271.
2. A. A. Alchian (1973) 'Costs and Outputs', in M. Abramovitz (ed.)
The Allocation of Economic Resources (Stanford: Stanford University
Press, 1959), reprinted in H. Townsend (ed.) Price Theory
(Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1973), pp. 228-49.
3. J. Dean (1951) Managerial Economics, p. 253.
4. U. E. Reinhart (1973) 'Break-Even Analysis for Lockheeds Tri Star:
An Application of Financial Theory', Journal of Finance , vol. 28,
September, pp. 821-38.
354 Managerial Economics
ChapterS
1. E. A. Robinson, quoted in J. Dean (1951) Managerial Economics
(Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall), p. 67.
2. G. Stigler (1978) 'The Literature of Economics: The Case of the Kinked
Demand Curve', Economic Inquiry, vol. 16, part 2, April, pp. 185-204.
3. D . Needham (1970) Economic Analysis and Industrial Structure (Lon-
don: Holt), p. 19.
4. Ibid., p. 25.
5. J. S. Bain (1956) Barriers to New Competition (Cambridge, Mass. :
Harvard University Press).
6. Ibid.
7. A. Singh (1975) 'Takeovers, Economic Natural Selection and the
Theory of the Firm: Evidence from UK Post-war Experience', Econo-
mic Journal, vol. 85.
8. This application is based on R. W. Shaw and S. A. Shaw (1984) 'Late
Entry, Market Shares and Competitive Survival: The Case of Synthetic
Fibres', Managerial and Decision Economics , vol. 15, no. 2, June,
pp. 72-9.
Chapter9
1. See F. M. Scherer (1970) Industrial Pricing: Theory and Evidence
(Chicago: Rand McNally), chapter 4.
2. F. Modigliani (1958) 'New Developments on the Oligopoly Front' ,
Journal of Political Economy , vol. 66, pp. 215-32.
3. SeeS. Hill (1982) 'The Multi-product Firm: Demand Relationships and
Decision-making', Managerial and Decision Economics, vol. 3, no. 2.
4. See, for example, J. L. Pappas, E . F.Brigham and B. Shipley (1983)
Managerial Economics, UK edition (London: Holt, Rinehart & Win-
ston), chapter 12:
Notes and References 355
Chapter 10
1. Quoted in N. Piercy (1986) Marketing Budgeting (London: Croom-
Helm), p. 2.
2. Quoted by W. Duncan Reekie (1975) Managerial Economics (Oxford:
Philip Allan), p. 208.
3. See, for example, A. Koutsoyiannis (1982) Non-Price Decisions (Lon-
don: Macmillan), pp. 84-6.
4. N. Piercy (1986) Marketing Budgeting, p. 39.
5. This section, loosely based on Blair and Kenny, may be omitted
without loss of continuity. However, perseverence with the concepts
involved may yield a high return. See R. Blair and L. Kenny (1982)
Microeconomics for Managerial Decision Making (Tokyo: McGraw-
Hill), pp. 347-59.
6. The sum of an infinite series is the first term divided by one minus the
common ratio. In this case, the first term is fN, and the common ratio
is(1 - f)(1-b).
7. See, for example, S. Schoeffler et al. (1974) 'The Impact of Strategic
Planning on Profit Performance', Harvard Business Review, March.
8. N. Piercy (1986) Marketing Budgeting.
9. A. Koutsoyiannis (1982) Non-Price Decisions (London: Macmillan)
provides an excellent survey of advertising evidence.
10. H. M. Mann et al. (1967) 'Advertising and Concentration' , Journal of
Industrial Economics, vol. 15, pp. 81-4.
11. D. F. Greer (1971) 'Advertising and Market Concentration', Southern
Economic Journal, vol. 38, pp. 17-32.
12. This case history is based on actual companies, but their names and the
figures given have been altered to protect commercial confidentiality.
356 Managerial Economics
Chapter 11
1. H . A. Taha (1982) Operations Research , 3rd edn (New York: Macmil-
lan), p. 495.
2. F. Lowenthal (1982) 'Cost of Prediction Error in the Economic Order
Quantity Formula', Managerial and Decision Economics, vol. 3, no. 2,
June.
3. Recall that a rectangular hyperbola describes a downwards sloping
curve of constant area. In this case, the area under the curve (TOCxq)
is always constant at rD.
4. It is evident that the expression on the right-hand side has two roots,
and equally evident that only one makes economic sense.
