Wine Industry Economics
Wine Industry Economics
Wine Industry Economics
mmorag@uchile.cl
Adeline Alonso Ugaglia
Jean-Marie Cardebat • Alessandro Corsi
Editors
The Palgrave
Handbook of Wine
Industry Economics
mmorag@uchile.cl
Editors
Adeline Alonso Ugaglia Jean-Marie Cardebat
Bordeaux Sciences Agro University of Bordeaux
University of Bordeaux Pessac, France
Gradignan, France
Alessandro Corsi
University of Turin
Turin, Italy
This Palgrave Macmillan imprint is published by the registered company Springer Nature Switzerland AG.
The registered company address is: Gewerbestrasse 11, 6330 Cham, Switzerland
mmorag@uchile.cl
Acknowledgments
This book received contributions from economists from Europe, South and
North America, Australia, South Africa and China. It describes and examines
varying models of wine industry in different countries. Two main models are
generally used to describe wine industries, Old and New wine worlds (appel-
lation regimes vs. brands and varietals), which are generally discussed and
compared with respect to their efficiency. What makes the difference between
these models? The industrial organization does. This book therefore proposes
a discussion of these models and highlights the key variables of the efficiency
of industrial organization in the wine industry worldwide for the first time.
This comprehensive volume is essential reading for students, researchers and
professionals in the wine industry.
Publishing a book is a long way off and this book would have not been
written without the help and encouragement of a lot of people and institu-
tions. This work received a grant from the Excellence Initiative of Bordeaux
University (2014–2015) (Initial Support for Exploratory Projects-PEPS
Emrgc 2014–2015_Adeline Alonso Ugaglia/MOMAVI/Modeling the
wine market in the Traditional Producing Countries (TPC)). Thanks to
this grant we have been able to have all the global experts contributing
together to this challenging project. It has also received the support of the
Bordeaux Wine Economics (BWE) group (bordeaux-wine-economics.
com). We would like to thank particularly our Editorial Advisory Board
who actively participated in this project since the early beginning and have
welcomed our meetings over the years to prepare the book. Of course, this
book would not exist without the contributions of all the authors who
have kindly accepted to take part to this original work. We thank them for
providing high-quality chapters specifically written for the book and to
mmorag@uchile.cl
vi Acknowledgments
comply with all the requirements we had. During the last months, the first
proposal has benefited from the suggestions made by the peer reviewers.
We have also been greatly helped by Laura Pacey and Clara Heathcock
from Palgrave Macmillan in the editorial preparation, and by Sarulatha
Krishnamurthy during the publishing process.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Contents
1 Introduction 1
Adeline Alonso Ugaglia, Jean-Marie Cardebat, and Alessandro Corsi
mmorag@uchile.cl
viii Contents
mmorag@uchile.cl
Contents ix
mmorag@uchile.cl
x Contents
Index531
mmorag@uchile.cl
Editorial Advisory Board
xi
mmorag@uchile.cl
Notes on Contributors
xiii
mmorag@uchile.cl
xiv Notes on Contributors
mmorag@uchile.cl
Notes on Contributors xv
mmorag@uchile.cl
xvi Notes on Contributors
mmorag@uchile.cl
List of Figures
Fig. 1.1 The growth of world wine exports 1995–2017 (volumes in thou-
sands of hL). (Source: OIV stats, http://www.oiv.int/fr/bases-de-
donnees-et-statistiques)3
Fig. 1.2 The emergence of the New World in the world wine trade. (Note:
Exported volumes in thousands of hectoliters; Source: OIV stats,
http://www.oiv.int/fr/bases-de-donnees-et-statistiques)5
Fig. 2.1 French wine imports and exports (in volume and value). (Source:
OIV stats, http://www.oiv.int/fr/bases-de-donnees-et-statistiques)20
Fig. 2.2 Wine production and consumption in France. (Source: OIV stats,
http://www.oiv.int/fr/bases-de-donnees-et-statistiques)22
Fig. 2.3 Evolution of organic surfaces in France (ha). (Source: Agence BIO
2017)29
Fig. 2.4 Wine harvest in France by region and color (2015). (Source:
DGDDI-CVI Harvest 2005–2015) 32
Fig. 2.5 AOC and PGI and wine color (2010). (Source: Agreste Primeur
2011)33
Fig. 2.6 Winemaking processing (volume, 2010). (Source: Agreste Primeur
2011)34
Fig. 2.7 On-farm winemakers’ distribution channels by percentage of vol-
ume. (Source: RGA 2010) 36
Fig. 2.8 Distribution channels (percentage of volume). (Source: Author’s
calculation based on RGA 2010) 37
Fig. 3.1 Geographical divisions and main wine-producing Regions 50
Fig. 3.2 Wine consuption flows. (Source: ISMEA, Scheda di settore 2015) 66
Fig. 3.3 Estimable grape flows among operators for total wine, generic
wine, GI wine, PDO wine. (Map legend: Grape flows share for
total wine (generic wine, PGI wine, PDO wine)) 69
xvii
mmorag@uchile.cl
xviii List of Figures
Fig. 4.1 Evolution of the vineyard area and the production of grapes in
Spain. (Source: Own elaboration from Agriculture Yearbooks and
Agriculture Statistics. MAGRAMA. Spanish Ministry of
Agriculture, Food and Environment (MAGRAMA 2016)) 79
Fig. 4.2 Wine vineyard specialization in Spain (2012). (Source: Own elabo-
ration from the Agriculture Yearbook 2013. MAGRAMA. Spanish
Ministry of Agriculture, Food and Environment (MAGRAMA
2015c))80
Fig. 4.3 Distribution of the main grape varieties in Spain (% on total sur-
face) (2014). (Source: Own elaboration from the Inventory of
wine-growing potential, 2015. MAGRAMA. Spanish Ministry of
Agriculture, Food and Environment (MAGRAMA 2015d)) 83
Fig. 4.4 Economic results of the Spanish viticulture holdings (euro).
([*Preliminary data] Source: Own elaboration from FADN 2018
(European Commission)) 85
Fig. 4.5 The Spanish market for wine (million liters). (Source: OeMv
(2018) (Spanish acronym for Spanish Observatory of Wine
Markets))91
Fig. 4.6 Spanish wine exports. (Source: OeMv (2018) (Spanish acronym
for Spanish Observatory of Wine Markets)) 92
Fig. 4.7 Spanish wine sales structure for the domestic market (%) (e = esti-
mation). (Source: OeMv (Spanish acronym for Spanish Observatory
of Wine Markets)) 95
Fig. 4.8 Wine consumption at home in Spain (liters per capita). (Source:
Own elaboration from MAPAMA. Spanish Agriculture Ministry.
Food Consumption Panel (MAPAMA 2018)) 97
Fig. 4.9 Place of purchase of wine for at-home consumption in Spain (%).
(Source: Own elaboration from MAGRAMA. Spanish Agriculture
Ministry. Food Consumption Panel (MAGRAMA 2015e)) 98
Fig. 5.1 US wine regions—area, volume, and value of production, 2016.
(Source: Created by the authors using data from USDA/NASS
2016a, 2016b, 2017, 2018) 109
Fig. 5.2 Volume shares (%) of tax-paid, domestically bottled wine, by wine
type, 2016. (Source: Created by the authors using data from US
Treasury/TTB 2016c) 116
Fig. 5.3 Volume and value of US imports and exports of wine, 1966–2015.
(Source: Fig. 5 in Alston et al. (2018a). Data are from ITC (2018).
Notes: Nominal monetary values in these graphs were deflated by
the consumer price index (CPI) for all goods taken from USDL/
BLS 2015) 120
Fig. 6.1 Bearing area of vineyards, Australia (upper line) and South Australia
(lower line), 1843 to 2013 (hectares). (Source: Anderson 2015,
Chart 5) 133
mmorag@uchile.cl
List of Figures xix
Fig. 6.2 Vine area, wine production and wine exports, Australia, 1843 to
2013 (log scale). (Source: Anderson 2015, Chart 9) 134
Fig. 6.3 Share of grape production used for winemaking, Australia, 1939 to
2013 (%). (Source: Anderson 2015, Table 8) 134
Fig. 6.4 Shares of table, fortified and distillation wine in total wine output,
Australia, 1923 to 2013 (percentage, three-year moving average
around year shown). (Source: Anderson 2015, Chart 31) 135
Fig. 6.5 Average price of winegrapes and of exports (RH axis), and vine area
(LH axis), Australia, 1986 to 2017 (A$/tonne, A$/hectoliter, and
‘000 hectares). (Source: Anderson 2015, Chart 17) 135
Fig. 6.6 Number of wineries in Australia, 1984 to 2016. (Source: Updated
from Anderson 2015, Table 21) 137
Fig. 6.7 Share of Australian wineries by crush, 1978, 1996 and 2016 (%).
(Source: Updated from Anderson 2015, Table 21) 138
Fig. 6.8 Shares of varieties in Australia’s winegrape-bearing area, 1956 to
2012 (%, three-year averages). (Source: Anderson 2015) 146
Fig. 6.9 Exports as percentage of wine production and imports as percent-
age of apparent wine consumption, Australia, 1843 to 2017 (per-
centage, three-year moving average around year shown). (Source:
Updated from Anderson 2015, Chart 8) 148
Fig. 6.10 Shares of the value of Australia’s exports to various regions, 1990 to
2017 (The 2016 data are for the 12 months to September 30).
(Source: Updated from Anderson and Nelgen 2013, Table 144) (%) 149
Fig. 7.1 Evolution of cultivated surface area of grapes for winemaking in
Argentina (ha). (Source: INV) 156
Fig. 7.2 Variation surface area (1990/2017). (Source: INV) 160
Fig. 7.3 Annual revenues in the viticulture sector (BB AR$ - Dec. 2017).
(Source: Area del Vino) 165
Fig. 7.4 Sales price vs. volume. (Source: Area del Vino) 167
Fig. 7.5 Total market in volume (millions of cases), average sales prices
(AR$ Dec. 2017/case), and annual revenues of wine (BB AR$ Dec
2017). (Source: Area del Vino) 171
Fig. 8.1 Chile: value chain in the wine industry 190
Fig. 9.1 The flow of product in the South African industry, 1982 206
Fig. 9.2 South Africa’s RCA in wine. (Source: Anderson and Pinilla 2018) 218
Fig. 10.1 Evolution of wine consumption and production in China. (Source:
Cossllected from OIV annual reports of World Vitiviniculture
Situation and OIV Statistics, 2013–2017) 226
Fig. 10.2 Main wine regions in China. (Drawn by author) 229
Fig. 10.3 China wine market share by volume. (Source: MarketLine 2015) 233
Fig. 10.4 Wine market share segmentation by color. (Source: MarketLine
2015 and author’s calculation based on Euromonitor International
2011, 2015) 237
mmorag@uchile.cl
xx List of Figures
mmorag@uchile.cl
List of Figures xxi
mmorag@uchile.cl
xxii List of Figures
mmorag@uchile.cl
List of Tables
Table 1.1 The top ten wine importers and exporters in 2017 3
Table 2.1 Surface, number and average size of grape-growing farms by
region (in 2010) (The three top regions, with more than
100,000 ha are in bold) 24
Table 2.2 Areas according to the varietals (%) 25
Table 2.3 Economic size according to the type of wine 26
Table 2.4 Repartition of organic farms and surfaces by region 30
Table 2.5 Four main French wine co-operatives 35
Table 2.6 Turnover of the three main downstream companies—still wine 38
Table 2.7 Cybercommerce in the French wine industry 41
Table 3.1 Number of farms producing wine grapes and vine-bearing area 49
Table 3.2 Italian wine production by type (hl, %) 53
Table 3.3 Total wine production by type of producer (2012) 56
Table 3.4 Shares of total wine production by type of wine, producer, and
area (2012) 57
Table 3.5 Bottling unit distribution by capacity 58
Table 3.6 Top 30 wine companies in Italy 61
Table 3.7 Percentage of Italian domestic supply by distribution channels
(2017, 155 top wine companies) 67
Table 4.1 Profile of the Spanish wine-exporting company in 2017 87
Table 4.2 Top 25 wineries in Spain according their sales in 2014 (million
Euros)88
Table 4.3 Spanish wine exports by type of wine in 2017 93
Table 5.1 Characteristics of US wine regions, 2016 data 107
Table 5.2 California: total grape area and number of grape-producing
farms, 2012 111
Table 5.3 California: size distribution of grape producers, 2012 112
xxiii
mmorag@uchile.cl
xxiv List of Tables
mmorag@uchile.cl
List of Tables xxv
Table 17.2 Mergers’ initial causes and final objectives (number of answers to
these items/number of co-operatives studied) 349
Table 17.3 The determinants of a commitment to merger 354
Table 17.4 Similarity, learning processes and success conditions for merger 356
Table 17.5 Observable organizational changes post-merger 358
Table 18.1 Vineyard price in Bordeaux rouge equivalent 371
Table 18.2 Merchants’ concentration in Bordeaux 375
Table 18.3 Typology of negociants in Bordeaux: variables 376
Table 18.4 Typology of negociants in Bordeaux: results 378
Table 20.1 Number of wine estates according to the wine-grape-growing
area, Burgundy 2011 390
Table 20.2 Efficiency and profitability of wine estates according to size and
business model 398
Table 21.1 Number and wine farms’ allocation 406
Table 21.2 Size, sales and distribution channel 407
Table 21.3 Economic balance by level of vertical integration 410
Table 21.4 Vertical integration and profitability ratios 411
Table 21.5 Vertical integration and financial risk 412
Table 21.6 Product price and price paid to producers 416
Table 21.7 Margins, obsolescence and leverage 417
Table 22.1 Prosecco Superiore DOCG price differentiation by type of supply
chain, wine destination and size on domestic market, 2016 428
Table 22.2 Conegliano Valdobbiadene Prosecco’s companies: concentration
index, 2008–2016 431
Table 22.3 Prosecco Superiore DOCG producers’ distribution by type of
supply chain and bottling size, 2016 431
Table 22.4 Prosecco Superiore DOCG industry structure: evolution over
the period analyzed, 2010–2016 432
Table 23.1 Concha y Toro: expansion of vineyard surfaces 2002–2018 (ha) 445
Table 23.2 Concha y Toro: expansion of vineyard surfaces in Chilean valleys
2005–2015 (ha) 445
Table 24.1 Average export price in 2017 (in € per liter) 457
Table 26.1 Main wine-related Programs for Modernization and
Competitiveness (PMCs) 490
Table 26.2 Concentration of the market shares in the domestic market of
the leading wine firms in Chile (% of the total volumes) 496
Table 26.3 Evolution of wine grape plantings in the main regions in Chile
(2000–2014) (ha) 502
Table 26.4 Evolution of grape variety plantings, wine production, and
exports in Chile (2000–2015) 502
Table 27.1 Consumption, imports and exports (2008–2013) 513
mmorag@uchile.cl
1
Introduction
Adeline Alonso Ugaglia, Jean-Marie Cardebat,
and Alessandro Corsi
A. Alonso Ugaglia (*)
Bordeaux Sciences Agro, University of Bordeaux, Gradignan, France
e-mail: adeline.ugaglia@agro-bordeaux.fr
J.-M. Cardebat
University of Bordeaux, Pessac, France
INSEEC Bordeaux, Bordeaux, France
e-mail: jean-marie.cardebat@u-bordeaux.fr
A. Corsi
University of Turin, Turin, Italy
e-mail: alessandro.corsi@unito.it
mmorag@uchile.cl
2 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
1.1 A
Global Panorama of Trade Flows
from Leading to Emerging Countries
In recent years, growth in world trade has accelerated and competition has
increased. The financial and economic crisis had a deep impact on the world
wine industry, both in the producing countries and in the consumer markets.
The wine market has to face a globalization process like all the other sectors,
following the same phases. Initially concentrated in a small number of coun-
tries, the wine trade has opened up to the world, bringing in new competitors.
In the process of globalization, it is not only the goods that are traded but also
the factors of production. The internationalization of the market therefore
also affects direct investment abroad and labor.
But if the globalization of the sector is today very advanced, we can wonder
how it will evolve and what the consequences for the wine industries are
worldwide. What forms could the future panorama of world trade take?
Several scenarios have to be considered.
Globalization comes with phases of emergence of new countries beginning
to participate in the exchanges. The wine sector is no exception to this
dynamic. After the growth of wine trade within a club limited to a few devel-
oped countries, a second phase of emergence has seen the New World coun-
tries take over. The leaders of the Old World are competing with the outsiders
of this New World, mainly in terms of price competitiveness. A third phase of
emergence is at work. It mainly concerns China, whose vineyard is one of the
largest in the world. The question is to identify when its exports will compete
with those from other producing countries.
Since the 1990s, two remarkable facts have to be noticed concerning the
international wine trade. First, the strong growth in trade, since global wine
exports have globally doubled between 1995 and 2015. Growth is even more
pronounced in value than in volume (see Fig. 1.1), reflecting a rise in the aver-
age quality of wine exchanged on the market. This increase in trade highlights
the globalization of the sector. We can note that global trade has been growing
rapidly and steadily since the mid-1950s and faced a significant decline in
2009 for the first time since the beginning of the decade followed by a rebound
in the following years.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Introduction 3
70000 35000
60000 30000
50000 25000
40000 20000
30000 15000
20000 10000
10000 5000
0 0
1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Old World (le scale) New world (right scale)
Fig. 1.1 The growth of world wine exports 1995–2017 (volumes in thousands of hL).
(Source: OIV stats, http://www.oiv.int/fr/bases-de-donnees-et-statistiques)
Table 1.1 The top ten wine importers and exporters in 2017
Importers Exporters
Euro/ Euro/
Country Volume Value liter Country Volume Value liter
Germany 15.2 2469 1.62 Spain 22.1 2814 1.27
United 13.2 3452 2.62 Italy 21.4 5873 2.74
Kingdom
United States 11.8 5190 4.40 France 15.4 8989 5.84
France 7.6 812 1.07 Chile 9.8 1741 1.78
China 7.5 2458 3.28 Australia 8 1727 2.16
Russia 4.5 878 1.95 South Africa 4.5 583 1.3
Netherlands 4.4 1139 2.59 Germany 3.8 926 2.44
Canada 4.1 1653 4.03 United 3.3 1280 3.88
States
Belgium 3.1 897 2.89 Portugal 3 752 2.51
Japan 2.6 1388 5.34 New Zealand 2.5 1054 4.22
Note: Volumes are in million hectoliters and values in million Euros
Source: OIV stats, http://www.oiv.int/fr/bases-de-donnees-et-statistiques
Second, the high concentration of trade among six countries is the other
feature of wine trade (see Table 1.1). The three largest exporters are tradition-
ally Spain, Italy, and France. In 1995, they accounted for 80% of total exports
in volume, just over 66% in 2017. These exports are largely directed to three
major consumer countries: the United States, the United Kingdom, and
Germany. These countries concentrated 80% of imports in volume in 1995,
about 54% in 2017. The international wine trade thus remains very concen-
trated despite a trend decrease of this degree of concentration.
mmorag@uchile.cl
4 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
The disparities in value and volume reflect the positions of the competitors
in the wine market. Table 1.1 shows that Spain dominates exports in volume,
whereas in value France is in a clear leadership position. These two countries
made different strategic choices. Spain has a very aggressive strategy in terms
of price on the international market, while France, unable to compete in
terms of price, prefers a non-price competitiveness, especially focused on
quality, the country, and the region of origin remaining a very important vec-
tor of image when a consumer purchases a wine. Italy is halfway between
these two competitors in terms of strategic positioning, though it is increas-
ingly moving toward a focus on quality.
The Spanish and French positioning, quite focused on the low or high end,
can pose some problems. Of course, a very large diversity of producers exists
in all countries, in Spain and France in particular, occupying all segments of
the range. It is therefore advisable to remain cautious with the generalizations.
Nevertheless, in Spain, the trap would be to devalue the image of the products
with prices too low and thus prevent some vineyards to be upgraded. The
production of bulk wine at a very low price, which is then exported to coun-
tries bottling and marketing it (mainly France), removes for Spain the main
part of the added value coming of marketing.
For France, the trap would be to leave the segment of low- and mid-range
wines and to promote luxury too much. Obviously, luxury is a segment with
very high added value, but gradually abandoning the lower segments would
lead to the ruin for many vineyards. Luxury is inherently reserved for a small
number of producers. The challenge is to keep a qualitative image for French
producers but without offering exclusive wines, which we open only on rare
occasions. The large size of the French vineyard indeed requires volume strate-
gies and not only exclusive upmarket strategies moving toward the ultra-
premium segments.
From this point of view, and still on a very global scale, the Italian strategy
is probably the most balanced between high-volume production with a good
added value, as attested, for example, by the international success of Prosecco,
and the more exclusive productions from Tuscany and Piedmont.
1.1.2 S
econd Phase: The Emergence of the New World
and the Arrival of Outsiders
Wines from the New World’s countries appeared in the international trade of
wines at the end of the 1990s. Figure 1.2 reveals the intensity of the increase
of exports in volume, while Table 1.1 shows the values of these exports in
mmorag@uchile.cl
Introduction 5
25,000
20,000
15,000
10,000
5,000
0
Italy France Spain Argentina US Chile Australia South China
Africa
1995 2017
Fig. 1.2 The emergence of the New World in the world wine trade. (Note: Exported
volumes in thousands of hectoliters; Source: OIV stats, http://www.oiv.int/fr/bases-de-
donnees-et-statistiques)
2015, both in volume and in value. The last column of this table also shows
the average price of a liter of wine exported by each country.
The performances of Chile and Australia appear to be the most remarkable.
These countries are emerging as the leaders of the New World. Their wine
sector is export oriented and very well organized through clusters drawn by
leading companies. They have raised their brands to top 10 of the world’s
leading brands. These countries are at the same time competitive on the costs
but with, in addition, products and a marketing strategy very adapted to the
Anglo-Saxon consumer. The United States and the United Kingdom are the
two main markets targeted by Chile and Australia.
In terms of pure growth, the case of New Zealand is emblematic with
exports multiplied by nearly 27 between 1995 and 2015. This performance is
all the more remarkable as the average price of wines exported is very high,
close to the prices for France. This shows that this wave of emergence induces
for the Old World a competition that is not only about volumes. Chardonnays
from New Zealand compete with Burgundy wines. This competition is on
price but more and more on quality. The example of the United States is also
symbolic of this quest for quality and high export prices. This country, and
especially California, was the first in the New World to choose constant inno-
vation and a constant search for quality.
mmorag@uchile.cl
6 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
The two New World countries that appear slightly behind compared to the
others are Argentina and South Africa. In the case of Argentina, it is because
the growth of its exports is very low compared to other countries. It is compa-
rable with Germany, a country whose exports of wine are not a priority.
Macroeconomic problems in Argentina partly explain these performances.
Wine exports contracted considerably during the economic crises of the late
1990s and 2008. In this latter case, restrictions on trade and exchange rate
movements are the main reasons for the decline. South Africa is facing a more
structural problem. The export performances are good but remain globally
associated to rather low-end wines. The price of its exports is struggling to
increase and is similar to that of Spain despite lower exports of bulk wine. The
trap of low end combined with low added value is very present in this case too.
But the reason why the countries of the New World are particularly remark-
able regards their marketing strategies. The creation of strong brands is the
main asset of countries like the United States, Australia, and, to a lesser extent,
Chile, the three New World countries with the best export performances.
These brands capture the added value of marketing while capitalizing on very
large volumes and thus achieving massive economies of scale. These brands
are therefore a major vector for the competitiveness of these countries. The
emergence of major international brands is another indication, together with
the emergence of new players, of the entry of the globalization of the wine
sector into a phase of maturity.
Argentina and South Africa have so far failed to develop such brands. In
addition to quality and price, the sustainability of wine is likely to be a crucial
competitive variable that will matter in international trade statistics over time.
In this respect, the countries of the New World are clearly ahead of those of
the Old World.
Other producing countries are gradually becoming part of world wine trade.
The countries around the Black Sea in particular, but also China, which
increased its exports sevenfold between 1995 and 2015, could be part of the
new wave of emergence, that of the “New New World”. China is probably the
best symbol of the changes at stake on the wine market, being the first coun-
try for red wine consumption in the world (the United States being the first
one when considering all types of wines).
On one side, the Old Producing countries still count on the global wine
market, but they are not dominating this market anymore. They are losing
mmorag@uchile.cl
Introduction 7
shares and have to make their strategy evolve. On the other side, the big brands
are from the United States, Australia, and Chile (New World countries), and
compete with the historical champions from the Old World. International
trade follows these trends and continues to grow at a steady pace. Wine is also
facing a financial globalization by becoming a support for financial investments
or even speculation. Wine has finally become a global product since the 2000s.
1.2 G
lobalization of the Wine Market: Two
Models into Question
We often hear about the existence of two main models in the wine industry,
Old and New ones (appellation regimes vs. brands and varietals), which are
generally discussed and compared with respect to their efficiency. From the
three phases described above, we distinguish three groups according to the
moment they appeared in the wine industry:
–– Old/Traditional producing countries also called the Old World: the coun-
tries historically producing wine for centuries as France, Spain, and Italy,
plus Portugal, Germany, and Greece if considering the countries still hav-
ing a significant production (volume and value).
–– New producing countries (New World), which have emerged since the 1950s:
new producing countries as they began to produce wine far after the countries
from the Old World. They had previously no vines and started on the wine
market during the second half of the twentieth century. South Africa,
Argentina, Australia, the United States, and New Zealand belong to this group.
–– New New producing countries (New New World), which appeared on the
international wine market in the recent years (twenty-first century) but some-
times had been producing wine for a long time. They include China, India,
Brazil, and the countries around the Black Sea. For example, although in
Brazil there are a lot of vineyards, only some of them are used for creating
wine. The rest produce table grapes, but the share of the wine production is
increasing. China has been producing grape wine for a long time, but it wasn’t
until the late 1890s that the process of true grape winemaking became rele-
vant, and now there are hundreds of varietals produced all over the country.
The book deals with the main ones in each group, respectively France, Italy,
and Spain for the Old World; the United States, Australia, Argentina, Chile,
and South Africa for the New World; and China for the New New World.
mmorag@uchile.cl
8 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
The way the terms Old/New World are commonly used is often close to
gross generalizations and also refers to differences in style in the specialized
press and media. The differences in Old World and New World wines are
described as coming from winemaking practices (tradition) and from the
effect of land and climate on the grapes, that is, the terroir. They can also
come from rules and regulations that dictate winemaking practices in many
Old World regions which could influence a wine’s style. Old World is often
associated with tradition and history, while New World invokes technology,
science, corporations, and marketing. The industrial organization does make
a difference as well. The actors involved in the industry, their role along the
production process, and the strategies to produce wine in the different coun-
tries can also be described as different ones. Considering the actors involved
in the chain, in the New wine countries most winemakers are processing and
selling wine but do not produce grapes, even if some of them now integrate
the grape production to control the supply part of production. The Old World
relies more on family estates producing grapes and wines with powerful inter-
mediate bodies to sell the wine on the market. To add value to the wine, they
are developing strategies which are often opposed. Old World countries are
used to rely on the denomination of origin and appellation regimes, while
New World countries focus on developing strong brands and “cepage” or vari-
etal wines. The protected designations of origin (PDO)/protected geographi-
cal indication (PGI) system has made the reputation of some famous wine
regions as Bordeaux and Burgundy in France with Grands Crus and Châteaux
and a strong reference to the terroir (soil, climate, and know-how).
But the existence of two different and really distinguishable models is very
often supposed and implicit. Reality is probably more complex with the coex-
istence of different strategies within the different producing countries. This is
one of the reasons why this book addresses several questions: What are the
models of industrial organization in the wine countries? Is it possible to
describe them? Are they really different? To go further into the globalization
at work for wine production, we intend to describe the industrial organization
of the main wine countries according to the international wine trade (France,
Italy, Spain, the United States, Australia, Argentina, Chile, South Africa, and
China) and analyze the status of these countries. In this competing frame-
work, we wonder about the different strategies and their performance.
Regarding the globalization process at work in the wine industry for wine
production, we wonder if the different countries will follow a general conver-
gence trend or if different models can and will coexist in the next years. The
perspective in this regard is the future challenges that producing countries will
face to choose the best strategy for their wine sectors, and this book tends to
highlight the key issues that have to be considered.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Introduction 9
1.3 Outline
The book is divided into five main parts (apart from the introduction and the
conclusion).
Part I aims to identify the different models of wine production in the main
wine-producing countries presented above. Based on the description of the
industrial organization of each wine country, this part represents a first step to
better know and to provide an overall picture of the main features of the wine
industry in the nine main wine countries from different regions: the Old
World (France, Italy, Spain), the New World (the United States, Australia,
Argentina, Chile, South Africa), and the New New World (China). This
allows for reasonable comparisons across countries and to discuss the issue of
wine industry organization in a context of globalization. The focus is set on
the structural features, that is, long-term and not easily changeable character-
istics of the sector, rather than on short-term performances. In each chapter,
the reader will be able to find many different information on the structural
features of the grape-growing/wine-growing sector for the country including
geographical distribution of wine-growing farms in the country, proportion
of wine-growing farms on the overall agriculture, the average size of wine-
growing farms, farm size distribution (small vs. big farms), grape varieties,
appellation vs. generic grapes (where applicable), farming techniques (irri-
gated vs. rainfed, yields, etc.) and related production costs and revenues, land
tenure, family vs. corporate farms. The chapters also include information on
the structural features of the winemaking sector (average plant size and size
distribution of wineries), types of winemaking firms (on-farm winemakers,
wine co-operatives, industrial firms (and shares on total production)), and
types of products (appellation vs. generic wines, brand vs. appellation wines,
marketing strategies, labeling and communication to consumers, number of
brands, price positioning, and volume by segment). Then come the distribu-
tion and the relationships along the distribution chain with the contractual
arrangements along the chain, the role and relative weight of mass retail, spe-
cialized shops, HORECA, and exports as final destinations of the production.
What this first part overall shows is that, though some general differences in
the structures exist between the Old and the New Worlds, they are not always
clear-cut. In particular, the main structural diversities concern the wine farm
sizes, the degree of concentration of the sector, and the role of co-operatives.
But what also emerges is that different models of organization of the chain
coexist. Both winemaker-grape growers and winemakers purchasing grapes
exist everywhere, though accounting for different shares of the domestic
production. The degrees of concentration are quite diverse, but big firms
mmorag@uchile.cl
10 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
relying on their brands exist in both the New and Old Worlds. The valoriza-
tion of specific local characteristics (the terroir and appellation typical model
of the Old World) is increasingly utilized in the New World, be it through
institutional arrangements or informally through the reputation and the
labels.
Part II focuses on the political processes structuring and influencing the
wine market worldwide, a perspective that shows that actors in the wine sec-
tor act and influence rules and standards. In a context of increasing competi-
tion between wines from different countries from all over the world, policies
governing the sector are no longer determined at the national level and have a
strong influence on the structure of wine industries. Therefore, the analysis
focuses here on wine regulations at European and international levels. After
the introduction (Chap. 11), Chap. 12 analyzes the international wine orga-
nizations and plurilateral agreements, and the dialectic between harmoniza-
tion and mutual recognition of standards. This chapter focuses on the role of
the international organizations such as the International Organisation of Vine
and Wine (OIV) and the World Wine Trade Group (WWTG). Through
detailed analysis, this section highlights their differences in philosophies and
goals of action. Then Chap. 13 focuses on the European wine policy, and its
regulations and strategies. It explores the history of the EU wine policies
through the analysis of budget expenditure that has characterized the public
interventions in 45 years (1970–2015). The objective is to analyze the main
drivers that have characterized the EU wine policy from the first CMO in
1962 until the last reform. The authors provide an in-depth analysis of the EU
wine policies identifying three main public policy orientations and strategies
that occurred in those years such as (1) “price and income support”, (2) “qual-
ity of wine”, and (3) “competitiveness”. Finally, Chap. 14 focuses on trade
barriers on wine markets as international wine trade, like any other trade, is
influenced by barriers which are relevant elements of the global wine market’s
institutional setting. Trade barriers result from customs tariffs or from policy
measures that can potentially have an economic effect on international trade
quantity and direction of flows. Wine exporters have actively negotiated pref-
erential trade agreements with importing countries to set lower barriers, and
the authors discuss their potential discriminatory effects. Considering the
current tensions in international relations, they identify a risk for the rising of
trade barriers in the next years and the need to empower an international
institution to harmonize the definitions and rules in wine production and
trade worldwide.
The next three parts are dedicated to the key variables to analyze industrial
organization in the wine sector and its performance: regulation, key actors
mmorag@uchile.cl
Introduction 11
and the governance of the industries, strategies developed by the players as the
vertical integration process.
Part III explores the diversity of business models in the wine industry. It
focuses on different key actors in the wine value chain in the Old World:
grape and wine growers, wine co-operatives, and negociants/wine merchants.
The first chapter of this part (Chap. 15) sets a view of the differences observed
in the industrial organization of the wine sector from the actors’ point of view,
including their strategies. In the Old World, wine industries are more frag-
mented and atomized. So this chapter focuses on the diversity of grape and
wine-growing farms and the variability of their performance, and on the
downstream actors as negociants and wine co-operatives. The author shows
that it is not all about the size but also on the strategies they develop to better
face market demand. Then, the authors of Chap. 16 go deeper into the analy-
sis of vineyard and wineries organization. They use a transaction cost frame-
work to examine the organization of vineyards and winemaking, focusing on
three important organizational features of worldwide production: limited
contracting, small vineyards producing high-quality grapes, and the separa-
tion of wineries from vineyards in the nineteenth century. Then, the part
focuses on particular and powerful actors of the Old wine industries: wine
co-operatives and negociants with French case studies. Chapter 17 presents
the French wine co-operatives and their specific status making them different
from wineries in the New World. The authors mainly analyze how the strate-
gies they set to survive on the market (mergers) impact the territorial anchor-
ing which was constitutive of their existence at the beginning. Then Chap. 18
introduces the negociants and la Place de Bordeaux, embedded in a complex
set of social relationships and governed by various institutions. The author
explores this so particular model in the wine sector and shows the diversity
and shifting power balance between negociants and winegrowers.
Part IV deals with an important driver of the strategies set by the actors
whatever the model and the wine country they are coming from. The chal-
lenge of vertical integration is particularly strong in the wine sector because of
the interdependence of grape growing and winemaking. Wine companies are
facing a process of concentration linked to the search for economies of scale,
investment capacities, and bargaining power vis-à-vis retailers. In this context,
creating value through downstream integration of production can be difficult
for firms, whose financial and human resources are generally limited. This
part examines this issue from different points of view according to the actors
(wine estates but also wine co-operatives and international companies) and
according to the scale (a regional one, concerning Burgundy and Bordeaux
wines, but also regional, national, or international). After an introducing
mmorag@uchile.cl
12 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
chapter (Chap. 19) dedicated to a literature overview on this issue in the wine
sector, Chap. 20 provides a cluster analysis to identify the main differences
among Burgundy wine estates in terms of winemaking outsourcing vs. verti-
cal integration. The authors show that winemaking integration has a positive
effect on wine estates’ profitability in Burgundy. Then, Chap. 21 focuses on
two levels of vertical integration strategies, first in wine estates and then in
wine co-operatives, to explore wine companies’ performance in relation to
their vertical integration level. The results show that such strategies appear as
an efficient way to create value for producers (private cellars and co-operatives
members) but that it should not stop at the bulk-wine production stage. The
next chapter (Chap. 22) analyzes the evolution and the current structure of
the Prosecco Superiore industry at the PDO level, giving qualitative and
quantitative evidence of the role of the different models of supply chain. The
authors highlight the interaction connecting the different supply chains via
the intermediate markets of grape and wine. The intense interrelation among
different operators seems to be one of the key factors of enduring success.
Finally, Chap. 23 goes up to the international level considering the backward
vertical strategies in leading companies, especially in the New World.
The last part finally gives clues to analyze the performance and the effi-
ciency of the wine industries.
Part V addresses the question of the efficiency of the wine industry. Are the
strategies developed in the different countries successful or not? To answer
that question, this part takes different angles to deal with the results the wine
industry got from their different strategies. It first focuses on international
trade and the characteristics of the wine industries coming back to their sta-
tus: Old vs. New World and appellations vs. brands with a simple indication
of origin (Chap. 24). The next chapter (Chap. 25) also considers the appella-
tions vs. brand debate, but from a microeconomic point of view. Indeed, the
results of wine producers have to be considered at firm level, trying to find out
the best way for them to manage reputation, and therefore their sales, either
individually through a brand or collectively through an appellation. This idea
is to overcome the implicit idea widely retained, about the supremacy of
branding in the New World. It starts from the collective reputation model,
analyzes its effects as well as its failures, to show that such a categorization
might be simplistic. Both coexist more and more frequently on the same label.
Then, we chose to present diametrically opposed national case studies of eco-
nomic success in the wine sector to show that different and opposed strategies
can be successful (Chaps. 26 and 27). Indeed, Chile and Switzerland have
both enjoyed great success in the wine industry, but by following completely
different trajectories. These chapters perfectly illustrate the cautious approach
mmorag@uchile.cl
Introduction 13
one must take when addressing questions of efficiency, performance, and eco-
nomic models. The major conclusion to be learnt from this part and probably
from the whole book is that there is not one single road to success when talk-
ing about industrial organization in the wine sector but that different strate-
gies are possible according to the micro- and macroeconomic characteristics
governing the country. Different “models” exist and go against the idea of the
homogenization of the wine industry worldwide.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Part I
Structure of the Wine Sectors
Worldwide
mmorag@uchile.cl
2
The French Wine Industry
Adeline Alonso Ugaglia, Jean-Marie Cardebat,
and Linda Jiao
2.1 Introduction
France is a historical wine-producing country, one of the first to have emerged
on the wine market, together with Italy and Spain. These three countries
define the basis of what is traditionally called the “Old World” in the wine
world, including Portugal, Germany and Greece. Rich of a millenary history,
wine is inseparable from the culture, heritage, terroirs and economy of France.
The wine and spirit sector keeps its position as a large surplus in the French
trade balance (11.51 billion Euros, 8.24 only for the wine in 2017) behind
aeronautics (17.4 billion Euros) and above perfumes and cosmetics (10.6 bil-
lion Euros) (FranceAgriMer 2018a, b). The wine sector is therefore crucial for
the French economy, representing the largest surplus in the French agri-food
trade balance. It is known as a major asset for France as it generates not only
A. Alonso Ugaglia (*)
Bordeaux Sciences Agro, University of Bordeaux, Gradignan, France
e-mail: adeline.ugaglia@agro-bordeaux.fr
J.-M. Cardebat
University of Bordeaux, Pessac, France
INSEEC Bordeaux, Bordeaux, France
e-mail: jean-marie.cardebat@u-bordeaux.fr
L. Jiao
University of Bordeaux, Pessac, France
e-mail: linda.jiao@u-bordeaux.fr
mmorag@uchile.cl
18 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
growth and employment, often in rural areas where jobs are rare (Porter and
Takeuchi 2013), but the wine industry also participates in the planning of the
territory with an essential landscape function and is, in addition, a well-
known supplier of local tax revenues (Cardebat 2017).
France is still one the first wine country in the world for the volumes pro-
duced, for the value of exports, for consumption and for the diversity of prod-
ucts. The French wine industry is therefore at a turning point in its history.
The evolution of food consumption and lifestyle, the rising of public health
and environmental concerns, climate change, but also the success of New
Producing Countries and the reform of the Common Market Organization in
Europe represent so many challenges for the wine industry in France. To suc-
ceed in meeting these challenges for the future, all the actors of the industry
have to engage and bring together their efforts for a renewed dynamics based
on all its successful assets like terroir, innovation, know-how, PDOs (Protected
Designations of Origin) and its worldwide reputation.
This chapter seeks to describe the French wine industry and its actors fol-
lowing the process to obtain the final product (grape growing, wine process-
ing and then distribution and commercialization). It begins with a presentation
of the wine industry according to its place in the international trade. It then
provides details of the winegrowing and winemaking sectors, before present-
ing the distribution channels. The final sections speculate on how that struc-
ture may change in the decades to come and provide a conclusion.
2.2 T
he French Wine Industry’s State
and Current Position in the Wine World
About 70% of the French wine production covers 83% of the wine consump-
tion in France and the imported wines the rest. The national market is defi-
nitely the main one for French wines for years as only 30% in volumes are
exported.
After a crisis in 2008, which had seen the collapse of the international market,
growth came back in 2010 (+14% in volume and +17% in value) for the
French wine industry. In the recent years, on one hand, French wine imports
have decreased in 2017 after 3 years of increase (+5% in 2016, +12% in 2015,
+23% in 2014) and represents 7.6 billion hectoliters in 2017 (OIV 2018). In
mmorag@uchile.cl
The French Wine Industry 19
value, the imports register a new record with 810 billion Euros (+10%) in
2017. The main part of the wine imported is bulk wine (80%), mainly cor-
responding to wine without any geographic indication and not mentioning
the cepage or the variety. This is the sign of the structural deficit of the French
wine industry in low-price wines that the low harvest successions are unable
to fill quantitatively. The search for bulk wines at moderate prices leads
importers to import wine from Spain for the main part of the volumes
imported.
On the other hand, wine trade is largely dominated by Spain, Italy and
France, which account for 55% of world market volume in 2017. In value,
France and Italy continue to dominate the market with 30% and 19%, respec-
tively, of wine exports in the world (OIV 2018). French wine exports repre-
sent 30% of the volumes produced in France and present a steady rise in
2017, staying at a very high level, even being a historical result if considered
together with the spirits sector (FranceAgriMer 2018a, b): +5% in volumes
(15.4 billion hectoliters) and +9% in value (8.89 billion Euros) (Fig. 2.1).
Fifty-four percent of the wines are exported to a European country. The main
part (around 50% in volumes) of the wine exported is still bottled wine,
mainly to Germany, China, the United Kingdom and the United States. Since
2005, although France has lost its status as the world’s largest exporter by
volume, it remains largely ahead in value (9.05 billion Euros in 2017—
FranceAgriMer 2018a, b). The prices of the wines exported by France are
among the highest in the world, reflecting a positioning on well-valued prod-
ucts and even better and better-valued products considering the evolution of
the average prices for 15 years (+9%), especially for PDO wines (+20%).
These good results were partly pushed by specific plans set by the French gov-
ernment (for the 2008–2013 period, e.g., the plan aimed at increasing the
volumes exported on the markets and reinforcing the image and the quality of
French wines to increase the value of the products).
It is a little bit different for organic wines which are more exported than
noncertified ones (46% of organic wines exported in 2016) (Agence BIO
Stats 2017).
The link between wine production and the terroir is worldwide recognized,
as AOC (Appellation d’Origine Contrôlée, French for PDO) wines account for
39% of French exported volumes and 51% of exported value. PGI (Protected
Geographical Indication) wines account for 26% in volume and 10% in value.
Champagne wines account for only 7% of exported volume, but it generates
29% of total value. The total AOC wines (still wines plus Champagne)
account for 46% of export volume and generate 80% of export value.
mmorag@uchile.cl
20 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
10000
Exports
9000
Imports
8000
7000
Value (million €)
6000
5000
4000
3000
2000
1000
0
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
18
16
14
Volume (million hL)
12
10
8
6
4
Exports
2
Imports
0
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
Fig. 2.1 French wine imports and exports (in volume and value). (Source: OIV stats,
http://www.oiv.int/fr/bases-de-donnees-et-statistiques)
After years of growth, during the nineteenth century, the area of the French
vineyard reached its peak, with 2.465 million ha, in the middle of the 1870s.
After this date and because of the Phylloxera crisis, the French vineyard has
experienced a long period of deceleration. Initially slow, the decline a ccelerates
mmorag@uchile.cl
The French Wine Industry 21
after World War II, and the surface was divided by two after a century. In the
first half of the twentieth century, the production remained relatively stable
thanks to an increase in yields. Then, from 1950 to 1990, it increased. Finally,
since 1990, it has dropped considerably to fall below the most productive
periods of the beginning of the century. Between 2000 and 2011, the vine-
yard lost 13% of its area. The crisis in the viticultural sector in the 2000s led
to major uprooting (together with EU policy). Since the end of the EU pro-
gram to regulate the wine production potential (2011/2012 campaign), the
rate of reduction of the vineyard in France has slowed significantly.1 The latest
available data showed a tendency toward stabilization of the overall area in
France around 785,000 ha (OIV 2018), second position right after Spain,
representing about 10% of the vines in the world.
France has been historically one of the leaders of wine production around
the world. It represents 10% of the vineyards worldwide right after Spain and
China and 15% of the wine production (36.7 million hl in 2017—OIV
(2018)). However, considering the volumes, wine production in France has
fallen sharply in 2017 to the point that—according to OIV—it will be a his-
torically low year but not representative because of extreme climatic events.
The production fell by 19% in volume and reached 36.7 million hectoliters.
After the decline following the 2008/2009 economic crisis, world wine
consumption has found a positive direction. This upward trend has been
observed since 2014. While the United States confirm their position as the
world’s largest consuming country since 2011 (32.6 million hl), France is the
second one (27 million hl in 2017, 11%), followed by Italy, Germany and
China (OIV 2018). The decline in consumption in the historically consum-
ing countries—France, Italy and Spain—seems stabilized while consumption
in the United States, China and Australia continues to grow. Historically, the
French wine market is supported by domestic consumption: France is still the
leading wine-consuming country in Europe above Italy, Portugal and Spain,
“absorbing” 14% of the wine produced worldwide. France is the first market
for French wines (70% of the volumes produced in France, 83% of the wines
purchased in France). The imported wines represent 17% of French
consumption.
But wine consumption in France has decreased for the last 30 years: whereas
in 1975 it was 100 liters per inhabitant per year, it has dropped to 42 liters per
inhabitant per year. According to FranceAgriMer (2014), however, there is a
decline in nonconsumers of wine for the first time since 1995. The occasional
consumption (1–2 once a week or more rarely) takes precedence over regular
mmorag@uchile.cl
22 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
70000
60000
50000
40000
1000hl
30000
20000
10000
0
Fig. 2.2 Wine production and consumption in France. (Source: OIV stats, http://www.
oiv.int/fr/bases-de-donnees-et-statistiques)
mmorag@uchile.cl
The French Wine Industry 23
grape production (20% of the total number of farms), the main part of them
(99%) being devoted to wine production.
The French wine industry is located in about ten specialized basins. These ter-
ritories have a strong identity, and each one has its own policy to manage the
local industry. For each wine production region, there is an Interprofessional
Wine Council mainly in charge of marketing and communication. The mar-
keting and communication department is dedicated to promote the wines in
France and abroad. It designs and diffuses the messages to help wine market-
ing. Especially, it helps in training prescribers (wine merchants, restaurateurs,
importers, etc.) and provides the information consumers need. It is also in
charge of the registration of transaction contracts, such as the transaction
contracts of bulk wine between on-farm winemaking properties and
negociants.
They are different according to the type of wine produced and the market-
ing methods, as well as the size of the farms. Vines are cultivated in different
regions, but always under temperate climates, which favor the growth of
plants. Together with temperate climates, a large diversity of grape varieties
and soils are also favorable to the cultivation of vines on the whole territory.
Ten main wine regions have been defined in France, from north to south, or
colder to warmer: Alsace-East, Champagne, Burgundy-Beaujolais-Savoie-Jura
for continental climate; Loire Valley, Aquitaine, Charentes-Cognac, South-
West for the Atlantic climate; Languedoc-Roussillon, Rhone Valley-Provence
and Corsica are warmer, covered by Mediterranean climate. Table 2.1 presents
the surface, the number and the average size of grape-growing farms for each
region and shows that Languedoc-Roussillon, Provence-Alpes-Côte d’Azur
and Aquitaine are the main wine regions according to the surface planted with
vines and the number of grape-growing farms. The average surface of grape-
growing farms in France stands at 9.16 hectares. There are large disparities
among wine regions in terms of average size: from the smallest – 2.44 hectares
on average for Champagne to the largest – 25.38 hectares for Corsica. Note
that three quarter of the vineyards are cultivated by one quarter of the farms
with surfaces exceeding 12 hectares on average. The erosion of surfaces men-
tioned before has affected most basins (HCCA 2017): Languedoc-Roussillon
(−19%), Corsica (−14%), Loire Valley Center (−11%), Rhône Valley and
Provence (−11%), Bordeaux-Bergerac (−9%), Burgundy-Beaujolais-Savoie-
mmorag@uchile.cl
24 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
Table 2.1 Surface, number and average size of grape-growing farms by region (in
2010) (The three top regions, with more than 100,000 ha are in bold)
Grape- Number of Average size of
growing grape-growing grape-growing
Wine regions surface (ha) farms farms (ha)
Languedoc-Roussillon 201,500 17,423 11.56
Provence-Alpes-Côte d’Azur 148,500 12,924 11.49
Aquitaine 137,600 9533 14.4
Charentes-Cognac 79,900 6047 13.21
Pays de la Loire-Centre 62,100 6289 9.87
Bourgogne-Beaujolais-Savoie-Jura 53,100 8368 6.34
Sud-Ouest 40,400 6037 6.69
Champagne 33,400 13,647 2.44
Alsace-Est 16,200 4462 3.63
Corsica 6600 260,000 25.38
France 779,300 84,990 9.16
Source: Agreste Primeur (2011) and FranceAgriMer (2014)
Jura (−9%) and South-West (−8%) Conversely, certain basins gained sur-
faces: Champagne (+ 10%), Alsace (+ 4%) and Charentes-Cognac (+ 4%).
These are high-valuated wines.
The French vineyard is mainly composed of vines of more than ten years
old. The choice for grapes varieties depends on wine production regions. Since
the first implantation of the vine in the south of France, and its development
in all Gaul by the Romans, the wine growers looked for the plants most
adapted to the climate and to the ground to obtain always a better wine.
Ranked by planting surface (FranceAgriMer 2014), the top 10 most planted
red grape varieties are Merlot, Grenache, Syrah, Cabernet Sauvignon,
Carignan, Cabernet Franc, Pinot Noir, Gamay, Cinsaut and Meunier
(Table 2.2). For the whites, the top 10 are Ugni Blanc, Chardonnay, Sauvignon
Blanc, Semillon, Melon, Chenin, Colombard, Muscat Petit Grain, Viognier
and Grenache Blanc. Red varieties represent 72% of the vine area in 2014,
and the share of international variety is increasing (42% in 2014).
French wines have an ancient and large reputation based on geographic indi-
cations, PDO, still called AOC in France, and PGI. AOC wines are produced
in limited areas and subject to strict and precise regulations defined according
to “local, loyal and consistent practices”. AOC wines are identified with cul-
tural products from a specific region, with its landscapes, history, winemakers
and know-how. AOC wines have been very successful in France for a long
mmorag@uchile.cl
The French Wine Industry 25
time. The main part of the production comes from AOC wines, that is, 47%
in volume (376 different AOCs in 2017) and from PGI wines, that is, 28%
in volume (75 different PGIs in 2017) (GraphAgri 2017), the rest being spir-
its or wines without any mention of origin. Each AOC or PGI is ruled by an
organization called “a defense and management organization” (ODG). It is
set up at the initiative of a group of producers and/or processors providing the
same production who join forces within a structure to take the step of recog-
nizing a sign of quality, from the elaboration of the specifications to the pro-
tection and the valorization of the product. The ODG develops and contributes
to the implementation of the product specifications (specificity of the prod-
uct, production area for AOC, PDO and PGI products whose characteristics
are linked to a geographical location), the rules for wine production, wine
processing and possibly packaging and labeling. It designates an organization,
approved at national level by INAO,2 to carry out the control of the specifica-
tions and gives its opinion on the control or inspection plan drawn up with
the inspection body. It participates in the defense and protection of the name
of the AOC or PGI, promotes the product and the terroir and develops
actions and the economic knowledge of the sector (providing information on
volumes, number of operators by category, means of production, product
development and outlets).
Ninety percent of the specialized grape farms in France are producing wine
under AOC or PGI systems, giving evidence to the importance of mentioning
the origin to value the production of this country (Agreste Primeur 2011).
2
INAO is an organization belonging to the French Ministry of Agriculture. It guarantees and protects the
denominations of origin, supervises modifications and examines the applications for recognition under
official geographical indication.
mmorag@uchile.cl
26 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
More than two third of the grape-growing farms are devoted to produce AOC
wines, and this part covers around 62% of the vine areas. Alsace-East,
Champagne and the Burgundy regions only produce wine under appellation
systems (AOC). Great part of the production in Loire Valley (75%), Rhone
Valley (67%) and Corsica (54%) is also produced in AOC systems. The pro-
duction of South-West is more diversified with 41% with AOC (but nearly
100% for the Bordeaux wine region). In Languedoc-Roussillon, the produc-
tion is mainly produced under PGI systems (59%), with only 26% in
AOC. Besides, the regions in the south, Loire Valley, South-West, Languedoc-
Roussillon, Rhone Valley and Corsica are characterized by mixed farms—they
produce both AOC and other wines. Charentes-Cognac is specialized in
grapes for spirits. The majority of wine farms producing AOC wines are big-
ger than the other ones and the wine farms producing PGI wines are rather
small or middle farms compared to AOC ones (Table 2.3).
Producing under appellation system is synonymous of production con-
straints, the main ones being the limited wine yield per hectare together with
a list of authorized varieties (only Vitis vinifera for AOCs). Each AOC/IGP
area establishes, in contact with INAO, its production conditions. Besides,
from an economic point of view, an early assessment of harvest volumes at
regional level facilitates the management of the volumes available on the wine
market. Some authors also claim for a link between yield limitation and better
quality of wines (concentration), but the literature is still too weak on this
topic to conclude. In France, vineyards are cultivated by rain-fed systems.
Vine irrigation is forbidden but French regulations allow, under certain con-
ditions, exceptional irrigation of vines. The irrigation is strictly forbidden for
mmorag@uchile.cl
The French Wine Industry 27
all wines between 15 August and the harvest. In the case of PGI and wines
without any geographical indication, the irrigation is possible after the harvest
until 15 August or the ripening (the moment when the color of the grape ber-
ries is changing). As for the AOC, by default, the irrigation of vines suitable
for the production is forbidden from 1 May up to the harvest and authorized
after the harvest until 1 May. However, the irrigation of vines can be autho-
rized, exceptionally, maximum from 15 June at the earliest until 15 August at
the latest. This finally explains the low rate of irrigated vineyards according to
the importance of the appellation regime in France. These conditions on
grape and wine production make a real difference to access natural resources
and for production costs/economies of scale.
Beyond the size of the farms, the 85,000 French grape farms can be character-
ized from three important variables: the labor force, the age of the grape grow-
ers and the men/women ratio.
Wine farms are characterized by the use of a large wage labor force. Farm
specialized in grape-growing use, on average, the equivalent of 1.9 full-time
workers seasonal including workers (+0.4 up to other farms). This is why
French viticulture is recognized as a sector supplying jobs in the countryside.
Nonfamily permanent employees provide 30% of the workload and 18% for
seasonal workers. Seasonal work is mainly present in Champagne and
Burgundy-Beaujolais-Savoie-Jura because the grape growers harvest by hand
more often (Agreste Primeur 2011).
In 2010 (RGA3 2010), 6 out of 10 grape growers are 50 years old and over.
Among the specialized farm owners of 50 years or older, the majority (60%)
does not know who will take over after them or even think the farm will dis-
appear. This could result in a potential loss of nearly 40% of French vineyards.
This is a particularly big concern in Gironde, where the share of over 50s
among wine growers continues to grow (54%). The demographic succession
seems to be less and less easy. Fewer and fewer are generational farms when
grape farms used to be family farms (they are dominant in France), and it is
more and more difficult to transmit a grape-growing farm.
3
The RGA, or General Agricultural Census, compiles statistics on the number of farms, on the technical
and economic orientations, on the agricultural surfaces used, the productions and surfaces concerned, the
areas still grassed, and the main grasslands. The RGA (or RA) is organized every 10 to 12 years. The first
census took place in 1998, then in 2000 and finally in 2010. They constitute the main data source from
the Ministry of Agriculture.
mmorag@uchile.cl
28 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The French Wine Industry 29
80000
70000
60000
50000
Surface (ha)
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016
Year 3 Year 1 Year 2 Organic surface (certified)
Fig. 2.3 Evolution of organic surfaces in France (ha). (Source: Agence BIO 2017)
In France, the average yield is around 50 hl/ha, close to the European one
(between 55 and 60 hL/ha depending on the vintage), but this number varies
from year to year. For quality and AOC wines, the maximum authorized yield
varies between 40 and 60 hl/ha. During the period 2003–2013, the annual
yield of AOC was comprised between 42 hl/ha (2013) and 55.8 hl/ha (2005).
For less qualified wines, the yield varies from 60 to 80 hl/ha. During
2003–2013, the annual yield of wines other than AOC (Cognac excluded)
varied from 63 hl/ha in 2003, 2007 and 2011 to 79.5 in 2004 (FranceAgriMer
2014).4 There are strong yield differentials between regions, and on average
mmorag@uchile.cl
Table 2.4 Repartition of organic farms and surfaces by region
30
Midi-Pyrénées 333 8.1% 2071 3% 266 198 103 568 43% 2638 10% 7.0%
Bourgogne 322 6.6% 2054 2% 173 469 200 842 40% 2896 10% 8.8%
Alsace 309 6.9% 2203 1% 160 89 99 348 56% 2551 6% 15.9%
Pays de la Loire 264 15.8% 2374 8% 385 442 146 973 39% 3346 15% 10.5%
Centre 213 7.6% 2421 1% 224 105 81 410 24% 2831 4% 13.3%
Val-de-Loire
Champagne- 158 19.7% 411 15% 128 85 42 256 45% 667 25% 2.1%
mmorag@uchile.cl
Ardenne
Poitou- 116 20.8% 946 5% 62 153 53 268 18% 1213 8% 1.4%
Charentes
Franche-Comté 74 8.8% 361 11% 16 56 18 90 −1% 452 9% 18.5%
Corsica 59 5.4% 675 13% 151 153 33 337 5% 1012 10% 15.1%
Auvergne 27 35% 75 4% 22 20 8 50 85% 125 26% 11.5%
Lorraine 25 38.9% 55 6% 43 7 1 52 285% 107 63% 31.5%
Picardie 16 6.7% 36 50% 5 1 2 9 −51% 45 5% 1.8%
Limousin 10 25% 29 160% 4 – 1 5 17% 34 117% 16.6%
Ile-de-France 4 −20% 1 42% – – – – −100% 1 37% 2.6%
Haute- 2 100% c – c c c c – c – –
Normandie
(continued)
Table 2.4 (continued)
mmorag@uchile.cl
The French Wine Industry
31
32 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
they are low compared to competing producing countries in the New World.
It impacts production costs compared to countries benefiting from favorable
production factors such as natural and human resources less costly. In addi-
tion, for many years, there has been a very significant increase in the mortality
of vines, which weakens the yields and the productivity of the French vine-
yards, despite the notable efforts of restructuring and renovating the vine-
yards, not to mention the National Research Programs on the decline of
vineyards in general and on trunk diseases in particular.
In 2010, farms produced 45% of red wines, a production that dominates
in France, slightly higher than white wines (43%), far ahead from rosé wines
(12%). A large proportion of white wines are detained to spirits (eaux de vie).
Figure 2.4 demonstrates the evolution of wine harvest in France by wine
region and color.
10,000
9,000
8,000
7,000
6,000
1000hl
5,000
4,000
3,000
2,000
1,000
Fig. 2.4 Wine harvest in France by region and color (2015). (Source: DGDDI-CVI Harvest
2005–2015)
mmorag@uchile.cl
The French Wine Industry 33
White wine
Rosé wine
Red wine
0 20 40 60 80 100
Volume (%)
AOP PGI no GI Eaux-de-vie
Fig. 2.5 AOC and PGI and wine color (2010). (Source: Agreste Primeur 2011)
AOC and PGI wines value French production since the majority of red and
rosé wines are produced under AOC (60%) (Fig. 2.5).
Before 2012, it was not possible to produce “organic wine” but only “wine
produced from organic grapes”. A European regulation (2012) designed new
production specifications defining what an organic wine is and how to pro-
duce it (n°203/2012). According to a study by AND-I, commissioned by
Agence BIO, nearly 1.82 million hectoliters of organic wines have been sold
in 2016. PDOs accounted for 68% of volumes of French organic wines mar-
keted in 2015 and PGIs 25%.
2.4.2 Winemakers
In France, grape-growing farms can deal with their grape harvest in three dif-
ferent wine processing modes:
(i) Using their harvest to make their own wine (on-farm winemakers) in a
fully integrated way (from grape production to wine commercialization).
In this case, the estates are managing both the grape growing and the
wine processing.
(ii) Being co-operative members and delivering the harvest to winemaking
co-operatives that process and sell wine on their behalf. There is no con-
tract to sell the grapes between co-operative members and wine co-
mmorag@uchile.cl
34 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
37%
Wine co-operative
8%
Fig. 2.6 Winemaking processing (volume, 2010). (Source: Agreste Primeur 2011)
mmorag@uchile.cl
The French Wine Industry 35
East of France (Languedoc, Valley of the Rhone and Provence). The biggest
ones are located in the same region, but also in Champagne (Table 2.5).
Twenty percent of the wine produced in co-operatives is organic wine
(FranceAgriMer 2014), representing 27% of the organic wine processed in
France. According to the 2015 notifications, 203 wine co-operatives produced
wine from organic grapes, up from 70 in 2009 (Agence BIO). They are mainly
mixed co-operatives producing both a range of organic and non-organic
wines. Nevertheless, to date, wine co-operatives are small businesses or SMEs.
Only one has a turnover exceeding 300 million Euros. While size is not in
itself a guarantee of success, we must distinguish between what is relevant for
the optimization of winemaking tools and what is the case with regard to
packaging and marketing. As with other sectors of activity, the rapproche-
ments between co-operatives continue. The number of wine co-operatives has
decreased by 40% in the last 20 years.
Once the wine has been processed, a wine farm (private cellar) or a wine co-
operative can sell it through different distribution channels: negociants (also
called wine merchants), producer groups, restaurants, wine stores, supermar-
kets and hypermarkets or directly to consumers (on-farm sale, online sale). An
important share of the volumes goes through negociants (64% of the vol-
umes), often via brokers (Fig. 2.7).
For organic wines, sales channels are highly diversified. Of the volumes,
73% are marketed by wine growers and 27% are by wine co-operatives. More
than half of the volumes marketed by co-operatives go to negociants. In 2015,
41% of sales of organic wines (in value) concerned direct sales and 23% in
wine stores dedicated to organic wines. Direct selling is therefore the main
mmorag@uchile.cl
36 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
3% 1%
4%
Négoce
Direct to consumer
28%
Wine store
Hypermarkets/supermarkets
64% Other-1%
channel for organic wines. Forty-six percent of organic wines (volume) have
been sold abroad in 2015 (Europe, especially Germany). Fifteen percent of
the volumes of organic wines sold in France in 2015 were sold in restaurants
or catering services. In 2014, nearly one out of two restaurants had organic
wine on their menu (compared with nearly two fifth in 2011). The restaurant
owners who have organic wines offered, on average, five different references
(CNIV—Panel CHD FACTS). According to Agence BIO, the value of pur-
chases of organic wines by households in France was estimated around 792
million Euros in 2016 (+ 17% between 2015 and 2016). Purchases of organic
wines more than tripled between 2005 and 2016. In 2015, organic wine
accounted for 12% in value of purchases of organic products by households.
The wine can be sold in bulk, in bottle, or in bag-in-box. Figure 2.8 repre-
sents the different distribution channels in France and their share in volumes
up to the type of packaging used at the moment of the sale. Bottled wine
stands for the majority of direct sales. The main part of the wine sold to the
negociants is bulk wine, which they bottle right after and before selling it. On
the contrary, when they are selling the wine directly to the consumers, the
winemakers bottle and label the main part of their wines.
While the organic wine distribution system appears to be diversified and
mobilizes all the classic channels, direct sales and export appear to be of par-
ticular relevance. Organic wine growers have to face extra production costs,
explained mainly by higher labor costs and partly justified by the higher qual-
ity of wines, and typically it results in higher prices for the final consumer. In
this case, direct sales could be seen the most remunerative as a producer’s
mmorag@uchile.cl
The French Wine Industry 37
2.5.2 N
egociants as Major Actors in the French
Distribution Channels
Negociants play important roles along the wine industry chain from produc-
tion through wine-maturation and commercialization. FranceAgriMer esti-
mates the number of 1500 wine negociants in France even if it is difficult to
identify them according to the diversity of their status and activities. They can
buy fresh grapes or grape musts and process their wine (as in the Champagne
region) and/or buy the wine in bulk or in bottles (selected via brokers). Then
they bottle it if needed and process the distribution step to the final consumer.
Growing grapes is the only part they do not manage or rarely. The negociants
have a particularly strong position in the Bordeaux wine region. We can con-
sider three types of negociants in the French wine sector:
mmorag@uchile.cl
38 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
(i) Negociants who own as well wine estates, or the contrary: wine growers
developing a négoce activity. In this case, the negociants can be the pro-
ducer and distributor of their own wine. They are often big groups and
their activities are highly vertically integrated. Such a negociant can also
carry out the activities of the two next ones.
(ii) Negociants who buy fresh grapes or grape musts from wine growers for
making their own wine. They are in charge of the winemaking, aging,
assembling and bottling, and then distributing the wine with their own
labels. Such a negociant can also carry out the activities of the next one.
(iii) Negociants only involved in the distribution process. They select wines
produced by on-farm winemakers, in bulk or in bottle. If bulk, the nego-
ciants can undertake the bottling and labeling in accordance with the
regulation at final destination.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The French Wine Industry 39
French consumers buy most of their wine in super and hypermarkets (70% of
wine purchases, 9.5 million hl) (FranceAgriMer 2018a, b). Then come hard
discount chains (14%), local wine stores (7%), wine stores (3%), direct sales
(3%) and sales online (1%) in 2016 (volume) (FranceAgrimer 2017). France
counts around 1700 wine stores, mostly owned by 3 chains: Nicolas (450),
Inter Caves (224) and Cavavin (120). Gourmet stores and delicatessen remain
residual. In terms of price (CNIV/FranceAgriMer 2016) in 2014:
• 29% of purchases of still wines were made at a price lower than 1.49€ per
bottle and 7% at a higher price than 5€ per bottle.
• 52% of wines without any geographic indication from France, 55% of
non-EU foreign wines (other origins) and 79% of wines without any geo-
graphic indication from Europe were purchased at a lower price than 1.49€
per bottle.
• 51% of purchases of AOC wines were made at less than 3€ per bottle and
16% of them at more than 5€ per bottle.
Even if red wines are still the top wines for consumption, the French con-
sumers are more and more interested in rosé wines at the expense of red wines.
mmorag@uchile.cl
40 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The French Wine Industry 41
2.6 C
onclusion and Synthesis: What
About the Performance?
The organization of the French wine industry is characterized by the complex-
ity and diversification among wine production regions concerning the actors
and their relationship along the distribution chain.
The majority of the grape harvest is vinified by on-farm winemakers, about
one third of the production is vinified in wine co-operatives and the selling of
fresh harvest takes only a small part of the market. This share varies depending
on the region (Exhibit 2.1). The intermediate bodies play important roles in
French wine industry. Negociants claim their leadership along the chain, and
they can interfere at different steps (rarely for grape production, sometimes to
process wine, very often to sell the wine). In addition, the transactions between
grape or wine producers and negociants are often linked by brokers. Around
60–70% of the production is commercialized by negociants in the main wine
regions. Supermarkets and hypermarkets are dominant channels for the dis-
tribution, and the on-trade (restaurants, bars, hotels, etc.) takes about one
third of the market. Red wines are the most sold in terms of both volume and
value. Whatever the region, wine co-operatives and negociants are the two
mmorag@uchile.cl
42 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
arms of the French wine industry. They join in industry groups, either region-
ally for AOC and PGI wines or nationally for wines with no geographical
indication. They fund efforts to promote their wines and monitor markets,
finance research and development initiatives (FranceAgriMer 2018a, b). We
present in Exhibit 2.1 the main actors and the way they are organized for four
representative wine regions in France: Bordeaux, Burgundy, Champagne and
Languedoc-Roussillon (Exhibit 2.1).
Bordeaux Burgundy
Nearly 80% of the harvest is 55% of the harvest is vinified by on-farm
processed by on-farm winemakers. It is less than in the past
winemakers. The transaction of due to the development of selling fresh
fresh grapes or grape musts is harvest grapes or musts (16% of the
negligible. In addition, this crop in 2010 against 10% in 2000), while
region is characterized by the the proportion of harvest processed by
dynamic and the power of wine co-operative remains stable (29%).
negociants. Over 70% of the The sale of fresh harvest grapes, which
Bordeaux wine production is can meet the cash requirements, is now
commercialized by negociants practiced by 47% of farms, which is
(51% for bulk wine and 49% for rather rare in the other regions. This is
bottled wine), representing 83% also explained by the increase of sales
of the wine estates. Brokers are contracts for the production of sparkling
important intermediaries in the wines. Negociants and wholesalers
Bordeaux wine region. 80% of remain the main destinations (59%).
the transactions between Still, half of the Burgundian wine
owner-seller and trader-buyer growers are managing sales through
involve brokers. direct selling (40%).
Champagne Languedoc-Roussillon
On-farm winemakers process less In this region, 47% of the farms are small
than one third of the harvest estates, which bring the wine
(30%), similar for wine co-operatives to play an important role
co-operatives (28%), while in winemaking. Nine out of ten
selling fresh grapes or grape operators send all or part of their
musts takes the most important harvest in wine co-operatives—over
part (42%). Different from other 70% of the total harvest. But big
regions, most of the wine properties often process all or almost
produced is sold by direct their whole harvest themselves. Two
channels or exported abroad, third of the wine production is
which presents over 80% of the commercialized via negociants. The
total transaction volume. direct sales represent the remaining one
Negociants or wholesalers third of the total sales.
distribute the rest.
Source: Authors from the information published on the ODG websites and
Agreste (2011a, b, 2012, 2013)
mmorag@uchile.cl
The French Wine Industry 43
The production and consumption of wine are inseparable from its circula-
tion and its international trade. We therefore end this chapter providing a
synthesis of France’s different strengths and weaknesses in relation to its per-
formance on the wine market. Some analyses of the performance of the French
wine industry have been published and nearly come to the same conclusions
(Porter and Takeuchi 2013; HCCA 2017; CNIV/FranceAgriMer 2016)
(Exhibit 2.2).
• The wine sector is crucial for the French economy as it represents France’s
leading sector of the agri-food balance, knowing that public subsidies rep-
resent only a small part of the turnover of the sector. Besides, it is worth
noted that the Champagne contributes a tiny part in terms of volume but
a significant share in this value. It is as well a job-creating sector in rural
areas, while unemployment in France is still a major concern.
• At the international level, France is a highly reputed historical wine coun-
try. It is still the first wine exporter in the world (in value) and about 30%
of the production goes abroad. The European Union is the first destina-
tion, and the US and Asian market are the main ones out of Europe.
Among the exports, AOP wines account for nearly half of the volume and
generate 80% of the value.
• The country is also one of the top producers for wine production (in vol-
ume), right after Spain. It offers a high diversity of products. The agrocli-
matic diversity ensures a high diversity in the combination of climates,
grape varieties and soils.
• France, as an Old Wine country, benefits from the know-how of the grape
and wine growers, who know the terroir very well. Its image of this indus-
try is strongly linked to “tradition” and to the high quality of the wine
produced. The terroir reference must not only be seen as an old traditional
notion and policy, invented to protect the production in the Old World,
but as a model which determines the life and the future of many producers
and people in this industry. It is a collective and long-term construction,
authentic by the respect it shows for tradition and local usages.
• With over 300 of AOCs in France, the term “appellation” dominates in
grape growing as well as in winemaking. The vineyards devoted to produce
AOC wines cover about two third of the areas under vines, and about half
of the total wine production is produced in an AOC context. The corollary
is that wine yield in the French appellation regime is restricted and s ubmitted
mmorag@uchile.cl
44 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
• However, the domestic wine production and consumption have been expe-
riencing a long-term decline. Facing the challenges from New World wines,
French producers need to maintain their competitiveness.
• Some estates are facing economic difficulties due to high production costs
for some wines and commercial issues (CNIV/FranceAgriMer 2016).
• Few big French importers and wholesalers focused on emerging markets
for wine consumption.
• Although leading brands account for an important market share and have
advantages in marketing and communication, the perception of appella-
tion prevails in the French market.
• No French brands in the top 10 of international brands but numerous
regions, appellations, farms, brands and intermediaries, unclear for the
consumers.
• An involvement for innovation and in research programs hardly recognized
by the markets.
Starting from this observation, the stakes for the French wine industry are
numerous. One of the main ones is to better adapt the offer to the demand, in
particular for the low-end wines. The growth of growing segments is a way to
offset the decline in demand. The French sector must also face another major
challenge: maintaining its export position and position itself on the best mar-
kets. This is an important outlet for French wines, particularly in terms of
mmorag@uchile.cl
The French Wine Industry 45
References
Agreste. 2011a. Premières tendances, Agreste Données Viticulture Languedoc-
Roussillon, Recensement agricole 2010, novembre 2011, 4p.
———. 2011b. La viticulture en Bourgogne : progression des surfaces et de l’emploi sala-
rié, Agreste Bourgogne, n°125, décembre 2011, 6p.
mmorag@uchile.cl
46 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
mmorag@uchile.cl
3
The Italian Wine Industry
Alessandro Corsi, Simonetta Mazzarino,
and Eugenio Pomarici
3.1 Introduction
Wine production is deeply rooted in the Italian tradition, since viticulture was
practiced even before Roman times, and thereafter almost everywhere in the
country. Nowadays, Italy is among the main world wine producers, and the
Italian wine industry leads the national agribusiness; indeed, although the
wine industry is third in the ranking of turnover in the agro-food sector, wine
is the true food icon of Made in Italy and the largest contributor to Italian
agro-food exports. In particular, viticulture is an important part of Italian
agriculture. Vineyards for wine production covered 622,000 ha in 2016, that
is, about 5% of the total utilized agricultural area (UAA), but viticulture
accounted for 10.2% of the value of agricultural production. With an
A. Corsi (*)
University of Turin, Turin, Italy
e-mail: alessandro.corsi@unito.it
S. Mazzarino
Department of Economics and Statistics “Cognetti de Martiis”,
University of Turin, Turin, Italy
e-mail: simonetta.mazzarino@unito.it
E. Pomarici
Department of Land, Environment, Agriculture and Forestry,
University of Padua, Padua, Italy
e-mail: eugenio.pomarici@unipd.it
mmorag@uchile.cl
48 A. Corsi et al.
e stimated 50.9 million hl in 2016 (Anderson et al. 2017), Italy was the first
producer in the world in quantitative terms (about 19% of the world produc-
tion), although France (which alternates with Italy in the first ranking) out-
performs Italy in value terms (Anderson et al. 2017). The Italian wine industry,
because of its size and historical evolution, comprises a large number of opera-
tors; most of them are professional producers linked to distribution channels,
but many only produce for self-consumption or as a hobby. According to the
last Agricultural Census, there were 369,000 farms growing wine grapes, but
considering only the professional operators, grape production is carried out in
about 197,000 farms. Wine-making is carried out in about 55,000 grape-
processing plants and bottling in about 8000 plants. These technical produc-
tion units are linked in various models of production organization, and the
Italian wine industry is organized into both integrated and de-integrated sup-
ply chains, the latter formed by operators specialized in one or two phases of
the wine supply chain.
To describe this complex production system, the chapter is organized as fol-
lows. Section 3.2 presents the main features of grape production in Italy.
Section 3.3 analyzes the organization of wine production, identifies the tech-
nical units involved and their different forms of integration in the supply
chains, and discusses the supply concentration and the different typical mar-
keting models of firms. Section 3.4 shows where Italian wine is delivered.
Section 3.5 analyzes the relationships and the flows along the chain, presenting
the contracts and the main aspects of the sector governance. Finally, Sect. 3.6
contains some final comments on the structure of the Italian wine industry.
3.2 S
tructural Features of the Wine-Growing
Sector
3.2.1 R
elevance and Distribution of Viticulture and Farm
Size
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Italian Wine Industry 49
Table 3.1 Number of farms producing wine grapes and vine-bearing area
Number of farmsa Area (hectares)
Vineyards Vineyards Vineyards
for PDO for other for PDO Vineyards for
Territory wines wines Total wines other wines Total
Italy 127,970 292,382 388,881 320,859 304,841 625,700
North-West 20,704 19,425 35,174 61,331 10,075 71,406
North-East 46,189 50,286 83,393 116,250 52,099 168,349
Center 17,400 59,850 71,993 65,923 39,553 105,476
South 32,116 113,966 139,346 54,983 102,952 157,935
Islands 8561 48,855 58,975 22,372 100,161 122,534
Source: ISTAT, Agricultural Census (2010)
a
In the Agricultural Census, the reported number of farms refers to farms where
there are predominantly or exclusively vineyards of the mentioned kind.
Consequently the overall number of farms is not the sum of partial values. In
addition, the overall number of farms also includes farms where there are
predominantly or exclusively table grape vineyards and vine nurseries
in 2013 by ISTAT further reduce the number of farms with wine vineyards to
just under 310,500 units, while the overall vineyard area estimated for 2017
rises to around 652,000 hectares (ISMEA 2018). These figures consider all
farms growing table grapes, including hobby farmers and production for
self-consumption.
Notwithstanding the wide diffusion of viticulture, geographical differences
are important, both in quantitative and qualitative terms. Consideration of
the large-scale territorial division among North-East (NE), North-West
(NW), Center, South, and Islands (NUTS1 level in the EU classification)
(Fig. 3.1) shows that a large proportion of wine-growing farms are located in
the South (36%), while NE (21%) and NW (9%) are less important, and the
Center and Islands have 19% and 15%, respectively. However, in terms of
vine-bearing area, the share of the South is much smaller (25%), and the share
of NE (27%) and of the Islands (20%) is much larger. The differences are
more striking in terms of quality, since the South only accounts for 19% of
farms producing only Protected Designation of Origin (PDO) wines, while
the NE has the largest share of such farms (41%) (Mazzarino and Corsi 2015).
Although the issue of “true quality” is much debated, some areas enjoy par-
ticular prestige; this is the case of Tuscany, Piedmont, and Veneto for red
wines, and Trentino-Alto Adige, Veneto, and Friuli for white ones. Nevertheless,
the wines really appreciated by national and international critics come nowa-
days from vineyards in every part of Italy.
mmorag@uchile.cl
50 A. Corsi et al.
Trentino A-A
Friuli V-G
NORTH-WEST Veneto
NORTH-EAST
Piedmont
Emilia-Romagna
Tuscany
CENTRE
SOUTH Apulia
ISLANDS
Sicily
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Italian Wine Industry 51
World. Nevertheless, 12% of wine grape area in Italy consists of farms with
less than 1 ha of vineyard, and this share is larger in the South (18%) and in
the Center (15%).
1
The most important varieties (over 10,000 ha) are Sangiovese, Trebbiano, Montepulciano, Merlot,
Catarratto Bianco, Barbera, Glera, Moscato Bianco, Pinot Grigio, Calabrese (Nero d’Avola), different
types of Lambrusco, Cabernet Sauvignon, Chardonnay, Primitivo, and Negro Amaro.
mmorag@uchile.cl
52 A. Corsi et al.
3.3 S
tructural Features of the Wine-Making
Sector
3.3.1 Supply Size and Composition
Wine production in volume is variable from year to year due to the climatic
conditions that obviously affect vineyard yields. According to ISTAT, it
amounts to between 40 and 45 million hectoliters (Table 3.2).
A typical characteristic of the Italian wine supply is the number and impor-
tance of wines with recognized geographical origins. Such wines are produced
under the EU rules on Protected Geographical Indication (PGI) and PDO. In
particular, within the European category of PDO wines, in Italy there are dif-
ferent appellation levels, characterized by increasing and more stringent
requirements.3 The Italian appellation system, modeled on the French one,
2
These figures concerning the professional grape growers come from the AGEA database. AGEA is the
Italian agency in charge of the payments of CAP subsidies. According to Reg. 1308/2013, all professional
wine grape farmers and all wine-makers have to submit each year a compulsory statement on the quantity
of grapes or wines that they produce.
3
According to Reg. (CE) 1308/2013 and Reg. (CE) 607/2009, EU wines can be marketed as:
• Varietal wines and generic wines, produced with no special restriction on where vineyards, wine-
making, and bottling plants are located (in Italy the maximum yield is 50 t/ha). The name of the wine
grape variety may be mentioned if at least 85% of the product has been made from that variety.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Table 3.2 Italian wine production by type (hl, %)
2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016
Generic wines 14,996,551 11,978,563 9,692,983 11,917,442 9,916,247 14,257,985 16,761,884
PGI wines 13,953,194 13,592,224 12,546,429 15,787,053 13,451,854 15,423,067 15,345,459
PDO wines 15,743,432 15,060,866 16,025,898 17,339,626 16,373,330 18,954,431 19,508,118
Overall 44,693,177 40,631,653 38,265,310 45,044,121 39,741,431 48,638,483 51,615,461
Generic wines 33.6 29.5 25.3 26.5 25.0 29.3 32.5
PGI wines 31.2 33.5 32.8 35.0 33.8 31.7 29.7
mmorag@uchile.cl
PDO wines 35.2 37.1 41.9 38.5 41.2 39.0 37.8
Overall 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Source: ISTAT, available at ww.agri.istat.it
The Italian Wine Industry
53
54 A. Corsi et al.
started in 1963, but the number of appellations has rapidly and steadily
increased since the 1990s. In 2016, the vine area for PGI wines was 149,009 ha,
and the corresponding figure for PDO wines was 359,962 ha. Together, PGI
and PDO represented 79% of the total vine-bearing area (ISMEA,
RETEVINO 2018).
Considering wine production in terms of quality, in the period 2012–2016,
Italian wine production in volume (Table 3.2) was almost evenly divided
among generic wines (27–28%), PGI wines (32–33%), and PDO wines
(39–40%). In terms of value, the shares were obviously different and were
estimated (for 2016) at 24%, 18%, and 58%, respectively (QUALIVITA
2018).4 Wine production is differentiated by type across areas: PDO wines
predominate in NW, NE, and Center, NE dominates the production of GI
wines, and South has the large majority of generic wines. Production of vari-
etal wines is modest, about half a million hl.
Because of changing consumption patterns and the growing production of
sparkling wines (based on white varieties), since the 2011 harvest, white wines
have dominated the overall Italian production, accounting in the 2014–2016
period for about 53–54% (ISTAT 2017) depending on the year. In fact, a
distribution of this type is more typical of the northern regions, while in the
South, Tuscany and Piedmont red wines (including rosé wines) predominate
over white ones.
• Wines with a recognized geographical origin, according to the categories Protected Geographical
Indication (PGI) and Protected Designation of Origin (PDO). A geographical indication and a desig-
nation of origin are names of a region, a specific place, or, in exceptional and duly justifiable cases, a
country, used to describe a wine whose quality depends (strictly in PDO case) on the delimited area
corresponding to the name, where grapes are cropped and processed according to a recognized set of
rules (product specification). In PDO wine production, only varieties belonging to Vitis vinifera are
admitted, and all grapes must be cropped in the delimited area; in PGI production, also crosses
between Vitis vinifera and other species of the genus Vitis are admitted, and at least 85% of grapes must
be cropped in the delimited area.
In Italy PGI wines are presented as IGTs, because “Indicazione Geografica Tipica” is the officially
recognized traditional term corresponding to the EU category PGI, and PDO wines are presented as
DOC and DOCG wines, because Denominazione di Origine Controllata (Controlled Designation of
Origin) and Denominazione d’Origine Controllata e Garantita (Controlled and Guaranteed Designation
of Origin) are the officially recognized traditional terms corresponding to the EU category PDO (L.
238/2016). Wines belonging to the DOC and DOCG categories are assumed to be of higher value than
IGT wines. Those DOC wines which have achieved particular appreciation by the market can be desig-
nated, on the producers’ request, as DOCG; in this case producers are obliged to comply with much
more stringent production rules concerning not only the grape varieties and the maximum yields in
vineyards and wine-making but also the grape selection and the aging. DOC and DOCG wines undergo
strict chemical and organoleptic tests at the end of aging and (only for DOCG wines) before bottling; the
bottling area can be inside or outside the origin area (depending on the production specification—
“Disciplinare di produzione” in Italian).
4
Estimates on bulk wine at the winery level.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Italian Wine Industry 55
A structural analysis of the wine-making sector must take into account that
wine-making is a phase of the wine production chain with several sub-phases,
frequently performed by different companies. Given the data availability, the
following structural analysis of the Italian wine-making sector considers (i)
the technical units5 operating in the two main sub-phases of wine-making,
that is, grape processing (crushing) and bottling and (ii) how such technical
units are vertically linked and how they are linked upwards with the grape
production phase according to different supply chain models characterized by
specific integration patterns.
According to the most recent data made available by AGEA and referred to
2012, crushing is carried out in about 55,000 plants. Processing capacity dif-
fers greatly, however, and the largest share of production is concentrated in
relatively few plants. About 80% of these plants are estimated to produce less
than 500 hl per year, overall representing less than 1% of Italian wine produc-
tion. On the other hand, about 200 plants, with a processing capacity of over
50,000 hl per year, represent about 60% of Italian wine production.
The grape-processing technical units can be classified into three categories:
individual farmers making wine on their farms by processing self-produced
grapes; cooperatives, which process mainly grapes delivered by members; and
private industrial wineries, which process purchased grapes. Sometimes the
borders between categories are not clear-cut, since some wine farmers also buy
grapes from other farmers to make their wine and some wineries have their
own vineyards. In 2012 individual farmers numbered 52,985 (97%), coop-
eratives 441, and industrial wine-makers 1414. In terms of the share of wine
produced, the cooperatives were the most important and produced 49.6% of
the total; industrial wine-makers produced 22.9% and farmers 27.5%
(Table 3.3).
Each category comprises technical units that can be very different in terms
of size and production orientation. Cooperatives include those with a few
dozen members, as well as the main Italian wine firms. Individual farmers
range from small producers to large prestigious firms. Also for the industrial
5
The term “technical unit” denotes a single production plant. Several technical units engaged in grape
processing may be under the control of the same company.
mmorag@uchile.cl
56 A. Corsi et al.
wineries, size may differ greatly. However, on average, the largest production
capacity by plant is among cooperatives, with an average size of over 50,000
hectoliters, as compared to 7295 for industrial wine-makers and only 233
hectoliters for on-farm producers. The plants with the highest average size are
located in the NE (1675 hectoliters) and in the Islands (1456), whereas the
lower average sizes are found in the NW (404 hl) and in the Center (430).
The weights of the categories differ among the different kinds (generic,
PGI, PDO) of wine (Table 3.3).6 According to the AGEA data, cooperatives
constitute the most important group for all kinds of wine but particularly in
the sector of PGI wines, where their share is about 58%. However, industrial
wine-makers are also strong in the sector of generic wine, with a share of 38%,
against the 45% of the cooperatives. Individual producers are stronger in the
sector of GI wines and, above all, for PDO wines, reaching 38% of the total.
The weights of the three categories also differ according to the area and the
type of wine. For generic wines (Table 3.4), cooperatives are of overwhelming
importance in the Islands. There, especially in Sicily, viticulture was tradition-
ally characterized by high yields, high alcohol degree, and low-quality grapes.
Hence, wine was mainly exported to be used to raise the alcohol degree of
other wines or was used for distillation funded by the EU. Although the aver-
age quality of wines in these regions has recently greatly improved, cooperatives,
which mainly collected those low-quality grapes, are still dominant. Along
with cooperatives, in the rest of Southern Italy, industrial wineries cover the
same segment. This outcome is probably also due to the lack of a high-quality
wine-making tradition and, hence, on the technical side, to the difficulty for
individual farmers to deal with flaws in the grapes and, on the commercial
6
The data presented here are based on AGEA data, which differ, in absolute terms, from the ISTAT data
(see Table 3.2) because the production volumes declared to AGEA every year may, for some types of wine
and for limited quantities, refer to the previous harvest. Nevertheless, we used them because they are the
only data available to estimate the grape flows to the various wine-making operators.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Italian Wine Industry 57
Table 3.4 Shares of total wine production by type of wine, producer, and area (2012)
Farmers Wineries Cooperatives Total
Generic
Italy 17.2 38.0 44.9 100.0
North-West 43.1 38.3 18.6 100.0
North-East 13.2 37.2 49.7 100.0
Center 43.3 43.5 13.2 100.0
South 16.4 45.0 38.6 100.0
Islands 8.3 9.9 81.9 100.0
PGI
Italy 29.0 13.2 57.8 100.0
North-West 34.1 19.7 46.2 100.0
North-East 31.3 10.8 57.9 100.0
Center 59.4 11.1 29.6 100.0
South 22.8 22.9 54.3 100.0
Islands 12.3 9.3 78.4 100.0
PDO
Italy 37.6 14.5 48.0 100.0
North-West 40.2 29.7 30.1 100.0
North-East 33.3 12.9 53.9 100.0
Center 63.9 7.5 28.6 100.0
South 21.0 8.8 70.2 100.0
Islands 31.0 8.3 60.7 100.0
Source: Based on AGEA data, 2014
mmorag@uchile.cl
58 A. Corsi et al.
due to the strong diversification of varieties and the access to several market-
ing channels. In particular, due to the long consumption tradition, consumers
prefer local wines, which makes finding local outlets easier. On the other
hand, small size makes it more difficult to exploit foreign markets, as well as
large-scale retail.
Bottling is the production phase with the lowest availability of specific infor-
mation. Nonetheless, bottling technical units are fewer than the number of
grape growers and wine-making technical units. A relatively recent study
(Malorgio et al. 2011b) estimated that about 8000 bottlers operate in Italy.
Also the bottling technical units are very different in size, and the largest
amount of wine (about 80%) is bottled by a very small share of bottlers (about
6%) with a relatively high processing capacity (more than 10,000 hl/year)
(Table 3.5).
About 20% of the bottling technical units belong to pure (plain) bottlers
bottling only wine produced by others. They deliver about one third of the
Italian bottled production to the market. The other bottling technical units
operate directly in wine-making plants. The majority of them (about 60%)
belong to on-farm wine-makers and the rest to both cooperatives and indus-
trial wine-makers. Despite the relatively high number of on-farm bottling
technical units, most on-farm wine-makers are not equipped with their own
bottling line; by contrast, most industrial and cooperative wine-makers are
equipped with bottling lines. The absence of bottling lines linked with wine-
making facilities has three causes. First, many wine producers (farms, indus-
trial wine-makers, or small cooperatives) have neither the sufficient size nor
the skills to market bottled wine on their own and therefore sell all their
production in bulk to other businesses. Second, several grape-processing tech-
nical units may belong to the same firm, which concentrates bottling in a
single station. Third, some small wine producers outsource bottling. Indeed,
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Italian Wine Industry 59
many large bottling plants operate as co-packers, and some firms equipped
with truck-mounted bottling lines supply the service to small wine
producers.
The foregoing discussion evidences that the Italian wine industry is based on
a complex network characterized by a radical concentration of flows. The
grapes originate in a huge number of farms but are crushed by a much smaller
number of wine-making technical units, and bottled wine is delivered to the
market by a small number of bottling wineries or pure bottlers.
Indeed, it is possible to identify different, though interrelated, supply
chains. These are two integrated chains, the Agricultural chain and the
Cooperative chain, and two de-integrated chains, the Industrial chain and the
pure Bottler chain.
The Agricultural chain and the Cooperative chain can be considered as
integrated supply chains because they are headed by bottling firms that deliver
to the market wine mostly deriving from self-produced grapes. Firms in these
chains can be simple, their technical structure consisting in a wine-making
and bottling plant, supplied by one or more vineyards in the immediate sur-
roundings, directly owned (the case of the Agricultural chain); or they can be
run by cooperative members (the case of the Cooperative chain). However,
firms in this chain can assume a complex network nature. For instance, one or
more bottling stations may be supplied by several grape-processing plants
belonging to the same firm and by grapes produced by farms directly owned
(case of Agricultural chain); or the bottling stations may be functionally
linked to wine-making plants via specific agreements among formally inde-
pendent cooperatives (the case of the Cooperative chain).
The Industrial chain and the Bottlers chain can be considered as de-
integrated supply chains because they are headed by firms delivering to the
market wine mostly derived from purchased grapes and/or wine. These firms
typically have a network of suppliers, in some cases located in the surround-
ings of the bottling station or, as in the case of larger actors in these chains,
spread throughout Italy and in some cases even located abroad. These net-
works of suppliers can be more or less stable, depending on the nature of the
relation between suppliers and supplied (contracts or market; see Sect. 3.5.2).
These four supply chains are anyway interrelated, because exchanges of
products may take place among firms belonging to different supply chains. In
some cases, grapes or wine produced by firms belonging to Agricultural or
mmorag@uchile.cl
60 A. Corsi et al.
Cooperative chains that exceed their needs are delivered to de-integrated sup-
ply chains. In other cases, to enlarge their supply, firms belonging to the
Agricultural chain purchase grapes or wine from agents operating mainly in
the de-integrated supply chains. All these supply chains are important, in
volume and value. Different types of suppliers therefore characterize the
Italian wine industry. According to reliable evaluations (Malorgio et al.
2011a), the shares in volume of the four supply chains can be estimated as
Agricultural chain, 20%; Cooperative chain, 17%; Industrial chain, 30%;
and Bottler chain, 33%. The shares in value are probably different. In particu-
lar, the share of the agricultural chain is higher because its share of the more
expensive PDO wines in the total supply is larger, and this supply chain
includes the producers of the most prestigious Italian wines.
Even considering that several technical units, also bottling plants, can belong
to a single company, wine supply in Italy remains quite fragmented, and the
degree of concentration of the industry is modest.
Mediobanca (2018) surveys the 155 main firms (those with a turnover of
more than 25 million euros). In 2016, their total turnover was 7.2 billion
euros, compared to an estimated Italian total of 13.9 (a share of 51.8%). The
four-firm concentration rate is only 13.6%, and the first ten companies only
account for 24% of the total turnover.
Two cooperatives (Cantine Riunite and Caviro) are the largest companies,
and another two (Cavit and Mezzacorona) are among the first ten companies:
cooperatives, though less in number, are absolutely significant in the overall
picture of Italian wine-making, both as to volume of wine and turnover
(Table 3.6). But also the other supply chains are represented among the top
wine firms. In fact, some big companies lead bottler supply chains (e.g.
Enoitalia and Italian Wine Brands) and other industrial supply chains (e.g.
Mondodelvino Group and Botter). Other companies represent cases of agri-
cultural supply chains, though among these large companies, a minor share of
grape and wine is usually outsourced7 (e.g. Compagnia de’ Frescobaldi and
Masi Agricola).
All the largest companies have their headquarters in the North (Veneto,
Emilia-Romagna, Piedmont, and Trentino) or in Tuscany but with plants or
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Italian Wine Industry 61
mmorag@uchile.cl
62 A. Corsi et al.
Table 3.6 (continued)
Turnover (€ millions)
Export
share Av.
Headquarter 2016 Price
Name (region) 2016 2015 2014 2013 (%) Governance €/bott
Lunelli Trentino 96 84 na na 26.5 Family na
control
Ruffino Toscana 93 94 81 75 93 Foreign 3.97
control
Villa Sandi Veneto 88 73 na na 45 Family na
control
Vivo Cantine Veneto 81 65 na na 47 Cooperative na
Cantina di La Trentino 76 83 na na 74 Cooperative na
Vis e Valle di
Cembra
Contri Veneto 76 79 82 92 39 Mixed na
Spumanti
Mionetto Veneto 72 65 na na 57 Foreign na
control
VS Vinicola Veneto 68 56 na na na Family na
Serena control
Gruppo Banfi Toscana 67 70 63 66 57 Foreign 4.69
control
Vignaioli Veneto 67 na na na na Cooperative na
Veneto
Friulani
Quargentan Veneto 66 68 na na na Family na
control
Masi Agricola Veneto 64 61 60 65 88 Family 5.2
controla
Sources: Mediobanca (2016, 2017, 2018) for turnover and governance; average prices
are our evaluations
a
Listed
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Italian Wine Industry 63
non-cooperative firms. Indeed, the big cooperatives are the result of a process
of aggregation of medium/small firms; but similar processes have not
occurred among family companies. In the recent history of the Italian wine
sector, there have been no cases of medium/large firms in financial crisis or
gone bankrupt that other firms could easily acquire. The existing large non-
cooperative firms have grown only by internal growth without the big jumps
that, in the new producing countries, have characterized the evolution of
some wine companies (Green et al. 2006; Mariani and Pomarici 2011). As a
result, there are no true sector leaders, even if the cooperatives are the most
important players.
The analysis of the top 30 players reveals two other characteristics of the
Italian wine sector. Wine is the main or the only business of the leading firms
(in one case only, that of Campari, wine production is a division of larger
group producing beverages and spirits). Foreign capital is rare, since only 4
top companies in the first 30 (and not in the top positions) are owned by
foreign capital and only few cases among smaller firms are known8; on the
other hand, also Italian investments abroad are scarce.
The turnover trends observed since 2011 for larger companies (i.e. those
with turnovers above 50 million euros) show that a process of polarization is
ongoing within the supply chain (Pomarici 2017). The relative weight of the
larger companies is increasing, probably because of economies of scale, which
are especially possible for big companies in the commercial premium segment.
Smaller companies instead exploit niche marketing strategies and special
skills, addressing the super-premium segment and the local distribution chan-
nels. By contrast, medium-sized companies, in the class between 50 and 100
million turnover, show a reduction in their turnover share. This is probably
due to their size itself, which prevents either reaching satisfactory economies
of scale for intermediate quality segments or achieving a competitive advan-
tage for the top quality segments.
The marketing strategies of individual firms are obviously very different, and
it is not easy to give a general assessment. In very general terms, firm brands
are not of primary importance for consumers, who are instead more attracted
by the appellations and by the region of origin in purchasing (Fait 2010;
Corduas et al. 2013).
The latest case (2016) is the transfer of the prestigious Biondi Santi winery in Montalcino to the EPI
8
mmorag@uchile.cl
64 A. Corsi et al.
First, as regards the domestic market, a reason for the limited importance
of brands is drinking habits, which are traditionally strongly linked to local
wines. Second, with such a large number of producers, it is difficult for con-
sumers to select the information and to check the reputation of the individual
producers, and appellations are, albeit imperfect, quality signals (Cacchiarelli
et al. 2014). Third, on the producers’ side, most firms lack the financial
strength and the skills to promote and advertise their products individually,
and also among larger firms, the appropriateness of branding activities typical
of fast-moving consumer goods is questioned.
In fact, the marketing activities for premium wines are mostly of the push
type, with a deep personal involvement of entrepreneurs and oenologists, and
addressed to intermediaries, retailers, media, HORECA actors, and selected
influential consumers. They also try to benefit from the collective reputation
of the appellation and, possibly, from marketing campaigns funded by local
public bodies or organizations. On the basic wine side, instead, promotion
relies mostly on price promotion and on favorable positions on the shelves.
There are exceptions, however. One is in the segment of very high-quality
wines (super-premium, icon), where the winery brand is obviously a strong
asset and a marketing tool. Nevertheless, even the most famous producers are
usually linked to particular areas and to individual appellations, so that the
brand is used in association with the PDO. Very few exceptions are the Super
Tuscans and some other similar wines, originally created outside DOC/G
regulations, and now still in many cases PGI wines and for which only the
brand is a quality signal for consumers.