5. This may be an opportune moment to review pages 73-5.
6. P(D ~ n) reads as the probability demand is greater than or equal ton .
7. A Poisson distribution is described by the formula
P(X = x) = tre-xlx! where a is the mean and e the natural exponent
( =2.718). The Poisson distribution is a useful approximation for
random arrival times.
8. For example, J. E. Freund (1972) Mathematical Statistics, 2nd edn
(Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall), p. 434.
9. P(D~ 16) = P(D< 17) = 0.899. Then stocking 16 gives a 90 per cent
service level.
.
10. Smce v'2rDhc = 2 . JrDhc
- 2- .
82 TRC 2DS
11. ~ = - 3- >0, so q* is a minimum.
uq q
12. The idea for this application came from R. Martin and B. Moores
(1935) Management Structures and Techniques (Oxford: Philadelphia)
p. 150, and subsequent conversations with Brian Moores.
Chapter 12
1. In Chapter 7, the marginal cost of output was related to the wage rate
and labour productivity by the equation MC = WIMPL, for a fixed
wage rate. To maximise profit, MC =MR. Substituting, MR = WIMPL
or MPL x MR = W, so that MRPL = W .
2. Generally, MFC = W +a W x N, where W is the new wage rate, a W is
the increase in wages necessary to employ an extra worker, and N is the
number previously employed. In the above case,
MPC= 1 =5+(5x10)= 155.
Notes and References 357
Chapter 13
1. SeeS. Hill and J. Gough (1981) 'Discounting Inflation', Managerial
and Decision Economics, vol. 2 (2), pp. 121-3.
2. Alternatively, a cursory glance at Table 13.1 reveals that £10 000 in
fifty years time (your life expectancy from now) will have a present
value approaching zero, especially when inflation is also taken into
account.
3. Generalising, the present value of a perpetuity offering a uniform £A
per year is Air, where r is the interest rate expressed as a decimal.
4. This section is loosely based on J. Gough and S. Hill (1979) Fun-
damentals of Managerial Economics (London: Macmillan) , pp. 21(}.-
14.
5. Although the implicit cost may be higher; seep. 316.
6. H. M. Markowitz (1952) 'Portfolio Selection', Journal of Finance,
vol. vii (1), March, pp. 72-91.
7. For a full explanation of CAPM, see A. Koutsoyiannis (1982) Non
Price Decisions (London, Macmillan), pp. 609-30.
8. See Koutsoyiannis (1982) Non Price Decisions, pp. 626-30 and Rosen-
berg, B. and Guy, J. (1976) 'Prediction of Beta Co-efficients from
Investment Fundamentals' , Financial Analysts Journal, 32, July.
9. Koutsoyiannis, Non Price Decisions, p . 621.
10. K. Alam and L. Stafford (1985) 'Tax Incentives and Investment
Policy', Managerial and Decision Economics, vol. 6 (1), March,
pp. 27-32.
11. S. Hill et al. (1984) Decision-making in the South Wales Engineering
Industry: A Survey, UWIST, Cardiff, December.
12. E. Miller (1985) 'Decision-making Under Uncertainty for Capital
Budgeting and Hiring', Managerial and Decision Economics, vol. 6
(1), March, pp. 11- 18.
358 Managerial Economics
Chapter 1
Baumol, W. J. (1961) 'What Can Economic Theory Contribute to Manage-
rial Economics', American Economic Review, 51, pp. 142-6.
Bransford, J. D. and Stein, B. S. (1984) The Ideal Problem Solver (New
York: W. H. Freeman).
Call, S. T. and Holahan, W. L. (1984) Managerial Economics (Belmont,
CA: Wadsworth) chapter 1, 'Studying Managerial Economics', pp. 1-16.
Chapter 2
Chiang, A. C. (1974) Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics,
2nd edn (Tokyo: McGraw Hill), chapters 2, 6, 9 and 18.
Gough, J. and Hill, S. (1979) Fundamentals of Managerial Economics
(London: Macmillan), chapters 2 and 12 ('Marginal Analysis' and
'Linear Programming').
Pappas, J. L., Brigham, E. F. and Shipley, B. (1983) Managerial Econo-
mics, UK edn (London: Holt Rhinehart & Winston), chapters 3 and 8.
Chapter 3
Dean, J. (1951) Managerial Economics (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-
Hall), chapter 1.
Kay, J. A. (1977) 'Inflation Accounting - A Review Article', Economic
Journal, 87, 346, pp. 300-11.
Koutsoyiannis, A. (1979) Modern microeconomics (London: Macmillan),
chapters 15-18.
Lee, T. A. (1980) Income and Value Measurement, 2nd edn (Walton-on-
Thames: Nelson), chapters 1 to 3.