On the opposite side of the quality scale, brands (but not private labels,
unlike in other countries) are used and advertised for generic wines, since this
is the only differentiation signal that consumers can receive. For instance,
among value wines, mainly sold in supermarkets, Tavernello is the leading
brand (Giacomini 2010). It was launched by Caviro, the second cooperative
firm by size in Italy, 30 years ago, as the first wine in cartons in Italy.
The marketing style in exports is substantially similar, and firm efforts,
depending on their financial resources, are mostly addressed to enlarging and
enhancing their relationships with distributors, retailers, media, and
HORECA actors, and to influencing consumers, privileging actions below
the line (public relations, etc.) instead of above it (advertising). Since 2010
the export promotion of Italian wine firms has been supported by substantial
resources provided by the EU Common Agricultural Policy.
In regard to larger firms, the market segments in which they operate and
the strategies adopted are quite diversified. In general, cooperatives operate in
segments of low- and medium-quality wines, mostly oriented to the mass
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Italian Wine Industry 65
market, with smaller margins due to the prevailing large-scale retail outlet and
to a lower orientation to foreign markets (Mediobanca 2016, 2017, 2018). In
terms of types of wine, in 2017 “great wines” (with prices over 25 euros per
bottle) were 2.9% of wine labels for cooperatives, compared to 8.2% for pri-
vate companies. The shares for DOCG and DOC wines were 12.8% and
38.9% for cooperatives and 11.4% and 32.8% for private companies. The
shares of PGI were similar (36.6% and 35.8% for cooperatives and private
companies, respectively), but the latter had a greater number of generic wines
(11.8% vs. 8.8%).
In short, while cooperatives are more concentrated on the medium seg-
ment (with the remarkable exceptions of Caviro for basic wines and Collis for
super-premium wines), private companies are more dedicated to either the
top segment or the lowest one. The comparison of average prices indicates
that private companies belonging to the Agricultural supply chain fetch higher
prices (especially in the cases of Antinori, Frescobaldi, and Santa Margherita),
since they are primarily oriented to super-premium wines, while firms belong-
ing to the other supply chains focus on the basic/premium market.
Analysis of the top players also illustrates the different performances of the
Italian companies in terms of exports. Of the first 30 firms, 12 obtain more
than 70% of their turnover from foreign markets (up to 97% for Botter and
93% for Ruffino), 7 between 50% and 70%, and the rest below 50% (with a
minimum of 26.5% for Lunelli), with no pattern in this respect between
cooperatives and private companies.
A special mention should be made of the production of sparkling wines,
which has rapidly increased in recent years, up to 610–630 million bottles in
20159 (Osservatorio Economico Vini 2016; available at www.ovse.org). The
sector is highly diversified in production methods (second fermentation in
tanks, i.e. Charmat, 95–96% of the total, and second fermentation in bot-
tles, i.e. Champenoise, for the rest), firm size, appellations (generic, PGI,
PDO), taste (sweet, brut, dry, extra dry), and longer or shorter aging.
Whatever the segment, big wineries cover the largest part of the production
(almost 60%), since the sparkling wine technology is not easily affordable
for small farms. The differences in production methods translate into quite
different production costs and, in some cases, are conditioned by the level of
designation (Zanfi 2009, 2011). Accordingly, sparkling wine can range from
the value segment to the super-premium segment, depending on the pro-
duction method, the aging, and, obviously, the brand. The most important
In 2016 the value of the Italian sparkling wines destined for export was 1.2 billion (ISMEA 2018).
9
mmorag@uchile.cl
66 A. Corsi et al.
production areas are located in the NW and the NE, and are represented by
Piedmont for Asti Spumante DOCG (70 million bottles in 2015), by
Lombardy for Franciacorta DOCG (top-class region for traditional method,
30 million), by Veneto and Friuli for Prosecco DOC and Valdobbiadene
Prosecco Superiore DOCG (470 million), and by Trentino-Alto Adige for
Trento DOC (8 million). The production of sparkling wines is expanding
out of the traditional areas under several appellations, with an overall share
that in 2017 was around 22% of the total.10
DOMESTIC PRODUTION
IMPORT CHANGE IN STOCKS
93%
5% 2%
TOTAL AVAILABILITY
DISTILLATION EXPORT
3% 46%
Potable alcohol, DOMESTIC
Crisis distillation,
3%
38% CONSUMPTION
By-products of 45%
wine-making, 59%
BULK BOTTLED
35% 65%
Fig. 3.2 Wine consuption flows. (Source: ISMEA, Scheda di settore 2015)
10
Unpublished information from UIV Wine Market Observatory.
11
The term “on-trade” means sold for consumption in hotels, pubs, restaurants, and cafes, whereas “off-
trade” means sold in supermarkets, stores, food retailers, corner shops, and so on.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Italian Wine Industry 67
Table 3.7 Percentage of Italian domestic supply by distribution channels (2017, 155
top wine companies)
Supply of the top Italian wine companies
All wines Great wines
Distribution channels for domestic All All
supply firms Private Coop firms Private Coop
Direct sale 12.6 14.4 10.6 18.8 23.6 12.1
Large-scale retail 38.2 33.9 45.5 3.3 3.4 2.1
HORECA 16.5 21.7 8.2 37 37.1 38
Wine shops and wine bars 8.1 10 4.5 23.6 26.3 16.7
Wholesalers and intermediaries 16.8 14.6 20.5 8 3.7 17.2
Other channels 7.8 5.4 10.7 9.3 5.9 13.9
Source: Mediobanca (2018)
12
It is also customary for farms and cooperatives to deliver bulk wine to consumers’ homes.
mmorag@uchile.cl
68 A. Corsi et al.
The destination of the great wines (those with a price of more than 25
euros) of the largest firms is rather different and suggests the different orienta-
tion of distribution channels in terms of type of wine. HORECA and small
shops (wine shops and wine bars) have the largest share (respectively, 37% and
24%) of consumption of great wines, followed by direct sales (19%), while
large-scale retail has a very low weight (3%). The main difference between
cooperatives and companies is that the latter use more direct sales and small
shops and rely less on trade.
Distribution outlets are reached in Italy in almost the same way by all firms.
Firms are connected with small outlets like wine shops, restaurants, bars, and
wholesalers through a network of sales representatives, which can be larger or
smaller according to the firm’s size. The purchase platforms of large-scale
retailers or restaurant chains are reached via specialized intermediaries.
Distributors (i.e. operators that have the monopoly within an area of the sales
of the products of a winery and that promote its brand) have a quite limited
role in Italy, especially in the case of great wines.
The exported wine is shipped mainly in bottles; indeed, bottled still and
sparkling wines account for 75% of total exports in volume.
Most wine firms reach the foreign markets through local importers abroad,
possibly supported, in the case of smaller firms, by specialized intermediaries
(Mediobanca 2018). Larger companies may have various importers in the
same country, one to reach large retailers and others to reach wine shops and
restaurants. The 155 larger companies too mostly export through foreign
importers (75% of their exports), less through their own networks (10%),
though cooperatives have a larger weight in the latter (14%). Indeed, only few
firms, private or cooperative, have established controlled distribution compa-
nies in some importing markets. Among the great wines, the share of import-
ers is slightly larger (78%), especially for private companies (88%).
The Italian wine production chain is based on different supply chains differ-
ently integrated. The flows of grapes originate from a very large number of
farms, but an increasingly smaller number of operators control the flows of
wine in the subsequent phases of the chain.
The available data enable detailed analysis of the flow in the first step of the
wine production chain, from grapes to bulk wine, showing how grapes
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Italian Wine Industry 69
28.1
(17.2-29.0-37.6) Winegrowers non
cooperative
members
Winegrowers
On-farm Other
cooperative
winemakers winegrowers
members
41.2 8.2
(35.6-46.7-41.9) (9.2-11.1-6.0) 22.5
(37.9-13.2-14.5)
Industrial 30.7
Cooperatives (47.2-24.3-20.5)
winemakers
Map legend: grape flows share for total wine (generic wine, PGI wine, PDO wine)
Fig. 3.3 Estimable grape flows among operators for total wine, generic wine, GI wine,
PDO wine. (Map legend: Grape flows share for total wine (generic wine, PGI wine, PDO
wine))
This estimate does not consider the flows of grapes produced by other farmers to farmers making wine;
13
moreover, grapes possibly sold to cooperatives and industrial wineries by farmers making wine, when
exceeding their processing capacity, are aggregated to the grapes sold by “other farmers”.
mmorag@uchile.cl
70 A. Corsi et al.
The flows are different for the different categories of wine. For the grapes
destined for generic wine, the part provided by cooperative members is 36%,
the part processed on the farm is 17%, that purchased by cooperatives is 9%,
and that purchased by industrial wineries is 38%, so that the share of the
formal market (47%) is relatively high. The corresponding share for PGI
grapes is only 24% (11% purchased by cooperatives, 13% by industrial win-
eries), while the share processed by cooperatives from their members is 47%,
and the amount self-provided by farmers is 29%. Finally, for PDO wines, the
share of the formal market is about 20% (6% purchased by cooperatives,
14.5% by industrial wineries), while 38% is used for on-farm wine-making,
and 42% is provided to the cooperatives by their members.
The analysis of flows in the second step of the wine production chain, from
bulk to bottled wine, cannot be supported by detailed data, but it can never-
theless be based on a reliable evaluation (Malorgio et al. 2011b). This second
step involves about 70% of the wine produced, as about 30% is marketed in
bulk for domestic consumption or export.
In analyzing this second step, it is convenient first to consider that the wine
produced on-farm and by cooperatives is only partially bottled by the same
operators. The shares of their own wine directly bottled by farmers and coop-
eratives are about 45% and 20%, respectively. Therefore, on-farm wine-
makers and cooperatives, net of internal exchanges, deliver to the intermediate
wine market over 50% of the wine volume. Indeed, on-farm wine-makers
typically either bottle their entire wine production or sell it totally in bulk. On
the contrary, most cooperatives are equipped with a bottling line, but they
typically bottle only a share of their wine and supply bottlers in Italy or abroad,
especially in the last period of development of an international bulk market
(Mariani et al. 2012).
The industrial wineries buy on the intermediate market and bottle bulk
wine for about 30% in addition to the wine that they produce directly. Of
course, pure bottlers buy the totality of the wine that they bottle on this mar-
ket. Also this intermediate market strongly concentrates the flows, as the wine
produced by about 45,000 wine-making technical units is delivered to fewer
than 3000 bottling stations.
Summing up, the structure of Italian wine industry, as based on both inte-
grated and de-integrated supply chains, includes two intermediate markets,
grapes and wine. Although smaller in volume than 30/40 years ago, these
markets are still important in quantitative and functional terms and are struc-
turally necessary for the functioning of the de-integrated supply chains but
also give flexibility to the functioning of the integrated supply chains.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Italian Wine Industry 71
In the past, there existed big local markets where intermediaries and wine-
makers traded a very large proportion of grapes. These markets are now
reduced in size because they handle only one third of the grapes, given that
most of the grapes are processed either by the farmers themselves or by their
cooperatives. Moreover, when wineries produce higher-quality wines, they
tend to have stable purchase relationships with wine-growers—so as to ensure
a supply of good-quality grapes—on the basis of formal or informal
contracts.
Price setting differs according to the different flows. Of particular impor-
tance is the mechanism used by cooperatives. Since the Italian law imposes
strong constraints on the destination of profits of cooperatives, in practice
profits are distributed to members as higher prices for the grapes that they
deliver. Members (who generally are bound to provide their total production
to their cooperative) therefore receive a first price as an advance. When the
cooperative accounts are closed, profits are distributed as an additional price
(balance). Hence, the real price that cooperative members receive depends on
the overall wine market and on the cooperative’s efficiency rather than on the
market for grapes. Similarly, for wine-growers that are also on-farm wine-
makers, the real price that they receive for their grapes depends on the overall
wine market and on the wine-making efficiency rather than on the market for
grapes. Of course, for on-farm wine-makers, also the quality of the grapes
(and, hence, their skills in growing the grapes) matters. The same applies to
the cooperative members, since cooperatives usually pay their members
according to the quality of their grapes. In the long term, cooperatives and
on-farm wine-makers have acted as powerful indirect regulators of the market
of grapes, over which wholesalers and industrial wine-makers traditionally
exercised market power. Partly, growers provide grapes to industrial wineries
under contract, so that prices are set in advance. This also concerns some on-
farm wineries, which increase their wine production by buying other grapes,
and it mainly happens when they aim at quality wines. When costs are the
main concern, wineries buy on the spot, have no long-term relationship with
the sellers, and choose mainly according to the price. The prices on these mar-
kets are not easy to detect but mainly depend on the supply of grapes and/or
on the existing wine stocks of previous harvests. However, the market for
grapes based on spot prices is a minor market, because it concerns a minor
part of the processed grapes. However, the share of the spot market is larger
for the grapes for generic wines or for some large-volume PDO/PGI wines.
mmorag@uchile.cl
72 A. Corsi et al.
The Italian wine industry lacks a unitary governance because the actors are
represented by many organizations. Farmers are represented by three general
farmers’ unions, and cooperatives are represented by two main unions plus
some minor ones. Moreover, two wine producer organizations (Unione
Italiana Vini and Federvini) are also active; many farmers or cooperative
members of these bodies are also members of their general association. As a
matter of fact, this fragmentation often hampers the development of efficient
and shared policies for the sector.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Italian Wine Industry 73
Also other bodies have a role in the governance of the Italian wine industry.
Among them, the association of oenologists (Assoenologi), the association for
wine tourism, the association of wine cities, and, in particular, the interbranch
organizations constituted among producers of one or more PDO/PGI wines
(Consorzi di Tutela) according to the EU and national regulations14 to pursue
the interests of their members—in particular to promote their wines, to
improve knowledge about production techniques and market conditions, to
regulate the supply, and to prevent the unlawful use of the name of the wine.
In Italy about 110 Consorzi di Tutela are active and are recognized by the
Ministry of Agricultural, Food and Forestry Policies; these bodies at the
regional level negotiate local wine policies, while their national association
(Federdoc) takes part in the negotiations concerning the national wine
policy.
Research and technical innovation are carried out mainly by research centers
of the network of the Ministry of Agricultural, Food and Forestry Policies
(Consiglio per la ricerca in agricoltura e l’analisi dell’economia agraria—CREA)
and by several university departments, which also train the oenologists.
3.6 Conclusions
The overall picture that can be drawn is a multifaceted one. However, some
main structural elements emerge.
A first aspect is the diversity of the operators included in the structure of
the Italian wine sector (Sardone 2014). This applies to grape-growing as well
as to wine-making and distribution.
The wine-growing sector extends throughout Italy but with specific territo-
rial differences. Its core lies in Veneto, Tuscany, and Piedmont for quality
wines and Emilia-Romagna, Veneto, and Apulia for mass consumption wines,
even if also other regions produce wine grapes. It is mainly composed of small
family farms, growing a large number of varieties and with a large number of
PDO and GI wines.
The wine-making sector, too, comprises a variety of operators with differ-
ent specializations and different relations for grape procurement, defining two
integrated supply chains (Agricultural and Cooperative) and two de-integrated
ones (Industrial and Bottler), each of which is highly diversified. In the overall
system, cooperatives are the most important players, both as leading firms and
14
EU: Reg. 1308/2013, art. 157, 158, 167; Italy: L. 238/2016, art. 41.
mmorag@uchile.cl
74 A. Corsi et al.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Italian Wine Industry 75
References
Anderson, K., S. Nelgen, and V. Pinilla. 2017. Global wine markets, 1860 to 2016.
Adelaide: University of Adelaide Press.
Cacchiarelli, L., A. Carbone, M. Esti, T. Laureti, and A. Sorrentino. 2014. Prezzi e
qualità del vino: un confronto fra regioni. AgriRegioniEuropa 10 (39): 13–18, Dic.
2014.
CIA. 2012. Siglato l’accordo interprofessionale sul prezzo dell’uva DOC Marsala. CIA di
Trapani. Available at: www.viniesapori.net
Corduas, M., L. Cinquanta, and C. Ievoli. 2013. The importance of wine attributes
for purchase decisions: A study of Italian consumers’ perception. Food Quality and
Preference 28: 407–418.
Corsi, A., E. Pomarici, and R. Sardone. 2004. Italy. In The world’s wine markets.
Globalization at work, ed. K. Anderson. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
———. 2018. Italy Post–1938. In Wine globalization: A new comparative history, ed.
Kim Anderson and Vicente Pinilla. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Fait, M. 2010. Brand-landequity nei territori del vino. Mercati e competitività (3):
119–140, Milano, Franco Angeli.
Giacomini, C. 2010. “Tavernello” il vino più bevuto nelle famiglie italiane: un caso
di successo. Mercati e competitività (2): 145–155, Milano: Franco Angeli.
Green, R., Zúñiga M. Rodríguez, and Pinto A. Seabra. 2006. Imprese del vino: un
sistema in continua evoluzione. In Il mercato del vino: tendenze strutturali e strategie
dei concorrenti, ed. G.P. Cesaretti, R. Green, A. Mariani, and E. Pomarici. Milano:
Franco Angeli.
———. 2015. Scheda di settore. Settore vino. Aggiornata al 21/10/2015. Ismea,
Rome.
mmorag@uchile.cl
76 A. Corsi et al.
———. 2018. Scheda di settore. Settore vino. Aggiornata ad aprile 2018. Ismea,
Rome. Available at: http://www.ismeaservizi.it/flex/cm/pages/ServeBLOB.php/L/
IT/IDPagina/3525#MenuV
ISMEA, Sezione RETEVINO DOP-IGP. 2018. Ismea, Rome. Available at: http://
www.ismeamercati.it/flex/FixedPages/IT/VinoDati.php/L/IT
ISTAT. 2010. 6° Censimento Generale dell’Agricoltura, data warehouse. Available at:
http://dati-censimentoagricoltura.istat.it/?lang=it
———. 2013. 9° Censimento dell’Industria e dei Servizi. Roma.
Malorgio, G., C. Grazia, and C. De Rosa. 2011a. Forme organizzative e scelte strate-
giche per la valorizzazione dei vini a denominazione di origine. Economia agroali-
mentare (1–2): 367–390, Franco Angeli.
Malorgio, G., E. Pomarici, R. Sardone, A. Scardera, and D. Tosco. 2011b. La catena
del valore nella filiera vitivinicola. Agriregionieuropa (27): 14–19, Dic. 2011.
Mariani, A., and E. Pomarici. 2011. Strategie per il vino italiano. Edizioni Scientifiche
Italiane, Napoli.
Mazzarino, S., and A. Corsi. 2015. I flussi dell’uva verso la vinificazione: un’analisi
comparata per regioni e macroaree. Economia agro-alimentare 20 (1): 29–58.
Mediobanca. 2016. Indagine sul settore vinicolo. Mediobanca, Milano, Aprile 2016.
Available at: www.mbres.it/sites/default/files/resources/download_it/Indagine_
vini_2016.pdf
———. 2017. Indagine sul settore vinicolo. Mediobanca, Milano, Aprile 2017.
Available at: https://www.mbres.it/sites/default/files/resources/download_it/
Indagine_vini_2017.pdf
———. 2018. Indagine sul settore vinicolo. Mediobanca, Milano, Aprile 2018.
Available at: https://www.mbres.it/sites/default/files/resources/download_it/
Indagine_vini_2018.pdf
Osservatorio Economico Vini. 2016. Produzione nazionale di vini spumanti 2015–2016.
Available at: http://www.ovse.org/mercati-e-consumi/avvio.cfm?idContent=198
Pomarici, E. 2017. Le grandi imprese del vino italiano: dinamica e peculiarità. AE
Agricoltura/Alimentazione/Economia/Ecologia (2): 56–69.
QUALIVITA. 2018. Rapporto 2017 ISMEA-QUALIVITA, XV. I Quaderni
Qualivita 35–39. Available at: www.ismea.it/flex/cm/pages/ServeBLOB.php/L/
IT/IDPagina/10226
Sardone, R. 2014. I numeri del vino italiano. Agriregionieuropa 10 (39): 9–13.
Zanfi, A. 2009. Atlante degli spumanti di Italia, vol. Metodo Classico, Carlo Cambi
Editore, 7–35.
———. 2011. Atlante degli spumanti di Italia, vol. Metodo Italiano, Carlo Cambi
Editore, 20–76.
mmorag@uchile.cl
4
The Spanish Wine Industry
Luis Miguel Albisu, Cristina Escobar, Rafael del Rey,
and José María Gil Roig
L. M. Albisu (*)
CITA, Zaragoza, Spain
e-mail: lmalbisu@cita-aragon.es
C. Escobar
Center for Research in Agro-food Economics and Development UPC-IRTA
(CREDA), Castelldefels, Spain
e-mail: cristina.escobar@upc.edu
R. del Rey
Spanish Observatory of Wine Markets (OeMv), Madrid, Spain
e-mail: direccion@oemv.es
J. M. Gil Roig
Technical University of Catalonia, Catalonia, Spain
Center for Research in Agro-food Economics and Development UPC-IRTA
(CREDA), Castelldefels, Spain
e-mail: chema.gil@upc.edu
mmorag@uchile.cl
78 L. M. Albisu et al.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Spanish Wine Industry 79
1186 1167
1165 1160
1200 1135 1131 10000
1108
1046
1002
963 946 946 947
1000 941
8000
800
6000
1000 ha
1000 t
600
4000
7241 7483
7064
400 6595
5934 6063 5963 5952 6108 6222
5535 5809 5799
5332
2000
200
0 0
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Production (1000 t) Area (1000 ha)
Fig. 4.1 Evolution of the vineyard area and the production of grapes in Spain. (Source:
Own elaboration from Agriculture Yearbooks and Agriculture Statistics.
MAGRAMA. Spanish Ministry of Agriculture, Food and Environment (MAGRAMA
2016))
• La Rioja and the province of Alava (the southern province of the Basque
Country). Both are included within the most known and important
Spanish wine regions (QDO La Rioja2).
2
QDO: Qualified Designation of Origin.
mmorag@uchile.cl
80 L. M. Albisu et al.
Fig. 4.2 Wine vineyard specialization in Spain (2012). (Source: Own elaboration from
the Agriculture Yearbook 2013. MAGRAMA. Spanish Ministry of Agriculture, Food and
Environment (MAGRAMA 2015c))
• The southern provinces of Galicia (NW of Spain), which are mainly known
for their PDO Rias Baixas and Ribeiro.
• The Canary Islands: They represent a small proportion of the total vineyard
in Spain. However, this crop is one of the few that bears their agro-climatic
circumstances, and, thus, the region is highly specialized on it.
• The provinces of Barcelona and Tarragona, in Catalonia. They account for
more than 90% of the cava (sparkling wine) produced in Spain (PDO
cava).
• Some of the provinces of Castilla-La Mancha and southern Extremadura.
This big land extension includes 17 PDOs, among them La Mancha and
Valdepeñas, two of the largest PDOs in Spain.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Spanish Wine Industry 81
big extension and its high crop specialization. Next, we find Extremadura,
Castilla and León and the Valencian Community, with similar percentages
over the total (8.7%, 7.8% and 7.5%, respectively). La Rioja and Catalonia
rank in the fourth and fifth places, with 5.8% and 4.7% of the surface, respec-
tively (MAGRAMA 2015c).
4.2 S
tructural Features of the Wine-Growing
Sector
4.2.1 Farm Size
Agricultural holdings (AHs) with vineyard in Spain are relatively small with
an average utilized agricultural area (UAA) of 6.57 hectares. There is, however,
a high heterogeneity among the different regions. Among specialized wine
regions, larger holdings are located in Extremadura and Castilla-La Mancha,
while the smallest are concentrated in the Canary Islands, Castilla-León and
Aragón. In relation to farm size, 39.8% of the holdings have from 1 to less
than 5 hectares (accounting for 8.6% of the total vineyard UAA), while 33.6%
have from 5 to less than 20 hectares (28.2% of the total vineyard UAA), being
the latter the most important segment. Holdings between 20 and less than 50
hectares of UAA (14.1% of the total number of vineyard holdings) represent
the second most important segment in terms of surface (26.8% of the vine-
yard area) followed by the segment with 100 hectares of UAA or more (4.2%
on the total holdings) and accounting for 20.5% of vineyard UAA (Agricultural
Census 2009, INE).
The land tenure of the vineyard holdings is primarily the private property,
representing 73.2% of their UAA. The rest is basically rented (20.0%), with a
small percentage of sharecropping or other systems (6.8%). If we segment
vineyard holdings taking into account their total standard output, it can be
observed that, in general terms, the smaller the total standard output, the
higher the share of land in property. Rented land accounts for over 25% in
larger holdings, while sharecropping is relatively more important in interme-
diate holdings (Farm Structure Survey 2013, INE).
mmorag@uchile.cl
82 L. M. Albisu et al.
4.2.3 Employment
According to the last available Agricultural Census (2009), AHs in Spain are
basically owned by natural persons (94.2% of the AH with UAA), not enter-
prises. The grape-growing sector does not differ significantly from this figure
(95.8%). Moreover, this model of family enterprise/farmer manager is quite
homogeneous across the different Spanish regions although some slight differ-
ences can be observed. Among the most important wine producer regions, in
Catalonia and Navarra, the percentage of commercial firms is relatively higher
(Farm Structure Survey 2013, INE).
Grape production in Spain is mainly used for the production of wine (95.7%
of the vineyard holdings allocate grape production to wine). Among these
holdings, approximately 50% are registered to produce wine with either a
PDO or a PGI indication, even though final sales under a quality indication
may depend on the needs of the market. Furthermore, the production of
quality wine is concentrated in larger holdings. In fact, the average size of
holdings oriented toward quality wines is 8.36 hectares, while it is only 4.64
hectares in the case of holdings producing table wines. In the case of holdings
oriented to produce table grapes or raisins, the average surface is 2.30 and
1.26 hectares, respectively (Agricultural Census 2009, INE).
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Spanish Wine Industry 83
In Spain there are 66 grape varieties that are relevant in surface. However, only
a few represent a high proportion of the Spanish vineyards (in relative num-
bers). The most importance grape variety in Spain is Airen, which occupies
22.5% of the surface. Airen is a white grape variety, very abundant in the
South Spanish plateau, especially in Castilla-La Mancha (Fig. 4.3). The sec-
ond most important grape variety is Tempranillo, which occupies 21.4% of
the Spanish vineyard. It is a red grape variety extensively grown to produce red
full wines. Its origin comes from the Spanish region of La Rioja, being, there-
fore, the most produced grape within this region. The third position in the
ranking, further down in significance from the previous two, is occupied by
the grape variety Bobal (6.7%), which has its origin in the Valencian
Community. It has been traditionally linked to bulk wine production,
although there is a growing interest in this variety to produce quality wines.
Grenache occupies the fourth position with 6.6% of the surface. This
Mediterranean variety is one of the most widely planted red wine grape variet-
ies in the world. Its origin is in Aragon but has spread rapidly across other
regions. It has a special relevance in the production of red and rosé wines.
Monastrell occupies 4.7% of the total surface and has also an important pres-
ence worldwide. These five varieties account for 61.9% of the total Spanish
vineyard. The remaining 38.1% is shared by a large amount of grape varieties,
25%
22.5%
21.4%
20%
15%
13.2%
10%
6.7% 6.6%
4.7% 4.3%
5%
2.9% 2.4%
2.2% 2.1% 2.0% 1.9%
1.4% 1.3% 1.2% 1.2% 1.1% 1.0%
0%
Airen
Grenache t.
Cabernet s.
Syrah
Tempranillo
Bobal
Grenache
Monastrell
Macabeo
Pardina
Not identified
Verdejo
Palomino
Merlot
Cayetana b.
Mixture
Muscatel Alex.
Xarel·lo
Rest
Fig. 4.3 Distribution of the main grape varieties in Spain (% on total surface) (2014).
(Source: Own elaboration from the Inventory of wine-growing potential, 2015.
MAGRAMA. Spanish Ministry of Agriculture, Food and Environment (MAGRAMA
2015d))
mmorag@uchile.cl
84 L. M. Albisu et al.
Farm Net Income (FNI) is obtained by adding to the total output the bal-
ances of the subsidies and taxes (also those related to investments). From this
result, the total costs are deducted. Total costs encompass the total intermedi-
ate costs (plants, fertilization, crop protection, machinery and buildings’
maintenance, energy, etc.), depreciation and the total external factors (rent,
interests and wages). In general terms FNI represents the compensation for
the use of the owner fix production factors (land, capital and work), plus the
business’ risk (benefits or losses). Data in this section come from the Farm
Account Data Network database (FADN 2018, European Commission).
Long trends have to be interpreted with some caution, as there have been
some changes both in the sample size and in the methodological framework.
In any case, results in Fig. 4.4 provide a good orientation about the economic
performance of vineyard holdings.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Spanish Wine Industry 85
70000
60000 5,999
50000
32,500
82 48 5,604
40000 4,679 4,607
4,917
21,757
108 678
21,379
202
19,119
22,246
175
55,905
30000 1,653 2,585 257 4,962
4,594
16,992
17,786
3,112
16,823
15,854
12,133
9,312
42,352
38,582
7,808
37,925
36,413
20000 6,465 6,433
30,418
6,652 4,932
28,459
26,510
4,523
24,859
5,166 3,762
10000 2,533
14,728
3,072 2,767 2,676
13,716
2,680
11,489
11,126
10,026
8,200
8,164
7,465
7,731
7,215
Total output…
Total output…
Total output…
Total output…
Total output…
Total output…
Total output…
Total output…
Total output…
Total Costs
Total Costs
Total Costs
Total Costs
Total Costs
Total Costs
Total Costs
Total Costs
Total Costs
Total Costs
-10000
Euros
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015* 2016*
Fig. 4.4 Economic results of the Spanish viticulture holdings (euro). ([*Preliminary
data] Source: Own elaboration from FADN 2018 (European Commission))
The FNI for viticulture holdings in Spain shows an upward trend from
2007 to 2016, with an average of 19,659€ per holding. The result from 2016
is especially high (32,500€). Conversely, minimum is found in 2009 (12,133€)
(Fig. 4.4). The variation on the FNI follows closely the variation on the total
output, which mainly comes from revenues from the production of wine and
grapes. On the other hand, total costs show a steady rise on the studied years,
with a higher rise in 2012 (25.3%). This last rise is experienced in the three
main cost types: intermediate consumption, depreciation and total external
factors, which raised 22.8%, 40.6% and 21.5%, respectively.3
The poor economic performance of grape production is a major challenge
to overcome. Low farm revenues may threaten the future sustainability of
small farms and provoke an increasing abandonment of vineyards. Low farm
prices per kilogram have stimulated grape production in volume to maintain
farm income in many Spanish wine regions, generating wine surpluses which,
in turn, have push prices down particularly for basic wines. Finally, the
increasing international market competition has accentuated this problem,
especially in nowadays economic crisis context (PTV 2012).
3
Considering the ten years globally, the total intermediate consumption represents the highest cost,
accounting for 49.0% of total costs, followed by external factor costs (31.0%) and depreciation (17.4%).
mmorag@uchile.cl
86 L. M. Albisu et al.
4.3 S
tructural Features of the Wine-Making
Sector
4.3.1 Plant Size and Size Distribution of Wineries
In 2013, it was reported that there were 4,036 wineries in Spain (down to
4,024 in 2014), which accounted for 14% of the total number of enterprises
in the agrifood sector. The average size was small as 84% had less than 10
workers and only 66 of them (1.6% of the total) had more than 50 workers
and 9 had more than 200 workers. This structure defines the scope of their
commercial activities although things are changing due to the recent crisis.
Some years ago the small size of most wineries encouraged them to focus pri-
marily on local markets, where there are strong emotional linkages between
producers and consumers; the recent crisis in domestic consumption has
forced a great number of companies to look at international markets.
According to ICEX’s profile of the export wine company (see OeMv 2015c),
in 2014 there were 3897 Spanish wineries exporting to international markets.
If we compare this figure with total number of wineries reported by the
Spanish National Institute of Statistics (INE) (INE 2015), such number
would mean that 96.8% of total registered wine companies have some inter-
national sales activity.
Actually, this profile of the exporting Spanish wine firm reinforces the idea
of many small companies in the wine sector but with a relatively high degree
of concentration of sales. As shown in the table, 65.3% of total exporting
companies sell less than 50,000€ of wine in international markets, and they
account for 1% of the total export value, whereas only 2.4% of total compa-
nies (the 93 largest ones) account for more than two thirds of total export
value (Table 4.1).
In total, all the wine enterprises occupied 23,743 persons, which accounted
for 6.7% of the total employment in the agrifood sector. However, that is the
direct employment as many more people were employed in other related
enterprises. Again, despite the existence of a large number of firms, there is
quite a big concentration of total sales among a small number of wineries. It
is estimated that five enterprises cover more than a quarter of the total sales in
the Spanish market and that the largest eight wineries in Spain—the only sell-
ing above 100 million euro—account for almost half of total sales (Castillo
2015a). Some cooperatives are large, and they collect their grapes from their
cooperative members close to where their elaboration plants are. In the case of
the most common small cooperatives, the grape production area is in the vil-
lage or nearby villages. The top 25 wineries in Spain are listed on Table 4.2.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Spanish Wine Industry 87
In 2014, four companies stand out with more than 200 million euros in
sales. These companies are the Freixenet Group, J. García Carrión, Félix Solís
Avantis and the Codorníu Group. Spain is a country with a large vineyard
area which is widespread all over the country although the cultivation inten-
sity is different among regions. The top wineries by volume are located in the
areas where the production is the greatest such as Castilla-La Mancha (large
cooperatives and the firms Félix Solís, García Carrión and others) or nearby
regions. There is not far distant grape transportation in the country. However,
there are some commercial flows among wineries for cheap wines or to rein-
force shortcoming due to climatological effects, varietal compositions to reach
wine balances and price differentials.
On the other hand, some medium to large wineries are fully related to
quality wines and are located in the most famous PDOs. Their margin is usu-
ally greater than the one for larger-volume wineries. However, during the last
20 years, there has been a wide distribution of companies of all sizes in differ-
ent regions in order to produce different wines. The largest ones have had a
tendency to invest in well-known PDOs in order to improve their margins
and provide higher-quality wines. Medium and even some small companies
traditionally linked to famous wine regions have also invested in other PDOs
or non-PDO areas to elaborate different wines (e.g. whites or sparkling) as
well as to elaborate products at lower cost. A special case should be considered
for cava wines, mostly located in the Catalonian region and concentrated
around two big firms (Freixenet Group and Codorníu Group), who have also
entered into the production of other types of wines in several Spanish PDOs.
mmorag@uchile.cl
88 L. M. Albisu et al.
Table 4.2 Top 25 wineries in Spain according their sales in 2014 (million Euros)
Company name Sales 2014 (million Euros)
1. Grupo Freixenet 535.0a,b
2. J. García Carrión, S.A. (wines) 334.4
3. Félix Solís Avantis, S.A. 253.0
4. Grupo Codorníu 218.0a,c
5. Grupo Miguel Torres 182.4
6. United Wineries Iberia, S.A. (Gr. Arco) 160.0a
7. Grupo González Byass (wines) 150.0a,d
8. Pernod Ricard Winemakers Spain 120.0a,c
9. Grupo Barón de Ley 86.9
10. Grupo Faustino 80.0a
11. Cia. Vin. Norte España, S.A. (CVNE) 77.6e
12. Grupo Marqués de Riscal, S.A. 55.0a
13. Grupo Vivanco 50.0a
14. Grupo Osborne (wines) 50.0a,f
15. Grupo Vinos & Bodegas 47.5
16. Reserva de la Tierra S.L. 47.5
17. Grupo Hijos de Antonio Barceló 45.0a
18. Juan Ramón Lozano, S.A. 43.4
19. Grupo Bodegas Gallegas 42.0
20. López Morenas, S.L. (wines) 40.0
21. Cherubino Valsangiacomo, S.A. 40.0a
22. Bodegas Ontañón, S.A. 39.9c
23. Vicente Gandía Pla, S.A. 36.0
24. Grupo Bodegas Muriel 35.0
25. Viñedos de Aldeanueva, S.Coop. 34.5
Source: Castillo (2015a)
Notes: aAuthors’ estimation; bClosing date of the balance sheet in April 2014 and
2015, respectively; cClosing date of the balance sheet in June 2013 and 2014,
respectively; dClosing date of the balance sheet in August 2013 and 2014,
respectively; eClosing date of the balance sheet in March 2014 and 2015,
respectively; and fClosing date of the balance sheet in January 2014 and 2015,
respectively
–– Firms that produce their own grapes, elaborate their wine and, after aging,
bottle it. They are mostly small and medium firms that sell high-quality
wines with prices above average.
–– Cooperatives that gather grapes from their members and produce bulk or
bottled wines. These enterprises account for around 60% of total wine
production, although a smaller portion of sales.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Spanish Wine Industry 89
–– Wine firms that buy grapes and elaborate wine which is sold on bulk or
bottled. They operate with contractual arrangements. Some of them mix
with their own grapes as well.
–– Wine firms that occasionally buy wine, mature it and bottle it. They can
mix with their own wine depending on their business strategies.
There are wine-making firms that have intermediate situations and cannot
be located in any of those groups. Altogether it can be said that, in a country
with large wine production, and with wineries located in many different
regions, all sort of wine-making firms can be found. It is also necessary to
point out that cooperatives and private firms have usually different approaches
due to their entrepreneurial circumstances. Generally speaking, cooperatives
concentrate their efforts on volume, whereas many private firms are small. It
does not mean that the opposite can also be found.
Spain has all sorts of wines (whites, reds and rosés) and many other kinds like
cavas (sparkling), fortified wines and wines with low alcohol content. Reds are
the most important corresponding to the traditional taste of the Spanish con-
sumer, which exist in many different regions.
Quality wines have been commonly identified with designation of origin
(PDO) wines, and top wineries are usually located in one or several of the
PDOs. This means that Spanish consumers relate quality wines to those com-
ing from PDOs, although perceptions vary for each one of them. Some PDOs
have limited or local markets, whereas others sell a great part of their produc-
tion in international markets.
QDO Rioja stands above all of them, and it has been able not only to have
a wide distribution in the Spanish market but to achieve leadership in many
geographical areas. Its system of young, “crianza” and “reserva” wines has been
widely used by many other wineries all over Spain. The main difference is the
amount of time needed to age wines and to follow certain technical specifica-
tions. Nowadays, international markets are not so prone to accept those cat-
egories, and they specify their own conditions, which creates some tensions
among members of the PDO regulatory councils.
mmorag@uchile.cl
90 L. M. Albisu et al.
their efforts on producing grapes and wines of good technical quality. They
have had an understanding that mainly technical measurable parameters are
essential to reach quality wines. There is a great amount of brands in the mar-
ket, estimated in more than 25,000. Distribution brands account for more
than a third of total sales, and the first entrepreneurial group covers 16.8% of
total sales, and the second only reaches 5.2%, which is another sign of the
limited impact of big wineries and the spread of wine businesses in this coun-
try (Castillo 2015a).
Although a vast majority of companies have recently experienced some
exposure to international markets, most of the smaller ones primarily reach
local markets where either their brands or the PDOs in which they are located
support their market penetration. Mid to large wineries have totally different
approaches looking for national and international distribution. Some of their
brands do not have much strength, and they rely either on PDO brands or on
country recognition. Most recent marketing trends, however, are pushing
wineries to heavily invest in recognized brands, which only since 2013 are
allowed to identify wines from different regions. In Europe PDOs have cer-
tain impact especially for the most important ones but faraway countries, like
the United States and China, rely more on the image of the country of origin.
Unfortunately, most Spanish wines reach low-segment prices, and therefore
their image is low. In the last decade, there has been a great increase of wine
volume exports, but growth in terms of value has been slower.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Spanish Wine Industry 91
the downfall was stabilized. At the same time, the strong need for urgent
international markets to sell excessive production is now less dramatic.
Although still very dependent on the size of the harvest, international sales of
Spanish wines do not seem to grow much more in liters while showing certain
signs of improvement in value terms.
Wine consumption in Spain, as in other traditional producing countries,
has been steadily declining. This downfall of consumption is mainly related to
a cultural change of habits, partly associated with the behavior of younger
generations showing a greater detachment from wine and its culture.
Traditionally, wine consumption used to be a daily routine (for lunch or din-
ner at home). However, over the last 20 years, there has been a progressive
substitution of wine by other drinks such as beer and nonalcoholic drinks.
Nowadays, the consumption of wine has become more sporadic, linked to
more special meals (with friends, business, etc.) and more focused on higher-
quality wines. In fact, the consumption of quality wine has increased, but it
has not compensated the decrease of non-PDO wines, as it will be shown
later.
On the other hand, in other traditionally non-producing countries, wine
consumption is growing, and consumers understand it differently than in the
Mediterranean producing countries (Albisu and Zeballos 2014). Therefore, it
would be helpful to fully understand why some of the formulas used in non-
producing countries are not working in Spain and, conversely, which formu-
mmorag@uchile.cl
92 L. M. Albisu et al.
las should be used in Spain in order to reverse this trend or, at last, to stabilize
current figures. Some hints could be to dissociate wine and food consump-
tion, make wine consumption an easy practice—not too sophisticated—and
bring it closer to the youth, among other measures (Albisu and Zeballos
2014).
2,873
2,926
2,748
2,486
3,040
2,965
2,853
2,765
2,767
2,157
2,113
2,019
2,685
1,693
1,869
2,403
1,755
1,695
1,605
1,497
2,110
1,503
1,463
2,031
2,089
1,366
1,348
1,863
1,181
1,832
1,902
1,802
1,622
931
1,377
1,291
800
1,314
1,251
1,208
1,128
848
779
1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
1.03
1.10
0.94
0.98
1.21
1.21
1.14
1.16
0.99
0.89
0.94
0.96
0.97
1.06
1.00
1.00
0.93
0.99
1.23
0.97
0.97
1.06
1.12
Fig. 4.6 Spanish wine exports. (Source: OeMv (2018) (Spanish acronym for Spanish
Observatory of Wine Markets))
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Spanish Wine Industry 93
The positive trend of the Spanish wine exports can be associated to the
competitive prices, which have been quite stable during the last decade with
the only exception of 2013, when prices increased because of a harvest short-
age on the previous year. Spain has become the most competitive wine exporter
in the world, especially in relation to non-PDO bulk wine at very low prices.
In 2017, bulk wine prices were as low as 0.47 €/l, after growing due to a new
relatively short crop that year. Therefore, exports of bulk wines account for
53.6% of the volume exported while only contributing to 20.1% of the total
export value (Table 4.3). On the opposite side, bottled wines4 including those
commercialized in bricks account up to 58.6% of the value of the Spanish
export although only represent 34.1% of the total volume.
This situation has generated some controversy among some stakeholders
who have questioned if this was the best strategy for the Spanish wine sector
(Del Rey 2015; de la Serna 2013; among others), encouraging a better market
positioning to achieve higher export prices. In this context, there is a general-
ized idea that Spain has to progressively move away from exporting “unspe-
cialized bulk wine” to varietal higher-priced bulk wines and increase exports
of branded and bottled wines to final international consumers.
However, the current situation has to be understood within a historical
perspective. Spain has had a long tradition in exporting wines which goes
back to the eighteenth century with the Jerez/Sherry wines (Maldonado 1999)
and even to the Roman and Phoenician times. More recently, exports of
Spanish wines recovered after the establishment of many good wine profes-
sionals in the North of the country, while phylloxera attacked French vines.
It was during the second half of the nineteenth century and the early twen-
tieth century when the production of quality wines started to attract atten-
tion, mainly focused in La Rioja (red wines) and Penedès (sparkling wines).
mmorag@uchile.cl
94 L. M. Albisu et al.
4.4.2 W
ine Distribution Channels in the Domestic
Market
As it was mentioned before, the wine domestic market has been shrinking
continuously during the last decades although it seems to be more stable in
recent years. This reduction has been worsened during the economic crisis
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Spanish Wine Industry 95
since 2008, which, among other effects, has strongly hit the HORECA
(HOtels, REstaurants and CAfeterias) sector (Fig. 4.7). According to official
figures—not always reliable particularly in this sector—wine consumption in
Spain in HORECA decreased by 53.4% between 2006 and 2017 (from 616
to 287 million liters) (OeMv 2018). This is linked to overall decrease of the
HORECA business during the economic crisis since 2010. However, the later
recovery from the hardest years of economic crisis shows positive change rates
for on-trade wine sales in 2016 and 2017. The decrease is also related to cul-
tural and socioeconomic changes, the rise of blood alcohol level controls, the
great diversity of wine references and a low product rotation (Castillo 2015b)
as well as due to legislation against smoking in public places.
In order to cope with this dramatic downfall, wineries have been working
to find other channels that could be a way out for their productions and that
would compensate the uninterrupted drop of domestic consumption. Some
companies started to increase sales on the off-premise channel to big distribu-
tors, which appeared as a challenging shift in their commercial development.
But a further search for other channels, especially for small and medium firms
previously relying on the HORECA sector, also responds to a strategy of
diminishing the strong dependence on big retailers and improving producers’
positioning in the food chain (PTV 2012).
Therefore, in the last recent years, there has been an increase of sales that go
through non-traditional channels of distribution, such as (1) wineries’ direct
sales, especially through wine tourism; (2) online sales and E-commerce, sup-
7.3% 8.0%
13.4% 13.2% 16.2% 13.8%
17.4% 20.6%
24.5%
31.0% 31.5% 30.6% 29.3% 29.9% 33.1%
36.5% 37.9% 39.6% 39.4%
51.7% 51.6%
48.8% 48.9%
47.4% 51.4% 32.8%
48.6% 45.1%
28.7% 26.6%
29.6% 29.7% 24.6%
34.4% 24.4%
25.7%
26.6% 27.2%
41.0%
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011* 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016e 2017e
Fig. 4.7 Spanish wine sales structure for the domestic market (%) (e = estimation).
(Source: OeMv (Spanish acronym for Spanish Observatory of Wine Markets))
mmorag@uchile.cl
96 L. M. Albisu et al.
The main drinks consumed in Spain are mineral water and soft drinks and
soda. Mineral water consumed was 52.36 liters per capita in 2013, followed
closely by soft drinks and soda with 45.90 liters per capita. However, both
have experienced opposite trends since 20085: while the consumption of min-
eral water is declining, that of soft drinks has increased. Among the alcoholic
drinks, beer is clearly preferred over wine; beer consumption reached 16.54
liters per capita in 2013 (following an upward trend), while the consumption
of wine only arrived at 9.23 liters per capita, with a clear declining trend also
for consumption at home. Table wines accounted for a higher percentage of
this reduction, while the consumption of quality wines has experienced a
slight but continuous upper trend (Fig. 4.8).
Methodological changes introduced in 2008 would explain a small break on data series.
5
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Spanish Wine Industry 97
16 15.2
14.41
14 13.31
12.87
12.16
12 11.52
11.00 10.70
10.38
10.00
10 9.88 9.61 9.47 9.45
LITRES/CAPITA
0
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013* 2014 2015 2016 YoY
june
2017
Total Wines AOC wines Non-AOC wines Sparkling wines Other wines
Fig. 4.8 Wine consumption at home in Spain (liters per capita). (Source: Own elabora-
tion from MAPAMA. Spanish Agriculture Ministry. Food Consumption Panel (MAPAMA
2018))
The structure of the supply chain determines the role of the different opera-
tors (Langreo and de Castillo 2013). Thus, there is a direct market from grapes
to wines, which account for 15–25% of total production with private firms
taking the lead; the cooperatives that have an important role on bulk wines;
and the distributors, at wholesale level, which gather wines coming from
many small and medium enterprises to sell bottled wines.
Cooperatives look for immediate benefits as they are caught with requests
from their members to achieve high prices for their grapes, whereas private
companies can have longer perspectives. It does not mean that this behavior
always happens because small- and medium-sized firms, which are the most
common types, do not have enough capital to face long-term strategic deci-
sions. Family wine firms have also their own difficulties, especially for second
and third generations, as it is difficult to meet agreements among many family
members.
mmorag@uchile.cl
98 L. M. Albisu et al.
7$0
MXQ
6XSHUPDUNHWVDQG6HOIVHUYLFHVWRUHV +\SHUPDUNHW
'LVFRXQWVWRUHV %DU7UDGLWLRQDOZLQHVKRS
,QWHUQHW &RRSHUDWLYHRUVWDIIVWRUH
7UDGLWLRQDOVWRUHV 6HOIVXSSO\
5HVW
Fig. 4.9 Place of purchase of wine for at-home consumption in Spain (%). (Source:
Own elaboration from MAGRAMA. Spanish Agriculture Ministry. Food Consumption
Panel (MAGRAMA 2015e))
Two stages can be differentiated. The first is between wine growers and wine
plants to transform grapes into wines. Nowadays, strong links exist among
farmers and their cooperatives because they have norms to compulsorily sup-
ply all the grapes they produce, which was not the case years ago. The price
settlement is open to final results, and they might get a small part a few
months after delivering the grapes. However, the final monetary compensa-
tion is arranged once the cooperative has received the full amount. This cre-
ates difficulties to farmers because the span between delivering the grapes and
getting the final compensation could last more than one season.
Unfortunately many cooperatives do not have quality specifications, or
they still have too weak requirements. This approach has negative conse-
quences because oenologists are not able to reach the quality standards they
would like to have for their wines. On the contrary, there are cooperatives that
specify many technical conditions, such as the distinction between grape vari-
eties, grape harvesting period, technical care needed along the season and all
sort of technical standards when the grapes reach the wineries.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Spanish Wine Industry 99
Retailers, like in many countries, take the leadership along the chain. Three
features reinforce their role in Spain: (1) the excess supply existing in the mar-
ket, (2) the need of many wineries to find a place on the shelves to sell their
wines and (3) the small size of most of the wineries. Specialized or gourmet
shops have a determinant role for small wineries as they are for them the most
important channel of distribution. Internet has not yet reached selling signifi-
cance, but it is the most important information channel for both the national
and foreign markets.
PDOs take the reference lead among consumers, and the diversity of brands
is compensated by the leadership that QDO Rioja and to a lesser extent PDO
Ribera del Duero have nationwide. Other PDOs are known locally or not so
widespread. Very few brands are distributed all over Spain, and some of them
do not have a great impact because it is quite common, among wine firms, not
mmorag@uchile.cl
100 L. M. Albisu et al.
to use the same brand in food shops and the HORECA channel of distribu-
tion. One of the reasons is the high markup that restaurants apply to their
wines and the contrast, on prices, consumers might have when comparing
different channels of distribution, which is a cause of continuous
misunderstanding.
Only a limited number of large wineries exert their power along the supply
chain. They mostly sell cheap wines although they are also entering into the
market of high-quality wines in different PDOs. Large cooperatives are taking
an important role because large distributors need big suppliers and coopera-
tives are able to attend their requests especially in export markets. Their trans-
formation from bulk wine sellers to bottled wine sellers has reinforced their
role in the supply chain.
4.6 Conclusions
The Spanish wine sector is characterized by its prominent position in the
world. It is the most important country in terms of land allocated to vineyard
area as well as one of the top wine producer countries, competing in the last
years with Italy for the first rank. It is also the largest wine exporter. However,
it is generally considered to have cheap wines in the market due to a big,
recent, disequilibrium between restructured and more irrigated vineyard sup-
ply and lower domestic consumption and distillations. This recent unbalance
has pushed large amounts of Spanish wines in bulk, mainly to other and more
experienced exporting countries like France, Italy, Portugal and Germany. At
the same time, stakeholders are increasingly concerned with the effect that
such unbalance may also have in the distribution of low-price bottled wines,
which may erode the image of the whole category. On top, the best wines
from the most prestigious regions occupy low- to medium-segment prices in
international markets expanding the idea of a country with a global supply of
low-price and somehow medium-quality wines. However, large investments
in reinforced distribution capacity and the expansion of the number of export-
ing firms, jointly with better knowledge of international markets, may improve
the value of Spanish wine exports.
There are vineyards in many regions, but Castilla-La Mancha gathers close
to 50% of the total area. It is distinguished by having more than 130 quality
geographic indications differentiated by its origin, either PDO or PGI, and
the PDO Rioja stands well above the rest, but there are several of them who
have increased their quality in the last decade and are making great efforts to
reach better positions on international markets.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Spanish Wine Industry 101
Water scarcity is one of the main determinants of traditional low and vola-
tile yields which, in turn, generate a lack of homogeneous quality, reducing
the competitiveness of the Spanish wines in international markets. To com-
pensate for this shortcoming, some wine trade flows among regions have usu-
ally taken place, lowering prices significantly. The recent restructuration of
around 300,000 hectares of new plantations (partially financed by the
Common Agricultural Policy) has allowed increasing yields generating posi-
tive expectations of production increases during the next decade which have
already been noticeable in the last years.
Grapes are cultivated in small holdings. To compensate the low competi-
tiveness of the small size of vineyards, the strategies have been focused on
creating large cooperatives or producing high-price wines. There are two
grapes widespread over the country, which distinguish their wines: Airen for
basic white wines and Tempranillo for red wines. However, there are many
other local varieties not fully exploited to sell wines in international markets
and, so far, only known in local markets.
Despite the fact that the average winery size is also small, their degree of
internationalization has increased sharply in recent years due to demand limi-
tations in the Spanish market. The proliferation of brands characterizes the
Spanish market, and there are few brands with a real national impact. The
largest wineries are not ranked among the top in the world. Private wineries
have put more emphasis on bottled wines than cooperatives although some of
the latter have placed their brands in the most competitive markets all over
the world.
One of the most intriguing questions is why wine consumption has been
so low in Spain and how to stop the downward trend. Young people do not
consider it a fashionable drink, and beer is more popular. Women have not
been incorporated as new consumers, and many efforts should be made to
create new products and images. Due to several reasons, consumption at
hotels and restaurants, at least until mid-2015, was suffering more than con-
sumption at home. This creates constant market tensions, as supply is con-
tinuously increasing, forcing wineries to make efforts to export their wines.
However, Spanish wines are poorly positioned in international markets in
terms of both price and image. There is a real need to significantly increase
investments to reverse this global situation. The good news, though, is that
such investments have been made in recent years and may have consequences
in the short run.
It is possible to find all sorts of wines, but red wines are prevalent over the
rest for bottled wines although the vineyard area for whites is larger. Cavas or
sparkling wines have particular significance for their penetration in interna-
mmorag@uchile.cl
102 L. M. Albisu et al.
References
Albisu, L.M., and G. Zeballos. 2014. Consumo de vino en España: tendencias y
comportamiento del consumidor. In La economía del vino en España y en el mundo,
ed. J.S. Castillo and R. Compés, 99–140. Spain: Cajamar Caja Rural.
Castillo, M. 2015a. Vino: Buscando atraer a un consumidor global. Alimarket. November
20. http://www.alimarket.es/noticia/196298/Vinos%2D%2DBuscando-atraer-a-
un-consumidor-global. Accessed 20 Nov 15.
———. 2015b. Lineal de vinos: El consumidor pide calidad. Alimarket. March 26.
http://www.alimarket.es/noticia/179033/Lineal-de-vinos%2D%2DEl-
consumidor-pide-calidad. Accessed 22 Sept 15.
Compés, R., C. Montoro, and K. Simón. 2014. Internacionalización, competitivi-
dad, diferenciación y estrategias de calidad. In La economía del vino en España y en
el mundo, ed. J.S. Castillo and R. Compés, 311–350. Spain: Cajamar Caja Rural.
De la Serna, V. 2013. El desafío de Castilla La Mancha. El Mundo Vino, October 28.
Del Rey, R. 2015. Oral communications of the OeMv. Observatorio Español del
Mercado del Vino.
FADN. 2018. Farm Accounting Data Network. European Commission.
Fernández, E., and V. Pinilla. 2014. Historia económica del vino en España
(1850–2000). In La economía del vino en España y en el mundo, ed. J.S. Castillo
and R. Compés, 67–98. Spain: Cajamar Caja Rural.
INE. 2009. Spanish National Statistics Institute. Spanish Agricultural Census.
———. 2013. Spanish National Statistics Institute. Farm Structure Survey.
———. 2015. Directorio Central de Empresas: explotación estadística (DIRCE).
http://www.ine.es/jaxi/menu.do?type=pcaxis&path=/t37/p201/&file=inebase.
Accessed 21 Sept 15.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Spanish Wine Industry 103
mmorag@uchile.cl
5
The US Wine Industry
James T. Lapsley, Julian M. Alston, and Olena Sambucci
5.1 Introduction
Among countries, the United States is the world’s fourth largest producer of
wine and the largest consumer and importer (Wine Institute 2015a, b; ITC
2017). Consequently, the structure of the US wine industry is of interest, not
The work for this project was partly supported by the University of California Agricultural Issues
Center and the National Institute of Food and Agriculture, US Department of Agriculture, under
award number 2011-51181-30635 (the VitisGen project). The authors are grateful for this support and
for excellent research assistance provided by Jarrett Hart. Views expressed are the authors’ alone.
J. T. Lapsley (*)
Department of Viticulture & Enology, University of California, Davis, Davis, CA, USA
University of California Agricultural Issues Center, Davis, CA, USA
J. M. Alston
Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California,
Davis, Davis, CA, USA
Robert Mondavi Institute Center for Wine Economics, University of California,
Davis, Davis, CA, USA
Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics, Berkeley, CA, USA
e-mail: julian@primal.ucdavis.edu
O. Sambucci
Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California,
Davis, Davis, CA, USA
e-mail: sloan@primal.ucdavis.edu
mmorag@uchile.cl
106 J. T. Lapsley et al.
just to Americans but also to wine producers and consumers in many other
countries. This chapter describes the salient features of this fascinating indus-
try throughout the marketing chain from the vineyard through to the final
consumer from an economics perspective and, where possible, in quantitative
terms.
The first main section (Sect. 5.2) describes the winegrape-producing indus-
try—which is predominantly located in California and two other West Coast
states, Washington and Oregon—in terms of the total number and size distri-
bution of firms, patterns of prices, and production. This section draws heavily
on Alston et al. (2015, 2018a, b). Winegrape production is somewhat vertically
integrated with winemaking, but many firms specialize at least to some extent
in either grape production or wine production, as we document. Section 5.3
documents details of US wine production and consumption, including the sig-
nificant roles of exports and imports. The winemaking industry is mostly located
close to where the grapes are grown, although each of the 50 states claims a wine
industry. Details are provided on the total production and the mixture of sizes
and types of firms. Next, Sect. 5.4 describes the unique US wine distribution
system, from the producer (winery) through to the final consumer, created by
the hodgepodge of laws and regulations governing the market as an aftermath
of national Prohibition (1920–1933). Section 5.5 concludes the chapter.
5.2 Winegrapes
In 2016, the United States produced 4.4 million tons of grapes crushed for
wine, with a farm value of $4.1 billion (Table 5.1), and it has accounted for
about 10% of the world’s wine volume in recent years (e.g., Wine Institute
2015a). Of the US total winegrape area of some 250,000 hectares in 2016, four
states accounted for over 94%: California (CA), 80.3%; Washington (WA),
8.6%; Oregon (OR), 3.8%; New York (NY), 1.9%.1 Of these, only New York
is not on the West Coast. The total value of all US farm production in 2016 was
$357 billion from a total of 370.1 million hectares, including $194 billion
worth of crops produced using 157.7 million hectares of cropland (USDA/ERS
2018; USDA/NASS 2012b). Hence, the wine industry contributed 1.1% of
the total value of farm production value (2.1% of crop value), but it did so using
only 0.07% of all land in agriculture (or 0.15% of cropland). Winegrapes are
more important in California, accounting for 8.9% of the value of farm produc-
tion and 2.3% of all land in agriculture (or 6.3% of cropland).
1
Areas of vines and cropland for 2016 in this paragraph are estimated based on areas in 2012, the most
recent census for which data are available at the time of writing.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The US Wine Industry 107
California differs from the other major producing states, and itself contains
several distinct wine production regions that differ in terms of their terrain,
climate, soil types, mixture of varieties grown, and quality of grapes and wines
mmorag@uchile.cl
108 J. T. Lapsley et al.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The US Wine Industry 109
Area by Region
NY
OR
WA SCV
Other
NCV
CC
NS
Volume by Region
NY
Other OR
WA
NS SCV
CC
NCV
WA NS
SCV
CC NCV
Fig. 5.1 US wine regions—area, volume, and value of production, 2016. (Source:
Created by the authors using data from USDA/NASS 2016a, 2016b, 2017, 2018)
mmorag@uchile.cl
110 J. T. Lapsley et al.
Equivalent data are not available for every state, but some detailed data on the
size distribution and nature of grape-producing firms are available for
California, which accounts for four-fifths of US winegrape production
mmorag@uchile.cl
The US Wine Industry 111
Table 5.2 California: total grape area and number of grape-producing farms, 2012
Total grape area
Geographic area Farms Acres Acres/farm
Napa-Sonoma 3148 113,128 35.9
Central Coast 1286 131,448 102.2
Southern Central Valley 3141 463,380 147.5
Northern Central Valley 1489 176,826 118.8
Other CA 2398 54,819 22.9
California State Total 11,462 940,177 82.0
Source: Table 2 in Alston et al. (2018a). Created by the authors using data from USDA/
NASS (2012a)
(Table 5.2). In 2012, California had 11,462 farms that grew grapes. The total
area (including nonbearing vines) was 940,177 acres planted to grapes, an
average of 82 acres per farm. These statewide average figures mask some varia-
tion among regions, and they also include grapes intended for grape juice,
table grapes, and (dried) raisin production—all in the Southern Central
Valley. Of the total of 463,380 acres of vines in the Southern Central Valley,
an estimated 128,449 acres would have been devoted to wine production.2 In
the Central Valley—with its higher yields and lower prices per ton—wine-
grape production generally is conducted at a larger scale compared with the
Coastal regions, especially Napa-Sonoma, with an average of 36 acres of wine-
grapes per producer. Not surprisingly, growers in California’s Central Valley
have mechanized, adopting mechanical pruning and harvesting at a higher
rate than coastal growers, who generally continue to rely on hand labor for
many operations. Over 80% of California’s winegrapes are harvested by
machine. Machine pruning is less widely adopted (Dokoozlian 2013).
Table 5.3 contains more information on the size distribution of grape pro-
ducers in terms of area planted to grapes—again, including all end uses of
grapes, not just wine. As is typical of farm-size distributions, this distribution
is heavily skewed to the right. The vast majority of grape producers have rela-
tively small vineyards and, while the average area is 80 acres of vines, the
median is closer to 15 acres. Reflecting this skewedness, the roughly 50% of
growers who had less than 15 acres of vines collectively accounted for less than
2% of the total vineyard area, while the 89 (less than 1%) growers who had
1500 acres or more were responsible for almost 30% of the total area. More
than half the total vineyard area is on farms with 500 or more acres of vine-
2
The percentage of winegrape acreage for the Southern Central Valley region in 2012 was estimated using
the California acreage report (USDA/NASS 2012d) and applied to the total acreage for 2012 from Table 2
in Alston et al. (2018a).
mmorag@uchile.cl
112 J. T. Lapsley et al.
yard. Of course, and as noted above, these distributional figures for the state-
wide industry as a whole will not be equally representative of all segments. In
particular very large vineyards are much more likely to be found in the Central
Valley than in the premium coastal valleys where land values are very much
higher.
California includes a diverse mixture of production models. A vineyard
may be vertically integrated with a winery, in a single enterprise, or the two
enterprises may be entirely separate. In some cases a winery may crush and
bottle only estate-grown fruit while, next door, a vineyard sells all its produc-
tion to a winery somewhere else. Because grape growing and wine production
are often separate businesses in California, most wineries contract with grape
growers. Goodhue et al. (2003) reported that 90% of California growers sold
grapes under contract and that 10% of contracts were pre-planting contracts
in which the winery contracted to purchase grapes from a not-yet-established
vineyard. Production models vary from region to region within California,
and Table 5.4 provides details, district by district, of the balance between pur-
chased, custom crush, and own tons crushed by wineries. For the state as a
whole, only 15% of tons crushed were own-grown, the vast majority were
purchased. This pattern was even more pronounced in the Southern Central
Valley where only 5% of the crush was own fruit. In the premium coastal
regions, the share of own-grown fruit was closer to 40% of the total crush.
Some wineries may have a cellar door from which they sell at retail whereas
others may leave the retailing to others. Reflecting this diversity, California has
mmorag@uchile.cl
The US Wine Industry 113
mmorag@uchile.cl
114 J. T. Lapsley et al.
sumption. Both trends are expected to continue and the volume of US wine
consumption is predicted to increase by 50% by 2030 from a 2010 base
(Lapsley 2010). US growth trends stand in marked contrast to declines in
volume of wine consumed in France, Italy, and Spain (OIV 2015). It is no
surprise that many suppliers, both domestic and foreign, are focused on the
US market.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The US Wine Industry 115
$3.30 per gallon, and naturally carbonated, which is taxed between $2.40 and
$3.40 per gallon (U.S. Treasury/TTB 2016a) depending upon volume pro-
duced. These tax rates are for calendar years 2018 and 2019 and may change
depending upon Congressional action (or inaction).
The TTB figures for production of still wines include wines made from
fruits other than Vitis vinifera and from non-vinifera grapes. “Wine” pro-
duced from apples is called “hard cider” and is taxed between $0.164 and
$0.226 cents per gallon depending upon the volume produced. Hard cider is
listed separately from other still wines in TTB reports, but non-vinifera wine
is not reported separately. Although we have no way of knowing the exact
volume of non-vinifera wines, we do know that wines produced in California
are made from Vitis vinifera and represent about 85% of all wine produced in
the United States.
Still wine accounts for the vast majority of domestically produced and bulk
imported wine that is bottled and consumed in the United States, although
smaller volumes of other types of wine are produced, and about 10–11% of
production is used for distillation. According to 2016 TTB data, over 604
million gallons of still wine were bottled and removed after payment of tax for
domestic consumption. This represented 82.6% of the approximately 708
million gallons of domestically bottled wine.3 Cider accounted for 6.5% of
total volume, effervescent wine was 3.9%, flavored wines, such as vermouth,
and wine coolers totaled 3.4% and 3.5%, respectively (Fig. 5.2).
In the past decade, the volume of domestically bottled wine (including
cider) tax-paid into the US market has increased by almost one-third, from
just over 527 million gallons in 2005 to over 700 million gallons in 2016.
Cider consumption increased more than eightfold, growing from 4.8 million
gallons to 47.5 million gallons. Still wine grew by almost one-third during the
same period, while wine cooler volume declined. Table 5.5 shows volumes by
type of wine removed tax-paid in 2005 and 2016, and the percentage change.
We assume tax-paid bottled wine is intended for the US market because
exported wine does not pay Federal tax.
The vast majority of wine produced in the United States is produced in
California. In 2016, the TTB reports approximately 806.4 million gallons
of still wine produced in the United States, with California responsible for
680.3 million gallons, or 84.3%. New York State, with 27.9 million gal-
lons, and Washington State, with 40.7 million gallons, are second and third
The term “removed” here refers to removal of the product from a bonded warehouse, as it enters com-
3
mmorag@uchile.cl
116 J. T. Lapsley et al.
3.4% 3.5%
3.9%
6.5%
Still wine
Cider
Effervescent
Flavored Wines
Wine Coolers
82.6%
Fig. 5.2 Volume shares (%) of tax-paid, domestically bottled wine, by wine type, 2016.
(Source: Created by the authors using data from US Treasury/TTB 2016c)
Table 5.5 Gallons of bottled wine removed tax paid into US market
2005 2016 Percentage change
Wine type Millions of gallons Percent
Still wine 457.2 604.2 32.2
Cider 4.9 47.5 867.3
Effervescent 19.4 28.6 47.4
Flavored wines 15.8 25.0 58.2
Wine coolers 30.3 25.8 −14.9
Total taxable removals 527.6 731.0 38.6
Source: Table 7 in Alston et al. (2018a). Data are from Treasury/TTB (2005, 2016c).
Percentage calculations by authors
mmorag@uchile.cl
The US Wine Industry 117
Although over 10,000 wineries are operating in the United States, a hand-
ful of large wineries dominate production and distribution of wine. Over the
past 20 years, the largest US wine producers have become marketers of wine
as well as producers, importing bulk wine to be bottled under their own
brands, and importing and distributing bottled wines from foreign producers.
It is estimated by industry analysts that in 2014, the three largest US wine
producers, E & J Gallo, The Wine Group, and Constellation Brands, together
produced or imported approximately half of all wine sold in the United States.
The top ten producers accounted for over 80% of US sales, and the top 30 are
estimated to be responsible for approximately 710 million gallons of the 769
million gallons of wine consumed in 2014, or 92% of sales (Wine Business
Monthly 2015; Wine Institute 2018), leaving 59 million gallons to be sup-
plied by the remaining smaller firms. These indicative figures impart a sense
of the concentration within the US industry.
Since the TTB does not release production data at the firm level, it is not
possible to report precise figures of production volume by wineries. However,
given that there were more than 10,000 wine producers in 2014 and having
estimated that US total wine consumption, after subtracting sales by the top
30 wine firms, was approximately 59 million gallons (which includes imported
bottled wine not sold by the largest firms), it follows that the typical US win-
ery is very small, perhaps producing 5000 gallons of wine. This conclusion is
reinforced by an examination of wine production by region within California.
Using TTB data of California wine producer and blender permit holders at
the end of 2015, we sorted wineries by production region. Then, for each
region, we computed its share of California’s total grape tonnage in 2016 and
its share of the total number of California wineries in 2015. Results are shown
in Table 5.6.
As noted in Sect. 5.2, California’s Northern and Southern Central Valley
vineyards (crush districts 9, 11, 12, 13, 14, and 17) produce approximately
70% of California’s winegrapes. However, this productive grape-growing
region has only 9% of California’s wineries. Central Valley wineries are quite
large and efficient, processing almost 3 million tons of grapes in 2016 and
producing inexpensive wine retailing at under $8 per bottle, which accounts
for a large share of all table wine sales. More than 70% of California’s wineries
are located in coastal areas (crush districts 1–8); yet, collectively, these areas
produced just 26% of all California winegrapes in 2016. For the most part,
these coastal wineries, along with wineries in California’s Sierra Nevada foot-
hills, are quite small, each producing small quantities of more expensive wines.
Wines consumed in the United States retail at a variety of prices and labels
often bear information on varietal content as well as where the grapes used to
mmorag@uchile.cl
118 J. T. Lapsley et al.
Table 5.6 Share of all California wineries (2015) and tons crushed (2016) by region
Number of Share of tons Share of
Crush Volume licenses crushed licenses
Region district (tons) (number) (percentage) (percentage)
Napa-Sonoma 3 226,442 785 5.6 20.3
(NS) 4 153,045 959 3.8 24.7
Total 379,487 1744 9.4 45.0
Central Coast 7 268,688 106 6.7 2.7
(CC) 8 224,584 719 5.6 18.6
Total 493,272 825 12.2 21.3
S. Central Valley 14 283,335 16 7.0 0.4
(SCV) 13 1,265,648 52 31.4 1.3
Total 1,548,983 68 38.4 1.7
N. Central Valley 9 62,690 112 1.6 2.9
(NCV) 11 802,122 141 19.9 3.6
12 372,947 14 9.3 0.4
17 168,592 17 4.2 0.4
Total 1,406,351 284 34.9 7.3
Other California 10 21,467 255 0.5 6.6
(OC) 15 425 39 0.0 1.0
16 4839 224 0.1 5.8
1 77,951 115 1.9 3.0
2 46,528 49 1.2 1.3
5 21,281 24 0.5 0.6
6 30,565 248 0.8 6.4
Total 203,056 954 5.0 24.7
California (CA) 4,031,149 3875 100.0 100.0
Source: Data from USDA/NASS (2016a), US Treasury/TTB (2015). Percentage
calculations by authors
produce the wine were grown. Price and varietal information is generally
derived from UPC (bar code) labels that are scanned by retailers, who then
sell their data to consumer research firms such as IRI or Nielsen, which then
collate and clean the data for resale to producers and others. Scanner data
represent perhaps 50% of US wine sales by volume and do not include infor-
mation from major retailers such as Costco or Walmart, or from restaurants
and bars, which retail approximately 25% of all alcoholic beverages by v olume.
Although scanner data do not represent the entire universe of wine sales in
the United States, they do provide information on the US marketplace for
wine. In 2014, according to Nielsen data, 70% of all table wine tracked by
Nielsen, both domestically produced and imported, sold for under $8 per
bottle, while approximately 4.7% retailed at above $15 per bottle (Penn
2015). These numbers differ somewhat from those supplied by industry ana-
lyst, Jon Fredrikson, who focuses on California wine sold in the United States.
Fredrikson (pers. comm. 2016) estimates that in 2015, 52% of California
mmorag@uchile.cl
The US Wine Industry 119
wine retailed for under $7 and that 15% retailed at above $14 per bottle. The
discrepancies are probably the result of comparing different years, different
data sources, and the inclusion of imported wine in the Nielsen data.
Wines sold in the United States may bear a varietal designation on the label
if 75% or more of the wine was produced from the named grape variety.
Nielsen data for table wine sales for the 52 weeks ending in October 2015
show that approximately 85% by value carried a varietal label. Chardonnay, at
19%, and Cabernet Sauvignon, at 16%, were the two most popular varieties,
followed by Pinot Grigio, Pinot noir, Merlot, and Sauvignon blanc, which
collectively accounted for 28% of the value of table wine sold in the United
States. In 2015, red wine represented just over 50% of Nielsen tracked wine
sales by value, followed by white wines at 43% of value, and rose or blush
wines at 6% (Wine Business Monthly 2016).
The United States consumes more wine than it produces, but even though a
net importer, the country exports significant quantities of wine: For the past
decade approximately 100 million gallons each year, a bit over 10% of its total
production in 2016, if distilling material is included. Hence, the United
States is a major importer of wine, and for the past decade, approximately
one-third of all wine consumed in the United States has been imported.
Figure 5.3 shows the volumes and values of imported and exported wine of all
types by year.
The share of imported wine in total consumption has increased slightly
over the past decade, but the increase in import volume has been primarily in
inexpensive bulk wine, rather than in bottled wine. In 2005, US wineries
imported 10.3 million gallons of wine in containers larger than 4 liters, a
volume that represented approximately 6% of all imported wine. By 2016
bulk wine imports had grown to 70.5 million gallons, accounting for almost
25% of all imported wine volume. During the same period, bottled wine
imports increased by 31%, from 176 million gallons in 2005 to 240 million
gallons in 2016 (ITC 2017).
The growth in volume of imported bulk wine has become an issue for
winegrape growers in California’s southern Central Valley. Their concern has
centered on a trade policy referred to as “drawback,” which allows an importer
to recapture up to 99% of taxes paid on imported goods when goods defined
as “interchangeable” are exported. In 2003, the US Bureau of Customs and
Border Protection allowed drawback on imported wine for the first time and
mmorag@uchile.cl
120 J. T. Lapsley et al.
350 6
300
5
200
3
150
2
100
1
50
0 0
Fig. 5.3 Volume and value of US imports and exports of wine, 1966–2015. (Source:
Fig. 5 in Alston et al. (2018a). Data are from ITC (2018). Notes: Nominal monetary val-
ues in these graphs were deflated by the consumer price index (CPI) for all goods taken
from USDL/BLS 2015)
mmorag@uchile.cl
The US Wine Industry 121
gallons in 2016. Most of this is bottled wine at an average price of over $27
per gallon (ITC 2017). Although volume and value of wine exported have
increased in the past ten years, it seems that most US producers are focused
more on the expanding domestic market than on export opportunities.
5.4 Distribution
In 2018, the United States was the largest national wine market in the world
in value and in volume. Yet, despite its name, as a market the United States is
hardly “united” and from a wine marketing perspective is better considered as
51 different entities consisting of 50 states and the Federal District of
Columbia. As a legacy of the American experiment with Prohibition from
1920 to 1933, each state has the constitutional power to regulate the produc-
tion, importation, and sales of alcoholic beverages within its borders. This has
resulted in significantly different systems of distribution and sales from state
to state. For instance, in Utah, the State acts as the sole importer and retailer
of alcoholic beverages. In contrast, other states license private importers,
wholesalers, and retailers to distribute and make retail sales.
Other differences among states abound. Some states, such as New York, do
not allow sales of alcoholic beverages in stores that sell foods. Other states,
such as Oregon, allow private licensed distribution of beer and wine but act as
distributors of distilled beverages sold in the state. Some states, such as Ohio,
require that suppliers post wholesale prices with the state prior to selling to an
Ohio distributor. This price posting, along with mandated markups for dis-
tributors and retailers, results in no discounting or price competition among
retail stores. Other states, such as Colorado, allow only one license per busi-
ness entity, which precludes chain retailing of alcoholic beverages. Because of
these differences among states, wine suppliers, whether domestic producers or
importers, must treat each state as a separate sales environment. For this
reason, a uniform system of wine marketing and distribution across the
United States is essentially impossible for wine producers and importers.
National Prohibition, which prohibited the commercial production, distri-
bution, and sale of alcoholic beverages, was enacted by Congress in 1917 as
the 18th Amendment to the US Constitution. As with all Constitutional
amendments, after approval by two-thirds of Congress, it required ratification
by three-quarters of the states. The 18th Amendment was ratified in January
1919, and Prohibition became effective a year later, on January 16, 1920 (Seff
and Cooney 1984). By the late 1920s, many observers believed that national
Prohibition was a failure, having led to illegal alcohol sales and the rise of
mmorag@uchile.cl
122 J. T. Lapsley et al.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The US Wine Industry 123
consumers. However the general case is that, in most states, out-of-state wine
suppliers (either domestic producers or importers of foreign wines) must
acquire licenses from the state ABC and then must sell to in-state wholesalers
licensed by the state ABC. These wholesalers pay state excise taxes for wine
imported into the state and maintain inventory for sale to state licensed retail-
ers. Licensed retailers then sell to consumers. This system is referred to as the
“three-tier” system, with the first tier being the supplier, the second tier being
the wholesaler, and the third tier being the retailer.
The three-tier system places at least two business entities between a supplier
and the end consumer. The system also requires that, in most instances, sup-
pliers must have a business relationship with at least one wholesaler in every
state in which the supplier desires to sell wine. A cursory examination of the
listing of wholesalers at the TTB web site (U.S. Treasury/TTB 2015) shows
over 19,000 licensed wholesalers across the 50 states. But this number is quite
misleading, as each wholesale location requires a separate license, and the
19,000 licensees are not distinct firms. Most wholesalers are quite small busi-
nesses that serve a limited geographic area within a state, but in every state
and nationally, distribution of alcoholic beverages is dominated by a handful
of large wholesalers.
Industry analysts indicate that in 2017 the four largest wholesalers of alco-
holic beverages accounted for approximately 55% of all wholesale sales (Wines
and Vines 2017). Wholesaler consolidation is an ongoing trend that will
probably continue because distribution of alcoholic beverages exhibits econo-
mies of scale. Table 5.7 lists the top four wholesalers in the United States, all
of which are multibillion dollar companies and all the result of recent merg-
ers. The top wholesaler, Southern Glazers, was created in 2016 when Southern,
the largest distributor, merged with Glazers, then the fourth largest. Breakthru
Beverage had been created a year earlier when Wirtz Beverage merged with
New York-based Chalmers Sunbelt. Republic National Distributing Company
was the result of a 2007 merger of Republic Beverage Company and National
Distributing Company. Most recently in November 2017, the numbers 2 and
3 wholesalers, Republic National and Breakthru Beverage, announced their
intention to merge operations in 2018 (Marsteller 2017) although as of this
writing, the merger has not yet occurred.
When a domestic wine producer or importer has distribution with a com-
pany such as Southern Glazers or Republic National Distributing Company, the
supplier can be assured of geographic reach for its products. However, the
supplier will also be one of hundreds, perhaps thousands, of suppliers, each
vying for attention from the large distributor. In a national sales environment
with over 9000 domestic producers, the reality is that most individual suppli-
mmorag@uchile.cl
124 J. T. Lapsley et al.
ers are not in a position to choose a distributor in a given market. Rather, the
distributor chooses the supplier. Without a licensed distributor, it is difficult
for a supplier to sell more than a few cases of wine in a given market.
Because of the inherent difficulty in securing distribution in every state,
some suppliers might decide to focus on one or two states or metropolitan
markets rather than to pursue national distribution. States differ greatly in
total population as well as rates of per capita consumption; hence the volume
of wine consumed varies tremendously from state to state. Table 5.8 lists the
top ten wine-consuming states in 2016, showing each state’s wine consump-
tion in thousands of gallons and as a share of total US wine consumption. In
2016, the top five wine-consuming states consumed 42% of all wine con-
sumed, and the top ten states almost 60% of all wine sold in the United
States. Collectively, in 2016 these top ten states consumed 526 million gal-
lons, which, if they were a country, would put them in fifth place, behind
Germany and ahead of the United Kingdom (Wine Institute 2015b). Clearly,
a wine supplier does not need to pursue national distribution in order to sell
significant volumes of wine in the United States. But it is equally true that
most suppliers focus on states with high volumes of wine consumption, mak-
ing those markets quite competitive.
State laws also affect where wine is sold, making it less meaningful to speak
of national trends. In those states where wine can be discounted and can be
sold in chain grocery stores, large retailers such as Costco and Walmart have
gained market share. These retailers use their purchasing power to negotiate
lower purchase prices, and this, combined with efficient store management
and scale, which allow lower operating margins, enables them to offer lower
prices to consumers. But some state sales environments are not conducive to
large chain retailers. The states of New York and New Jersey, the third and
fourth largest wine markets by volume in the United States, do not allow wine
to be sold in grocery stores. Retailers in these states must choose between sell-
mmorag@uchile.cl
The US Wine Industry 125
ing groceries and selling alcoholic beverages. Some states, such as Ohio, do
not allow distributors to offer price discounts to retailers based on volume
purchases, thus negating the purchasing power inherent in chain retailing, at
least for alcoholic beverages. Other states, such as Colorado and Massachusetts,
limit the number of retail locations per license holder, thus reducing the
potential for chain retail sales.
The reduction of costs in supply chains has been a major force in business
modernization for at least two decades. However, the current alcoholic bever-
age supply chain in the United States is entrenched in state law and efforts to
bypass the three-tier system have met with little success, although there have
been some changes. In 2005, the US Supreme Court reviewed Michigan and
New York laws that allowed in-state wineries to make direct shipments to in-
state consumers, but disallowed that privilege to out-of-state wineries. In a 5
to 4 decision in Granholm v. Heald, the Court found that states could not
discriminate between in- and out-of-state producers, thus opening the door
for direct shipments from winery to consumer (Mendelson 2009).
Although this decision has legalized the possibility of direct shipments to
many states, the reality is that states can legally require registration fees, pay-
ment of excise taxes, and reporting requirements that, while in aggregate are
reasonable expenses for in-state wineries with significant volumes of direct
sales, become prohibitively expensive for an out-of-state winery that is ship-
ping only a few cases per month to a particular state. Shipping costs for a few
cases are also significantly higher than for truckloads of wine. Although direct
shipping of wine and the bypassing of the three-tier system may widen the
range of consumer choice, direct shipping still represents a very small percent-
age of wine sales in the United States. In 2014, nine years after the Granholm
mmorag@uchile.cl
126 J. T. Lapsley et al.
5.5 Conclusion
This chapter has reviewed winegrape growing and wine production, distribu-
tion, and consumption in the United States. The industry is concentrated in
the western United States, dominated by California, which produces four-
fifths of the total. Nationally, winegrape growing is relatively unimportant
when compared with commodities such as corn or soybeans, and winegrapes
are best understood as a high-value specialty crop, whose high prices are
driven by an increasing demand for wine on the part of American consumers.
This increased demand has been met by expansion of vineyard acreage across
the United States, by increased importation of bulk and bottled wine, and by
a doubling of the number of US wineries over the past decade. Although the
experiment with Prohibition has left a legacy of patchwork laws throughout
the nation, making wine distribution cumbersome and costly, increased
consumer demand for wines of all types is forcing changes in distribution.
These changes, coupled with increased rates of per capita consumption and
population growth, should insure that the United States remains the world’s
major wine-consuming country for the first half of the twenty-first century.
References
Alston, J.M., K. Anderson, and O. Sambucci. 2015. Drifting towards Bordeaux? The
evolving varietal emphasis of U.S. Wine regions. Journal of Wine Economics 10 (3):
349–378.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The US Wine Industry 127
Alston, J.M., J.T. Lapsley, and O. Sambucci. 2018a. Grape and wine production in
California. In California agriculture: Dimensions and issues (in process), ed.
R. Goodhue, P. Martin, and B. Wright. Berkeley: Giannin Foundation of
Agricultural Economics.
Alston, J.M., J.T. Lapsley, O. Sambucci, and D.A. Sumner. 2018b. United States. In
Wine’s evolving globalization: Comparative histories of the old and new world, ed.
K. Anderson and V. Pinilla, 410–440. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Dokoozlian, N. 2013. The evolution of mechanized vineyard production systems in
California. Acta Horticultura 978: 265–278.
Goodhue, R.E., D.M. Heien, H. Lee, and D.A. Sumner. 2003. Contracts and qual-
ity in the California winegrape industry. Review of Industrial Organization 23 (3):
267–282.
Gordon, J. 2015. DtC Wine Shipments Grow 15% in 2014. Wines and Vines,
January 15. Available from: http://www.winesandvines.com/template.cfm?section
=news&content=144614. Accessed 16 Dec 2015.
Haughwout, S., M. Slater, and I. Castle. 2018. Apparent per capita alcohol consump-
tion: National, state, and regional trends, 1977–2016. National Institute on Alcohol
Abuse and Alcoholism. Surveillance report #110. Available from: https://pubs.
niaaa.nih.gov/publications/surveillance104/CONS14.htm. Accessed 24 May
2018.
International Organization of Vine and Wine (OIV). 2015. World vitiviniculture
situation. Available from: http://www.oiv.int/oiv/info/enpublicationsstatistiques.
Accessed 16 Dec 2015.
Lapsley, J.T. 2010. Looking forward: Imagining the market for California wine in
2030. Agricultural and Resource Economics Update 13 (6): 12–15.
Marsteller, D. 2017. SND: Republic and Breakthru Join Forces. The Wine Spectator,
November 20. Available from http://www.winespectator.com/webfeature/show/
id/Republic-and-Breakthru-Join-Forces. Accessed 5 April 2018.
Mendelson, R. 2009. From demon to darling: A legal history of wine in America.
Berkeley: University of California Press.
Penn, C. 2015. Industry outlook and trends. Wine Business Monthly. February.
Seff, J., and J. Cooney. 1984. The legal and political history of California wine. In The
University of California/Sotheby Book of California Wine, ed. D. Muscatine,
A. Maynard, and B. Thompson, 412–446. Berkeley: University of California
Press.
Sumner, D.A., J.T. Lapsley, and J.T. Rosen-Molina. 2012. Economics of wine import
duty and excise tax drawbacks. Agricultural and Resource Economics Update 15 (4):
1–4.
United States Department of The Treasury/Alcohol and Tobacco Tax and Trade
Bureau (U.S. Treasury/TTB). 2005. Monthly statistical report–wine, January
2005–December 2005. Available from: http://www.ttb.gov/statistics/05winestats.
shtml. Accessed 17 Dec 2015.
mmorag@uchile.cl
128 J. T. Lapsley et al.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The US Wine Industry 129
———. 2017. Noncitrus fruits and nuts. 2016 Summary. Available from: http://usda.
mannlib.cornell.edu/usda/current/NoncFruiNu/NoncFruiNu-06-27-2017.pdf.
Accessed 20 May 2018.
———. 2018. Statistics by state. Available at: https://quickstats.nass.usda.gov/.
Accessed 22 May 2018.
United States Department of Labor/Bureau of Labor Statistics (USDL/BLS). 2015.
Consumer price index detailed report. December. Available at: http://www.bls.gov/
cpi/cpid1512.pdf. Accessed 15 Oct 2016.
Wine Business Monthly. 2015. WBM 30 list. Wine Business Monthly, February.
———. 2016. Retail sales analysis. Wine Business Monthly, January.
Wine Institute. 2015a. World wine production by country. Available from: http://
www.wineinstitute.org/files/World_Wine_Production_by_Country_2015.pdf.
Accessed 20 May 2018.
———. 2015b. World wine consumption by country. Available from: http://www.win-
einstitute.org/files/World_Wine_Consumption_by_Country_2015.pdf.
Accessed 18 Feb 2016.
———. 2018. Wine consumption in the U.S. Available from: http://www.wineinsti-
tute.org/resources/statistics/article86. Accessed 24 May 2018.
Wines and Vines. 2017. Top U.S. Wine Distributors. Wines and Vines, September.
Available from https://www.winesandvines.com/features/article/189047/Top%20
10%20U.S.%20Wine%20Distributors. Accessed 5 Apr 2018.
mmorag@uchile.cl
6
The Australian Wine Industry
Kym Anderson
6.1 Introduction
Vines were planted in Australia as soon as Europeans first settled in 1788, but
for the next 50 years they were used to produce table grapes and wine mostly
for family, friends, and neighbors. During that time rum and other spirits,
plus beer, were the dominant alcoholic beverages. Commercial wine produc-
tion only began in the 1840s, but it accelerated when a gold rush led to the
trebling of Australia’s non-aboriginal population in the 1850s.
Despite having favorable wine-growing conditions, Australian wine exports
were insignificant before the mid-1860s, net export status was not achieved
until the 1890s and it took until the 1970s before annual per capita domestic
consumption of wine exceeded 10 liters. Even that represented only one-fifth
of national alcohol consumption; and barely 2% of Australia’s wine produc-
tion was being exported in the 1970s and early 1980s. The country’s index of
revealed comparative advantage (the share of wine in the value of Australia’s
exports of all goods divided by wine’s share of global merchandise exports)
was always below 1 before 1990, but by 2005 it reached 11 (when it was
K. Anderson (*)
Wine Economics Research Centre, University of Adelaide, Adelaide, SA, Australia
Crawford School of Public Policy, Australian National University,
Canberra, ACT, Australia
e-mail: kym.anderson@adelaide.edu.au
mmorag@uchile.cl
132 K. Anderson
exceeded only by Moldova and Georgia) before falling to less than 4 by 2014.
By then, Australia’s index was also below that of New Zealand, Chile, France,
Portugal, Italy, Spain and South Africa (Anderson 2018).
Over that 150-year period of long-run growth, the industry went through
four boom-slump cycles before beginning its fifth boom in the latter 1980s.
During the next two decades per capita consumption trebled, wine produc-
tion quadrupled, and the share of production exported rose to two-thirds—
by which time Australia accounted for almost one-tenth of global wine
exports. That latest boom peaked just as the global financial crisis hit in 2008,
following which the industry saw profits slump once more for a decade.
Considerable structural adjustments were made over that decade as wineries
positioned themselves to a return to another growth phase.
This chapter seeks to explain why the industrial organization of Australia’s
wine industry has changed over those 17 decades of growth and cycles to what
it is currently. It begins with a brief outline of the industry’s emergence and
how it has evolved through those past cycles around its long-run growth path.
It then provides details of the industry’s current structural organization and
how it developed. The final sections speculate on how that structure may
change in the decades to come and provide a synthesis.
6.2 T
he Australian Industry’s Emergence
and Cyclical Growth
Grapes are perishable, and vines are perennial; planting such a crop involves a
large up-front investment with no yield for the first three years, and full pro-
duction of quality fruit requires at least four more vintages. Furthermore, the
future demand for winegrapes is uncertain. Hence the decision as to whether,
when and how much to expand or contract the area and varieties of grape-
vines is a complex one, depending as it does on expected product prices, costs
and capital appreciation or depreciation. Since producers vary in their expec-
tations, if an expansion or contraction is to occur, it will tend to happen only
gradually as more and more would-be investors become convinced that a
change in profitability will persist long enough to be worth responding to
(Dixit and Pindyck 1994). Meanwhile, in the open Australian economy, the
market price of grapes will move away from its trend level while this slow sup-
ply adjustment is occurring, and then gradually move back to trend as the last
of the adjustment occurs. Should there be excessive exuberance on the part of
investors in response to a period of high grape prices, and if firms have
incomplete information on the extent of new investments by other firms,
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Australian Wine Industry 133
180000
Up 104,800 ha (4800/yr, 3-fold rise)
Up 6,300 ha (400/yr, 10-fold rise)
160000
Up 21,600 ha (2200/yr, 2-fold
140000
120000
100000
80000
60000
40000
20000
0
1873
1913
1953
1993
1843
1848
1853
1858
1863
1868
1878
1883
1888
1893
1898
1903
1908
1918
1923
1928
1933
1938
1943
1948
1958
1963
1968
1973
1978
1983
1988
1998
2003
2008
2013
Fig. 6.1 Bearing area of vineyards, Australia (upper line) and South Australia (lower
line), 1843 to 2013 (hectares). (Source: Anderson 2015, Chart 5)
mmorag@uchile.cl
134 K. Anderson
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
1843
1851
1859
1867
1875
1883
1891
1899
1907
1915
1923
1931
1939
1947
1955
1963
1971
1979
1987
1995
2003
2011
Vine area Wine producon Wine exports
Fig. 6.2 Vine area, wine production and wine exports, Australia, 1843 to 2013 (log
scale). (Source: Anderson 2015, Chart 9)
100
80
60
40
20
0
1939
1942
1945
1948
1951
1954
1957
1960
1963
1966
1969
1972
1975
1978
1981
1984
1987
1990
1993
1996
1999
2002
2005
2008
2011
Fig. 6.3 Share of grape production used for winemaking, Australia, 1939 to 2013 (%).
(Source: Anderson 2015, Table 8)
one-quarter was fortified (Fig. 6.4). Only since the 1980s has (mostly still)
table wine regained the dominance it had in the nineteenth century.
The latest cycle began with the rise in the local price of exported wine when
the Australian dollar slumped in the mid-1980s. That export price got reflected
in the price of winegrapes, but it took until the mid-1990s before the area of
bearing vineyards began to rise as potential investors adjusted their expecta-
tions—especially following the release of a 30-year strategic plan by the
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Australian Wine Industry 135
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1924
1928
1932
1936
1940
1944
1948
1952
1956
1960
1964
1968
1972
1976
1980
1984
1988
1992
1996
2000
2004
2008
2012
Table wine Fortified wine Distillation wine
Fig. 6.4 Shares of table, fortified and distillation wine in total wine output, Australia,
1923 to 2013 (percentage, three-year moving average around year shown). (Source:
Anderson 2015, Chart 31)
200 1000
180 900
160 800
140 700
120 600
100 500
80 400
60 300
40 200
20 100
0 0
Vine area (LH) Winegrape price (RH) Wine export price (RH)
Fig. 6.5 Average price of winegrapes and of exports (RH axis), and vine area (LH axis),
Australia, 1986 to 2017 (A$/tonne, A$/hectoliter, and ‘000 hectares). (Source: Anderson
2015, Chart 17)
industry (AWBC and WFA 2007). That bearing area continued to rise for a
dozen vintages until 2008—even though the average prices of exported wine
and of winegrapes peaked at the turn of the century (Fig. 6.5). Between 2001
and 2011, the export price halved and the winegrape average price fell by
60% in nominal Australian dollars, and they remained at those low levels
through to the 2014 vintage.
mmorag@uchile.cl
136 K. Anderson
A key reason for the slump of the past decade has been a boom in Australia’s
mining sector, thanks to China’s rapid industrialization. That caused the
Australian real exchange rate to double in value between 2001–02 and
2012–13. However, during the subsequent two years it returned halfway back
to its 2001–02 level, which has enabled wine producers to sell much of their
excess wine stocks. As a result, average winegrape prices rose slightly in 2015
and somewhat more in 2016 and 2017 (Fig. 6.5).
Many winegrape growers, unable to recover even their variable costs during
recent years (WFA 2015), decided to replace their vines with more profitable
crops. As a result, by 2015 Australia’s total bearing area of grapes was one-fifth
below the peak in 2008.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Australian Wine Industry 137
3000
2500
2000
1500
1000
500
0
84 986 988 990 992 994 996 998 000 002 004 006 008 010 012 014 016
19 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2
Fig. 6.6 Number of wineries in Australia, 1984 to 2016. (Source: Updated from
Anderson 2015, Table 21)
In 2000, 80% of wineries had a ‘cellar door’ (meaning they sell direct to
retail customers from the winery itself or a separate retail outlet they own),
and 40% were exporting (though mostly to just four English-language
destinations). By 2016, there were twice as many wineries, but only two-thirds
had a cellar door, and the share exporting had already peaked and then fallen
to 47%. While virtually all make table wines, a declining share is making forti-
fied wines (less than 30% in 2016) and a rising share (42% by 2016) produces
mmorag@uchile.cl
138 K. Anderson
80
70
60
1978 1996 2016
50
40
30
20
10
0
<100 t 100-999 t 1000-9999 t 10000+ t
Fig. 6.7 Share of Australian wineries by crush, 1978, 1996 and 2016 (%). (Source:
Updated from Anderson 2015, Table 21)
Table 6.3 Various attributes of Australian wineries, 2000, 2010 and 2016
2000 2010 2016
Total no. of producers 1197 2420 2468
Share (%) of producers…
Making table wine 99 99 98
Making fortified wine 33 29 29
Making sparkling wine 28 35 42
Making organic wine na 5 4
Making wine on site 63 52 53
With a website 25 84 90
With a cellar door 78 68 66
Who export wine 41 51 47
Who export to the United Kingdom 28 27 21
Who export to the United States 26 27 18
Who export to Canada 11 24 19
Who export to NZ 14 8 8
Who export to Japan 12 12 13
Who export to Hong Kong 8 19 21
Who export to Singapore 7 25 22
Who export to China 2 23 30
Source: http://winetitles.com.au/statistics/wineries_numbers.asp
sparkling wines; 4% are making organic wines and only half are making wine
on site (down from two-thirds prior to 2000). All but one-tenth now have a
website. Around half export wine, but in 2016 only one in five or six exported
to what had been Australia’s two largest markets, the United Kingdom and the
United States, with a larger proportion exporting to the fast-growing markets
in Asia, especially China (Table 6.3).
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Australian Wine Industry 139
The 1% of Australian wineries that crush more than 10,000 tonnes account
for all but one-seventh of the national crush, with around half crushed by the
three biggest wineries. By contrast, those firms crushing less than 1000 tonnes
account for no more than 4% of the national crush and of the wine produced
in Australia.
This very strong concentration of firms in Australia’s wine production is
not uncommon among New World wine-exporting countries. In 2009
Australia at 62% was second after Chile in the share of domestic sales
accounted for by the country’s four largest wineries. That share had fallen to
41% by 2015 though, as several large firms consciously moved away from
producing large-volume but low-priced/low-profit lines. This compares with
Chile at 91%, Argentina at 60% and the United States at 56% in 2015. By
contrast, in Western Europe the highest national four-firm concentration in
2015 was 20% (Spain), followed by Italy (18%, up from 10% in 2009) and
France (16% in 2009)—see Table 6.4.