359
360 Managerial Economics
Rice, G. H. (1986) 'But How Do Managers Make Decisions?', Management
Decisions, 18, 4.
Silberston, A. (1970) 'Price Behaviour of Firms', Economic Journal, 80,
319, pp. 511-82.
Chapter4
Call, S. T . and Holahan, W. L. (1984) Managerial Economics (Belmont,
CA: Wadsworth), chapter 8.
Gough, T. J. and Hill, S. (1979) Fundamentals of Managerial Economics
(London: Macmillan), chapter 3.
Horowitz, I. (1972) An Introduction to Quantitative Business Analysis, 2nd
edn (Tokyo: McGraw Hill), chapters 1 to 4.
Raiffa, H. (1968) Decision Theory (Reading, Mass: Addison Wesley) .
ChapterS
Davies, J. R. and Chang, S. (1986) Principles of Managerial Economics
(Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall), chapters 4 to 7.
Heineke, J. M. (1976) Microeconomics for Business Decisions (Englewood
Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall).
Salvatore, D. (1986) Microeconomics: Theory and Application (New York:
Macmillan), chapters 3 to 6.
Chapter6
Baird, C. W. (1982) Prices and Markets , 2nd edn (St Paul: West),
chapter 4.
Davies, J. R and Chang, S. (1986) Principles of Managerial Economics
(Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall), chapter 8.
Heineke, J. M. (1976) Microeconomics for Business Decisions (Englewood
Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall), chapters 3, 4 and 5.
Salvatore, D. (1986) Microeconomics: Theory and Applications (New
York: Macmillan), chapter 9.
Chapter7
Dean, J. (1951) Managerial Economics (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-
Hall) , chapter 5.
Further reading 361
ChapterS
Dean, J. (1951) Managerial Economics (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-
Hall), chapter 2.
Griffiths, A. and Wall, S. (1984) Applied Economics (London: Longman),
chapters 5 and 6.
Monopolies Commission (1981) Competition in the Wholesale Supply of
Petrol, reprinted as Reading 3 in L. Wagner (ed.) Readings in Applied
Microeconomics (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Needham, D. (1978). Economic Analysis and Industrial Structure, 2nd edn
(New York: Holt), chapter 3.
Pappas, J . L., Brigham, E. F. and Shipley, B. (1983) Managerial Econo-
mics, UK edn (London: Holt, Rhinehart & Winston).
Chapter9
Dean, J. (1951) Managerial Economics (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-
Hall), chapters 7, 8 and 9.
Kotler, P. (1986) Principles of Marketing, 3rd edn (Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
Prentice-Hall), chapters 13 and 14.
Pappas, J. L., Brigham, E . F. and Shipley, B. (1983) Managerial Econo-
mics, UK edn (London: Holt, Rhinehart & Winston), chapters 11
and 12.
Silberston, A. (1970) 'The Price Behaviour of Firms', Economic Journal,
September.
Chapter 10
Kotler, P. (1986) Principles of Marketing, 3rd edn (Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
Prentice-Hall), <;hapters 17 to 19.
362 Managerial Economics
Koutsoyiannis, A. (1982) Non-Price Decisions (London: Macmillan),
chapter2.
Piercy, N. (1986) Marketing Budgeting (London: Croom Helm), chapters 2
and3.
Chapter 11
Horowitz, I. (1972) An Introduction to Quantitative Business Analysis
(Tokyo: McGraw-Hill), chapter 11.
Martin, R. and Moores, B. (1985) Management Structures and Techniques
(Oxford: Philip Alan), chapter 8.
Taha, H. A . (1982) Operations Research, 3rd edn (New York: Macmillan),
chapter 13.
Chapter 12
Blair, R. D. and Kenny, L. W. (1982) Microeconomics for Managerial
Decision Making (Tokyo: McGraw-Hill).
DeSerpa, A. C. (1981) Microeconomic Theory: Issues and Applications
(Boston: Allyn & Bacon).
Thomason, G . (1981) A Textbook of Personnel Management, 4th edn
(London: IPM).
Chapter 13
Pappas, J. L., Brigham, E. F. and Shipley, B. (1983) Managerial Econo-
mics , UK edn (London: Holt, Rhinehart & Winston), chapter 14.
Koutsoyiannis, A. (1982) Non-Price Decisions (London: Macmillan).
Chapter 14
Bodily, S. E . (1985) Modern Decision Making (New York: McGraw-Hill).
Dennis, L. B. and Dennis, T. L. (1986) Microcomputer Models for
Management Decision Making (New York: West).
Index
363
364 Index