Table 6.4 Shares of domestic wine sales volume by largest four wineries, Australia and
other key wine-producing countries, 2009 and 2015(%)
Largest firm Largest four firms
2009 2015 2009 2015
Australia 23 16 62 41
Other New World
New Zealand 24 23 48 53
Canada 21 12 42 34
United States 21 23 56 56
Argentina 29 27 61 60
Chile 33 31 >86 91
South Africa 34 31 37 36
Western Europe
France 11 na 16 na
Italy 6 8 10 18
Portugal 8 3 25 10
Spain 12 11 21 20
Austria 5 6 13 10
Germany 1 1 4 4
C/Eastern Europe
Bulgaria 13 12 40 38
Hungary 8 9 15 19
Romania 11 11 32 38
World 13 na 28 na
Source: Anderson and Nelgen (2013, Table 33), compiled and updated from
Euromonitor International (2016)
mmorag@uchile.cl
140 K. Anderson
1
The introduction of commercial television in the 1980s strengthened the market power of large super-
markets. See the special issue on the history of commercial television in Europe in VIEW Journal of
European Television History and Culture, Volume 6, Issue 11, 2017.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Australian Wine Industry 141
Table 6.5 Ranking of Australia’s largest wine companies by wine sales value and other
criteria, 2015
Wine Wine Owned Owned Wine Wine Earliest
sales prod’n or leased or leased export export year of
value volume vine area vines (ha) value volume brands
Treasury 1 3 1 9133 1 2 1843
Wine
Pernod 2 4 5 1662 3 4 1828
Ricard
Accolade 3 1 9 1002 4 1 1836
Casella 4 2 2 2891 2 3 1969
Australian 5 5 3 2700 5 5 1938
Vintage
McWilliam’s 6 11 10 980 10 10 1877
De Bortoli 7 7 11 845 8 7 1928
Warburn 8 8 8 1017 14 13 1959
Brown 9 18 13 787 12 18 1889
Brothers
Yalumba 10 13 12 820 7 8 1849
Tahbilk 11 19 21 421 17 15 1860
Angove 12 15 na na 15 12 1889
Kingston 13 6 6 1500 9 na 1979
Estate
Qualia 14 10 14 690 18 17 2009
Wine 15 na 17 508 na na 1930
Insights
Andrew 16 12 16 565 6 6 1995
Peace
Littore 17 14 4 1850 19 14 2008
Zilzie 18 9 15 587 20 19 1999
Source: http://winetitles.com.au/statistics/wineries_numbers.asp
close historical ties with Britain, its firms were able to dominate that market
in the final decade of the twentieth century.
Not all of Australia’s oldest wineries are the largest. Among them are the
dozen so-called First Families of Wine, which between them have 1200 years
of winemaking experience (www.australiasfirstfamiliesofwine.com.au). These
are all family-owned private businesses, some of them several generations old.
They formed an alliance in 2009 to tell the world about the heritage of
Australia’s premium wines, to share the stories behind them, to celebrate the
things they have in common and the differences that make them unique and
occasionally to travel together on sales missions abroad.
In terms of quality of wines produced in Australia, as of 2009 about one-
eighth were non-premium, half were commercial premium (between US$2.50
and $7.50 per liter wholesale pre-tax), a bit over one-quarter were super pre-
mium still wines and one-tenth were sparkling wines. Domestic consumption
mmorag@uchile.cl
142 K. Anderson
and imports were more biased toward higher quality, while exports were more
biased toward the lower-quality range in 2009 (Anderson and Nelgen 2013,
Section VI). Since then, however, the quality of Australian wines produced,
consumed domestically and exported have all risen somewhat. In the case of
red wines, for example, the share of off-trade domestic sales at less than AUD6
per liter fell from 35% to 25% between 2009 and 2016 while the share above
AUD13.50 per liter rose from 27% to 33% and the share between those two
extremes rose from 38% to 42% (Euromonitor International 2017).
mmorag@uchile.cl
Table 6.6 Number, vine-bearing area and crush of Australian independent and winemaker grape-growing establishments, by vineyard size
range (ha) and state, 2012
Number Independent grapegrowers Sub-total Winemaker-grapegrowers Sub- Total
total
<10 10–25 25–50 50–100 >100 <10 10–25 25–50 50–100 >100
South 1158 585 261 117 55 2176 161 145 95 50 58 509 2685
Australia
New South 430 244 124 65 53 916 204 66 21 16 29 335 1252
Wales
Victoria 568 190 63 39 25 885 348 89 50 29 17 532 1417
Western 214 70 21 11 6 323 168 79 16 18 17 298 620
Australia
Tasmania 51 2 2 56 61 10 1 3 3 79 134
Australia 2458 1096 472 232 140 4398 994 394 187 116 125 1815 6213
totala
Area (ha) Independent grapegrowers Sub-total Winemaker-grapegrowers Sub- Total
total
<10 10–25 25–50 50–100 >100 <10 10–25 25–50 50–100 >100
South 5844 9018 9033 8192 11,596 43,683 761 2437 3395 3453 16,242 26,287 69,970
mmorag@uchile.cl
Australia
New South 1853 3870 4423 4315 13,194 27,654 872 977 671 1075 7114 10,709 38,363
Wales
Victoria 2333 2876 2167 2565 4272 14,213 1465 1347 1688 2124 3876 10,500 24,713
Western 799 1069 733 760 860 4222 766 1281 494 1206 2349 6095 10,316
Australia
Tasmania 105 28 71 205 213 125 41 204 442 1024 1229
Australia 11,045 16,934 16,427 15,833 29,921 90,160 4254 6229 6399 8144 30,196 55,222 145,382
totala
(continued)
Table 6.6 (continued)
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Australian Wine Industry 145
Since the demise of cooperatives, growers have sought contracts with win-
eries. These have varied from a handshake to a written legal document.
Typically they specify an area of vines by variety and certain quality criteria or
proxies such as a maximum number of tonnes per hectare. In the 1990s as the
industry was expanding and wineries were keen to secure grape supplies, con-
tracts as long as ten years were not uncommon. But as the oversupply situa-
tion emerged in the new century, those contracts were often renewed with
much shorter time frames. In some cases they were not renewed at all, leaving
the grower to either sell on the spot market or get the grapes produced into
wine for later resale in the wholesale bulk market or for retail sale under their
own new label.
Despite the rapid expansion of Australia’s wine industry over the two
decades to 2008, vineyards still account for less than 1% of the country’s area
under crops, and even less than was the case in the first globalization wave in
the latter half of the nineteenth century. In 2015 its share was 0.55%, which
is not much above the global average of 0.45% of total crop area—and barely
one-tenth the fraction in the key wine-producing countries of Western
Europe.
Winegrapes in Australia are grown in more than 60 legally defined regions
or geographical indications, covering a spectrum from cool (similar to
Burgundy) to hot (similar to some Mediterranean regions). A little over two-
fifths of the bearing area is located in hot regions, a similar proportion is in
warm regions and the remaining one-eighth is in cool regions. Almost half the
vineyards are in the state of South Australia, which has all three types of cli-
mate zones. The vineyards on the island of Tasmania, by contrast, are virtually
all classified as cool climate. Irrigation is essential in the hot regions, so their
vineyards are mostly located along the sides of major rivers. In cool regions,
by contrast, irrigation is rarely used once young vines are established.
In sharp contrast to the European Union, there are relatively few regula-
tions controlling the winegrape production process in Australia. In particular,
blending of wines from any combination of grape varieties is allowed, as is
blending from any number of regions. There is therefore no distinction in
Australia of the sort made in Europe between appellation and generic wines.
Australian producers have made a point of marketing their wines with varietal
labeling and have only recently begun to also emphasize regional (and even
single vineyard) origins of the grapes. Meanwhile, France is beginning to add
varietal names to the labels of some of its wines. Hence the Old World and
New World are converging toward both using both attributes in their
marketing.
mmorag@uchile.cl
146
K. Anderson
mmorag@uchile.cl
Fig. 6.8 Shares of varieties in Australia’s winegrape-bearing area, 1956 to 2012 (%, three-year averages). (Source: Anderson 2015)
The Australian Wine Industry 147
Australia has changed its winegrape varietal mix enormously during the
past six decades. Figure 6.8 reveals the expanded share of bearing area of reds
through the 1960s and 1970s before whites emerged with a new preference
for Chardonnay, and then reds re-emerged with the expansion of both
Cabernet Sauvignon and Syrah (Shiraz) plus Merlot. Accompanying the
growth of these varieties was the demise in popularity of grape varieties such
as Garnacha Tinta (Grenache), Muscat of Alexandria, Doradillo, Sultana,
Palomino and Pedro Ximenes. Those declining varieties had been the main-
stay of fortified wines and/or served well as multipurpose grapes able to be
directed to drying when that was more profitable than their use in winemak-
ing (Fig. 6.8).
These trends in winegrape-bearing areas mean there have also been great
changes in the country of origin shares of the nation’s winegrape varieties, as
defined by Robinson et al. (2012). Australia’s mix has become more ‘interna-
tional’ or, more accurately, more French than most countries. In the 1950s,
20% of the national vineyard was planted to French varieties while 40% was
planted to Spanish varieties and another 10% to Greek varieties. Only small
shares were from Italy and Germany, and the shares from other countries were
tiny. By contrast, by the early 2000s all but 10% of the bearing area was
planted to French varieties, and Spanish and German varieties filled half of
the remainder. In this second decade of the present century, there has been
new interest in planting varieties from warm parts of southern Europe (espe-
cially Italy) in anticipation of further global warming, but they still comprise
only a small fraction of the national area (Anderson 2016, Table 2).
The main reason for Australia’s varietal mix becoming more French has to
do with Shiraz, or Syrah as it is called in most parts of the world. The popular-
ity which Australia brought to Syrah in the 1990s has led to many other
countries expanding their plantings of this variety. In 1990 there were barely
35,000 bearing hectares globally, making it 35th in the area ranking of all
winegrape varieties in the world. But by 2000 there were 102,000 hectares,
and by 2010 that had risen to 186,000, bringing Syrah to the 6th position on
that global ladder and less than one-third below the global areas of the two
now-most-widespread varieties, namely, Cabernet Sauvignon and Merlot
(Anderson 2013).
Over the decade to 2010, the Syrah area globally grew more than either
Cabernet or Merlot—in fact only Tempranillo expanded faster. Certainly
Australia contributed to that expanding area of Syrah, but expansion was even
greater in France and Spain. There were also large plantings in other key New
World wine countries, and in Italy and Portugal. As a result, Australia is no
longer as globally dominant in this variety: Its share of the global Syrah area
mmorag@uchile.cl
148 K. Anderson
6.5 T
he Changing Structure of Australian Wine
Distribution and Retailing
During Australia’s first export boom in the three decades to World War I (see
Fig. 6.9), virtually all its wine was shipped bulk, in hogsheads (large wooden
barrels). Exports were generally of extremely low quality prior to that (mostly
dry red, shipped only weeks after the grapes had been crushed), with little
invested in marketing and distribution arrangements in the (almost sole) des-
tination country of Britain. While strong prejudices against New World wine
remained throughout that first globalization wave, a firm reputation for
100
90
80
70
Exports as % of producon
60
Imports as % of consumpon
50
40
30
20
10
0
1843
1850
1857
1864
1871
1878
1885
1892
1899
1906
1913
1920
1927
1934
1941
1948
1955
1962
1969
1976
1983
1990
1997
2004
2011
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Australian Wine Industry 149
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1990-95 1996-01 2002-06 2007-12 2013-16 2017
Europe N. America Asia Other
Fig. 6.10 Shares of the value of Australia’s exports to various regions, 1990 to 2017
(The 2016 data are for the 12 months to September 30). (Source: Updated from
Anderson and Nelgen 2013, Table 144) (%)
mmorag@uchile.cl
150 K. Anderson
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Australian Wine Industry 151
China, which will mean Australia’s exporters to that expanding market will
not have escaped that retailer’s influence.
One indication of that increasing dominance is the declining share of the
five top wineries’ brands in the volume of Australia’s domestic sales. In 2008
those five brands accounted for 65% of the still wine market in Australia, but
by 2016 their share was just 48% (Euromonitor International 2017).
mmorag@uchile.cl
152 K. Anderson
lion Euros for wine promotion, the equivalent to 0.6 Australian cents per liter
of EU wine produced. Moreover, that EU promotion expenditure is to be
raised to 1156 million Euros for the period 2014–18 (European Court of
Auditors 2014). That is around 1.3 cents per liter, or double the rate recently
spent in Australia—and that is just the supplement from Brussels, which adds
to what will be spent by national governments and EU wine regions
themselves.
Fortunately for the Australian industry, the national government announced
in 2016 that it would provide a one-off grant of AUD50 million over the four
years to 2020 to boost the industry’s competitiveness and thereby reboot prof-
itability. More specifically, this Export and Regional Wine Support Package is
to focus on wine promotion internationally and domestically and is designed
to help regional wine producers, wine-related tourism and export-focused
businesses.
As for grape and wine research, less than 1% of the value of grape and wine
production has been invested in R&D in the past, despite the returns from
such investments being very high. Returns in the next two decades are likely
to be even higher, bearing in mind rapid marketplace changes (the need to
produce better quality rather than quantity of grapes and wine) and long-
term uncertainties such as climate change and global economic growth.
Wine consumer tax policy reform could contribute to the transition to
higher-quality wine production. If Australia were to switch from its current
29% ad valorem wholesale tax to a volumetric tax on domestic sales, that
would encourage the transition to finer wines while weakening the case by
anti-alcohol lobbies and the beer and spirits producers for a higher rate of tax
on wine. Such a switch would make it easier for small fine-wine producers to
sell all their production on the domestic market, thereby avoiding the high
fixed costs of breaking into new export markets.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Australian Wine Industry 153
• Wineries too face relatively few regulations and so can blend wines from
various regions, blend whatever varieties they wish and label their bottles
with as much varietal, regional and vineyard information as they wish.
• Since the industry’s take-off in the 1990s, the focus has been on export
markets, since the domestic market has been growing very little in volume
terms at least.
• The importance of Asia, and especially China, to Australian wine exporters
is already very strong and will become even more so in the next few years
as Australia’s new bilateral trade agreements with Northeast Asian countries
are implemented.
• The average quality of wine will keep rising as the share of production in
the warmest regions, where quality is lowest, shrinks in response to global
warming and rising prices of irrigation water.
References
Anderson, K. 2016. Evolving varietal and quality distinctiveness of Australia’s wine
regions. Journal of Wine Research 27 (3): 173–192, September.
———. 2017. Australia’s wine industry competitiveness: Why so slow to emerge? Wine
economics research centre working paper 0317, University of Adelaide, November.
Anderson, K. (with the assistance of N.R. Aryal). 2013. Which winegrape varieties are
grown where? A global empirical picture. Adelaide: University of Adelaide Press.
www.adelaide.edu.au/press/titles/winegrapes.
———. 2015. Growth and cycles in Australia’s wine industry: A statistical compendium,
1843 to 2013. Adelaide: University of Adelaide Press. www.adelaide.edu.au/press/
titles/austwine.
Anderson, K., and S. Nelgen. 2013. Global wine markets, 1961 to 2009: A statistical
compendium. Adelaide: University of Adelaide Press. www.adelaide.edu.au/press/
titles/global-wine.
Anderson, K., and G. Wittwer. 2015. Asia’s evolving role in global wine markets.
China Economic Review 35: 1–14, September.
———. 2018. Cumulative effects of Brexit and other UK and EU27 bilateral FTAs on
the world’s wine markets. Wine Economics Research Centre Working Paper 0118,
University of Adelaide, January.
AWBC and WFA. 2007. Wine Australia: Directions to 2025. Adelaide: Australian
Wine and Brandy Corporation and Winemakers Federation of Australia. www.
wineaustralia.com/Australia/Default.aspx?tabid=3529.
Dixit, A., and R.S. Pindyck. 1994. Investment under uncertainty. Princeton: Princeton
University Press.
mmorag@uchile.cl
154 K. Anderson
mmorag@uchile.cl
7
The Argentinean Wine Industry
Javier Merino
7.1 Introduction
In the last three decades, the Argentinean wine industry has experienced a
dramatic change in its value-added chain. In the 1990s it opened its economy,
and very important foregoing investors came to the wine sector. At the begin-
ning the most important change took place in the vineyards. A special situa-
tion in the exchange rate then allowed the wineries to go to export markets
and introduce the wine successfully in the most sophisticated markets. At the
same time, some wineries introduced Malbec, which was welcomed by con-
sumers. This caused a drastic change in the Argentinean wine sector that
became a competitive player in the wine market worldwide. The recent years
have been very difficult for the Argentinean economy, and many wineries
have had to adapt the business to new conditions, especially in the domestic
market. Nowadays the Argentinean wine sector structure is very different, and
the wineries and producers have the challenge to grow in a very competitive
market with opportunities and very strong threats.
J. Merino (*)
Cuyo National University, Mendoza, Argentina
University of Mendoza, Mendoza, Argentina
e-mail: jmerino@areadelvino.com
mmorag@uchile.cl
156 J. Merino
7.2 S
tructural Features of the Vinegrowing
Sector
7.2.1 Evolution of Vineyard-Planted Areas
314.655
Fig. 7.1 Evolution of cultivated surface area of grapes for winemaking in Argentina
(ha). (Source: INV)
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Argentinean Wine Industry 157
From 1990 to the present day, the cultivated surface area of high-quality
varieties has increased by almost 4600 ha (11,300 acres). However, when ana-
lyzing the nine most purchased varieties for export (Malbec being the leader),
their growth in particular has increased to more than 77,000 ha (190,000
acres), while other varieties have fallen by more than 72,000 ha (178,000
acres).
Argentina’s switch in grape varieties went hand in hand with the adoption of
new technologies in the irrigation systems, which additionally expanded the
planted surface area-inadequate vinegrowing regions where traditional irriga-
tion methods were otherwise not possible. This spurred Argentine viticulture
to extend to high-altitude areas and regions where the combination of ther-
mal amplitude and soils offered the possibility of growing higher-quality
grape varieties, very much demanded by international markets.
Between 2001 and 2013, the provinces of Mendoza, Neuquén, and Salta
revealed the largest area expansion. In the first one, Mendoza, new regions
began being cultivated. Neuquén, the newest of the Argentine winemaking
regions, expanded due to private investments, financial support from the local
government, and optimal agricultural conditions given its latitude, sun expo-
sure, and the presence of wind year-round. In Salta, the vinegrowing region
with the highest altitude in the country, the surface area expanded in an
attempt to increase thermal amplitude for the production of red varieties.
mmorag@uchile.cl
158 J. Merino
Observing the change in planted surface area and the variations of more
than 5000 ha (12,500 acres) alone hides the fact that 11 regions still managed
to increase their planted surface area by 26,000 ha (64,000 acres) between
2001 and 2013. Luján de Cuyo, Argentina’s most traditional winegrowing
region, with the largest Malbec-planted surface area, led this change by
expanding to the south and west. This area is home to some of the oldest
wineries in the country, along with those founded in Maipú.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Argentinean Wine Industry 159
mmorag@uchile.cl
160 J. Merino
and its high yields in certain regions. For a long time now, many wineries have
been trying to position this grape internationally as the second most impor-
tant variety from a.
Chardonnay, on its part, fifth in the expansion of cultivated surface area,
shares a similar story as that of Cabernet Sauvignon. Implanted because of its
international popularity, Chardonnay can be used in producing sparkling
wines, which experienced an impressive growth in Argentina, following the
worldwide trends set by younger generations (Fig. 7.2).
In Argentina, Merlot suffered the same fate as that on the world stage. A
once prestigious variety suffering depreciation from consumers, its extension
in our country went from about 1000 ha (2500 acres) in 1990 to more than
7400 ha (18,200 acres) in 2006, to ultimately decline in 2017 to less than
5500 ha (13,500 acres).
Fascinating stories concern the rest of the varieties that expanded in the last
quarter of this century, since all of them constitute modern phenomena. In
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Argentinean Wine Industry 161
the case of Sauvignon Blanc, its expansion reflected the formidable acceptance
it was getting from New Zealand, which led it to expand to new regions, such
as Chile. Consequently, given its international popularity, many Argentinean
wineries began growing this variety, contributing to expand its cultivated sur-
face area during the first decade of this century.
Pinot Noir, on its part, has been growing uninterruptedly since 1990 for a
variety of reasons, including the demand for sparkling wines in medium-to-
high price ranges as well as its exceptional adaptation to regions in Valle de
Uco and Patagonia. Additionally, the growing international demand for still
red wines from Burgundy, France, resulted in the creation of new wine styles
from the regions of Sonoma and Oregon in the United States and, more
recently, New Zealand.
The decreasing cultivated surface area experienced by some varieties has
been attributable to the inability to adapt to a number of consumers’ demands,
such as price and quality.
mmorag@uchile.cl
162 J. Merino
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Argentinean Wine Industry 163
mmorag@uchile.cl
164 J. Merino
Argentina’s raw material (grape or bulk wine) market is very well developed.
In the last decade, about 25% of the grapes intended for wine production
were sold to independent producers. In addition, about 8% of the total rep-
resented bulk wine sales from wineries that were not able to bottle their
production on their own. In other words, the raw material market accounts
for one third of the total number of bottled wines. Given the type and qual-
ity of raw materials, the bulk wine market is intended for low-price wines,
while the grape market aims at medium- to high-end wines. The former
market involves estate owners who have made large investments in their pro-
duction in order to meet the large wine producers and bottlers’ requirements.
Lastly, it should be mentioned that high-quality grapes, intended for high-
end wines, are generally grown by the same wineries that make and bottle
the said wines.
The grape market is typically managed by means of agreements between
wineries and producers. Some have been able to maintain their commercial
relationship to this day, after many years of business. The larger wineries will
regularly visit the vineyards and make suggestions on vineyard management.
Great trust is developed in this type of relationship, since most grape prices
will be defined after the harvest, once the wineries have already crushed the
berries. In the case of bulk wine, many wine agents will offer the product to
different potential buyers and receive a commission upon closing the deal.
Finally, some producers who do not bottle their own production will nor-
mally grow their grapes in wineries and ultimately sell their wine to them.
The total revenue of the viticulture sector has been calculated taking into
account the figures for grape sales and the considered value of the finished
product owned by the wineries. Over the last 15 years, oscillations in grape
prices and the sector’s strong transformation process have been two important
factors affecting revenue (Fig. 7.3). In its early stage, the participation of red
grapes was nowhere near the levels it would reach between 2004 and 2009. In
these years, red grapes were able to maintain their revenue due to productivity
expansion and stable prices. In 2010 and 2011, wine producers’ turnover
increased because of the price spike due to the scarce availability of grapes, the
grim result of two consecutive poor harvest seasons. At that time, the demand
for red grapes shifted to regions where prices were lower.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Argentinean Wine Industry 165
40
35 32.7 33.5
30 28.2
26.6
24.6 23.8
25 22.7 23.5
22.5
20.7 20.1
20 17.9
16.5
15
11.6 12.3 12.2
10.1 9.7
10 9.1
0
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
Total Red Variees White variees Rosé Variees
Fig. 7.3 Annual revenues in the viticulture sector (BB AR$ - Dec. 2017). (Source: Area
del Vino)
As from 2004, the demand for varietal wine exports grew significantly.
This, in turn, increased the sector’s profitability and boosted expansion given
the advantageous exchange rate in place.
The decline in pinked-skinned grape production has been independent
from economic transformations and is rather the result of opposite interna-
tional and domestic demand trends.
When calculating the average revenue per hectare across different varieties,
Malbec comes across as the outright winner, outperforming every other vari-
ety given its greater expansion process. Pinot Noir ranks second, although it
should be noted this variety is much more developed in certain regions.
7.3 S
tructural Features of the Winemaking
Sector
7.3.1 Average Winery Size
mmorag@uchile.cl
166 J. Merino
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Argentinean Wine Industry 167
Mendoza, San Juan (showing a drastic change in this respect), La Rioja, Río
Negro, and Neuquén. Salta and Catamarca, on the other hand, displayed alto-
gether an opposite situation. With respect to the company distribution accord-
ing to size, no significant differences were observed between 2005 and 2013.
2,500
2,000
7 (7,5%) companies focused
Average sales price ($ Dec 2016/Box)
on differentiation
1.1% of turnover
1,500
22 (24%) companies
focused on volume
85% of turnover
500
Fig. 7.4 Sales price vs. volume. (Source: Area del Vino)
mmorag@uchile.cl
168 J. Merino
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Argentinean Wine Industry 169
For a few years now, the volume of wine sold in the Argentinean winemak-
ing sector has been declining. A decade ago, 40 million extra wine cases were
sold with respect to today. However, the domestic and export markets reported
a dramatic decrease five years ago, and, in 2017, the total number of wine
cases sold was 125 million.
With sporadic variations, Argentina’s domestic market has been declining
over the past 30 years. It finally reached a plateau in 2008, making any price
changes directly dependent on price movements experienced by the products
placed at the lower half of the wine pyramid, especially regarding Tetra Brik
wine shipments. In parallel, the foreign market has shown a reduction in vol-
ume, both for bulk and bottled wines. In 2016, in total, this number has hit
its lowest mark in the past decade.
The combination of smaller volume and lower prices led the industry’s total
revenue to a sum below that obtained in 2006 and 18% below its all-time
high, recorded in 2011. The industry has been suffering consecutive decline
mmorag@uchile.cl
170 J. Merino
in sales for five years in a row, resulting in very serious effects on several fronts,
including:
The Fall in Grape Price The price of raw material is one of the main items
affected when revenues decline. An asset with no alternative use in the cur-
rent economy, its value is flexible, unlike that of other goods and services
consumed by the industry. As a consequence of low prices, winemakers have
had to cope with a very harsh reality in the past few years, sometimes work-
ing despite evident losses, which resulted in disinvestment and lesser quality.
Smaller wineries, however, were less likely to transfer this adjustment to
vinegrowers as they have a larger proportion of their own grapes for
winemaking.
7.4 D
istribution and Relationship Along the
Distribution Chain
7.4.1 Argentinean Wine Markets
Of the 125 million cases sold in 2017 (Fig. 7.5), 80% were destined for the
domestic market. In terms of revenue, this meant 64% revenue originating
from the Argentinean market and 36% from export operations. This clearly
shows the difference between export and domestic prices, the average export
prices being much higher than the domestic ones. Argentina has been increas-
ingly concentrated on producing wines for the medium- to high-end price
ranges in global markets.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Argentinean Wine Industry 171
Total market in volume (Million of boxes) Annual Revenues of wine (BB $ Dec 2017)
63.2 62.7
156 164 165
146 139 144 152 150 140 144 60.1 59.9
123 124 119 115 134 125
108 109 112 115 110 114 105 100 57.3
56.1 55.5
51.2 51.8
40 46 41 47.6
33 31 30 35 35 29 30 29 25
43.1 42.4 43.7 43.1
41.8
40.2
38.9
2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
36.2 35.7
34.9 35.0
Total Domestic market Exports
30.5
27.7 27.6
Average sales price ($ Dec 2017/Box)
700 21.3
623 19.9 20.6 19.6 19.9
585 18.4
566 551 577 553 16.3
17.5
16.1 17.2 16.0 15.5
499 497 501
447 455 437 489
391 395 400 371
328 342 337 331 327 346
386 395 361 369
338 323
283 292 295 267 265 276
2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
Fig. 7.5 Total market in volume (millions of cases), average sales prices (AR$ Dec.
2017/case), and annual revenues of wine (BB AR$ Dec 2017). (Source: Area del Vino)
When it comes to destination countries, the United States has been the
most significant one in the last few years, importing 32% of Argentina’s total
bottled wine exports. The United States has been a steady and very dynamic
market for Argentinean exports, especially due to Americans’ preference for
Malbec. In the second place, the United Kingdom accounts for 18% of the
total export operations. Argentinean wines experienced a substantial change
in focus in the UK market over the last decade. In the last years, efforts have
been directed to importers with large participation shares of on-trade sales as
well as off-trade chains with higher prices. After many years of continuous
hard work, China has become a top market, joining Canada, Brazil, and the
Netherlands.
The domestic wine market has followed behavioral patterns that mirror those
of the global markets. For more than a decade, international discussions have
ensued about the changes in consumer habits leaning toward higher-price
wines, a phenomenon known as premiumization.
Several causes may help explain this change: firstly, older generations, with
higher incomes, are slowly evolving into connoisseurs who are willing to pay
higher prices for the wines they seek. Additionally, the 2008 crisis largely
mmorag@uchile.cl
172 J. Merino
changed at a global scale the amount of wine that was consumed at home
versus that which was consumed outside. Rather than paying high prices at
restaurants, consumers prefer to buy wines on off-trade channels, which
entails the possibility of purchasing higher-quality wines at lower prices when
compared to hospitality establishments. This behavior, which started after the
crisis in 2008, has remained valid until the present days.
In the case of Argentina, this process has been more accentuated, as the
price pyramid started at a lower baseline than that of other countries. The
total volume of wine consumption fell at an annual rate of 1% in the last
decade. In this context, consumption of low-price wines, sold in Tetra Brik
packaging, fell at an annual rate of 1.8%. However, bottled wine grew at an
average of 1.2% annually, an early sign of premiumization. The phenomenon
becomes increasingly evident when analyzing the evolution of bottled wines
across different price ranges. Those at the bottom range (ARS 164 per case)
fell at a rate about 5% annually, while the top price segment (ARS 835 per
case) increased their volume at an annual average rate close to 19%.
It should be highlighted that sparkling wines and frizzes (sparkling wines
typically aimed at a fun, young adult segment) have expanded greatly. This
event not only signals a premiumization but also a change in consumers’
behavior. Consumers seem to be shifting from still to sparkling wines, which
additionally constitute a strategic introduction of a younger audience and of
women into the wine market. This very marked change had a positive impact
on those wineries leaning toward premium wine lines, as they could now
improve their profitability. In turn, the wineries working in the lower price
segments resorted to more aggressive strategies in order to maintain their posi-
tion on the shelf, hoping for better consumption habits worldwide.
Despite the impressive sales growth volume evidenced by high-end wine
lines, they still represent a small percentage of the total. In 2016, bottled wine
accounted for almost 55% of the total volume, while higher price ranges, at
ARS 422 per case, accounted for only 7.6%. The share of sparkling wines is
about 4.6% of the total of volume. This market sector, it should be noted,
represents 12.2% of the overall market that breaks down into 200 wineries
that produce a total volume of 13.6 million cases, with an average of 68,000
cases per winery, figures obviously much higher for large wineries.
In the domestic market, the revenue derived from bottled wine represents
76% of the total revenue, and it has been growing at an average rate of 2% per
year. The bottled wine market is clearly very attractive for investment, proudly
showing considerable revenue both domestically and internationally. Due to
their higher prices when compared to those available domestically, external
markets have offered substantial investment opportunities.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Argentinean Wine Industry 173
The current domestic wine market may be characterized as relatively saturated and
highly competitive. A variety of elements serves to illustrate the said features:
Retraction from the Market Over the past decade, the domestic wine market
has been declining in volume. Given the projections for population growth,
this scenario will ultimately create a market that becomes saturated with
brands and competitive wineries.
Discount Policies With sales plummeting over the past few years, the busi-
ness strategies designed by large retail alcohol beverage stores and wine shops
aimed at offering discounts and special sale prices. These strategies are often
devised by the stores themselves, in an attempt to attract new clients who will
buy other products or who will contribute to product rotation. These strate-
gies sometimes also include a variety of payment options, such as credit or
debit cards, or the creation of a store club membership offering discounts to
its members. Only large wineries with a large production volume, however,
are able to take the impact of this type of deals, and very few can negotiate not
being a part of them.
mmorag@uchile.cl
174 J. Merino
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Argentinean Wine Industry 175
Buenos Aires but also in other regions of Argentina. Supermarkets have not
been the only ones to develop online sale platforms for their customers, with
leading specialist stores also developing their own, thus leading to a systematic
and continuous growth in e-commerce.
With respect to winery presence in supermarkets and specialist stores, a
small sample has been gathered, composed of the largest companies from each
category, accounting for a total of 13 businesses, many of whom work jointly
with chains throughout the country or have developed online platforms.
These large chains, then, commercialize the wines from 189 wineries, a figure
that represents half of the companies that export wines.
Fifty-five percent of all wineries have access to both supermarkets and large
supermarkets. In other words, these establishments are responsible for selling
the wines of only 104 wineries. In the case of specialist stores, on average, they
sell the products from an increased number of wineries (139) and feature
wines from smaller establishments that do not run business on larger channels.
Only 54 wineries participate in both channels. Incidentally, these wineries are
the largest ones in the country, many of them holding a dominant position in
foreign markets as well. These figures, however, fail to reveal the fact that the
supermarket with the most comprehensive winery list includes only 68 estab-
lishments, while the least comprehensive supermarket, with a modest domes-
tic distribution, lists only 40. Specialist stores, on their part, cover 134 in the
best-case scenario, while only 24 on the opposite end. This analysis clearly
reveals not all wineries manage to be present across all channels.
It becomes clear, then, that the main off-trade sales channels leave aside a
large number of wineries with their own wine brand. Many of these wineries
have no participation in the domestic market as they only perform export oper-
ations. Others, however, will sell in small regional markets, while some have
started to develop direct-to-consumer sales strategies as an alternative profitable
option, in a scenario where wine tourism is of outmost importance.
Only 20 wineries (some of which belong to a single economic group)
represent more than 85% of the total sales of wines from supermarkets.
This shows that the said wineries focus on this channel in particular and
hold the power to negotiate active participation on store shelves, in addi-
tion to maintaining rotation standards and margins that signify good busi-
ness for commercial venues. The explicit nature behind the power of
negotiation is evident in the ratio between the price paid by the customers
and the price received by the wineries. On average, wineries receive 52% of
what is paid by the consumer, which is much lower than many products
with less added value.
mmorag@uchile.cl
176 J. Merino
7.5 Conclusion
The Argentinean viticulture sector has undergone striking transformations in
the last quarter of the century, from the process of uprooting low-quality
grapevines covering 72,000 ha (178,000 acres) to the plantation of highly
demanded grapevines extending over 77,000 ha (185,000 acres), 30,000 ha
(74,000 acres) of which correspond to Malbec. Additionally, production
capacity has increased, combined with the arrival of national and interna-
tional investments in the sector. Finally, two commercial developments are
worth mentioning: wine premiumization in the domestic market and their
export to the main international markets. The last five years have witnessed an
adverse economic context in Argentina, which has slowed down the momen-
tum for many wineries. In the next few years, lower inflation rates and a policy
for remaining open to the world will allow the Argentinean wine industry to
expand and evolve into an increasingly professional industry with an even
sharper strategic focus, even, perhaps, with fewer companies operating.
References
Area del Vino – http://areadelvino.com
Bolsa de Comercio de Mendoza - https://bolsamza.com.ar
División Vinos Banco Supervielle - http://www.supervielle.com.ar
Euromonitor Internacional - http://www.euromonitor.com/
Instituto Nacional de Vitivinicultura (INV) - http://inv.gov.ar
Instituto Nacional de Tecnología Agropecuaria - https://inta.gob.ar
Kantar Worldpanel - https://www.kantarworldpanel.com/ar
Observatorio Vitivinícola Argentino - http://observatoriova.com
Organización Internacional de la Vid y del Vino - http://www.oiv.int
Nielsen Company - http://www.nielsen.com
Trade Map - https://www.trademap.org
Wines of Argentina - http://www.winesofargentina.org
Wine-Searcher - https://www.wine-searcher.com
mmorag@uchile.cl
8
The Chilean Wine Industry
G. Marcos Mora
G. M. Mora (*)
Faculty of Agricultural Science, Department of Agricultural Economics,
University of Chile, Santiago, Chile
e-mail: mmorag@uchile.cl
mmorag@uchile.cl
178 G. M. Mora
Exchange rate at 17 February 2016: 704.92 Chilean pesos per dollar. Source: Central Bank of Chile.
1
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Industry 179
dollars, the share of the wine industry could be seen as marginal; however, it
is necessary to take account of the contribution to GDP from other sectors
involved in the wine business, such as transportation, logistics and communi-
cations, other manufacturing industries (glass, cardboard) and restaurants.
Accordingly, it is an important sector for the Chilean economy for its capacity
to generate productive linkages and its high added value, especially in the case
of bottled wines.
According to Mora et al. (2014), the production of wine has an important
impact on regional development, from the Coquimbo Region to the Araucania
Region—it is one activity that takes place in much of the territory and has a
strong impact on agricultural activities and labor employment as well as on
demand of products and services. In recent times it has been extended to the
regions of Atacama in the north and Lagos in the south. The wine industry is
a cluster with a large capacity to generate added value, widely labor-intensive
and of regional coverage; it involves a large number of industries related to
suppliers and is involved in the exporting process, and it uses an extensive
network of transport and communication for the development of its activities
and has great potential to add value to their products.
Areas with vines intended for winemaking in the country are located
between the regions of Atacama and Los Lagos, including the Metropolitan
Region. According to the figures below, 74% of the vineyards correspond to
red varieties and 26% of white varieties, mainly represented by Cabernet
Sauvignon, Merlot and Carmenere for reds, and Sauvignon Blanc and
Chardonnay for whites. Below is a chart with a greater number of varieties,
highlighting Syrah and Carmenere, which have increased significantly in
recent times.
Regarding the evolution of the vines, it is important to highlight the sus-
tained growth of Carmenere, Syrah, Pinot noir, Cabernet Franc and Sauvignon
Blanc (Table 8.1). However, it is necessary to pay attention to other grape
varieties, which have also had a sustained and significant increase, and they
approach 20,000 hectares. Behind this figure there is the incorporation of
vines traditionally not produced in Chile such as Tempranillo, Viognier and
Malbec.
In Chile, wine production is based mainly on a set of grape varieties of
French origin and a local variety called Country (Pais), which currently
accounts for about 5% of the total area of the Chilean vineyard. In 1985, the
surface of this variety was nearly 30,000 hectares or approximately 25% of the
current area, while Cabernet Sauvignon, the main cultivated variety at pres-
ent, only reached just over 8000 hectares. Also, the first and largest change
occurred between 1985 and 1994 with the increase from 245 to 4150 h ectares
mmorag@uchile.cl
180 G. M. Mora
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Industry 181
Table 8.2 Cultivated area (ha) with grapevines in irrigated, rainfed and tended irriga-
tion areas
Water regime
Region Irrigated Rainfed Tended irrigation Total
Tarapacá 5.00 5.00
Antofagasta 4.97 4.97
Atacama 117.42 117.42
Coquimbo 3371.67 11.90 3383.57
Valparaíso 10,137.29 18.40 6.50 10,162.19
Lib. Bdo. O’Higgins 46,610.97 679.20 91.90 47,382.07
Del Maule 46,385.52 6420.32 690.67 53,496.51
Del Bío Bío 2223.09 7052.06 292.90 9568.05
Araucanía 27.06 27.90 54.96
De los Lagos 19.00 19.00
Metropolitana 13,398.30 0.40 13,398.70
Total nacional 122,300.29 14,198.28 1093.87 137,592.44
Source: ODEPA
• In trellises: system was introduced in Chile in the second half of the nine-
teenth century by French technicians. Driving means consist of a frame
and wires that support for lifting the vine at the approximate height of 1.2
to 1.5 meters, allowing better illumination of fruit and facilitating the work
of care and harvesting. In addition, this technique allows the mechaniza-
tion of vineyards, since it is currently one of the most commonly used
forms of driving, mainly in vineyards intended for the production of pref-
erably fine wines from the Central Valley (Table 8.3).
• In parronal: a driving system with heights of 1.8 to 2.0 meters, with hori-
zontal trellis. It is widely used for the production of table grapes, although
it is also used in some vineyards of Cabernet Sauvignon.
• In head or Gobelet: it was introduced by the Spaniards in the period of the
conquest, so it is the oldest driving system; although this system is not suit-
able for the production of good-quality wines, it is still used in southern
Chile and in dry vineyards.
mmorag@uchile.cl
182
Table 8.3 Chile: surface area of vineyards according to conduction system (ha)
G. M. Mora
Conduction system
Double High Low Scott Smart
Region Head curtain trellises trellises Lira Others Parron Henry Dyson Total
Tarapacá 5.0 5.0
Antofagasta 5.0 5.0
Atacama 24.4 93.0 117.4
Coquimbo 1.5 757.6 1310.7 8.9 109.8 1195.1 3383.6
Valparaíso 25.3 6627.1 3151.5 34.8 263.5 60.0 10,162.2
Lib. Bdo. 71.1 288.5 21,879.8 14,794.0 1116.6 988.7 8105.6 125.2 12.7 47,382.1
O’Higgins
mmorag@uchile.cl
Del Maule 4753.1 668.9 15,604.5 23,107.4 610.5 853.2 7877.8 21.2 53,496.5
Del Bío Bío 6401.0 2053.7 782.1 69.4 97.7 16.4 147.9 9568.1
Araucanía 4.4 49.1 1.5 55.0
De los Lagos 0.2 18.8 19.0
Metropolitana 7.8 56.2 6849.5 5356.8 139.1 121.4 868.0 13,398.7
Total 11,264.4 1013.5 53,831.3 48,547.1 1979.3 2434.2 18,215.8 294.2 12.7 137,592.4
Source: Catastro vitícola 2014
The Chilean Wine Industry 183
According to Lima (2015), in the case of fine strains, the producer must incur
a large initial investment to plant them (using a trellis system and drip irriga-
tion). Also, you must wait at least two years to start production, which goes
up to the fifth year just to achieve maximum production. When you consider
the costs of planting and the first two years without production and fixed
costs for the producer, who must incur mandatory cost to start production,
which could eventually be recovered if he sells or leases the plantation to a
third party, they represent between 16% and 21% of the total cost of produc-
tion of the vineyard throughout their economic life (20 years).
Also, if you consider a return rate of 10% annually for the investment,
which must be recovered in 20 years, the average total production cost per kg
would rank between 0,15 and 0,33 dollars depending primarily on the level
of production that can be achieved in the vineyard. Grape plantings, if prop-
erly maintained, can have a longer production than the usual 20 years (between
50 and 100 years); after recovering the initial investment, it becomes relevant
to recover, at least, the annual costs of production, for which we take as a
proxy for the average annual cost of production in the vineyard. This cost
would be located between 0,12 and 0,27 dollars/kg produced.
Lima (2015) states that, with regard to the Country vine grape strain,
whose production dates back to colonial times, it is important to know the
average annual cost of production, which ranges between 0,10 and 0,21 dol-
lar/kg, depending on the quantity produced. To estimate the average cost of
production of the Country grape, as in the fine strains, yields are also impor-
tant in the case of small winemakers (who have, on average, two hectares
mmorag@uchile.cl
184 G. M. Mora
planted with wine grapes in the Bío Bio and four hectares in the region of
Maule) having a large dispersion in unit production costs: for example, for
low yields of 4000 kg/ha, the declared average costs range between 0,13 and
0,30 dollars/kg.
In Chile, for many years the wine-producing companies were mostly of family
environment; the conversion of the Chilean industry entailed the develop-
Table 8.4 Costs and prices of wine grapes at producer level (dollars)
Costs and prices of wine grapes at
producer level Variety
Cabernet
Sauvignon Merlot Carmenere Country
Cost range(2012) 0.15–0.33 0.15–0.33 0.15–0.33 0.10–0.21
Average price, high quality (2012) 0.44 0.44 0.44 0.23
Average price, low quality (2012) 0.31 0.31 0.31 0.21
Average price, high quality (2015) 0.19 0.18 0.19 0.13
Average price, low quality (2015) 0.16 0.16 0.16 0.13
Source: ODEPA; Central Bank of Chile
Note: Exchange rate at 17 February 2016: 704.92 Chilean pesos per dollar
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Industry 185
ment of the Chilean export model (mid-1980s) and the appearance of other
legal properties. This is related to the foundations of the economic model
applied in Chile since 1974, which favored large wine companies (Gilbert
2014). In this business environment, one of the most important was, and
remains to be, Concha y Toro winemaking that was transformed from a fam-
ily business into a company of a corporation type, which means that the
traded value is known and therefore is subject to business performance. This
transformation involved a more professional way of operating the technical
and administrative management of the company. Today, Concha y Toro is one
of the largest companies in the world, and the wine business investments have
exceeded the borders with investments in Argentina and the USA, through
the Trivento and Fetzer Vineyards companies, respectively (www.conchay-
toro.com).
8.2.4 T
he Average Size Businesses and Wine Processors
Types of Wines Marketed
In general, according to Mora et al. (2014), the Chilean wine industry has a
significant concentration, as it shows about 50% of exports in value are attrib-
uted to almost ten companies, and only one of them is responsible for nearly
20% of Chilean wine exports value. This occurs in a context of an industry
where more than 400 wineries spread between the Coquimbo Region and Bío
Bío but with a high concentration in the Maule and O’Higgins Regions
involved. It is also important to note that out of the total Chilean production,
more than 75% of domestic is exported (Table 8.5).
Table 8.6 shows clearly that ten countries account for approximately 75%
of Chilean exports, with five of them exceeding $100 million exported. In
addition, it can be seen that there are countries from different continents,
highlighting lately Asian countries like China and Japan.
With regard to the grape varieties used in the production of wines, the fol-
lowing are presented. The most important wines are blends, followed by
monovarietal as Cabernet Sauvignon, Sauvignon Blanc, Chardonnay, Merlot
and Carmenere, among others. It is important to relieve some unit values,
such as wine with designation of origin, and some varieties such as Cabernet
Franc and Pinot noir and sparkling wine. The latter wines have been an inno-
vation in the field of exports, which have had a significant development in
recent years.
mmorag@uchile.cl
186 G. M. Mora
Table 8.5 Chile: production of wines by type of wine and market (million liters)
Wine type and market 2013 2014
Domestic market (million liters)
Popular wines (bag in box and others) 95.9 96.0
Low-end wines 7.3 6.7
Reserve wines 18.0 18.8
Great reserve wines 10.1 11.3
Sparkling wines 3.5 4.2
Others 81.7 91.9
Total domestic market 216.5 228.9
Export market (million liters)
Bottled wines 435.8 451.8
0–20 dollars FOB/box 120.1 109.8
20–30 dollars FOB/box 169.4 186.4
30–40 dollars FOB/box 82.1 86.8
More than 40 dollars FOB/box 64.7 68.8
Others’ packaging 26.5 26.7
Bulk 411.9 317.3
Sparkling wine 3.5 4.1
“Wine” with fruit 1.3 1.4
Total export market 879.0 801.3
Total 1095.4 1030.2
Source: ODEPA Y SAG, 2015
8.2.5 T
ypes of Wineries: The Winegrowers’ Farm
Cooperatives and Industrial Enterprises
mmorag@uchile.cl
Table 8.6 Chile: exports of wines of denomination of origin in volume and FOB value
Volume (000 liters) Value (000 USD FOB)
January–November January–November
Countries 2014 2014 2015 Var. 2015/2014 (%) 2014 2014 2015 Var. 2015/2014 (%) (%)
United Kingdom 57,319 54,089 53,538 −1.0 177,486 168,122 152,840 −9.1 11.7
China 31,880 28,599 43,755 53.0 110,577 99,451 144,533 45.3 11.0
USA 38,183 34,976 37,103 6.1 148,892 136,237 143,747 5.5 11.0
Japan 42,168 38,749 46,666 20.4 124,703 115,019 135,612 17.9 10.3
Brazil 33,852 31,944 34,806 9.0 109,207 102,721 103,736 1.0 7.9
The Netherlands 30,225 28,451 26,556 −6.7 98,637 93,215 76,786 −17.6 5.9
Canada 12,942 12,080 13,163 9.0 65,713 61,300 58,961 −3.8 4.5
mmorag@uchile.cl
Ireland 12,889 12,392 12,850 3.7 43,173 41,786 37,255 −10.8 2.8
Denmark 11,051 10,204 10,532 3.2 44,695 41,414 36,499 −11.9 2.8
Mexico 10,599 9953 12,135 21.9 32,438 30,385 33,888 11.5 2.6
Subtotal 281,108 261,437 291,104 11.3 955,521 889,650 923,857 3.8 70.4
Other countries 132,461 121,763 110,596 −9.2 466,728 427,551 387,972 −9.3 29.6
Total 413,569 383,200 401,700 4.8 1,422,249 1,317,201 1,311,829 −0.4 100.0
Source: ODEPA with information from the National Customs Service. Figures subject to review by further reports
The Chilean Wine Industry
187
188 G. M. Mora
8.2.6 C
ontractual Arrangements Between Warehouses
and Distribution
8.2.7 C
ontractual Arrangements Between Growers
and Winemakers
Historically it has not been a practice to formalize the sale of grapes from
growers to wineries. This situation has created problems between the actors in
the chain of wine, because it has created problems of information asymme-
try—misunderstanding in some cases between the parties taking advantage
some of the wineries to pay less and even some moments below the cost of
production. Currently, it has been regulated but not for intervention but
rather for business sustainability, as international demand is requiring better
quality and the wineries do not have enough grapes to cope with the demand
and are used to buy from third parties under the technical assistance of the
winery encouraging to produce grapes that allows making the required wine.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Industry 189
Then, with a focus on the value chain, activities and actors involved in the
chain are presented. In this regard, the logic of a traffic light (red, critical;
yellow, to be improved; and green, in good condition) can mean that small
companies are the ones with the largest shortcomings in general (yellow and
red) in both specific chain activities and the overall support. In general, large
wineries have few shortcomings to stay and grow in this competitive market
(Fig. 8.1).
mmorag@uchile.cl
190 G. M. Mora
Support Activities
Primary Activities
8.3 B
usiness Strategies for Marketing, Labeling
and Communicating with Consumers
In the 1970s, buying wine in Chile was relatively simple, because it could be
found in a liquor store or supermarket, bottled in 750 ml or 1 liter (at that
time was the family wine) or larger format (5 liters of glass containers placed
in a wicker mesh, which have now evolved to the package pet). There was no
wine in boxes (bag in box), and the supply was very limited in terms of trade-
marks; there was no internet and promotion/advertising, which is why the
source of information was the shop and talk to the clerk, something simple.
Currently, the search for information is more complex, mainly due to the
diversity of products both on shops and on virtual platforms. Moreover, the
available supply has changed a lot, starting with the rapid development of
supermarkets and high participation of food retailing (Reardon and Berdegué
2002). They have become the main shopping plaza wines. Along these lines,
there are supermarkets oriented to sell differentiated products and others
selling generic products. There are also specialty shops, which aimed at high-
income segments of the market, where they offer a wide range of wines,
including imported wines, and they are located in areas with residents who
belong to a high socioeconomic status. With respect to the on-trade, the offer
is available mainly at restaurants and hotels, which charge prices between 30%
and 100% more than the off-trade channels (supermarket, specialty store,
liquor stores).
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Industry 191
mmorag@uchile.cl
192 G. M. Mora
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Industry 193
wine; “modern millennium” review the available supply and pay attention
to package design and labeling; “involved” appreciate the wine and buy
larger quantities of wine; “basic or essential” buy ordinary wine, for low
price and higher-frequency purchase and consumption; and “traditional
baby boomers” are now more affluent, interested in the product, and look-
ing for differentiation when there are special occasions. However, even
when it was found, the existence of these segments in the Chilean market
segments “involved” and “basic or essential” are those that concentrate
more than 70% of this market, especially the latter.
Chilean wine consumers that belong to the millennium generation are simi-
lar to that described by Magistris et al. (2011) for the US millennium genera-
tion consumers, as people who are interested to try first and then buy and
consume. It can be achieved through tasting and evaluating the aroma and
flavor attributes, similar to that reported by Schmidt et al. (2013), who points
out that these are the most important when choosing wine attributes. In studies
conducted by Mora et al. (2008), Mora et al. (2010), Adasme et al. (2012) and
Mora et al. (2012b), it is a segment that is characterized by its skepticism about
wine, which could be associated with the millennium generation, according to
age, since the people described are relatively young. Currently the younger gen-
erations of Chilean wine consumers are more demanding in terms of informa-
tion. Consequently, people are increasingly buying reviewed wines from the
available supply, and if there is something that appeals to them, they buy it.
8.3.2 N
umber of Brands, Price Positioning and Volume
Segment
Lima (2015) makes an estimate of the domestic market share of the three larg-
est wineries in Chile (Concha y Toro, San Pedro and Santa Rita), considering
all their brands and subsidiaries, according to the sales reported (for both cur-
rent and premium wines) on their balance sheets and reports to the authori-
ties. It is estimated that these three vineyards accounted for 87% of the
domestic market in 2014 (85% in 2013) and sales focused mainly on bottling
and packaging formats. It should be noted that those three main vineyards
indicated virtually no wine in bulk format sold in the domestic and interna-
tional markets. Then, the information and prices listed are shown.
For Concha y Toro, one can say that it is a company facing all segments of
the market, since the icon wines, led by Carmín de Peumo satisfying the ultra-
premium segment on the top, are much above Tocornal boxed wines, Clos de
Pirque and Fressco Cooler, which are placed at the bottom segment of popu-
lar wines (Table 8.7).
mmorag@uchile.cl
194 G. M. Mora
Table 8.7 Concha y Toro Winery: segment, brand and price of their wines
Price in dollars
Segment Brand 2014
Ultra premium Carmín de Peumo 133.3
Gravas del Maipo 73.8
Don Melchor 110.7
Terrunyo 29.8
Amelia 29.8
Super premium Marqués de Casa Concha 16.3
Gran Reserva Serie Riberas 10.3
Premium Trío 7.4
Casillero del Diablo 5.9
Late Harvest 3.5
Sparkling Subercaseaux 5.2
Varietal Sunrise 3.1
Santa Emiliana 2.8
Bi-varietal Frontera 2.8
Popular Exportación 1.9
Exportación Selecto 2.1
Clos de Pirque 1.9
Tocornal 1.6
Fressco Cooler 1.6
Note: Exchange rate at 17 February 2016: 704.92 Chilean pesos per dollar
Source: Central Bank of Chile
8.3.3 C
ommercial and Business Strategies of Chilean
Wineries
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Industry 195
mmorag@uchile.cl
196 G. M. Mora
the type of clients and their respective preferred product segment. During
2014, the company claims to have made great efforts in advertising their great
reserve brands, Clos de Pirque, Casillero del Diablo and Marques de Casa
Concha, through campaigns on radio, television and press, that is, wines that
are below $12 a bottle.
The strategy states that Concha y Toro seeks to sustain attractive growth rates
and to achieve greater brand penetration and visibility in different markets.
Therefore, it has developed a wide range of products seeking to participate in
different market segments, offering good-quality wines at competitive prices.
They have focused mainly on the growth of the “Premium” segment, which
according to reports is attractive given its growth potential and prices, allow-
ing them to improve their sales mix and increase its average sales price.
Following this strategy, Concha y Toro has invested nearly $407 billion pesos
in the last ten years in land, vineyards, infrastructure and other businesses to
increase their own production. They also have constantly developed new
products, research into new varieties and incorporate new production valleys.
As for the commercial area, Concha y Toro notes that it has strengthened its
global distribution network with the help of new own regional offices in key
markets. At the same time, they indicate that in Argentina they have followed
the same business model they have used in Chile since the Trivento winery has
grown steadily in exports, taking advantage of the penetration of Argentine
wines in major markets. The budget for 2015 is around US $50 million,
which is planned to be allocated to support for future sales growth through
the planting of new vineyards and expansion of productive capacity. Concha
y Toro intends to continue planting new vineyards and the corresponding
developing new infrastructure necessary on Chilean and the US grounds.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Industry 197
not vary substantially from one year to the next, since the list of producers
remains the same for years. The criteria used to choose the producers are
the geographical location, the grape variety and the agricultural methods.
To guarantee quality, Concha y Toro offers technical assistance based on
criteria similar to those used at its own vineyards. The company also aims
to make purchases in small wineries that produce wine.
The winery San Pedro Tarapaca (VSPT) believes that it competes primarily
against Concha y Toro and Santa Rita, and their competitive strength is based
on a broad product portfolio, well-known brands and well-established distri-
bution networks. In 2014, Concha y Toro and Santa Rita had a market share
of approximately 27% and 31%, respectively. Along with these competitors,
San Pedro Tarapaca considers that it also competes with Santa Carolina and
medium wineries, such as Undurraga and Cousiño Macul, and small wine
producers that make up the informal market of wine in Chile.
8.4 Conclusions
Chile is a major player in the wine world trade occupying the fifth place on
worldwide exports with more than 1800 million dollars. There are more than
137,000 hectares of mainly French varieties, including Cabernet Sauvignon
and Sauvignon Blanc. There are over 400 wineries, but just 10% account for
more than 50% of total exports. The domestic market accounts for approxi-
mately 20% of the total selling, and the rest (80%) is gone to exports. The
main international markets are the UK, the USA, China, Japan and Brazil.
Exports of bottled wines with designation of origin and sparkling wines have
had successful economic performance over the last five years. The vineyard
area stretches from north to south along 900 km, and the areas of greatest
wine importance are in the regions of O’Higgins and Maule, both located in
the Central Valley.
Chile has achieved worldwide significant recognition. Every day the entire
industry searches ways to improve competitiveness and makes progress in the
development of the various components of the value chain. This requires fur-
ther research, development and innovation, which require support, commit-
ment and assessment of applied research by companies that are directly or
indirectly related to the wine industry and also from the State. The search for
a better value chain and production chains necessarily involves the generation
of an accurate multidimensional knowledge that responds effectively to the
solution of the problems of this industry making it increasingly competitive.
mmorag@uchile.cl
198 G. M. Mora
References
Adasme, C., M. Mora, and M. Sánchez. 2012. Segmentación del consumidor de vino
orgánico en Talca, Chile. In: Marketing agroalimentario Aplicaciones metodológi-
cas estudios de casos en el contexto global. Ed. Pearson, México.
Agricultural Decree N° 464, 1994, establishes viticultural zoning and sets standards
for its use (official journal of May 26, 1995, last official daily modification n °
38.268 of September 22, 2005).
Alvarado, R. 1999. Los caminos del vino. Ed. Universitaria. 131 pp.
Del Pozo, J. 1998. Historia del vino Chileno: Desde 1850 hasta hoy. Ed. Universitaria.
Farinelli, F. 2013. Innovation and learning dynamics in the Chilean and Argentine wine
industries. AAWE working paper no. 145. Disponibleen: http://www.wine-eco-
nomics.org/aawe/wp-content/uploads/2013/12/AAWE_WP145.pdf
Gilbert, J. 2014. Chile país del vino: Historia de la Industria Vitivinícola, 1492–2014.
Ed. Universitaria. 300 p.
Gneezy A. and U. Gneezy. 2011. Price-based expectations, advances in consumer
research, volume 38. Ed. Darren W. Dahl, Gita V. Johar, and Stijn M.J. Van
Osselaer. Duluth: Association for Consumer Research. Disponible en: http://
www.acrwebsite.org/volumes/v38/acr_v38_15794.pdf
Hollebeek, L., S. Jaeger, R. Brodie, and A. Balemi. 2007. The influence of involve-
ment on purchase intention for new world wine. Food Quality and Preference 18:
1033–1049.
Lima, J. 2015. Estudio de caracterización de la cadena de producción y comercial-
ización de la agroindustria vitivinícola: estructura, agentes y prácticas. Estudio
encargado por Oficina de Estudios y Política Agraria del Ministerio de Agricultura
de Chile. 209 pp.
Lockshin, L., W. Jarvis, F. d’Hauteville, and J.P. Perrouty. 2006. Simulations from
discrete choice experiments to measure consumer sensitivity to brand, region,
price, and awards in wine choice. Food Quality and Preference 17: 166–178.
Lockshin, L., S. Mueller, J. Louviere, L. Francis, and P. Osidacz. 2009. Development
of a new method to measure how consumers choose wine. The Australian and New
Zealand Wine Industry Journal 24: 35–40.
Magistris, T., E. Groot, A. Gracia, and L.M. Albisu. 2011. Do Millennial generation’s
wine preferences of the “new world” differ from the “old world”? International
Journal of Wine Business Research 23 (2): 145–160.
Martínez-Carrasco, L., M. Brugarolas, F.J. Del Campo, and A. Martínez. 2006.
Influence of purchase place and consumption frequency over quality wine prefer-
ences. Food Quality and Preference 17: 315–327.
Mora, M. 2004. Estudio de las actitudes y percepciones de los consumidores hacia los
vinos de las Denominaciones de Origen de la Comunidad Valenciana. Tesis
Doctoral. Departamento de Estudios Económicos y Financieros, Universidad
Miguel Hernández de Elche, 270 p.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Industry 199
———. 2012a. Los grandes aportes de la agronomía en los últimos 20 años. In: Un
siglo de compromisos con la innovación científica y tecnológica de la agricultura
1910–2010. Sociedad Agronómica de Chile, pp. 85–102.
———. 2012b. Conociendo al consumidor chileno de vinos para construir una rel-
ación comercial de mayor plazo relativo. Encuentro Nacional de Facultades de
Administración y Economía – ENEFA 2012. Universidad de Talca, 21–23 de
noviembre de 2012.
Mora, M., V. Padilla, and J. Espinoza. 2004a. Los países emergentes en el mercado
mundial vitivinícola: el vino chileno, situación actual perspectivas y estrategia.
Revista de Enología y Viticultura Profesional. N° 92:5–26. Año XV. Mayo – Junio.
2004.
Mora, M., M. Brugarolas, L. Martínez-Carrasco, and J. A. Espinoza. 2004b. Actitudes
hacia los vinos de Denominación de Origen (D.O.) en la Comunidad Valenciana
Revista ITEA (Información Técnica Económica Agraria). Asociación
Interprofesional para el Desarrollo Agrario. pp. 119–123. Noviembre 2004.
Número Extraordinario. Zaragoza. España.
Mora, M., C. Juri, R. Marchant, and N. Magner. 2008. Factores y atributos que
explican la lealtad del cliente de vinotintoembotellado en las tres comunas de
mayor ingreso de la Región Metropolitana, Chile. II Congreso Regional de
Economía Agraria – XIII Congreso de Economistas Agrarios de Chile, 5 y 7 de
noviembre de 2008 en Montevideo, Uruguay.
Mora, M., N. Magner, and R. Marchant. 2010. Segmentación de mercado de acu-
erdo a estilos de vida de consumidores de vino orgánico de la Región Metropolitana
de Chile. Revista IDESIA 28 (3): 25–34.
Mora, M., S. Boza, Y. Aravena, and B. Schnettler. 2012. You can add functional value
of an attribute on the label of a bottle of wine? 5th European Conference on
Sensory and Consumer Research, Bern, Switzerland, 9–12, September 2012.
Mora, M., C. Adasme, and R. Escobedo. 2013. The Chilean wine market: Comparing
wine sales at supermarkets and specialty wine shops. In: Wine case business case
studies thirteen cases from the real world of wine business management. The Wine
Appreciate Wild. Academy of Wine Business Research (AWBR), 97–108 p.
Mora, M., B. Schnettler, and G. Lobos. 2014. El gran crecimiento de la Industria
Vitivinícola Chilena. In: La economía del vinos en España y en el Mundo. Serie
Economía 23: 581–623.
Panzone. 2012. Alcohol tax, price-quality proxy and discounting: A reason why alco-
hol taxes may rebound. Journal of Agricultural Economics 63 (3): 715–736.
Reardon, T., and J. Berdegué. 2002. The rapid rise of supermarkets in latinamerica:
Challenges and opportunities for development. Development Policy Review 20 (4):
371–388.
Schmidt, T., R. Bradley, and J. Taber. 2013. Consumer valuation of environmentally
friendly production practices in wines, considering asymmetric information and
sensory effects. Journal of Agricultural Economics 64 (2): 483–504.
mmorag@uchile.cl
200 G. M. Mora
Schnettler, B., and A. Rivera. 2003. Características del proceso de decisión de compra
de vino en la IX Región de La Araucanía. Ciencia e InvestigaciónAgraria 30 (1):
1–14.
Schnettler, B., H. Miranda, J. Sepúlveda, N. Mills, M.J. González, M. Mora, and
G. Lobos. 2012. Acceptance of national and store brands of wine by supermarket
consumers in the south of Chile. Ciência e Técnica Vitivinícola 27 (1): 3–15.
Zago. 2007. The design of quality pricing in procurement settings via technology
estimation, working paper, Universidad de Verona. Disponible en: http://idei.fr/
sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/fpi/papers_2006/zago.pdf
Websites
mmorag@uchile.cl
9
The South African Wine Industry
Nick Vink
9.1 Introduction
A number of aspects of the structure of the South African wine industry are
of interest to any speculation about the likely futures of the industry. These
include the structure of farm sizes, the relationship between what was tradi-
tionally called ‘the trade’ or producer wholesalers (brand owners) and the erst-
while cooperatives, the dominance of one firm in the market for branded
wine, and the competitiveness of the industry as a whole, that is, including
the upstream and downstream industries that service the sector. In this chap-
ter, the origin and consequences of these are explained, to give a clearer pic-
ture of the likely future trajectory of the industry.
N. Vink (*)
Department of Agricultural Economics, Stellenbosch University,
Stellenbosch, South Africa
e-mail: nv@sun.ac.za
mmorag@uchile.cl
202 N. Vink
The new Cape always remained a genuinely colonial society, which could not
achieve the autonomy and self-sufficiency of the San and Khoikhoi societies
which preceded it. The settlers provided both the impetus for its growth and the
measure of its dependence. The birth of the settler community was linked with
the economic value to Europe of the Cape’s resources, a harbour with fresh
water where fresh vegetables and meat could be produced for passing ships. The
existence of the ‘Tavern of the Seas’, the town of De Kaap [Cape Town] and its
hinterland of corn and wine farming in the south-western Cape, was always
dependent on its usefulness to Europe, expressed in the size of the Cape market
constituted by the garrison and the visiting ships.1
Europeans knew about the Cape since 1488 when the Portuguese seafarer
Bartholomew Diaz reached the Cape on his way to opening the Asian spice
trade. However, the Portuguese had little interest in a settlement there because
they (Katzen 1982: 187)2:
[C]rossed the Indian Ocean on the south-west monsoon on their voyages from
Lisbon to Goa or Cochin, usually stopping at Mozambique on the way out, St
Helena or the Azores on the way home.
In other words the Cape was too close to the origin of both outward and
homebound journeys.
The Dutch and the English traveled around the Cape at the same time and
with the same objective: to break the Portuguese monopoly of the spice trade
(Terreblanche 2014). They both aimed at the weak point of the Portuguese
monopoly, namely, South-East Asia rather than further north in China. The
Cape was conveniently almost halfway on this new route (Katzen 1982)—
thus the creation of the refreshment station on 6 April 1652 by the Dutch
East India Company (the VOC). However, the settlement soon proved too
expensive to run, so in 1657 the Company started to hand out land and cheap
loans to free burghers to encourage settlement, in the process disregarding the
land rights of the indigenous population (Terreblanche 2014).
Unfortunately, these free burghers also wanted to be free to take on slaves.
Williams (2016) explains that Jan van Riebeeck, the first Commander of the
settlement, took less than two months after his arrival to ask the company
1
The total settler and slave population of the Cape remained lower than 1000 people through to around
1720, while the average number of sailors and soldiers aboard ships in the Cape Town harbor numbered
more than 6000 per year, hence an export market (Boshoff and Fourie 2010).
2
Katzen quotes from Boxer (2001). This is a translation (originally published in 1959) of a Portuguese
publication by Bernardo Gomes de Bruto on famous Portuguese shipwreck stories.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The South African Wine Industry 203
authorities in Batavia (present-day Jakarta) for slaves ‘to do the dirtiest and
heaviest work in place of the Netherlanders’. As the production of wine con-
stituted the largest source of revenue to the VOC for much of the first cen-
tury, the wine farmers were politically influential. However, the VOC would
not allow the enslavement of the indigenous ‘free’ Khoi, as they wanted to
trade cattle with them. Slaves were, therefore, brought in, the first coming
from what is now Angola, but most thereafter from the east. Thus, in the
words of Williams (2016: 895) ‘The elementary social and political relations
of a slave economy and a slave society had been put in place –slaves and their
masters producing wine and wheat under the authority of a merchant
company’.
The second long expansion took place during the late 1700s and was also
dependent on the strategic location of the Cape. In this case, Britain’s compe-
tition with France for colonial possessions in Asia (specifically India) during
the time of the Napoleonic Wars resulted in a French attempt to occupy the
Cape. This was thwarted by Britain, which occupied the Cape in 1795 (and
again in 1803) in order to keep their link to India open (Van Jaarsveld 1975).
The resulting boost to the British economy spilled over to wine exports, which
were given preferential access to the British market through to 1860 (Vink
et al. 2018a).
The third long expansion in the South African wine industry coincided
with the political changes of the 1990s that marked the end of apartheid,
ushered in democracy, and resulted in growth in per capita income for the
first time in decades. These changes marked a complete break from the past
which, in the case of the wine industry, had been shaped by the Land Acts; by
the establishment of a cooperative, the KWV,3 in 1918 that eventually gained
statutory power over the industry; and by a concerted effort among a small
group of pioneering wine farmers to improve the quality of wine produced in
the late 1960s and early 1970s.
Apartheid was introduced into South Africa as formal government policy
after the National Party won the elections in 1948. With these elections, the
government inherited a land dispensation that rested on two important laws,
namely, the Natives Land Act of 1913 and the Native Trust and Land Act of
1936. These cemented the dispossession of land from black people that had
occurred since the first settlement (Delius and Beinart 2013). They had two
important implications for the industry, namely, that land ownership would
3
‘Ko-operatieweWynboukundigeunie van Suid-Afrika’ (later the ‘Ko-öperatieveWijnbouwersVereniging
van Zuid-Afrika, Beperkt’ KWV, or Cooperative Wine Farmers’ Association of South Africa, Limited).
mmorag@uchile.cl
204 N. Vink
be segregated (the 1913 Act stipulated that black people could only buy or
lease land from other black people, and vice versa) and that the land rights of
black people would be attenuated (e.g. their ‘ownership’ could not be used to
secure a mortgage and did not qualify as property rights for the purpose of
voting). Thus the Acts served as the basis for the suppression of black farming
in an attempt to ensure a steady supply of (cheap) labor to the mines and to
the farms of white South Africa (Greyling et al. 2018). At the same time,
white farmers were supported in a myriad of different ways, including legisla-
tion to support the establishment and growth of cooperatives in the form of
tax concessions as well as the principle of ‘forced cooperation’ as a means of
countering free riding.
The KWV was established in 1918 against the wishes of ‘the trade’ (today’s
producer wholesalers4) (Van Zyl 1993). The aim was to counter the weaker
bargaining power of grape growers (and their cooperatives where these
existed). Members had to sell through KWV, which would in turn declare a
surplus annually, which would be delivered free of charge and turned into
spirits for disposal at the discretion of the organization. The restriction was
that no produce could be sold on the domestic market at lower than the mini-
mum price. The income would be used to finance the purchase of distilleries,
vats, and buildings, and profits would be distributed to members on a pro rata
basis. Ironically, the trade agreed to distill and store the surplus on behalf of
KWV, and to purchase only from KWV. This was in exchange for an under-
taking from KWV not to compete in the market with their products and not
to deal directly with their clients. This agreement was eventually taken up in
legislation in 1924 and formed the basis of a symbiotic relationship between
the two parties until the 1990s.
However, the agreement proved to be ineffectual until KWV was granted
statutory powers in a process that started in 1924, mainly because grape grow-
ers sold directly to the trade at less than the minimum price when it suited
them (Van Zyl 1993). These statutory powers were expanded over time and
eventually included the ability to set a minimum or floor price, to limit pro-
duction by means of quotas, to force sales of all wine through the KWV, and
to declare an annual wine surplus that had to be delivered to KWV free of
charge. KWV also implemented production quotas in an attempt to gain
control over the surplus even before it was produced. In the process, KWV
4
The industry body that represents their interests is the South African Liquor Brand Owners Association
(SALBA), earlier known as the Cape Wine and Spirit Institute (CWSI).
mmorag@uchile.cl
The South African Wine Industry 205
mmorag@uchile.cl
206 N. Vink
90 000 tons of grapes produced by 6 000 grape growers and wine farmers. Members of producer
cooperatives produce 85% of the grape harvest
Wine must
Wine KWV
76%
Fig. 9.1 The flow of product in the South African industry, 1982
mmorag@uchile.cl
The South African Wine Industry 207
5
Data in this section are from the annual publication of South African Wine Industry Information
and Systems (SAWIS) (http://www.sawis.co.za/info/annualpublication.php) unless otherwise specified.
6
The author of this chapter was an independent member of this Committee.
mmorag@uchile.cl
208 N. Vink
Numerically, the South African wine industry has always been dominated by
grape growers, with never more than 20% of them having their own cellars
on-farm to turn the grapes into wine. Their numbers ranged from some
6000 in the early 1980s to little more than 3000 today. Instead, most wine
was made by the producer wholesalers (so-called because they also produced
some grapes, but mostly bought in grapes, wine must, or wine, branded the
product, and sold it into the retail market). The largest of these in 1990 were
Stellenbosch Farmers Winery (SFW), Distillers Corporation, Gilbey’s, and
Douglas Green, all well-known purveyors of wine at that time. The current
structure of these entities is, however, a product of the ‘beer wars’ of the 1970s
(Mager 2008).
South African Breweries (SAB) was formed in the mid-1950s out of a num-
ber of smaller breweries. In 1960 it branched into the wine business by assum-
ing control of SFW as a means of safeguarding its interests as an ‘English’
At a time when the exchange rate was in the order of $1 = ZAR4.50 – R4.70, that is, around $40
7
million.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The South African Wine Industry 209
mmorag@uchile.cl
210 N. Vink
Table 9.1 Concentration in the market: a ‘new world’ comparison, 2014 (%)
New South
Argentina Australia Chile Zealand Africa USA World
Market shares (%)
Largest winery 27 16 31 23 31 23 12
Second largest 14 9 30 11 3 15 8
winery
Third largest 12 9 29 10 2 13 6
winery
Fourth largest 7 7 1 9 1 6 3
winery
Combined 60 41 91 53 36 44 30
share
All others 40 59 9 47 64 56 70
Herfindahl-Hirsch Index (HHI)
Largest winery 252.81 729.00 930.25 547.56 930.25 524.41 151.29
Second largest 86.49 198.81 876.16 129.96 6.25 210.25 67.24
winery
Third largest 84.64 144.00 846.81 90.25 2.56 166.41 40.96
winery
Fourth largest 49.00 43.56 1.96 75.69 1.96 31.36 10.24
winery
Total 472.94 1115.37 2655.18 843.46 941.02 932.43 269.73
Source: Based on Anderson and Pinilla (2017)
In Chile (Concha y Toro) and South Africa (Distell), the largest enterprise
has a market share of above 30%, far higher than their next competitors, New
Zealand and the USA, with 23% each. However, large enterprises dominate
the Chilean market, with the combined market share of the four biggest
operators above 90%, which is in turn higher than any of the other countries,
as shown by the HHI which shows that Chile’s is the only uncompetitive
domestic market among these countries. The South African market is unusual
because, even though it has the lowest market share for the four largest enter-
prises at 36%, it has a higher HHI than all except Australia and Chile. Thus,
in South Africa, one firm dominates the domestic market, given that the
country imports less than 0.5% of domestic consumption.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The South African Wine Industry 211
hardly any cooperatives left in South African agriculture and, where they have
survived in the wine industry, it is more for convenience that out of any con-
viction that it is a superior business form.
Most of the cooperatives established under this legislation were in the field
crop industries, that is, maize and wheat, and their main purpose was to sup-
ply inputs (including credit) to their farmer members. There were fewer coop-
eratives that took responsibility for processing farm products—these were
prevalent in livestock products (dairy) and notably in wine, where wine grape
farmers formed cooperatives to process the grapes into wine. There were 5
such cooperatives in 1915, 20 in 1945, and 69 by 1975, a number that
remained through to 2000, that is, during the period when they started to
change enterprise form from cooperatives to joint stock companies. These
cooperatives handled 89.9% of the wine grape harvest in 1976.
The process of conversion of cooperatives to joint stock companies should
be based on sound business principles: Sikuka (2010) summarizes the argu-
ments that have been used, including the value of equity, corporate acquisi-
tion, the cost of equity, and the efficiency of the governance structure. Cook
(1995) argues that cooperatives develop through different stages and come to
a point where they have to choose between exit, continuation, or transition.
However, as virtually all of South Africa’s agricultural cooperatives (including
the wine cooperatives) transformed at more or less the same time, it is clear
that the driving force was rather the fear that the new government was going
to relieve them of assets such as grain silos and cellar machinery that were
built up with support from the former regime.
In many cases, the wine cooperatives are still operating in the same way as
they did in the past, especially the operation of pool systems, whereby all wine
of a certain type is pooled regardless of origin, and farmers are then paid out
the average of the pool. This gives rise to familiar problems (Vink 2012), first
of which is ‘hiding in the pool’ or adverse selection. In a pool system, the
individual farmer has an incentive to deliver a product whose quality is below
the average quality of the pool (and hence costs less to produce), and this
works against all attempts to improve quality. Of course, the managers of a
pool have to contend with fixed technology: they are operating a processing
plant that may not be able to cater for small production runs, typically the
case with higher-quality produce. There is also the problem that managers are
tempted to overcompensate themselves when calculating the deductible cost
of administering the pool.
mmorag@uchile.cl
212 N. Vink
The picture of a magnificent Cape Dutch homestead rising out of serried trel-
lised ranks of green vines defines the image of itself that the industry has long
propagated both domestically and overseas. The first of these wine farms was
Groot Constantia, founded in 1685 and the oldest wine-producing farm in
South Africa. These private cellars crush less than 25% of the total grape har-
vest in the country but capture an obviously larger proportion of the value of
wine sold and exported (a statistic that is unfortunately not readily available).
What we do know is that the off-consumption market is about 50–60% of
the total domestic market and that the domestic market for basic wine is 56
times larger than the domestic market for ultra-premium wines in volume
terms and 9 times larger in value terms. It is also three times larger in value
terms than the market for super-premium and ultra-premium wines put
together.
These wine farms were generally unregulated and without legal protection
until the Wine of Origin system was introduced in legislation in 1973 in
accordance with the Wine, Other Fermented Beverages and Spirits Act, 1957,
largely because of the need to comply with EU regulations. It is in a sense a
hybrid scheme, somewhere between the extremes of control found in
Burgundy and Bordeaux and the much more relaxed rules found in the USA
and Australia. It protects not only the geographic origin of a wine but also the
cultivar and vintage.
The smallest demarcation is a ‘single vineyard wine’, where the vineyard
may not exceed 6 hectares. This is followed by an estate wine, which has its
own production cellar on the farming unit where the wine is produced: when
this appellation is used, it means that the wine was produced from grapes
grown on that unit. The next level is a ward, which describes a small demar-
cated area which may or may not fall under a district, which is the better
known geographical description, and includes the well-known Stellenbosch
and Paarl. Different districts then constitute a region, such as Klein Karoo and
Coastal Region.
One of the more interesting changes over the past few decades since the
introduction of this scheme is that most of the ‘estates’ have deregistered from
this appellation (hence the more accurate ‘producer cellars’ because the con-
straint that grapes had to be produced on the farm itself meant that these
enterprises could not fully exploit the value of their brands). Producers such
as Beyerskloof and Kanonkop have made full use of this opportunity, using
their brand image as super-premium wine producers to bring in high-volume
mmorag@uchile.cl
The South African Wine Industry 213
second labels that sell at a premium in the market. So, for example, in 1991
there were 77 estates and 59 ‘non-estates’ among the producer sellers, while by
the year 2000 there were 92 estates and 185 ‘non-estates’. Today there are no
more than a handful of estates left.
The producer cellars are even more geographically concentrated than the
industry itself. Stellenbosch (which until 2017 included the Cape Town win-
eries around Groot Constantia and Durbanville) had 16.36% of the country’s
vines and 16.02% of the vineyard area, but 44% of all the private cellars.
Most of the wine grapes grown in South Africa are grown on farms that pro-
duce grapes and not wine (and most of these farms produce grapes as one of
a range of different enterprises, i.e. not many actually specialize in viticulture).
The number of these grape growers has been declining quite rapidly: from
more than 6000 registered growers in the 1970s to around 4600 in 1994 (and
fewer than 3200 in 2016). However, most of these are small-scale growers. In
1997, for example, half of them delivered or pressed fewer than 100 tons of
grapes, declining to 40% in 2016. At the same time grape producers were
investing less: the area under vines has declined from above 103,000 hectares
to some 95,000 currently. Furthermore, in a system where vines are kept on
average for 20 years, the annual replacement should be 4%, that is, 20% of
the national vineyard should be equal to or less than 4 years old. Instead, this
proportion was 12.9% in 1997 and only 7.3% currently.
The cultivar composition of the South African industry also tells of the
impact of the measures that KWV put in place to manage the surplus. The
three most prevalent grape cultivars in the industry were the high-bearing
Chenin Blanc, Palomino, and Colombar, represented 50% of the vineyard in
1975–1985, dropping to less than a third by 2005. By contrast, the plantings
of Sauvignon Blanc, Chardonnay, Cabernet Sauvignon, Shiraz, Merlot, and
Pinotage made up a derisory 5% of plantings in 1975 and were still less than
10% in 1990. Of course the Chenin Blanc planting of today is very different
from that of the earlier era, while the area under Palomino and Colombar is
now derisory.
mmorag@uchile.cl
214 N. Vink
Note that the process started a decade before the first democratic elections in 1994.
8
mmorag@uchile.cl
The South African Wine Industry 215
mmorag@uchile.cl
216 N. Vink
mentary purposes, hence as insurance rather than to boost yields), while more
dryland had a negative effect in the new areas but not the old. A higher pro-
portion of red to white grapes reduced efficiency in the old regions but not the
new. And finally, more old vines as a share of the total, suggesting low levels
of replacement of the vine stock, only had a negative effect in the new regions.
There is, therefore, evidence that farmers in the new regions have tended to go
for higher yields at the expense of quality, whereas the old regions have tried
to maintain their reputation for quality, a strategy that was wrong, at least in
the short term.
There is also no real sign of an inverse farm size productivity relationship, a
point made two decades ago by Townsend et al. (1998). For example, while
the average vineyard increased by 55% between 1995 and 2015, the yield of
wine grapes increased by 100% despite the shift to lower-yielding varieties,
and the yield of wine increased by 75%.
South Africa is known for its highly sophisticated financial services sector. For
example, the country was ranked 53rd out of 63 countries in the World
Competitiveness Report of the World Economic Forum (2017), while the
financial services sector ranked 31st (Schwab 2017). However, this was not
always the case, and the wine industry more or less had to finance its own
growth out of the devastation wrought by phylloxera (1886), tariff-restricted
access to the market in Johannesburg in the period leading up to and during
the Boer War (1899–1902) and the Great Depression (Vink et al. 2018a).
We have shown that one of the main instruments around this capital con-
straint was the producer cooperatives (aided by government loans and legisla-
tion that supported the cooperatives). However, because the cooperatives
traded mostly in bulk wine, their main modus operandi was to manage a pool
system, largely because their priority was quantity rather than quality. This
became a self-fulfilling prophecy because the wineries themselves were built to
deal with rapid throughput rather than with small batch production. As a
result, the farmers’ grapes were aggregated into pools with a wide range of
qualities, and little differentiation in price, leaving individual producers with
the age-old temptation to ‘hide in the pool’, as was shown earlier. Thus the
solution to the problem of a lack of capital became the reason why farmers
could not build up sufficient capital to produce higher-quality grapes.
One of the consequences of the export boom that commenced after the
end of apartheid was the establishment of new grape production units in the
mmorag@uchile.cl
The South African Wine Industry 217
industry, but this time with a difference: while the total number of producers
was declining rapidly (and mostly among the smaller producers, as has been
shown), the number of private cellars was increasing, and there was little sub-
stitution between these; in other words there has been no increase in the
numbers of grape growers in the industry. While this does not change much
in terms of fragmentation, it is interesting to speculate on its impact on those
representative institutions that have the grape growers as their base member-
ship, such as the industry body VinPro, and the relative influence of the pro-
ducer cellars in industry initiatives.
What is evident currently, though, is a lack of leadership in the industry
with regard to transformation, including land reform, even though a major
initiative was launched more than a decade ago with the establishment of the
South Africa Wine and Brandy Company (SAWB), an industry body whose
main task was to influence government policy on behalf of the industry and
in the process to support the work of the business units (SAWIS, Wines of
South Africa (WOSA), and the Wine Industry Network for Expertise and
Technology (Winetech)) with a focus on transformation of the industry. To
this end, SAWB designed the Wine Industry Plan (WIP). Furthermore, a
BEE program and scorecard were proposed, in accordance with the govern-
ment’s Broad-Based Black Economic Empowerment (B-BBEE program), but
these initiatives came to naught when SAWB, which had just been trans-
formed into the South African Wine Industry Council (SAWIC) was sum-
marily terminated in 2008.
One of the unique features of the South African wine industry is its geo-
graphic concentration around Cape Town and the Cape Peninsular, with
some 90% of the vineyards less than 200 km from downtown Cape Town.
From a wine tourism perspective, the industry is even more fortunate, as the
epicenter of good wine production is right on the city’s doorstep, with the
Durbanville Hills and Cape Town wards and the Stellenbosch and Paarl
District all within an hour’s drive. These four demarcations have a total of
almost 300 private cellars, that is, some 60% of the industry total. Furthermore,
while there are only about 50 old Cape Dutch farmhouses left, these are all in
close proximity to Cape Town.
The geography of the wine industry has been changing globally over the
past decades, arguably because of climate, a factor that has been prevalent in
the wine business for a long time (Storchmann 2011), and more specifically
mmorag@uchile.cl
218 N. Vink
Figure 9.2 shows the international competitiveness of the South African wine
industry since 1985, measured in terms of the revealed comparative advantage
South Africa
7.0
6.0
5.0
4.0
3.0
2.0
1.0
0.0
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
Fig. 9.2 South Africa’s RCA in wine. (Source: Anderson and Pinilla 2018)
mmorag@uchile.cl
The South African Wine Industry 219
9.4.5 Summary
There are a number of other aspects of the industry that should properly also
be addressed in more detail, such as the lack of progress with land reform, the
position of farm workers, and technology development and adoption, but
space constraints preclude such discussion. In summary, then, the South
African wine industry grew from the 17th largest wine producer by volume in
1910 to the 8th largest today. However, this relatively rapid growth in output
was largely the result of growth in relatively low-quality high-yielding wine
grape varietals.
At the same time, domestic wine consumption has been stagnant for the
past five decades at a level of 8 to 10 liters per capita, excepting for a brief five
years (1971–1976) after the establishment of the Stellenbosch Wine Route
and the introduction of the Wine of Origin Scheme. The market for wine was
clearly limited by the small middle-class market, which at the time consisted
mmorag@uchile.cl
220 N. Vink
mmorag@uchile.cl
The South African Wine Industry 221
5. The South African industry has hardly transformed in the 24 years since
democracy, but the government has not sanctioned it for this lack of prog-
ress. The wine industry is no exception in this regard (nor is the agricul-
tural sector as a whole) but industry expectations of government support
must be tempered by realism about the ability of government to continu-
ally ignore this lack of progress.
References
Anderson, K., and V. Pinilla (with the assistance of A. J. Holmes). 2017. Annual
database of global wine markets, 1835 to 2015, freely available in Excel at the
University of Adelaide’s Wine Economics Research Centre. www.adelaide.edu.au/
wine-econ/databases.
Ashenfelter, Orley, and Karl Storchmann. 2016. Climate change and wine: A review
of the economic implications. Journal of Wine Economics 11 (1): 105–138.
Bonnardot, V., and V.A. Carey. 2008. Observed climatic trends in South African
wine regions and potential implications for viticulture. In Proceedings of the VIIth
international viticultural terroir congress 19–23 May 2008, Nyon, Switzerland. 1,
216–221, AgroscopeChangins-Wädenswil.
Boshoff, W.H., and J. Fourie. 2010. The significance of the Cape trade route to eco-
nomic activity in the Cape Colony: A medium-term business cycle analysis.
European Review of Economic History 14 (3): 469–503.
Boxer, C.R. 2001. The tragic history of the sea. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota
Press.
Business Day. 1997. Johannesburg.
Conradie, Beatrice, Jenifer Piesse, Colin Thirtle, and Nick Vink. 2018. Labour
demand in the post-apartheid South African wine industry. Journal of Agricultural
Economics, forthcoming. doi: https://doi.org/10.1111/1477-9552.12270.
Cook, M.L. 1995. The future of U.S. agricultural cooperatives: A neo-institutional
approach. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 (5): 1153–1159.
Crotty, Ann. 2016. Battle looms over KWV sale. Johannesburg, Business Day. October
25. Available at https://www.businesslive.co.za/bd/companies/retail-and-
consumer/2016-10-25-battle-looms-over-kwv-sale/. Accessed 8 May 2018.
Delius, Peter, and William Beinart. 2013. 1913 Land Act: A longer history of dispos-
session. Mail and Guardian, June 14. Available at https://mg.co.za/article/2013-
06-14-00-1913-land-act-a-longer-history-of-dispossession. Accessed 23 April
2018.
Donald, Kirsten A.M., Anne Fernandez, Kasey Claborn, Caroline Kuo, Nastassja
Koen, Heather Zar, and Dan J. Stein. 2017. The developmental effects of HIV
and alcohol: A comparison of gestational outcomes among babies from South
mmorag@uchile.cl
222 N. Vink
African communities with high prevalence of HIV and alcohol use. AIDS Research
and Therapy 14: 28.
Esterhuizen, D., and C.J. van Rooyen. 2006. An inquiry into factors impacting on
the competitiveness of the South African wine industry. Agrekon Volume 45 (4):
467–485.
Fin24. 2005. Available at https://www.fin24.com/Companies/KWV-Distell-shares-
at-highest-20050121. Accessed 8 May 2018.
Greyling, Jan, Nick Vink, and Emily van der Merwe. 2018. Gold: South African
agriculture’s transition from suppression to support (1886–1948). In Agricultural
development in the world periphery: A global economic history approach, ed. Vicente
Pinilla and Willebald. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan.
Katzen, M.F. 1982. White settlers and the origin of a new society, 1652–1778. In A
history of South Africa to 1870, ed. Monica Wilson and Leonard Thompson.
London: Croom Helm.
London, Leslie. 1999. The ‘dop’ system, alcohol abuse and social control amongst
farm workers in South Africa: A public health challenge. Social Science & Medicine
48 (10): 1407–1414.
Mager, Anne Kelk. 2008. Apartheid and business: Competition, monopoly and the
growth of the malted beer industry in South Africa. Business History 50 (3):
272–290.
Marcus, Tessa. 1989. Modernising super-exploitation: Restructuring South African agri-
culture. London: Zed Books.
May, Philip A., J. Phillip Gossage, Lesley E. Brooke, and Cudore L. Snel. 2005.
Maternal risk factors for fetal alcohol syndrome in the Western Cape Province of
South Africa: A population-based study. American Journal of Public Health 95 (7):
1190–1199.
Morss, Elliott R. 2017. The future of the global wine industry: Boxes, bulk and blends.
Available at http://www.morssglobalfinance.com. Accessed 29 May 2018.
Piesse, Jennifer, Beatrice Conradie, Colin Thirtle, and Nick Vink. 2018. Efficiency in
wine grape production: Comparing long-established and newly developed regions
of South Africa. Journal of Agricultural Economics 49: 203–212.
RSA. 1997. Report of the committee to investigate regulation of the wine and distillation
industry. Pretoria: Government of the Republic of South Africa.
SAWIS, various years. Wine industry statistics. Paarl: South African Wine Industry
Information and Systems.
Schwab, Klaus, ed. 2017. The global competitiveness report 2017–2018. Geneva:
World Economic Forum.
Sikuka, Wellington. 2010. The comparative performance of selected agribusiness
companies and cooperatives in the Western Cape, South Africa. Thesis submitted
in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the MScAgric (Agricultural Economics)
degree, Stellenbosch University.
Southall, Roger. 2004. Political change and the black middle class in democratic
South Africa. Canadian Journal of African Studies 38 (3): 521–542.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The South African Wine Industry 223
mmorag@uchile.cl
10
The Chinese Wine Industry
Linda Jiao and Shan Ouyang
10.1 Introduction
China is an emerging wine market experiencing rapid growth since the begin-
ning of the 2000s. This market is also a market in evolution, in every aspect,
from wine production to wine consumption. The cultivation of the vine in
China can be traced back to ancient times, when people described their enjoy-
ment of grape wine in poetry. Nowadays, China has come to be the world’s
second largest winegrower (by vineyard surface area), the sixth biggest wine
producer, and the fifth most important wine consumer in terms of volume
(OIV 2017). In addition, as we can observe from Fig. 10.1, the gap between
wine consumption and production, which is filled by imports, has been
expanding since the second half of the 2000s. Imported wine is a growing and
developing part of the Chinese wine market, due to the evolving consump-
tion behavior of Chinese wine drinkers. Regarding market size, according to
International Wine & Spirits Research (IWSR), China is predicted to become
the second largest wine market and the largest non-sparkling wine consumer
by 2020.
The wine-production sector is highly concentrated in China with leading
national wine groups providing a wide range of products which take over half
L. Jiao (*)
University of Bordeaux, Pessac, France
e-mail: linda.jiao@u-bordeaux.fr
S. Ouyang
Beijing Artix Investment Company Co., Ltd, Beijing, China
mmorag@uchile.cl
226 L. Jiao and S. Ouyang
10.00
8.00
6.00
4.00
2.00
0.00
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
Consumption Production
Fig. 10.1 Evolution of wine consumption and production in China. (Source: Cossllected
from OIV annual reports of World Vitiviniculture Situation and OIV Statistics, 2013–2017)
of the entire market. However, the small wineries in Ningxia have gained the
highest reputation among quality wine producers. In addition, the Chinese
domestic wine industry is characterized by a high vertical integration along
the value chain. Large groups and small wineries often have their own distri-
bution channels. In particular, e-commerce and social network marketing
have emerged over recent years, and the wine market is no exception to these
trends.
Last but not least, it is worth mentioning that the intervention of the
Chinese government is a key factor in the Chinese wine industry. The govern-
ment released the first national standards and policies to regulate the domestic
wine industry in the early 1990s and improved them during the 2000s. Then,
in the “12th Five-Year Plan” for the Chinese wine industry (2012), the
Ministry of Industry and Information Technology and the Ministry of
Agriculture underlined the importance of government support in the domes-
tic wine industry, especially in the development of the wine-production sec-
tor, the improvement of industrial structure, the innovation of science and
technology, the guarantee of product quality and safety, and the promotion of
domestic wine culture. Afterward, green development in the wine-production
sector was highlighted in the “13th Five-Year Plan”. Moreover, the govern-
ment promotes wine as a healthier alternative to traditional spirits and encour-
ages people to consume wine with moderation. During 2013–2014, the wine
market, especially the fine-wine market, suffered significantly as a result of the
crackdown on gifting and corruption, but it has been gradually recovering
since 2015.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chinese Wine Industry 227
10.2 W
inegrowing and Winemaking Sectors
in China
In China, the cultivation of the vine can be dated back to the fourth century
BC. Poems like The Song of Grapes and The Song of Liangzhou in the Tang
Dynasty recorded ancient people enjoying grape wine. Wine industrialization
in China started in the late nineteenth century when European missionaries
brought in vines and winemaking technologies. In 1892, Mr. Chang Bishi
(1841–1916), a patriotic overseas Chinese, set up the Changyu Pioneer Wine
Company. Four years later, Changyu imported quality grape vines in large
quantities from Europe to Yantai, Shandong Province, and that is how the
first wines in modern China were established. But the birth of Chinese wine
culture should be dated to the 1980, thanks to China’s reform, opening up to
the rest of the world and the investment of foreign groups. Influential Sino-
French joint ventures appeared during that time, such as the Remy Martin
Group, which created the Dynasty Fine Wine Group in 1980, and Pernod
Ricard, associated with the Beijing Winery, which created Dragon Seal in
1988. Later on, with the support and promotion of the Chinese government,
wine production in China has been increasing gradually since the 1980s.
According to the report by the International Organisation of Vine and Wine
(OIV) (2017), in China, the surface area under vine was 830,000 hectares in
2015 and forecasted to be 847,000 hectares in 2016, which accounts for about
1.5% of the entire national agricultural land. Most of the production is for
table grapes and wine grapes account only for 15% of the total grape produc-
tion. As regards wine production, the volume has been dropping slightly since
2012 from 13.5 to 11.4 million hectoliters, but China still remains in sixth
position in the world. In fact, there are wineries in western China selling their
bulk wine to be bottled in eastern China, and the production of wine is often
double counted—the first time in the west and for a second time in the east.
As a result, statistics on Chinese wine production are questionable.
mmorag@uchile.cl
228 L. Jiao and S. Ouyang
A specific challenge for grapes is that, in winter, the climate in certain wine
regions is extremely cold and sometimes the temperature falls below −20 °C. To
protect the grapes from the wind and cold, vines have to be buried in winter in
order to keep them alive and then unburied in spring. Covering vines for the
winter is undertaken by hand, which implies extra costs. This is the major rea-
son why Chinese wine production has higher costs. Furthermore, vines gener-
ally need to be irrigated by river water or groundwater in most of the wine
regions. Besides, Chinese wineries like hiring French winemakers and oenolo-
gists as consultants, as well as investing in advanced and expensive equipment.
Wine regions are dispersed throughout the country, but most of them are
in eastern China. When it comes to wine regions, people usually talk about
their administrative divisions, although those are insufficient to define cer-
tain wine regions (Li, 2016). It helps to have a first location of Chinese win-
eries. Geographically speaking, eight main wine regions can be considered:
Shandong, Hebei-Beijing, Shanxi, Dongbei, Xinjiang, Ningxia, Gansu, and
Yunnan (Fig. 10.2).
Regional official data concerning winegrowing and winemaking sectors are
rarely available. In order to acquire more information, data on major wineries
for each region were collected. These data are from online resources and not
available for all considered wineries.
The eight main regions considered are:
10.2.1.1 Shandong
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chinese Wine Industry 229
Yearbook)) and value. The Hebei and Shandong regions represent nearly half
of the total domestic wine production. The Hebei wineries are located in
Shacheng (northwest of Beijing) and Changli (northeast of Beijing). The
wines produced from these two regions are protected as geographical indica-
tions. The winter here is rather cold which means vines need to be protected
artificially. The domestic grape variety Dragon Eye is widely planted in this
region. The planting size of the wineries here is mainly from 100 hectares to
over 500 hectares. There are also relatively smaller wineries such as Domaine
Franco-Chinois, a Sino-French joint venture, which has 23 hectares of vine-
yards and 25 hectares in total.
Several relatively smaller wineries, with 70–100 hectares in plantation, are
in the northwest and southwest of Beijing’s outer suburbs, such as Dragon
Seal and Changyu Aifeibao Winery. These wineries can be ideal for wine tour-
ism thanks to their geographical location.
mmorag@uchile.cl
230 L. Jiao and S. Ouyang
10.2.1.3 Shanxi
10.2.1.5 Xinjiang
10.2.1.6 Ningxia
Contrary to other provinces, “the wine industry occupies the most important
position in the economic development of Ningxia” according to Pr. Li Demei,
consultant of Ningxia Helan Qingxue Vineyard. Due to the Helan Mountain
East Foothill appellation, the provincial wine bureau, and the winery classifi-
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chinese Wine Industry 231
cation system, Ningxia has gained the reputation as the producer of the
highest-quality Chinese wines and is regarded as one of the country’s most
promising wine regions. The climate here is arid or semiarid with good condi-
tions of sunlight and warmth. There are also convenient irrigation conditions
thanks to the Yellow River. The vines have to be buried each winter to be
protected from the cold and wind. There are 72 wineries with 34,000 hectares
of vines for winemaking. More details about this region will be presented in
the following sections.
10.2.1.7 Gansu
Gansu has a relatively long history of winemaking, but the wine industry
hasn’t taken an important position in this region, probably due to the incon-
venience of transportation. The wine quality here has been barely satisfactory
because of unfavorable climate conditions. Over the last few years, the wine
industry has developed rapidly thanks to the support of the regional
government, especially as regards organic wine production. In addition, the
Hexi Corridor has become a protected geographic indication since 2012. The
size of the wineries ranges from hundreds to thousands of hectares.
10.2.1.8 Yunnan
There is not a long winemaking history in this region, although the climate is
relatively favorable for winegrowing. In a high-altitude but low-latitude geo-
graphical location, the sunlight is sufficient, the weather is not hot in summer
and in winter, like the Shandong region, vines do not have to be protected as
they can survive naturally. The vineyards are tiny, scattered all over the moun-
tains in small plots with normally dozens of plots making up just 1 hectare.
The difficulties and challenges of producing wine in Yunnan will be presented
by the Ao Yun case in the section on foreign investment.
mmorag@uchile.cl
232 L. Jiao and S. Ouyang
eties in small quantities plus Vitis amurensis, which is a domestic variety. For
white wine, Chardonnay accounts for over 61% of the total white-wine grape
area, followed by Riesling representing about 36%, plus Chenin Blanc,
Sauvignon Blanc, Gewurztraminer, Ugni Blanc, and so on. Dragon Eye is a
celebrated domestic white variety (the Chinese Agricultural Year Book;
Anderson and Aryal, 2013; Li, 2000).
The “12th Five-year Plan” indicates that strengthening winegrowing bases
is a key factor to ensuring the quality and stability of winemaking raw materi-
als. Local government should be in support of breeding high-quality imported-
wine grape varieties that adapt well to the climate of Chinese wine regions.
Marselan, a hybrid variety of Cabernet Sauvignon and Grenache, is bred by
INRA (French National Institute for Agricultural Research) and was first
imported to China in 2001. Unlike in France where Marselan is cultivated
little, this variety has spread across China during the last 15 years. Strongly
structured and elegant wines are made from Marselan, and the result is that it
is regarded as a grape variety which is highly adapted to the taste of Chinese
consumers. Several Chinese wineries (such as Zhongfei Winery, Yiyuan
Winery, and Huailai Amethyst Manor) present Marselan wines as their main
product.
There are about 450 wine producers in China but only 150 companies
with a turnover of more than 5 million RMB registered in official statis-
tics. The wine-production sector is highly concentrated in China with 5
leading groups taking more than 60% of total volume. The main groups
are Yantai Changyu Group Co., Ltd.; Great Wall Wine Group Co., Ltd.
of COFCO Ltd.; Dynasty Fine Wine Group Co., Ltd.; Yantai Weilong
Grape Wine Co., Ltd.; and Dragon Seal Wines Co., Ltd. (Ubifrance
2012; IWSR 2015). According to the study by MarketLine, in 2015, in
terms of market volume of domestic wine, the top 4 account for almost
60% of total volume and the remaining 40% is shared by hundreds of
operators (see Fig. 10.3). However, since 2016, the degree of concentra-
tion has been diluted so that the top 4 account for less than half of the
total volume. But, Changyu still holds the first position in China and
takes around one fifth of the market.
Large companies provide a wide range of products from low-priced to
high-end ones in large volumes. As a result, they need grape sources and grape
juices from independent domestic growers or those worldwide. They buy
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chinese Wine Industry 233
7.5% 9.5%
Fig. 10.3 China wine market share by volume. (Source: MarketLine 2015)
grape juices from New World producers such as Chile, Australia, and also
from the Xinjiang Province. They mainly negotiate the price of grape juices
without strict quality criteria. Therefore, in some cases, grapes produced by
company-owned vineyards are often used for high-end products, while third-
party grapes are for low-priced products. Besides, there are local producers
who are used to importing bulk wine from Chile, Spain, or Australia and then
mixing them with their own “grape juice” to improve their qualities, because
their costs are lower than growing grapes themselves.
Wineries in the Ningxia region are the best representatives of elite Chinese
wineries. All wines are produced by grapes cultivated in their own vineyards
following certain requirements in quality in order to pinpoint their origin.
“The idea was to change the current situation of the wine industry in China,
which tended to ‘industrialize wine production’ and generate a ‘massive
amount of low-quality wines’ according to a special consultant of the region’s
wine industry.
Most of the large companies and “small and fine” wineries operate verti-
cally integrated businesses from growing grapes to making wine and then
bottling. But there are some exceptions, and the bottling of bulk wine is
described in the section entitled “Relationships along the chain”.
mmorag@uchile.cl
234 L. Jiao and S. Ouyang
10.2.5 C
ase Study: Changyu Versus Helan Qingxue
Vineyard
Changyu is one of the oldest Chinese wineries. It has now been transformed
into a big group which offers a wide range of products from wine to spirits
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chinese Wine Industry 235
produced from six production regions in China and eight chateaux from their
properties in China and abroad. Their Pioneer International Chateau Alliance
with several chateaux from France, Italy, Spain, New Zealand, and Australia
produce their high-end wines with a very competitive image.
Changyu holds an important market share in almost every catalog in the
Chinese wine market, with a very large range of products from cheap wine to
high-end wine, cognac and brandy from their estates abroad, ice wine, and
health-care liquor. Changyu still holds a positive status and keeps expanding
its investment overseas in spite of the economic decline, the competition from
imported wines and the downturn of wine consuming caused by the anti-
corruption campaign from 2012.
By contrast, Helan Qingxue is not only at the opposite extreme to Changyu
because of the size of the company but also in the building of the image of
their products—100% Chinese ancestry. Founded in 2005, Helan Qingxue
Vineyard is the first demonstration vineyard in Ningxia. It has about 13.33
hectares of vineyard with an annual production of 50,000 bottles, situated in
Helan Mountain East Foothill. Its consultant, Li Demei, is a well-known
Chinese winemaker trained in Bordeaux, as well as a professor in Beijing
Agricultural College. This winery has built up its image and reputation gradu-
ally by the successful performance of their wines in several competitions.
Their wines have won many awards in international contexts such as the
Decanter World Wine Award and the “best Chinese wine” selected by the
Revue du Vin de France (RVF) China.
mmorag@uchile.cl
236 L. Jiao and S. Ouyang
As we can see in Fig. 10.4, still red wine dominates the market, accounting for
71% of the total wine sales in volume, followed by still white wine represent-
ing 23% of the total, complemented with small percentages of still rosé, spar-
kling wine, and Champagne. With an increasing popularity of Champagne,
sparkling wines have gained some share but it is still limited. Among the grape
varieties for red wine, Cabernet Sauvignon occupies the first place with around
35% of the total sales in volume, followed by Merlot with about 23%,
Cabernet Franc 10%, Cabernet Sauvignon/Shiraz 10%, and others. For white
wine, the top 3 most popular varieties are Chardonnay with 43%, Riesling
26% and Dragon Eye 8%, and others account for 23% of the total (author’s
calculation based on Euromonitor International (2011, 2015)). Rosé wines
consumed in China are mainly made of Merlot.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chinese Wine Industry 237
Fig. 10.4 Wine market share segmentation by color. (Source: MarketLine 2015 and
author’s calculation based on Euromonitor International 2011, 2015)
10.3.2.1 Export
Exports of Chinese wines are negligible and the main destination is Hong
Kong. As the wine industry is still very young in China, only a few wineries
sell their wines abroad. But with a good trend of development, it will not be
long until we see Chinese wine all around the world as it is already possible to
find Ningxia wines in California’s wine cellars.
mmorag@uchile.cl
238 L. Jiao and S. Ouyang
Off-trade, the most common selling price range for all wines is 20–59.9 RMB
(3–10 USD) per bottle. Nearly 80% of red wines are sold within that price
range, and the same occurs for 71% of white wines, 78% of rosé wines, and
79% of sparkling wines (author’s calculation based on Euromonitor
International (2011, 2015)).
When it comes to imported wines, the average spending per bottle ranges
from 179 RMB for a casual drink to 260 RMB for a special occasion.
On-trade, average spending per bottle varies from 219 RMB for an informal
meal, to 296 RMB for a party or celebration, and up to 424 RMB for a busi-
ness meal (Wine Intelligence 2015).
The Chinese wine market is still in an hourglass structure (Fig. 10.6) with
a mid-range market smaller than the low-priced and high-end markets.
Domestic wine, along with low-priced imported wine, has gained the largest
market share and still has potential. The top-end fine wines have been experi-
encing a decline over the last two years (2013–2015). While the mid-range
market that includes mid-priced imported wines from a wide diversity of ori-
5.7%
3.9% 44.3%
14.9% Supermarkets/hypermarkets
31.1%
Fig. 10.5 Wine distribution in China. (Source: MarketLine 2015 and author’s calcula-
tion based on Euromonitor International 2011, 2015)
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chinese Wine Industry 239
(b) During the past decades, the model of “wineries + independent wine-
growers” has shown a lot of disadvantages, such as unstable quality and
quantity of grape and unstable income for winegrowers. Recently, a grow-
ing number of pioneer wineries have tried to rent the land themselves and
train their hired winegrowers.
mmorag@uchile.cl
240 L. Jiao and S. Ouyang
1
Generally speaking, the wineries in the eastern part of China are relatively small compared to the winer-
ies in the western regions such as Xinjiang and Gansu. Ningxia is a special case, though it is located in the
western part of China.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chinese Wine Industry 241
10.4.3.2 E-commerce
2
Literally, guanxi means “go through the gate and get connections” or simply “relationships”. In the busi-
ness world, it is a Chinese term used to describe the network of relationships aimed to provide support
and cooperation or exchange favors among the parties involved.
mmorag@uchile.cl
242 L. Jiao and S. Ouyang
10.4.3.3 Promotion
There are not many barriers for foreign wine entering China. Unlike the
three-tiered system in the USA, there are no particular regulations in China
to prevent an importer distributing the wine on their own and even reaching
end-buyers. Guanxi is also important for distributing domestic wine as well as
imported wine.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chinese Wine Industry 243
Fig. 10.7 Distribution chain of import wine in China. (Source: Wine Intelligence 2013).
Dashed line represents significant relationship but with little volume
Smugglers use the gray markets in Hong Kong or Macao to transfer imported wines into mainland
3
mmorag@uchile.cl
244 L. Jiao and S. Ouyang
10.5 Conclusion
• China is an emerging wine market and has a young domestic wine indus-
try. The market is characterized by its dynamism. The industry structure,
especially the channels of distribution, has been evolving rapidly to adapt
to changes in consumer behavior.
• The domestic wine industry is characterized by high vertical integra-
tion along the chain from winegrowing to winemaking and finally to
distribution.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chinese Wine Industry 245
mmorag@uchile.cl
246 L. Jiao and S. Ouyang
• There are not many entry barriers for imported wines. The border of the
activities between importers and distributors is not clear. There is evidence
of a vertical-integration trend along the imported-wine distribution chain.
• The export of domestic wine is negligible, although there is room for opti-
mism because the quality of wine is improving.
References
Anderson, K., and N.R. Aryal. 2013. Which winegrape varieties are grown where? A
global empirical picture. Adelaide: University of Adelaide Press.
Li, S.H. 2000. Grape production in China. FAO Corporate Document Repository.
Available at: http://www.fao.org/docrep/003/x6897e/x6897e05.htm#TopOfPage.
Li, D. 2016. Defining the Chinese wine regions. Decanter China. Available at: https://
www.decanterchina.com/en/columns/demeis-view-wine-communication-from-a-
chinese-winemaker/defining-the-chinese-wine-regions.
Schmitt, P. 2016. Moët’s Chinese wine ‘a logistical nightmare’. The Drink Business.
Available at: https://www.thedrinksbusiness.com/2016/06/moets-chinese-wine-a-
logistical-nightmare/.
Wu, S. 2014. Ningxia wine region: We’ve got your back, says the government.
Decanter China. Available at: https://www.decanterchina.com/en/knowledge/
people/region-authorities/ningxia-wine-region-we-ve-got-your-back-says-the-
government.
Wu, S. 2016. Ningxia announces wine classification system. Decanter China. Available
at: https://www.decanterchina.com/en/news/ningxia-announces-wine-classifica-
tion-system.
Audit de la distribution du vin en Chine. 2013. Wine Intelligence.
China Brewing Industry Yearbook. 2008–2011. China Alcoholic Drinks Association.
Le marché des vins et spiritueux en Chine Continentale. 2012. Ubifrance.
Portraits China. 2015. Wine Intelligence.
The IWSR/Vinexpo Report – The Wine World 2009–2019. 2015. International
Wine and Spirit Research.
Wine in China. 2011, 2015. Euromonitor International.
Wine in China. 2015–2017. MarketLine.
World Vitiviniculture Situation. 2013–2017. International Organisation of Vine and
Wine (OIV).
“12 Five-Year Plan” for Chinese wine industry. 2012. Chinese Ministry of Industry
and Information Technology and Ministry of Agriculture.
“13 Five-Year Plan” for Chinese wine industry. 2015. Chinese Ministry of Industry
and Information Technology and Ministry of Agriculture.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Part II
Regulations in the Wine Sector
mmorag@uchile.cl
11
Introduction: Regulations in the
Wine Sector
Paola Corsinovi and Davide Gaeta
The European Union is the first wine-producing area with around 65% of
world production; however, over the years the Europe’s share of the world’s
vineyards has declined from 63% in 2000 to 54% in 2014 as the effect of EU
policy as the permanent abandonment premiums ended in 2011 (OIV 2015).
In the meantime, the share of all other world wine regions is increasing, in
particular in Asia, which now accounts for 25% of the world’s vineyards, and
the international trade had a growth: which reached 20 million hl in volume
in 2015; only 20 years before, in 1995, the export was about 11 million hl.
Nowadays, wine has become one of the most globalized products in the world.
A variety of factors have contributed to the process of globalization.
Nevertheless, on the demand and consumers’ side, social and religious cul-
ture, diet issues and alcohol policies have contributed to major changes in the
geography of consumption with a reduction in the traditional EU wine coun-
tries versus outside the EU.
The EU domestic context and international scenes have (probably) played
an important role in the design of wine strategies and interventions, since
their inception in 1962. Wine policy is one of the most articulate laws of the
Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) and the single Common Market
Organization (CMO), and this is due to the complexity and heterogeneity of
P. Corsinovi (*)
Centre of Economics, Hochschule Geisenheim University, Geisenheim, Germany
D. Gaeta
Department of Business Administration, University of Verona, Verona, Italy
e-mail: davide.gaeta@univr.it
mmorag@uchile.cl
250 P. Corsinovi and D. Gaeta
mmorag@uchile.cl
Introduction: Regulations in the Wine Sector 251
mmorag@uchile.cl
252 P. Corsinovi and D. Gaeta
Wine Trade” by Mariani and Pomarici that helps to interpret how the wine
market evolved over time and to foresee how could it evolve in the future.
Chapter 14 offers an updated analysis of tariff barriers and non-tariff measures
and the free trade agreement relevant to wine trade. This chapter is organized
as follows: in paragraph 2 the tariff barriers operating in the wine market are
discussed, and an assessment of the impact of such barriers on the wine export
flows is introduced; in paragraph 3 a general overview of non-tariff measures
is offered, showing how these operate as barriers in the wine sector; in para-
graph 4 an analysis is done of technical measures, which are the non-tariff
measures more frequently resulting in trade barriers; in paragraph 5 it is
shown how exporting and importing countries reduce the wine trade’s barri-
ers; and in paragraph 6, the events and processes which could modify trade
barrier status in the wine market over the near future are presented. Some
final remarks, in paragraph 7, conclude the chapter.
Reference
OIV. 2015. World vitiviniculture situation. Available at http://www.oiv.int/public/
medias/2777/report-mainzcongress-2015-oiv-en-7.pdf
mmorag@uchile.cl
12
International Wine Organizations
and Plurilateral Agreements:
Harmonization Versus Mutual Recognition
of Standards
Raúl Compés López
12.1 Introduction
Until the late 1980s, the European Union (EU) was the only real-world player
in the global wine market because the new wine world was still in its infancy.
The EU’s wine policy was, and continues to be, different from the Common
Agricultural Policy’s rules and was largely influenced by the traditional phi-
losophy of French regulation. At the time, the EU’s policy was autonomous
and independent of external influences. The only external institution of refer-
ence was the International Organisation of Vine and Wine (OIV), but its
influence was very restricted in both technical and oenological standards.
Things started to change during the mid-1990s in several ways. First, the
creation of the World Trade Organization (WTO) and the arrival of the cur-
rent globalization era pushed the opening of markets. Second, the rapid and
successful emergence of the new world wine countries changed the dynamics
of international markets, increasing competition and leading to new business
models and new forms of regulation. Third, the new entrants, at least some of
them, wanted to promote a more liberal approach to issues related to the
international markets. In the face of the European interventionist model—
R. Compés López (*)
Department of Economics and Social Sciences, Universitat Politècnica de València,
València, Spain
e-mail: rcompes@esp.upv.es
mmorag@uchile.cl
254 R. Compés López
created to monitor the supply and protect the origin in keeping up a main
standard of quality—the new world model was based on self-governance and
private coordination in order to reach common goals, mainly in the fields of
innovation and in external markets (Castillo et al. 2014).
EU policy had to react to these changes, a reaction which took place on
several levels: modifying internal changes of its wine’s rules in 2008, pressing
the WTO to defend geographical indications (GI), and strengthening the
OIV’s role in harmonizing standards. In the twenty-first century, a new para-
digm in wine regulation began to spread.
Globalization increases interdependence among countries, and the wine
sector is one of the paradigms of the globalization movement in the agrifood
sector (Dubois 2013). In the field of policies, this pushes toward cooperation
and the pursuit of convergence or, at the very least, coexistence of standards
(Bingen and Busch 2006). This process is carried out in the frame of interna-
tional organizations and through multilateral, plurilateral, or bilateral agree-
ments (Dai 2007). One of the most relevant of all them is the WTO because
it sets the framework for trade policies, internal policies that can distort trade,
and, very often, other agreements.1
However, other specialized institutions also play an important role in the
design of wine policies. The most important is the OIV, but the World Wine
Trade Group (WWTG) must also be taken into account. Although there are
clear differences between the two, they share the ultimate aim of promoting
trade and facilitating business performance. In a global perspective, the OIV
represents the search of convergence through harmonization (Juban 1994;
Tinlot 2000) and the WWTG through recognition and mutual equivalence
(Battaglene and Barker 2008). The OIV is a hard institution with European
roots in which both new and old world countries participate, while the
WWTG is a soft institution supported mainly by the United States and con-
sisting of “new world” countries.2 Even though the OIV and WWTG do not
compete directly, they represent two ways of understanding interdependence
1
WTO is the main influence in national—both internal and trade—policies. Some of the WTO agree-
ments have direct influence over wine policies. It is a case of horizontal agreement for the Agriculture,
SPS, and TBT and also for the TRIPS, who have specific provisions for protecting geographical indica-
tion of wines.
2
From the emergence of “new” non-European producers after the Wine Tasting of 1976, also called the
Judgement of Paris (Taber 2006), it is usual to divide wines into the new and the old worlds (Anderson
2003). This taxonomy is currently employed (Schirmer 2007), even if differences between the two are
becoming weaker (Banks and Overton 2010), due to the bilateral and reciprocal influences in policies
and management models.
mmorag@uchile.cl
International Wine Organizations and Plurilateral Agreements… 255
policies in the framework of the WTO, and their philosophies fit the theoreti-
cal essence of the old and new worlds, respectively.
In this chapter we are going to analyze the role of the OIV and the WWTG
in wine policies. This is an important topic because these institutions have
received minimal attention throughout the analysis of wine’s economic policy
(Randelli and Dini 2013; Meloni and Swinnen 2013). The OIV has gained
international recognition as the first source of technical harmonization in the
wine sector (Hannin et al. 2006), and the WWTG is trying to go beyond this
as a source of technical equivalence agreements.
The current OIV is the result of the evolution of several different actions of
wine-producing countries in defending their common interests. The roots of
this organization can be traced to the Congress held in Montpellier in 1874,
where some European countries met to collaborate in the fight against phyl-
loxera. Some years later, once the phylloxera challenge was overcome, in the
Congress of Geneva, 1908, and Paris, 1909, the new common interest was in
the prevention of fraud.
With these positive antecedents facing the international challenge of viti-
culture, in 1922 the French Society for the Encouragement of Agriculture sug-
gested the creation of an international wine organization. The result was the
creation of an International Wine Office (OIV) through an agreement dated
November 29, 1924, between the governments of eight countries: France,
Greece, Hungary, Italy, Luxembourg, Portugal, Spain, and Tunisia. It began
its operations in Paris in 1928 (Peaslee 1974). On September 4, 1958, the
organization’s name was changed to the International Vine and Wine Office,
in order to allow the incorporation of countries producing table grapes and
dried grapes.
The International Vine and Wine Office was transformed into the
International Organisation of Vine and Wine by decision of its General
Assembly on December 5, 1997, in Buenos Aires (Argentina). Its mission was
to modernize the resources of the office and to ease its adaptation to the world
Most of the descriptive information on this point comes from the OIV website and from OIV docu-
3
ments and presentations.
mmorag@uchile.cl
256 R. Compés López
context of the vitiviniculture sector. The agreement for the new organization
was established on April 3, 2001, between 35 nations4 and went into effect on
January 1, 2004, based in Paris.
Today, the OIV has 46 member states throughout five continents, among
which 21 are members of the European Union. It has also some territory and
organization observers, most of them producers but also mainly consumers.5
They account for about 85% of wine production and 80% of wine consump-
tion worldwide. Its total budget, decided each year by the General Assembly
and coming mostly from members’ financial contributions, amounts to 1.5
million euros. The current president is the German Professor Dr. Monika
Christmann, appointed during the 38th World Congress in Mainz, July 2015.
The United States is the only large producing country that is currently not
an OIV member. In fact, it was previously a member as of 1984 but left the
organization in 2001. The causes seem to be differences between the United
States and European countries in matters of oenological standards and geo-
graphical indication protection and a representation system in which they
were sometimes the minority.6
But in spite of US absence, the OIV is the most influential intergovern-
mental organization in the wine world. Its nature is scientific and technical,
and its main role is setting standards for all products derived from the vine
(vines, wine, wine-based beverages, table grapes, raisins, and other vine-based
products). This involves drafting resolutions, recommendations, and propos-
als on various aspects of the production of and trade in wine products (i.e.
oenological practices, product descriptions and definitions, labeling rules,
marketing conditions, analysis and assessment methods, the protection of
geographical indications, and the protection of varieties).
4
Republic of Algeria, Federal Republic of Germany, Republic of Argentina, Australia, Republic of
Austria, Republic of Bolivia, Federal Republic of Brazil, Republic of Chile, Republic of Cyprus, Kingdom
of Denmark, Kingdom of Spain, Republic of Finland, Republic of France, Republic of Georgia, United
Kingdom, Hellenic Republic, Republic of Hungary, State of Israel, Republic of Italy, Republic of
Lebanon, Grand Duchy of Luxemburg, United Mexican States, Republic of Moldavia, Kingdom of
Norway, New Zealand, Kingdom of the Netherlands, Republic of Portugal, Romania, Republic of
Slovakia, Kingdom of Sweden, Swiss Confederation, Czech Republic, Republic of Tunisia, Republic of
Turkey, Eastern Republic of Uruguay.
5
AIDV (International Wine Law Association), Amorim Academy, AREV (Assembly of Wine-Producing
European Regions), AUIV (International University Association of Wine), CERVIM (Centre for
Research, Environmental Sustainability and Advancement of Mountain Viticulture), FIVS (International
Federation of Wines and Spirits), OENOPPIA (Oenological Products and Practices International
Association), UIOE (Union Internationale des Œnologues), VINOFED (World Federation of Major
International Wine and Spirits Competitions), ASI (Association de la Sommellerie Internationale), WIM
(Wine in Moderation), Yantaï (China), prefecture-level municipality and Ningxia Hui autonomous
region, China.
6
More information about this issue can be found in http://www.senat.fr/rap/l03-095/l03-0951.html
mmorag@uchile.cl
International Wine Organizations and Plurilateral Agreements… 257
The main body of the OIV is the General Assembly, composed of dele-
gates nominated by members. It delegates some of its powers into the
Executive Committee, which then entrusts some of its routine adminis-
trative powers to the OIV Steering Committee. The Office of Director
General (who as of January 1, 2014, is Mr. Jean-Marie Aurand) is respon-
sible for the internal administration of the OIV, which is composed of 14
members.
The OIV conducts its scientific and technical activity through expert
groups, two sub-commissions and four commissions, coordinated by a
Scientific and Technical Committee. This committee presents proposals to
define the work and activity programs of the bodies of the organization.7
Participating in the expert groups, sub-commissions and commissions are
close to 1000 scientific representatives and experts that are appointed and
managed by government authorities in OIV member states. They come from
the scientific community and also, to a considerable extent, from the profes-
sional sector.
The resolutions of the General Assembly and the Executive Committee are
adopted by general consensus and are usually incorporated, with no change to
their legal scope, into more detailed standards—usually in the form of codes,
periodically updated on the basis of the resolutions adopted by the
organization.8
The main activities of the OIV are:
7
The four commissions are Viticulture, Oenology, Economy and Law, Safety and Health; and the two
sub-commissions Methods of Analysis and Table Grapes, Raisins and Unfermented Vine Products; with
the expert groups to support their tasks.
8
For instance, the International Oenological Codex, the Compendium of International Methods of
Analysis of Wine and Must, the Compendium of international methods of analysis of spirited beverages,
international standards for wine and spirit competitions, and the international standard for labeling
wines and spirit drinks.
mmorag@uchile.cl
258 R. Compés López
mmorag@uchile.cl
International Wine Organizations and Plurilateral Agreements… 259
4. Formation and training. The OIV establishes and coordinates the develop-
ment of international research on emerging topics—impact of climate
change, environmental issues, concern related to the consumption of
wine—and training programs in the sector. It fosters contacts and scien-
tific exchanges and training in countries throughout the world. This
includes the OIV MSc in “Wine Management”, created in 1986, and the
World Congress of Vine and Wine, now in its 41st year.
5. Patronage and competitions. The OIV may grant patronage to interna-
tional scientific conferences or national and international wine and spirits
of vitivinicultural origin competitions, provided that their organization
and internal rule procedures are in accordance with the international stan-
dards of the OIV.
12.3 WWTG9
12.3.1 Nature and Goals
9
The main sources of information for the above are the WWTG website (http://www.wwtg-gmcv.org/),
the US Department of Commerce (http://ita.doc.gov/td/ocg/wwtg.htm), the US Department
of Treasury/Alcohol and Tobacco Tax and Trade Bureau (http://www.ttb.gov/itd/world_wine.shtml),
and Wine Institute (https://www.wineinstitute.org/). The Wine Institute is the voice for California wine
and represents more than 1000 wineries and affiliated businesses. It works closely with several US official
entities on tariff and trade barrier reduction, free trade agreements, and other negotiations to grow US
wine exports globally.
10
The WWTG welcomes participation in the group as observers of any national governments or mem-
bers of the World Trade Organization interested in furthering these goals. Other countries that have
participated in the meetings are China, Mexico, Paraguay, Uruguay, Brazil, and Moldova. In 2006, it set
down principles derived from the WWTG agreements that could be applied in other international con-
texts. The most important extension initiative has been the development of the APEC Wine Regulators
Forum (WRF).
mmorag@uchile.cl
260 R. Compés López
The main outputs of the WWTG have been two agreements which are at the
core of their framework—a memorandum and a protocol—and two state-
ments. Additionally, a January 2007 meeting included, for the first time, a
Regulators Forum to provide regulatory bodies with an opportunity to discuss
possible approaches to emerging regulatory issues. In 2008, the WWTG also
11
Four WWTG members (Chile, Argentina, New Zealand, and South Africa) plus California formed the
New World Wines Alliance. On March 10, 2010, they joined forces and put on an unprecedented com-
bined show named “Down to Earth” at ProWein in Germany. ProWein is one of the leading trade fairs
for the international wine and spirits industry (Source: The World Wine Trade Group And The Need To
Promote Cooperation Among Wine Producers Of The New World, Marcela B. Knaup; This article was
first published by the International Trade Committee Newsletter of the American Bar Association, Section of
International Law, Volume IV, No 3, 8-2010).
12
The decision to change the name of the group to World Wine Trade Group was to reflect the focus of
the group on facilitating trade in wine.
mmorag@uchile.cl
International Wine Organizations and Plurilateral Agreements… 261
represented the global wine industry, in conjunction with the CEEV (Comité
Européen des Entreprises Vins, the representative professional body of the EU
industry and trade in wines) at the WTO consultation on its strategy for
reducing the harmful use of alcoholic beverages. In 2011, a joint meeting was
held between FIVS13 and WWTG on sustainability, which identified impor-
tant synergies between WWTG and non-WWTG industries around this
topic; finally, in 2015, a winegrowing report was produced.
The Mutual Acceptance Agreement (MAA) on Oenological (winemaking)
Practices was signed in Toronto, Canada, in December 2001 by the United
States and Canada, with Argentina becoming a signatory in December 2002.
By 2005, all WWTG participants had ratified the MAA with the exception of
South Africa, which ratified the MAA in 2011. Under that agreement, each
country will permit the importation of wines from every other signatory
country as long as these wines are made in accordance with the producing
country’s domestic laws, regulations, and requirements on oenological prac-
tices. The agreement recognizes that different countries use different wine-
making practices due to local conditions, climatic variations, and traditions,
and that grape-growing and winemaking practices are constantly evolving.14
The Agreement on Requirements for Wine Labelling (Labelling Agreement)
was signed on January 23, 2007, in Canberra, Australia, by all participants
with the exception of South Africa. It enables wine exporters to sell wine into
WWTG markets without having to redesign all of their labels for each indi-
vidual market. Under the Labelling Agreement, the WWTG participants
have agreed to a single field of vision approach to wine labeling in order to ease
the comparison of different wines for consumers, whereby four key common
items of information (country of origin, product name, net contents, and
alcohol content) are deemed to comply with domestic labeling requirements
if they are presented together in any singular field of vision on the container.
WWTG countries consider that these principles of clarity, consistency, and
efficiency for wine labeling could provide the basis for a global standard if
adopted by sufficient international bodies and countries—given that Codex
Alimentarius Commission does not have an international standard for wine
labeling.
On March 21, 2013, in Brussels, phase two of the Labelling Agreement
was concluded through the Protocol to the Agreement on Requirements for
Wine Labelling. This extends the earlier Labelling Agreement by providing
13
Since 1951, is the International Alcoholic Beverage Federation, siege in Paris.
14
A copy of the Mutual Acceptance Agreement is available on the US Department of Commerce website
at:www.ita.doc.gov/td/ocg/eng_agreement.htm
mmorag@uchile.cl
262 R. Compés López
12.4 Conclusions
The globalization of wine markets is pushed forward by several factors. On
the institutional side, the most important are the broad liberalization caused
by the WTO agreements and the soft wine rules created by the EU’s reaction-
ary reforms of 2008 toward new world wine countries model. This move is
accompanied by the role of international organizations such as the OIV and
the WWTG. The first attempts to promote harmonization and the second the
mutual acceptance and recognition of standards, two different ways to facili-
tate trade and promote business. The OIV is stronger with a more global
influence, but the fact that the United States is not included could be seen as
a weak point.
There are no formal relations between WWTG and OIV, although many
WWTG participant countries also participate in the OIV. While they don’t
15
Any countries require certification of compositional requirements for wine, which can act as an unnec-
essary barrier to trade, particularly when they do not relate to a health or safety issue in relation to wine
or when the exporting country already has adequate systems in place to address such issues. Noting that
the MAA already provided that routine certification should not be required between parties for oenologi-
cal practices.
mmorag@uchile.cl
International Wine Organizations and Plurilateral Agreements… 263
directly compete, their philosophies are very different. WWTG is smaller and
nimbler due to having fewer members. It also has a direct link between indus-
try practitioners and government, while the OIV have a strong influence from
governments and from public and private researchers. The WWTG exists to
facilitate trade and because of the unique partnership between industry and
government can develop international trading agreements to facilitate trade.
It also provides a strong link to the Asia-Pacific region due to well-developed
relationships.
The OIV, despite its broad international nature, has a European focus, and
its main activity is the establishment of standards and the development and
approval of new practices. Perhaps a formal relationship with the European
Commission could cause tensions with non-EU member states. However,
even if some differences in regulation continue existing, and “new world”
countries approach seems more liberal and trade oriented, the world of wine
is every day more interconnected, and all big producers depend more and
more on exports. In this situation, “new world” and “old world” trademarks
seem every day less pertinent, which should drive to a convergence between
WWTG and OIV.
References
Anderson, K. 2003. Wine’s new world. Foreign Policy 136: 47–54.
Banks, G., and J. Overton. 2010. Old world, new world, third world?
Reconceptualising the worlds of wine. Journal of Wine Research 21 (1): 57–75.
Battaglene, T., and J. Barker. 2008. Reconciling diverse approaches to regulation in
the wine sector: Harmonisation, equivalence and mutual recognition. Bulletin de
l’OIV 80 (920–922): 625–637.
Bingen, J., and L. Busch. 2006. Agricultural standards. Vol. 6. Amsterdam: Springer.
Castillo, S., R. Compés, and J.M. García. 2014. La regulaciónvitivinícola. Evolución
en la UE y España y situación en el panorama internacional. In Economía del vino
en España y en elmundo, coord. S. Castillo and R. Compés. CajamarCaja Rural.
Dai, X. 2007. International institutions and national policies. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Dubois, S. 2013. Lecture géopolitique d’un produitalimentairemondialisé: le vin.
Revue internationale et stratégique 1 (89): 18–29.
Hannin, H., J.M. Codron, and S. Thoyer. 2006. The International Office of Vine
and Wine (OIV) and the World Trade Organization (WTO): Standardization
issues in the wine sector. In Agricultural standards, 73–92. Dordrecht: Springer.
Juban, Y. 1994. Harmonization, standardization carried out by the OIV in the per-
spective of the World Trade Organisation. Bulletin de l’OIV (France).
mmorag@uchile.cl
264 R. Compés López
Meloni, G., and J.F.M. Swinnen. 2013. The political economy of European wine
regulations. Journal of Wine Economics 8 (3): 244–284.
Peaslee, A.J. 1974. International governmental organizations. Vol. 1. Leiden: Brill.
Randelli, F., and F. Dini. 2013. Oltre la globalizzazione: le proposte della Geografia
economica.
Schirmer, R. 2007. Les vins du Nouveau Monde sont-ils a-géographiques. Bulletin de
l’association des géographesfrançais 1: 65–80.
Taber, G.M. 2006. Judgment of Paris. New York: Scribner.
Tinlot, R. 2000. The risks of globalization and the necessary international harmoni-
zation carried out by the OIV. Bulletin de l’OIV 73 (827/828): 67–77.
mmorag@uchile.cl
13
The European Wine Policies: Regulations
and Strategies
Paola Corsinovi and Davide Gaeta
13.1 Introduction
Over the years the European Union (EU) has introduced a number of mea-
sures/instruments designed to address the problems of income instability and
supply control: until the middle of the 1980s, the principal goal of the EU
wine policies was to ensure the development of productivity, create market
stability, and provide income support (EU Commission 2002, 2006). Since
the beginning, the context in which those reforms were forged has shifted
significantly. In particular, the wine policy changed from a policy based on
subsidizing production and the protection of domestic markets from non-
European producers to a policy that aims to stimulate quality production and
the competitiveness of the wine sector on the international scene. Many econ-
omists have been addressing wine policies and their effects (such as Anderson
2004, 2010, 2014; Anderson and Jensen 2016; Coleman 2010; Dal Bianco
et al. 2016; Malassis 1959; Mariani et al. 2012; Montaigne and Coelho 2006;
Corsinovi and Gaeta 2016, 2017; Meloni and Swinnen 2013, 2016;
Niederbacher 1983; Pomarici and Sardone 2001, 2009; Spahni 1988).
This chapter is divided into three sections. Section 13.2 analyzes the main
drivers that have characterized the EU wine policy from the first Common
P. Corsinovi (*)
Centre of Economics, Hochschule Geisenheim University, Geisenheim, Germany
D. Gaeta
Department of Business Administration, University of Verona, Verona, Italy
e-mail: davidenicola.gaeta@univr.it
mmorag@uchile.cl
266 P. Corsinovi and D. Gaeta
13.2 T
he Development of European Wine
Policies: Objectives
Under the framework of the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP), the CMOs1
were created with the scope to (1) implement a gradual convergence (agree-
ment) of prices, (2) eliminate customs barriers, and (3) establish a single mar-
ket for products under one common customs tariff for the rest of the world.
From 1962 to 2007, 21 agricultural products were governed by their respec-
tive CMOs: from 2007 the CMO has incorporated within a single regulation
all of the agriculture products (including the wine sector). The CMO of wine
constitutes the legal and regulatory basis of the European wine market, cover-
ing all the rules from vineyards to wine production, from labeling to interna-
tional trade.
The CMO of wine was initially established under the CAP in 1962 when
the first legal text was created. Only in 1970 two formal regulations were
published: one related to interventions on table wines (Reg. 816/1970) and
the other concerning production of quality wines (Reg. 817/1970). During
these years, the most important rules were adopted in 1987 (Reg. 822/1987),
in 1999 (Reg. 1493/99), in 2008 (Reg. 479/2008), and in 2013 under the
CAP reform (Reg. 1308/2013).
1
The Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) is the main agricultural policy instrument of the EU. Today, it
is organized in two pillars. Pillar I defines and funds market measure and it is founded by the European
Agricultural Guarantee Fund (EAGF). Pillar II regards the Rural Development Programs (RDP), aimed
to improve quality of life in rural areas, to support young farmers setting up a farm for the first time, and
to introduce measures for investments and innovation in farms. Measures under Pillar II are financed by
the European Agricultural Fund for Rural Development (EAFRD) and co-financed by EU Member
States.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The European Wine Policies: Regulations and Strategies 267
The objective of this part is to analyze the main drivers that have character-
ized the EU wine policy from 1962 until the last reform in 2013. The latest
wine reform adopted by the EU in 2008 and included in the 2013 single
CMO had the following goals:
As far as the wine sector is concerned, the 2013 CAP reform, in addition to
its general goals to harmonize, streamline, and simplify the provisions of the
CAP, maintains the fundamentals of the 2008 wine reform.2
The authors focus on the main public policy orientations that occurred in
those years for the wine sector: the first, being referred to as price and income
support, the second as quality of wine, and the third as competitiveness.
Table 13.1 summarizes three orientations—the main interventions in
force, their period of implementation, and the outcome. The analysis of total
wine expenditure will be presented in the following section: the impact of
orientations on the total budget is shown in Fig. 13.2; Table 13.2 shows the
main expenditure’s line in millions of euros and % on the total budget
(1970–2015).
Reflecting on the future of the wine policy strategies and monetary sup-
port, Fig. 13.2 shows the financial scheme of the provision budget expendi-
ture from 2014 to 2018 and published by the EU in the last reform in 2013
(Reg. 1308/2013). The data on expenditures has been collected from the
European Agricultural Guidance and Guarantee Fund (EAGGF) and National
Support Programs (annual financial report). The dataset created by the authors
covers the CMO expenditures (included in the guarantee fund and EU own
budgetary) but excludes the expenditures of the rural development funds and
the co-financing from the Member States. The future amounts are available at
EU Commission (Agriculture Direction) and published in the annex of Reg.
1308/2013 that establishes a common organization of the markets in agricul-
tural products.
https://ec.europa.eu/agriculture/wine_en
2
mmorag@uchile.cl
268 P. Corsinovi and D. Gaeta
mmorag@uchile.cl
The European Wine Policies: Regulations and Strategies 269
The first orientation strategy (Table 13.1) was identified as price and income
support. Most of the interventions introduced between 1970 and 1979 were
addressed to help and stabilize the income of the wine producers and defend
the internal wine market of the EU.
More specifically three forms of distillations were implemented,3 with the
expectation to achieve market equilibrium by reducing surplus quantities.
The objectives were twofold: to guarantee a fair price for producers while cre-
ating more effective measures to tackle growing market surpluses. As a conse-
quence, market withdrawals and buying-in of alcohol from compulsory
distillation were supported with the goal to remove wine and alcohol from the
market. The aids for concentrated grape must4 were meant to balance the
increasing costs of producers in southern and northern wine-growing regions:
in order to compensate for the competitive disadvantage suffered due to the
higher cost of enrichment using must incurred by producers who were banned
from using sugar to regulate alcoholic strength. The storage for table wine and
grape musts should have encouraged producers to take surplus wine off the
market, thus supporting market price stabilization. Export refunds were fixed
by the difference between EU table wine prices (for wines to be exported) and
the prices of these wines in the world market. The measure was implemented
with the aim to establish a basis for commercial exports; however, it proved to
be an instrument for helping to reduce and pay the EU’s structural surplus of
table wines.
From 2008, the EU introduced other market measures and direct pay-
ments to wine farmers with the aim to regulate wine markets and stabilize the
income. In the regulatory measures (see note Table 13.1), the authors had
3
(1) Obligatory distillation of wine from dual-purpose grapes, which originate from other grape wine
varieties or dual-purpose grapes produced in excess of the normal verified quantity. (2) Obligatory distil-
lation of by-products as wine lees and grape marc. (3) Voluntary distillation for table wine or distillation
“with a guarantee of proper use” for those with long-term storage contracts. A few years later, with the
reform in 1987, three distillations were voluntary and could be chosen by the producer: (1) distillation
supplementary to long-term storage contracts, (2) preventive distillation, and (3) support distillation.
Whereas the remaining three were compulsory: (1) distillation of by-products, (2) distillation of wines
other than table wines, and (3) distillation of table wines. The 1999 (Reg. 1493/99) reform provided for
two types of compulsory distillation, (1) wine obtained from dual-purpose grapes and (2) by-product
distillation, and two types of voluntary distillation: (3) for the production of potable alcohol and (4) crisis
distillation.
4
Use of must for enrichment in order to compensate for the competitive disadvantage suffered due to the
higher cost of enrichment using must incurred by producers who were banned from using sugar to regu-
late alcoholic strength.
mmorag@uchile.cl
270
Aid for concentrated grape must 3523.95 7.8 18.15 1.1 868.61 6.5 1328.23 8.7 882.82 10.9 426.14 6.3
Aid for storagea 3558.10 7.9 318.04 19.8 1221.59 9.1 1871.35 12.3 147.12 1.8 0.00 0.0
Export refunds 1046.64 2.3 36.92 2.3 270.51 2.0 540.71 3.5 198.50 2.4 0.00 0.0
Regulatory measuresa 719.32 1.6 0.00 0.0 0.00 0.0 0.00 0.0 73.65 0.9 645.66 9.5
Other intervention expendituresa 2760.37 6.1 91.71 5.7 942.17 7.0 1726.00 11.3 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.0
mmorag@uchile.cl
Grubbing up/abandonment 3743.06 8.3 0.00 0.0 214.36 1.6 2330.92 15.3 939.03 11.6 258.76 3.8
Restructuring and reconversion 6167.34 13.7 26.88 1.6 40.02 0.3 743.73 4.8 2743.33 33.9 2613.38 38.6
Green harvesting 953.19 2.1 0.00 0.0 0.00 0.0 0.00 0.0 147.79 1.8 805.40 11.9
Investments and innovations 944.92 2.1 0.00 0.0 0.00 0.0 0.00 0.0 92.98 1.1 851.94 12.6
Promotion in third countries 980.83 2.1 0.00 0.0 0.00 0.0 0.00 0.0 122.39 1.5 858.45 12.7
Total expenditures 45,027.31 1601.19 13,360.60 15,236.32 8071.53 6757.19
Source: Author’s dataset (our elaboration from EAGGF annual expenditures), Corsinovi and Gaeta 2017)
a
See notes in Table 13.1
The European Wine Policies: Regulations and Strategies 271
CMO policies should have encouraged the wine sector to bring supply into
line with demand in terms of both quantity and quality (EU Commission
2002). As a consequence of high costs and surplus quantities, EU recognized
5
Among these, only the single payment scheme (SPS) and harvest insurance were financed in the wine
sector between 2008 and 2015. Support for setting up mutual funds was created in order to provide
assistance to producers seeking to insure themselves against market fluctuations. The measure is subject
to national (and local) choices and covers the amounts paid by the mutual fund to holders of financial
compensation.
6
Article 68 allowed all Member States to retain up to 10% of their national ceilings for direct payments
to provide support to specific sectors, for an expanded range of purposes: payments for disadvantages
faced by specific sectors (dairy, beef, sheep and goats, and rice) economically vulnerable, support for risk
assurance in the form of contributions to crop insurance premium, contributions to mutual funds for
animal and plant diseases, and so on.
mmorag@uchile.cl
272 P. Corsinovi and D. Gaeta
7
In the political economy mechanism of quality wine regulation, Meloni and Swinnen (2013) provide
interesting analyses of the expenditure distribution effects.
8
The basic principle of the planting rights measures is that vines cannot be planted unless a right to
replant or a right to make a new planting is held by the vine-grower. The CMO in 2013 abolished the
total ban on the planting of new vineyards and replaced the transitional planting rights from 2016 to
2030 by a new system of authorizations for vine planting, for which Member States shall make available
each year authorizations for new plantings corresponding to 1% of the total area actually planted with
vines in their territory, as measured on 31 July of the previous year. Planting rights granted to producers,
which have not been used by those producers, may be converted into authorizations as from 1 January
2016. Member States may decide to allow producers to submit requests to convert rights into authoriza-
tions until 31 December 2020. As a replacement, personal authorizations are granted free of charge,
which are no longer transferable to the market.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The European Wine Policies: Regulations and Strategies 273
While the EU debated on how to resolve the high budgetary expenditures and
the consequences of overproduction and wine stock, the international compe-
tition was becoming ever stiffer.
In 2005 accumulated wine stocks represented the equivalent of one year of
production and the structural surplus was estimated at approximately 14.5
million hl, equivalent to 8.5% of the total production. The EU wine produc-
ers were finding themselves at a disadvantage compared to those from third
countries, who were often represented by a few restrictive production and
market rules, large multinationals, and massive marketing operations. One of
the greatest fears for the EU Agriculture Commission was the “attack” of new
wine players on EU market: the imports from New World wine countries
have increased substantially and the EU wine market was confronted with a
reduction in the demand for domestic produced wines as overall consump-
tion of wine has decreased especially in the most wine-procuring countries
(EU Commission 2006). Although intentions were good, the problem was
resolved too late. Among traditional European producer and/or consumer
countries, the main EU producer countries (France, Italy, and Spain) show a
negative average between 2000 and 2013. These values demonstrate the dif-
ficulty that EU countries have covering internal consumption (Gaeta and
Corsinovi 2014).
After 38 years from the first CMO wine and less than 10 years from the
reform 1493/99, a new CMO orientation identified by the author as orienta-
mmorag@uchile.cl
274 P. Corsinovi and D. Gaeta
13.3 H
istorical Expenditure and Provisional
Distribution
The percentage of expenditures on the wine policy is represented in Fig. 13.1.
The period 1970–2015 covers all of policy implementation period. During
this time, orientation 1 price and income support represented the most impor-
tant spending between 1970 and 2015 (almost 70% of the total); 24% of the
total budget was designated for orientation 2 quality wines, and only 4% rep-
resented the amount for competitiveness (orientation 3).
In recent years, during the decade 2001–2010, half of the spending (47.5%
of the total) occurred to support quality interventions. This value increased in
the last six years of the decade while reaching 54.4% of the expenditure, fol-
lowed by 25.3% in competitiveness and 20.3% for the price and income
support.
Table 13.2 focuses on main expenditure cost line items in millions of euros
and % of the total budget. As shown in the table, the spending for the distil-
lation scheme was more than €9.60 billion in the period 1970–2015. Market
withdrawals of wine, as political consequences of distillations schemes, has
risen more than €6.6 billion in the same period. It represented more than
mmorag@uchile.cl
The European Wine Policies: Regulations and Strategies 275
one-third of all the wine budget costs used in 45 years (€45.027 billion). The
buying-in of alcohol from compulsory distillation amounts more than 9% of
the payments in the whole period with average cost around €1.5 billion (every
ten years), while the aid for concentrated grape must was around €3.5 billion
in 1970–2015 (7.8% of the total).
25.3 Competitiviness
2011-2015 54.4
20.3
Quality wines
2.7
2001-2010 47.5
49.9 Price and ncome support
0
1991-2000 20.2
79.8
0
1981-1990 1.9
98.1
0
1971-1980 1.7
98.3
4.3
1970-2015 24.1
71.6
0 20 40 60 80 100
Fig. 13.1 Policy orientations through the % of budget expenditure. (Source: Author’s
dataset (elaboration from EAGGF annual expenditures), 2015)
9. By-product
distillation
7%
1. Single
payments
scheme
12%
7. Investments in
enterprises 2. Promotion
23% 19%
3. Restructuring and
conversion
39%
mmorag@uchile.cl
276 P. Corsinovi and D. Gaeta
9
(1) Single payment scheme, (2) promotion in third countries, (3) restructuring and reconversion, (4)
green harvesting, (5) mutual funds, (6) harvest insurance, (7) investments, (8) use of concentrated grape
must, (9) by-product distillation, (10) potable alcohol distillation, and (11) crisis distillation. The first
nine measures were called definitive measures (2009–2013), which could be activated for the new CMO’s
entire programming period. The others (such as potable alcohol distillation, crisis distillation, and aid for
the use of must for enrichment or concentrated musts) could be used for a maximum of four years
(phasing-out measures) and are taken from the market support mechanisms provided for in the previous
CMO.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The European Wine Policies: Regulations and Strategies 277
scheme for the NPS programmed from 2019 to 2023. The 2013 CMO
reforms introduce as a new measure innovation in the wine sector aiming at
the development of new products, processes, and technologies concerning the
wine products. Furthermore it opens promotion measures to information in
Member States, with a view to informing consumers about the responsible
consumption of wine and about the Union systems covering designations of
origin and geographical indications. It also extends the restructuring and con-
version of vineyards to replanting of vineyards where that is necessary follow-
ing mandatory grubbing up for health or phytosanitary reasons. The regulation
provides for more streamlined national programs with only 9 eligible mea-
sures rather than 11 of the 2008 wine policy: (1) SPS; (2) promotion; (3)
restructuring and conversion (3) a, replanting of vineyards for health or phy-
tosanitary reasons); (4) green harvesting; (5) mutual funds; (6) harvest insur-
ance, (7) investments in enterprises; (8) Innovation; and (9) by-product
distillation.10 Looking at the distribution of funds, restructuring and vineyard
reconvention represent the largest share of the future wine policy followed by
the investments and promotion.
There can be no doubt that the move to eliminate and reduce the economic
funds to market measures was well intentioned after more than 30 years, as it
aimed to increase the efficiency and competitiveness of the European wine
sector. The hope was for a future where wine makers would produce for the
market and not for the distiller.
Who exactly had benefitted from these measures thus far? Undoubtedly,
those with the biggest interest in obtaining aid for distillation were large-scale
vineyards, which found themselves able to reallocate huge volumes of must
and wine that would otherwise be in excess of market demand. Thus, in an
anticompetitive manner, these aid payments rewarded those businesses not
controlling production variables, safe in the knowledge that community sub-
sidies would always be there.
During more than 45 years of wine reforms, both internal and interna-
tional measures described in the previous three different phases represent an
example of compromise between protectionist and liberalist policy, with obvi-
ously different effects on the market.
The new programs no longer contain potable alcohol distillation, crisis distillation, funds for grape
10
mmorag@uchile.cl
278 P. Corsinovi and D. Gaeta
Among the wine literature, the political economy mechanism that created the existing set of European
11
quality wine regulations is shown by Meloni and Swinnen (2013) and Gaeta and Corsinovi (2014); while
other authors develop a political economy model of the size of geographical indications (Moschini et al.
2008; Deconinck and Swinnen 2014).
mmorag@uchile.cl
The European Wine Policies: Regulations and Strategies 279
distinctive of the wider area. This is closely connected to the terroir as specific
soils have a certain physical homogeneity, meaning that the nature of the soil
can pass on a particular characteristic to its produce, notably to wine (Josling
2006). This term may thus be defined as the terroir, the place of production,
and more specifically it is often used to indicate a specific name or legally
defined vineyard and the vines that grow on that terroir. An example, or per-
haps a model, of this is the French term cru. In reality, the stronger the link
with the area of origin is, the richer the system is in terms of legislative speci-
fications and production restrictions. Many restrictions are also imposed by
producers’ organizations or consortia in the production protocols such as pro-
hibition of bottling the wine outside the geographical production area (e.g.
Rioja; Chianti Classico, etc.); many wines cannot be exported in bulk
(Corsinovi and Gaeta 2015). From 2008, the EU law for quality wine consists
of two types of classification: (1) Protected Denomination of Origin (PDO)
regarding quality wines produced in a specified region and (2) Protected
Geographical Indication (PGI) regarding quality wines with geographical indi-
cation. PDO and PGI refer to the geographical names and qualifiers corre-
sponding to the regions of production, used to designate the wines referred to
in regulations, whose characteristics depend on the natural conditions, cor-
related to its viticulture characteristics (Gaeta and Corsinovi 2014).
The new EU wine regulations are largely inspired by the legislation applying
to agricultural products and foodstuffs. At the international level, GIs are
legally provided for by the WTO Agreement on Trade-Related Aspect of
Intellectual Property rights (TRIPS).
In recent years the EU has held several bilateral negotiations for free trade
agreements with third countries with the aims on one hand to reduce tariff
and duties and open new markets and increase sales in both developed and
emerging markets and provide on the other hand for the protection and rec-
ognition of specific quality production (Cogeca 2014).
Since 1994, the EU has developed specific agreements for protection of GIs
for wines and spirits with other key producing countries, beginning with
Australia (1994, renewed 2008), Chile (2002), South Africa (2002), Canada
(2003), and the USA (2006, updated 2011).12 However, such initiative has
12
DG AGRI Working Document on international protection of GIs: objectives, outcomes, and chal-
lenges, 25 June 2012.
mmorag@uchile.cl
280 P. Corsinovi and D. Gaeta
not made much progress due to opposition, in particular, from the USA,
Australia, Chile, New Zealand, Argentina, Canada, and Japan. Until the
TRIPS agreement will not offer adequate protection for European GIs, the
EU is seeking this objective through different types of bilateral agreements
(Cogeca 2014).
The EU wine sector has consolidated its market share in the last ten years
as a first market destination for the top five EU wine-producing countries
(Italy, France, Spain, and Portugal). The USA plays a key role for the EU wine
business firms as the first market destination outside Europe in terms of value
and volume (OIV 2016).
For these reasons the EU-US trade agreement—Transatlantic Trade and
Investment Partnership (TTIP)—has taken on an important role among the
EU trade policy. However, after three years of negotiation and with the new
US President from November 2016, the negotiation seems to be far removed
from to the final agreement. Its objective sought by policymakers is to remove
trade barriers (tariffs, unnecessary regulation, restrictions on investment, etc.)
to a wide range of economic sectors, including agriculture, in order to make
it easier to buy and sell goods and services between the two partners. Rickard
et al. (2014) have analyzed the impacts of the proposed EU-US free trade
agreement on wine markets. They develop parameters to characterize the
effects of tariffs and domestic regulations that affect production and con-
sumption of wine between EU and the USA. The authors “show that reduc-
tions in tariffs would have relatively small effects in these wine markets,
whereas reductions in EU domestic policies that affect wine grape production
would have much larger trade and welfare implications”.
The 2006 agreement between the EU and the USA on the marketing of
wine did not resolve the issue and did not venture into who, prior to it being
stipulated, had the possibility of using names, which at that point were con-
sidered to be “semi-generic” and were then promoted to “generic”. As a con-
sequence of this, American producers who in the past had marketed their
wine under the names in question (such as Californian Chianti) could con-
tinue to do so. Looking back at where this all started, two important points
arise.
The first is linked to the American classification system. The second is
linked to the incomplete nature of the TRIPS agreement.
In relation to the first of these points as regards the American Classification
system, the US Department of the Treasury, which is responsible for the
Alcohol and Tobacco Tax and Trade Bureau (TTB) under the section of the
Code of Federal Regulations (CFR) on labeling and promotion of wine prod-
ucts, created a classification system for geographically relevant symbols.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The European Wine Policies: Regulations and Strategies 281
13
Vermouth is a type of aperitif wine compounded from grape wine, having the taste, aroma, and charac-
teristics generally attributed to vermouth and shall be so designated.
14
It should be specified that when the first European pioneer from the “old country” made wine in
California from Vitis vinifera grapes that looked, smelled, and tasted like what they knew at home, they
called it by old country names. By the early 1880s, names like Champagne, Burgundy, and so on were
commonly used to describe wine similar to those grown in France (Muscatine et al. 1984).
mmorag@uchile.cl
282 P. Corsinovi and D. Gaeta
mmorag@uchile.cl
The European Wine Policies: Regulations and Strategies 283
13.4.2 T
he Protection of Traditional Wine Terms
and Their Origins
The system described above has never been launched, and as the interpreta-
tion of the standards is done on the basis of national decisions, this has been
the outcome. One the one hand, EU is calling for more protection for wines,
and on the other, the USA is using strong arm tactics. It is precisely the pro-
tection of traditional terms that is an important issue being discussed in
Brussels’ European quarter and US wine departments. They are well and truly
a characteristic specific to the wine sector. They provide (or perhaps “should
provide”) protection to certain designations traditionally associated with spe-
cific wines bearing a designation or indication of origin (Table 13.3). These
terms are particularly complex as they face many problems and are of interest
to a broad range of political actors (Member States and EU and non-EU wine
organizations).
At EU level, two different types of traditional terms are included in the
CMO. The first type is used for PDO or PGI. The second type is used for
production or aging methods, quality, color, type of place, or for a particular
event linked to the history of the product with a PDO or PGI. In addition to
this, all terms and all new information connected to the protection of tradi-
tional terms are entered and updated in the EU’s E-Bacchus database.15
Traditional terms do not however constitute intellectual and industrial prop-
erty rights like PDO and PGI but instead refer to production, processing, or
aging details or to the quality, color, and type of place included and recog-
nized on the label. In order to avoid discrimination between wines originating
in the Union and those imported from third countries, terms traditionally
used in third countries may obtain recognition and protection as traditional
terms in the Union also where they are in conjunction with GIs and DOs
regulated by those third countries.
In order to be able to use EU traditional terms (TTs) on the community
market (see Table 13.3, bearing in mind that these terms include Riserva,
Brunello, Amarone, Vin Santo, Château, Torcolato, and Governo all’uso toscano),
third countries must demonstrate that the traditional terms in question are
regulated by applicable standards, including those laid down by representative
15
The E-Bacchus database is the register of EU PDOs and PGIs protected under the single CMO. This
includes the list of GIs and DOs for third countries protected in the EU following the implementation
of bilateral agreements on trade in wine and signed between the EU and the third countries concerned.
E-Bacchus also includes the list of traditional terms protected in the EU under the single CMO
Regulation.
mmorag@uchile.cl
284 P. Corsinovi and D. Gaeta
mmorag@uchile.cl
The European Wine Policies: Regulations and Strategies 285
Table 13.3 (continued)
Historical
Place of Production and Quality wine
States origin aging method characteristics typology Color
Spain Añejo; Chacolí- Amontillado; Dorado
Txakolina; Fino; Superior
Clásico
Criaderas y
Solera;
Crianza;
Fondillón;
Pajarete;
Pálido; Solera;
Sobremadre
Gran Reserve;
Lágrima;
Noble;
Oloroso; Vino
Maestro
Vendimia Inicial;
Vino de Tea
Portugal Canteiro; Fino; Superior; Escuro;
Frasqueira; Super Reserva; Ruby
Garrafeira; Reserva velha
Nobre; Solera; (ou grande
Leve; Làgrima reserva);
Vintage
Source: Author’s creation from E-Bacchus database (2015) and EU Regulation
607/2009
professional organizations from the third country; that the terms enjoy a good
reputation within the third country; that the terms have been used tradition-
ally for at least ten years in the third country; and that the third country’s
regulations are clear enough so as not to mislead the consumer about the term
in question. Many of these terms relate to famous wine countries or place or
particular expressions. Table 13.3 tried to divide the main traditional terms
according to their main characteristics like place of origin, production method
and aging method, quality characteristics, historical wine typology, and color:
Many of them identify both the quality characteristics that historical typol-
ogy. For example, in France the traditional term “Château” refers to the
historical expression related to a type of area and to a type of wine and is
reserved to wines coming from an estate which really exists or which is called
exactly by this word. “Cru artisan” and “bourgeois” are expressions related
to the quality of a wine, to its history, and to a type of area evoking a hierar-
chy of merit between wines coming from a specific estate (PDO “Médoc”,
mmorag@uchile.cl
286 P. Corsinovi and D. Gaeta
mmorag@uchile.cl
The European Wine Policies: Regulations and Strategies 287
USTR stated that EU regulations on the use of terms such as Riserva, Rubino,
Chateau, and Tawny restrict the ability of non-EU wine producers to use
these terms on their wines sold in Europe: terms which the USTR considers
to be common, descriptive, and commercially valuable.
It can be argued that rules for wine may acquire or lose relevance depend-
ing on the economic importance of other sectors covered by the agreements,
as trade-offs between different types of traded goods (or services) are likely to
occur.
Is it really a problem of international competition and protection for the
European wine sector, or is it more a political and therefore lobbying debate?
mmorag@uchile.cl
288 P. Corsinovi and D. Gaeta
is changing. There can be no doubt after more than 30 years that the move to
eliminate and reduce economic funds to market measures, like distillation,
and which we called phase one, was well intentioned; it aimed to increase the
efficiency and competitiveness of the European wine sector. This move may
have been too late, with millions of euros thrown in the garbage basket of a
privileged lobby made of cooperatives and farmers who survived without a
real market and only with the holy help of their deputies in the EU Parliament
in phase one.
There is no doubt also that a concrete forward step in international com-
petitiveness was brought through quality policies that increased and fortified,
with PDO and PGI production, the characteristics of the EU quality wine
personality in the world market.
The EU is still moving from the administration of protection—quotas,
tariffs, and subsidies—to the administration of precaution: security, safety,
health, and environmental sustainability. This is the new version of the old
divide between tariff and non-tariff barriers.
In summarizing the best and worst EU wine decisions, special evaluation of
the EU international wine policy should be undertaken. Every phase described
shows that it is still concerned with a strong protective action, both through
tariff and non-tariff measures. International free trade agreements slowly keep
on entertaining Brussels’ bureaucrats without reaching a final agreement.
References
Anderson, K., ed. 2004. The world’s wine markets: Globalization at work. Cheltenham:
Edward Elgar.
———. 2010. Excise and import taxes on wine versus beer and spirit: An interna-
tional comparison. Economic Papers 29 (2): 215–228.
———. 2014. Excise taxes on wines, beers and spirits: An updated international com-
parison. Working paper No. 170, American Association of Wine Economists,
October.
Anderson, K., and H. Jensen. 2016. How much does the European Union assist its
wine producers? Journal of Wine Economics 11 (2): 289–305.
Appiano, E.M., and S. Dindo. 2007. Le Pratiche Enologiche e la Tutela delle
Denominazioni d’Origine nell’Accordo UE/USA sul Commercio Del vino.
Contratto e impresa/Europa, Cedam 12 (1): 455–500.
Cogeca. 2014. Study on the competitiveness of European wines: Final report. http://
ec.europa.eu/agriculture/external-studies/2014/eu-wines/fulltext_en.pdf
Corsinovi, P., and D. Gaeta. 2015. Managing the quality wines beyond policies and
business strategies. Review of Contemporary Business Research 4 (1): 24–31.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The European Wine Policies: Regulations and Strategies 289
———. 2016. The EU wine policy orientations through the budget expenditure analysis
(1970–2015). Annual American Association of Wine Economists (AAWE) June
21–25, 2016, Bordeaux (France).
———. 2017. EU wine policies and their consequences on the global wine trade.
Economia Agroalimentare/Food Economy 19 (1): 59–88.
Council Regulation (EC) No. 1493/1999 of 17 May 1999 on the common organiza-
tion of the market in wine.
Council Regulation (EC) No. 479/2008 of 29 April 2008 on the common organisa-
tion of the market in wine, amending Regulations (EC) Nos. 1493/1999,
1782/2003, 1290/2005, and 3/2008 and repealing Regulations (EEC) Nos.
2392/86 and 1493/1999.
Council Regulation (EC) No. 607/2009 of 14 July 2009 laying down certain detailed
rules for the implementation of Council Regulation (EC) No. 479/2008 as regards
protected designations of origin and geographical indications, traditional terms,
labelling and presentation of certain wine sector products.
Council Regulation (EEC) No. 816/70 of 28 April 1970 laying down additional
provisions for the common organization of the market in wine.
Council Regulation (EEC) No. 817/70 of 28 April 1970 laying down special provi-
sions relating to quality wines produced in specific regions.
Council Regulation (EEC) No. 822/87 of 16 March 1987 on the common organiza-
tion of the market in wine.
Council Regulation (EEC) No. 823/87 of 16 March 1987 laying down special provi-
sions relating to quality wines produced in specified regions.
Dal Bianco, A., V. Boatto, F. Caracciolo, and F.G. Santeramo. 2016. Tariffs and non
tariff frictions in the world wine trade. European Review of Agricultural Economics
43 (1): 31–57.
Deconinck, K., and J. Swinnen. 2014. The political economy of geographical indica-
tions. AAWE working paper No. 174, December.
European Commission. 2002. DG Agriculture Tender AGRI/Evaluation/2002/6:
“Ex-post evaluation of the Common Market Organisation for wine”. Available at:
http://ec.europa.eu/agriculture/eval/reports/wine/fullrep_en.pdf
———. 2006. Towards a sustainable European wine sector. Communication from the
Commission to the Council and the European Parliament.
Gaeta, D., and P. Corsinovi. 2014. Economics, governance, and politics in the wine
market: European Union developments. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Josling, T. 2006. The war on terroir: Geographical indications as a transatlantic trade
conflict. Journal of Agriculture Economics 57 (3): 337–363.
Mariani, A., E. Pomarici, and V. Boatto. 2012. The international wine trade: Recent
trends and critical issues. Wine Economics and Politics 1 (1): 24–40.
Meloni, G., and J.F.M. Swinnen. 2013. The political economy of European wine
regulations. Journal of Wine Economics 8 (3): 244–284.
Montaigne, E., and A. Coelho. 2006. Reform of the common organisation of the
market. In Wine Study Requested by The European Parliament’s Committee on
Agriculture and Rural Development. Brussels.
mmorag@uchile.cl
290 P. Corsinovi and D. Gaeta
Moschini, G., L. Menapace, and D. Pick. 2008. Geographical indications and the
competitive provision of quality in agricultural markets. American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 90 (3): 794–812.
Muscatine, D., A.M. Amerin, and B. Thompson. 1984. Book of California wine.
Berkeley, Los Angeles/London: University of California Press/Sotheby Publications.
Niederbacher, A. 1983. Wine in the European Community. Office for Official
Publication of the European Communities, Periodical 2/3-1983, Luxembourg.
OIV. 2016. State of the vitiviniculture world market (April 2016). Available at http://
www.oiv.int/public/medias/4710/oiv-noteconjmars2016-en.pdf
Pomarici, E., and R. Sardone. 2001. Il Settore Vitivinicolo In Italia. Strutture Produttive,
Mercati e Competitività alla Luce della Nuova Organizzazione Comune di Mercato.
Roma: Studi & Ricerche, INEA.
———. 2009. L’OCM Vino. La Difficile Transazione Verso una Strategia di Comparto.
Roma: INEA.
Rickard, B.J., O. Gergaud, S. Ho, and W. Hu. 2014. Trade liberalization in the pres-
ence of domestic regulations: Impacts of the proposed EU-U.S free trade agreement on
wine market. AAWE working paper No. 173, November 2014.
Spahni, P. 1988. The common wine policy and price stabilization. Aldershot/Brookfeild:
Avebury.
mmorag@uchile.cl
14
Barriers to Wine Trade
Angela Mariani and Eugenio Pomarici
14.1 Introduction
Wine has traditionally been traded goods, but only in the past two decades,
the international wine trade has experienced a considerable growth: in the
1960s the exported share of global wine production was 10% and in 1990
this share had reached only 15%. However, by the year 2000 exported pro-
duction had reached 25% of global production and more than 35% in 2017.
More in detail, wine exports were in 2000 about 60 million hectoliters and 17
years later they are higher than 100 million hectoliters. This extraordinary
growth suggests that the international wine trade was rather free to expand,
without relevant hindrances; indeed, in 2010 the share of export from coun-
tries outside regional integrated areas was 60% in value and 52% in volume,
with a 6-year increase of about 6 percentage points (in value and volume)
(Mariani et al. 2014a).
Nevertheless, the international wine trade, like any other trade, is influ-
enced by barriers which, even though they have not prevented the growth of
A. Mariani (*)
Department of Economic and Legal Studies, University of Naples “Parthenope”,
Naples, Italy
e-mail: mariani@uniparthenope.it
E. Pomarici
Department of Land, Environment, Agriculture and Forestry, University of Padua,
Padua, Italy
e-mail: eugenio.pomarici@unipd.it
mmorag@uchile.cl
292 A. Mariani and E. Pomarici
mmorag@uchile.cl
Barriers to Wine Trade 293
mmorag@uchile.cl
294 A. Mariani and E. Pomarici
Due to the presence of specific tariffs, evaluating and comparing the level
of market protection for wine require complex estimates and specific tariffs
should be transformed into the so-called ad valorem equivalent (Babili 2009).1
Overall, tariff protection is quite low in countries which have long been
involved in the wine trade such as the European Union (EU), the USA,
Canada, Australia, and New Zealand (with the notable exception of Japan).
By contrast, the tariff level is high in countries which have recently experi-
enced growing wine imports, that is, mainly Asian markets (Anderson 2010;
Anderson and Nelgen 2011).
Table 14.2 shows the import duties defined according to the principle of
most favored nations for EU. The highest is that applied to sparkling wine,
€0.37/liter, while the lowest, which would be applied to low alcohol bulk
wine, is only €0, 12/liter.
All in all, the impact of tariff barriers on the international wine trade is
rather small, but not negligible. Anderson and Wittwer (2018) simulated
changes in the global wine flows (production, consumption, international
trade) from 2014 to 2015 under various scenarios; in the scenario in which all
import tariffs on wine were to be removed multilaterally, the value of world
wine trade would be 7% greater in 2025 compared to a baseline solution
which includes the likely effect of the UK leaving the EU.
14.3 N
on-tariff Measures as Trade Barriers:
An Overview
A wide and heterogeneous range of policy interventions other than border
tariffs could affect trade costs incurred from producers to final consumer and/
or alter conditions of international trade, including policies and regulations
mmorag@uchile.cl
Barriers to Wine Trade 295
that restrict trade and those that facilitate it. NTMs have the potential to
distort international trade, whether their trade effects are protectionist or not,
and could be applied to imported and exported goods.
For practical purposes, as shown in Table 14.3, NTMs have been catego-
rized by UNCTAD depending on their scope and/or design in 16 chapters (A
to P), with each individual chapter divided into groupings with up to three
layers of subcategories (UNCTAD 2013). The last chapter includes all the
relevant export measures. While the import measures are broadly distin-
guished as:
The WTO provides guidelines for the application of NTMs. Overall, focus-
ing on the import measures, the WTO rules indicate that they must be trans-
parent, not overly restrictive to trade or applied arbitrarily. These rules help
mmorag@uchile.cl
296 A. Mariani and E. Pomarici
mmorag@uchile.cl
Barriers to Wine Trade 297
mmorag@uchile.cl
298 A. Mariani and E. Pomarici
2018; European Commission 2016; USTR 2018; ICE 2010; Battaglene and
Milton 2010; Battaglene 2014):
mmorag@uchile.cl
Barriers to Wine Trade 299
SPS measures and TBTs are subject to WTO regulation under two agree-
ments: the Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade and the Agreement on
Sanitary and Phyto-Sanitary Measures. In brief:
The main principles behind the regulation of such agreements are summa-
rized in Table 14.5 (WTO 2010, 2014).
Implementation of WTO regulations has given rise to some critical issues
for the wine trade. The main issue is that few standards have so far been defined
by the Codex Alimentarius, recognized by the WTO as a standard-setting orga-
nization while the International Organisation of Vine and Wine (OIV),
though an intergovernmental organization committed to establishing techni-
cal and commercial standards for wine, is not recognized by the WTO.2
It should be noted that the problem of non-tariff barriers could further
intensify as some new fast-growing wine-importing countries are setting up
wine market regulations. Furthermore, in some of these countries (including
China, India, and Brazil), growing interest in domestic wine production could
lead to maintaining (or raising) protectionist policies and stepping up support
for local producers.
The OIV has applied to become observer at the WTO but the request has not yet been discussed.
2
mmorag@uchile.cl
Table 14.5 Key elements in SPS and TBT agreements
South
300
EU USA Canada Others in America R-K-B GCC China (#) India Japan Korea AFTA
EU WA WA FTA (Mexico) N FTA FTA N (Singapore,
Malaysia, Vietnam,
Thailand, Philippines,
Indonesia, Myanmar)
USA WA FTA FTA (Mexico-NAFTA) FTA
(NAFTA) FTA (Peru, Colombia,
Panama, and
CAFTA-DR)
Chile FTA FTA FTA FTA (MERCOSUR) FTA FTA FTA FTA FTA (Singapore,
Thailand, Vietnam)
Australia WA FTA FTA (Perù) N (Mexico, N FTA N N FTA FTA (Singapore,
A. Mariani and E. Pomarici
mmorag@uchile.cl
FTA (AANZFTA)
Source: Our elaboration
Explanatory notes:
WA wine agreement, FTA free trade agreement, N negotiation ongoing for FTA, M member
CAFTA-DR Dominican Republic-Central America FTA (Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Nicaragua, and the Dominican
Republic)
NAFTA North American FTA (USA, Canada, and Mexico)
MERCOSUR South American FTA (Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay, Uruguay, and Venezuela)
R-K-B: FTA among Russia, Kazakhstan, Belarus
GCC Gulf Cooperation Council (Bahrain, Kuwait, Oman, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, and United Arab Emirates; Jordan and Morocco have
been invited to join)
AFTA ASEAN FTA (Brunei, Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand, Vietnam, Laos, Myanmar, and Cambodia). Unlike the
EU, AFTA does not apply a common external tariff on imported goods
AANZFTA FTA among ASEAN, Australia, and New Zealand
(#) Since 2008 wine imports to Hong Kong and Macao have not been subject to tariffs and there are no certification requirements
Barriers to Wine Trade 301
3
The WWTG is presented in Chap. 12 (The International Wine Organisations and Plurilateral
Agreements and The Dialectic Between Harmonisation and Mutual Recognition of Standards Raúl
Compés López).
4
Australia, Brunei Darussalam, Canada, Chile, People’s Republic of China, Hong Kong, Indonesia,
Japan, Republic of Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, New Zealand, Papua New Guinea, Peru, the Philippines,
Russia, Singapore, Chinese Taipei, Thailand, the USA, Vietnam.
mmorag@uchile.cl
302 A. Mariani and E. Pomarici
5
FIVS-Abridge is a comprehensive, up-to-date, and interactive database of international regulations and
trade agreements covering wine. FIVS-Abridge consists of a database of national regulations and relevant
international agreements for markets around the world, covering topics such as certification, composi-
tion, labeling, marketing, packaging, production, promotion, tariffs, taxation, and transportation (http://
fivs-abridge.com/index.htm).
mmorag@uchile.cl
Barriers to Wine Trade 303
mmorag@uchile.cl
304 A. Mariani and E. Pomarici
6
Japan-Australia Economic Partnership Agreement (JAEPA) entered into force on 15 January 2015. The
bulk wine tariff (> 150 liters) was eliminated on entry into force of the agreement. The tariff for wine in
containers (> 10 l < 150 l) will be eliminated over ten years. The wine tariff for bottled (and bag-in-
box < 10 liters) wine will be eliminated on 1 April 2021.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Barriers to Wine Trade 305
mmorag@uchile.cl
306 A. Mariani and E. Pomarici
Over time, Australia and New Zealand have negotiated FTAs that phase
out tariffs on wine with other Asian countries, such as Thailand and the
Philippines. A FTA is in force with the Association of South-East Asian
Nations (ASEAN) countries (AANZFTA), overall with limited tariff reduc-
tion for wine (or total exclusion for religious or cultural sensitivities such as
for Malaysia).
In the Chinese market Chile and New Zealand have got an important
advantage over competitors, as both countries (Chile in 2005 and New
Zealand in 2008) have signed FTAs. Tariffs on wine imports (14% for bot-
tled wine and 20% for bulk wine) have been progressively reduced, to reach
zero in 2012 for New Zealand and, in 2015, for Chile. As a result, Chile
and New Zealand have been able to enjoy a significant advantage over com-
petitors (ABARES 2012). Later on, Australia signed a FTA in 2015 where
tariffs on wine will be eliminated within four years (from 14% to 11.2%
and then by a further 2.8% on January 1 every year until it reaches zero in
2019).
The EU and China, inside the “EU-China 2020 Strategic Agenda for
Cooperation”, have concluded in 2017 a bilateral agreement that will result in
the protection, against imitations and usurpations, of 100 European geo-
graphical indications (of which more than half related to wine) in China and
100 Chinese geographical indications in the EU. Cooperation between the
EU and China on geographical indications began over ten years ago, leading
to the protection in 2012 of ten geographical indication names on both sides
(“10+10” project).
Currently no country has agreements with Russia. (Negotiations were
ongoing with New Zealand; however, they were suspended in 2014 following
events in the Ukraine.) Russia joined the WTO in late 2011, and while its
high wine tariffs are likely to decrease over time, a complex and non-predictable
assortment of non-tariff barriers (mainly certification and customs proce-
dures) continues to be the biggest obstacles to entering this market. Recently
trade relation between Russia and the main Western countries has become
very controversial, as trade sanctions (embargo on imports) have been used
for political reasons by western countries supporting the Ukraine, all this in
response to Russia’s occupation of Crimea. Starting in 2014, Russia banned
some major food products (pork, poultry, fish and seafood, vegetables and
dairy products), from the EU, the USA, Canada, Australia, and Norway.
After, the embargo was extended to include Albania, Montenegro, Iceland
and Liechtenstein, the Ukraine, and Turkey (in October 2016 the embargo
on Turkish food was relaxed slightly). Wine up to now has been excluded
mmorag@uchile.cl
Barriers to Wine Trade 307
from retaliation against major exporters,7 but Russia has first banned wine
imports from Georgia, between 2006 and 2013, and recently (2017) from
Montenegro.
The emergence of an increasing number of FTAs between wine-producing
countries and emerging consumer markets could change the mid- to long-
term dynamics of the global wine market.
Overall it is to be stressed that, among the New World wine countries,
Chile has focused much of its marketing strategy on wine export opportuni-
ties (Wehner 2009). As a result of its success in negotiating FTAs, it has
obtained preferential market access to the top developed and emerging wine
markets around the world. In contrast another important Latin-American
wine-producing country like Argentina, after joining the Mercado Común
del Sur (MERCOSUR), lost the possibility to sign any FTA on its own. This
lack of openness toward international trade, according to Del Bianco et al.
(2017), contributes to explain the country’s weak export performance. In
addition, it is to be mentioned that Argentina is the only major wine producer
to have imposed a 5% tax on the value of exported wines.
Australia and New Zealand have also been very active in negotiations to
reach agreements with emerging wine-importing Asian countries. In particu-
lar Australia has been able to bridge the gap with other competitors in two
major markets such as South Korea and China even though these competitors
had already obtained improved access to those markets through their own
FTAs (Anderson and Wittwer 2015).
In this scenario, EU exporters without a preferential access to China could
continue to face a disadvantage as New World producing countries, thanks to
existing trade deals, would be able to consolidate their positions. Overall, the
EU has been able to sign several FTAs that allow better access to markets and
an increase of GIs’ protection for wines.
7
However, wine imports to Russia in the period 2015–2016 have been significantly lower than in the
previous two years; imports then rose to the pre-crisis levels (2013, 5 million hl for €920,000; 2017, 4.7
million hl for €880,000).
mmorag@uchile.cl
308 A. Mariani and E. Pomarici
The world economic globalization process has been governed for a long time
by the paradigm of multilateral liberalization following the WTO’s rules. The
failure of the Doha round, together with the increase in the economic and
political weight of the major developing countries on the international scene,
mainly in the Asia-Pacific region, and, more recently, the US President Trump
strategy called “America first”, led to more complex and less predictable inter-
national relations.
In particular the USA seems to propose moving away from multilateral or
regional arrangements with multiple trade partners to bilateral agreements
where they can stress more their negotiation strength. Up to now, the USA
has withdrawn from the Trans-Pacific Partnership and has requested to rene-
gotiate the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). Furthermore,
they intend to rebalance trade with those countries that experienced the most
commercial surplus in respect to the USA, such as China and Germany
(ISMEA 2017), and start to increase tariff on some products (steel and
aluminum).
In such context, the USA runs a significant deficit in food and agricultural
trade with the EU. The threat to apply protectionist measures could have a
major impact on EU exports of food products and in particular wine, given
its great importance in trade with the USA: EU countries export wine for €10
billion, of which one third is exported to the USA.
Furthermore, the USA contests that the EU’s GI system contributes to the
asymmetry (trade deficit) in US-EU trade in agricultural products for prod-
ucts subject to the EU’s GI regime.
The Special 301 Report of the annual review of the state of intellectual
property protection and enforcement in US trading partners around the
world states that “The United States is working intensively through bilateral
and multilateral channels to advance U.S. market access interests in foreign
markets and to ensure that GI-related trade initiatives of the EU, its Member
States, like-minded countries, and international organizations, do not under-
cut such market access” (USTR 2017, p. 22).
mmorag@uchile.cl
Barriers to Wine Trade 309
The EU GI agenda remains highly concerning for the USA, for several
reasons. In the first place, the EU GI system raises concerns regarding the
extent to which it impairs the scope of trademark protection, including a
respect to prior trademark rights. Secondly, some troubling aspects of the EU
GI system influence access for the USA and other producers to the EU mar-
ket. Lastly, EU continues to seek to expand its GI system beyond its border,
through bilateral trade agreements and in multilateral and plurilateral bodies
as well (such as the WIPO Lisbon Agreement) which impose the negative
impact of the EU GI system on market access and trademark protection in
third countries.
The USA is trying to fight the EU’s aggressive promotion of its exclusionary
GI policies through FTAs negotiation, as well as in international forums,
including APEC, WIPO, and the WTO. “In addition to these negotiations,
the United States is engaging bilaterally to address concerns resulting from the
GI provisions in existing EU trade agreements, agreements under negotiation,
and other initiatives, including with Canada, China, Costa Rica, Ecuador, El
Salvador, Indonesia, Japan, Malaysia, Morocco, the Philippines, South Africa,
and Vietnam, among others” (USTR 2017, p. 23).
Brexit, the parting of the UK from the EU, is going to modify the interna-
tional wine trade scenario as the UK is one of the most important players in
the wine market. The UK currently represents the first wine consumer market
among non-producing countries, the second wine importer in value and vol-
ume, and it is also an important re-exporter. Such wine-related trading activi-
ties make the UK the home of a flourishing wine business, which is worth
about £17 billions. When it quits the EU, the UK will leave a wide regional
integrated area and will lose the preferential import and export channels rep-
resented by the preferential agreements arranged by EU with several partners.
As a consequence, wine imports in the UK (13.5 million hectoliters) and wine
exports (about 880,000 hectoliters for a value of €615 million) from the UK
will be exposed to barriers higher than today. How this will happen will
depend on how the UK will define trade relationship with the EU and other
partners. Rollo et al. (2016) suggest that the most practical trade policy for
the UK to adopt when leaving the EU is the EU’s tariff schedules previously
agreed at the WTO. On the base of this assumption, and under the hypoth-
esis that negotiations for preferential arrangement will take years, Anderson
and Wittwer (2017, 2018) have simulated Brexit effects. They forecast that
mmorag@uchile.cl
310 A. Mariani and E. Pomarici
between 2014 and 2025 the growth (in value) of the UK’s wine consumption
and import will be 9% instead of 24%, warning, though, that it will be the
slower income growth to make a smaller wine market in the UK in 2025 than
would otherwise have been the case. As a matter of fact, the import duties
applied in their simulations are the small ones indicated in Table 14.2, which
can play only a minor role.
Anderson and Wittwer’s simulations assume a smooth transition in the
technical aspects of trade between the UK and the EU. But this is a worrying
issue for the wine business community. In October 2017 the most important
bodies representing traders and producers in the UK and Europe signed a
joint declaration8 urging “the EU and the UK to agree to a gold standard
agreement that preserves wine and spirit tariff-free trade and fair competition”
and calling “for predictable, pragmatic, non-disruptive transitional imple-
mentation arrangements, allowing businesses to continue trading in the
knowledge that the rules will not change at all without a phase-in period”.
Indeed, the joint declaration highlights several matters that may endanger
trade flows between the UK and the EU after the transition period, generating
relevant trade barriers, which involve rules concerning oenological practices,
labeling, intellectual property rights protection and in particular GI protec-
tion, custom practices, and people movements. Also in the case of Brexit,
therefore, NTMs will be the true variables which will determine trade flow
evolution.
Last but not least, it should be stressed that the international wine trade is
constrained not only by national technical regulations resulting in non-tariff
barriers but also by private standards. In the last decade there has been an
intense development of private standards, mainly targeting, initially, food
safety (often exceeding requirements established in international standards
developed by the Codex Alimentarius) and in recent years mainly related to
social and environmental aspects. Such standards can be set by individual
firms (usually large retailers), collective national organizations, or interna-
tional standards organizations. Private standards are voluntary, but if required
by large retailers and/or large companies they become de facto mandatory for
suppliers. Such standards do not fall within the rules of the WTO. Indeed,
these standards area matter of increasing concern for all the effects that they
Joint paper about Brexit published by spiritsEUROPE, Comité Européen des Entreprises Vins, Scotch
8
mmorag@uchile.cl
Barriers to Wine Trade 311
may have upon access to international markets, especially for small businesses
(Henson and Humphrey 2009). Private standards, therefore, may operate as
barriers which will discriminate not among countries but among types of
firms or supply chains.
Concerning social and environmental standards, in most wine-producing
countries specific initiatives were developed to measure, communicate, and, in
some cases, certify the compliance of wineries with principles of sustainable
development, that is, environmental, social, and economic sustainability
(Flores 2018; Merlo et al. 2018; Mariani and Vastola 2015). The scope was to
make available to wine producers a simpler and more focused standard com-
pared to ISO standard as ISO 14001 (environmental management) or ISO
26000 (corporate social responsibility). Despite the lower administrative bur-
den of such wine-specific standards, the compliance with their prescription
could be difficult for some actors and, in some circumstances, for all actors in
specific areas resulting in relevant trade barriers (Pomarici et al. 2015; Jourjon
et al. 2016). Moreover, the compliance with such standards, in case of not-
integrated supply chains (bottlers purchasing wine or winery purchasing grape)
may have serious consequences on the overall chain’s governance and on the
linkages among the participants (Cafaggi 2016). As a matter of fact, in order
to guarantee final product compliance with the desired set of requirements, the
lead firms have to apply a strict control upon the whole upward supply chain.
Therefore this compliance asks for specific contracts between participants to
the supply chain, sometimes international,9 which may influence both the
forms and the functions of the chains, and that may result in new barriers to
trade. As a matter of fact, regulatory provisions related to social responsibility
and sustainability expand the scope of contracting along the chain from the
exchange (of products or services) to the regulation (of the process) and pro-
duce changes in the contractual relationships between participants, that is, the
leader chains and the suppliers and eventually their subcontractors.
9
The importance in the wine industry of de-integrated supply chains emerges in many chapters of this
book and with quantitative details in Chap. 23 (Conegliano Valdobbiadene Prosecco case). The increas-
ing relevance of de-integrated supply chains with an international extension is demonstrated by the rise
of international trade of bulk wine, which accounts for near 40% of total export (+ 88% on 2000).
mmorag@uchile.cl
312 A. Mariani and E. Pomarici
by high tariffs and regular wine export faces a variety of technical barriers
related to the particular characteristics of this alcoholic product, which is
obtained with production practices often subject to rules and regulated by
specific labeling systems.
In this scenario, the object of negotiations is a push to negotiate bilateral
agreements, to reduce the impact of tariff and non-tariff barriers which affect
wine trade. In negotiating these agreements, each exporting country targets
specific issues to protect the distinctive elements of their offer and, in so
doing, distorting and diverting effects are generated. It is not easy to assess the
effects of preferential access to the markets on export flow changes, because
the competitive performance is determined by many factors (e.g. exchange
rate, marketing effort) but scientific studies demonstrate the discriminatory
effect of preferential agreements (ABARES 2012) and the heterogeneous
impacts on trade of technical measures (Dal Bianco et al. 2016).
Considered the elements of change discussed in Sect. 14.6, in the future
the impact of tariff and non-tariff barriers could become even stronger and in
such perspective it would be useful to renovate the commitment for a non-
discriminatory reduction of non-tariff barriers at the very least. As Codex
Alimentarius does not cover many relevant concerning issues (and it is not
likely that something will change), it would be desirable to increase the role of
OIV, eventually with an official recognition of this organization by WTO.
Concluding, what looks worth highlighting is that the rules concerning the
wine’s international trade act as barriers but also, as far as NTMs are con-
cerned, act as drivers of specific behavior, which are relevant elements of the
global wine market’s institutional settings. As a matter of fact, such rules,
beyond the discriminatory effects that may operate locally, are likely to sup-
port the consumers’ trust, which is the key element of a fair progress in a
globalized wine market.
References
ABARES – Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics and Sciences.
2012. Consultation with the Australian wine sector on barriers to trade in wine mar-
kets. Report to client prepared for the Grape and Wine Research and Development
Corporation.
Ahearn, R.J. 2011. Europe’s preferential trade agreements: Status, content, and implica-
tions. Congressional Research Service, 7–5700. www.crs.gov, R41143, 1–41.
Anderson, K. 2010. Excise and import taxes on wine versus beer and spirits: An inter-
national comparison. Economic Papers 29 (2): 215–228.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Barriers to Wine Trade 313
Anderson, K., and S. Nelgen. 2011. Global wine markets: A statistical compendium,
1961 to 2009. Adelaide: University of Adelaide Press. www.adelaide.edu.au/press.
Anderson, K., and G. Wittwer. 2015. Impact of Australia’s free trade agreements with
China, Japan and Korea: The case of wine, Wine Economics Research Centre. Working
paper No. 0415.
———. 2017. U.K. and global wine markets by 2025, and implications of Brexit.
Journal of Wine Economics 12 (3): 221–251.
———. 2018. Brexit, follow-on FTAs, and global wine trade, University of Adelaide:
Wine Economics Research Centre, Wine Policy Brief No. 19.
Babili, M. 2009. Ad valorem equivalent in the WTO, NAPC-TPD. Working paper n. 43.
Battaglene, T. 2014. An analysis of ingredient and nutritional labeling for wine. In
BIO Web of Conferences. Vol. 3. EDP Sciences.
Battaglene, T., and C. Milton. 2010. Potential impacts of organic wine regulation as
a technical barrier to trade. In Proceedings of the 33rd World Congress of Vine and
Wine, Tbilisi, Georgia, June 20–27.
Cafaggi, F. 2016. Regulation through contracts: Supply-chain contracting and sus-
tainability standards. European Review of Contract Law 12 (3): 218–258.
COGEA. 2014. Study on the competitiveness of European wine. Brussels: European
Commission.
Dal Bianco, A., M.J. Estrella-Orrego, V.L. Boatto, and A.J. Gennari. 2017. Is
Mercosur promoting trade? Insights from Argentinean wine exports. Spanish
Journal of Agricultural Research 15 (1): 8.
Dal Bianco, A., V. Boatto, F. Caracciolo, and F.G. Santeramo. 2016. Tariffs and non-
tariff frictions in the world wine trade. European Review of Agricultural Economics
43 (1): 31–57.
Disdier, A.C., L. Fontagné, and M. Mimuni. 2007. The impact of regulations on agricul-
tural trade: Evidence from SPS and TBT agreements. CEPII Working papers n. 04.
Dunn, R.M., Jr., and J.H. Mutti. 2004. International economics. New York: Routledge.
European Commission. 2006. Global Europe: Competing in the world, communica-
tion COM (2006) 567.
———. 2010. EU-South Korea free trade agreement: A quick reading guide. Available
at: http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2009/october/tradoc_145203.pdf.
———. 2014. CETA – Summary of the final negotiating results. Available at: https://
trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2014/december/tradoc_152982.pdf.
———. 2016. Report from the commission to the European Parliament and the council
on trade and investment barriers. Available at: http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/
docs/2017/june/tradoc_155642.pdf.
———. 2018. Overview of FTA and other trade negotiations. Available at: http://
trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2006/december/tradoc_118238.pdf.
Financial Times. 2015. The Doha round finally dies a merciful death. Available at:
https://www.ft.com/content/9cb1ab9e-a7e2-11e5-955c-1e1d6de94879.
Flores, S.S. 2018. What is sustainability in the wine world? A cross-country analysis
of wine sustainability frameworks. Journal of Cleaner Production 172: 2301–2312.
mmorag@uchile.cl
314 A. Mariani and E. Pomarici
Henson, S., and J. Humphrey. 2009. The impacts of private food safety standards on the
food chain and on public standard-setting processes. Paper prepared for FAO/WHO.
Available at www.fao.org.
ICE. 2010. Raccolta delle documentazioni necessarie per l’esportazione del vino. Verona.
ISMEA. 2017. L’America first di Trump scenari globali per il commercio agroalimentare.
Jourjon, F., H.C. Chou, A. Gezart, A.E. Kadison, L. Martinat, E. Pomarici, and
R. Vecchio. 2016. Wineries evaluation of costs and benefits of sustainability certi-
fication program: The case of Terra Vitis in France, recent patents on food.
Nutrition and Agriculture 8 (2): 138–147.
Mariani, A., and A. Vastola. 2015. Sustainable winegrowing: Current perspectives.
International Journal of Wine Research 7: 37–48.
Mariani, A., E. Pomarici, and V. Boatto. 2012. The international wine trade: Recent
trends and critical issues. Wine Economics and Policy 1 (1): 24–40.
Mariani, A., F. Napoletano, E. Pomarici, and R. Vecchio. 2014a. Tariff and non-tariff
barriers to wine exports and initiatives to reduce their effects. Agricultural Economics
Review 15 (1): 5–24.
Mariani, A., F. Napoletano, R. Vecchio, and E. Pomarici. 2014b. European wine
exports: The key role of trade policy. EuroChoices 13 (3): 46–53.
Merli, R., M. Preziosi, and A. Acampora. 2018. Sustainability experiences in the
wine sector: Toward the development of an international indicators system.
Journal of Cleaner Production 172: 3791–3805.
Morrison, A., and R. Rabellotti. 2017. Gradual catch up and enduring leadership in
the global wine industry. Research Policy 46 (2): 417–430.
Pomarici, E., R. Vecchio, and A. Mariani. 2015. Wineries’ perception of sustainabil-
ity costs and benefits: An exploratory study in California. Sustainability 7 (12):
16164–16174.
Rickard, B.J., O. Gergaud, S.T. Ho, and F. Livat. 2017. Trade liberalization in the
presence of domestic regulations: Public policies applied to EU and U.S. wine
markets. Applied Economics 50 (18): 2028–2047.
Rollo, J., I. Borchert, K. Dawar, P. Holmes, and L.A. Winters. 2016. The World Trade
Organization: A safety net for a post-Brexit UK trade policy? Briefing paper 1.
UKTPO, University of Sussex. Available at: http://blogs.sussex.ac.uk/uktpo/
files/2017/01/Briefing-paper-1-final-1.pdf.
UNCTAD. 2013. Non-tariff measures to trade: Economic and policy issues for develop-
ing countries for developing countries. Geneva.
USTR (Office of the United States Trade Representative). 2017. Special 301 Report.
Available at: https://upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/4/41/
US-TradeRepresentative-Seal.svg/1200px-US-TradeRepresentative-Seal.svg.png.
———. 2018. National trade estimate report on foreign trade barriers. Available at:
https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/files/Press/Reports/2018%20National%20
Trade%20Estimate%20Report.pdf.
Wehner, L. 2009. Power, governance, and ideas in Chile’s free trade agreement policy,
German Institute of Global and Area Studies (GIGA). Working papers No 102.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Barriers to Wine Trade 315
mmorag@uchile.cl
Part III
Diversity of Organization in the Wine
Industry
mmorag@uchile.cl
15
Introduction: The Diversity
of Organizational Patterns in the Wine
Industry
Adeline Alonso Ugaglia
A. Alonso Ugaglia (*)
Bordeaux Sciences Agro, University of Bordeaux, Gradignan, France
e-mail: adeline.ugaglia@agro-bordeaux.fr
mmorag@uchile.cl
320 A. Alonso Ugaglia
On-farm winemaking
Wineries/ WINE Wine co-operatives
Processing facilities
Wholesalers
Negociants
Large distributors/
Imorters
Brokers
Unions
Importers/Wholesalers INTERMEDIATE BODIES
Direct sales
Direct sales
Direct sales
Retailers (super and
hypermarkets, wine Retailers (super and
stores, HORECA, hypermarkets, winestores,
e-commerce) SALE HORECA, e-commerce)
Consumers
Fig. 15.1 Simplified representation of wine industries for Old and New world coun-
tries. (Source: Author; Note: The dashed arrows reflect the potential financial contract
to buy fresh grapes between producers and co-operatives or between co-operatives
and commercial unions depending of the law status of the co-operative)
15.1 P
roducing Firms: From Producing Grapes
to Selling Wine
The production of grapes and wine rely on different actors according to the
status of the country (Old/New), but it can also vary within a wine industry,
especially in the Old world. For grapes (or must) production, it is possible to
observe simple grape-growing farms in both types of countries. The farms are
producing fresh grapes and sell or deliver them to the following actor in the
chain. But in the Old world, these farms can also be the ones processing, dis-
tributing and/or selling the wine directly to the consumer. They are in this
case very different from the basic grape-growing farms, especially from those
in the New world. This difference has some consequences on the economic
performance of these firms. Regardless of how it is measured, the winemakers’
income has a great variability. This variability is related to differences in size
(area) of farms (economies of scale in the New world) but also in productivity
mmorag@uchile.cl
Introduction: The Diversity of Organizational Patterns in the Wine… 321
and costs of the labor force. The winemakers bottling and selling their wines
also have to support the cost of vinification and commercialization. The price
also plays an important role in the differentiation of winegrowers’ income
levels. But the main difference for winegrowers from Old and New wine
countries relies on yield. The appellation regimes dominating the Old world
constraint yields to preserve quantity and quality of wines on the market,
while yields are not limited in the New world. It means that the production
costs are higher in the Old than in the New world, relative to the quantity
produced per ha. As might be expected from the product differentiation and
market segmentation in France, income differences are quite clearly related to
geographic division into regions (Delord 2011). Wine bottling can be consid-
ered as an alternative element of income differentiation. The appellation sys-
tem is certainly an essential factor to explain the differences in the economic
performance of grape-growing farms, but the collective and individual aspects
of this differentiation should also be distinguished.
mmorag@uchile.cl
322 A. Alonso Ugaglia
Type 1 Integrated governance Same manager for the co-operative(s) and the union
Union model
Type 2 Shared governance Union co-management
Type 3 Fragmented governance Different managers for the co-operative(s) and the union
Fig. 15.2 Diversity of strategies for wine co-operatives. (Source: Corade et Lacour
2015)
mmorag@uchile.cl
Introduction: The Diversity of Organizational Patterns in the Wine… 323
mmorag@uchile.cl
324 A. Alonso Ugaglia
they also come together with new geographical and organized proximities,
prone to the re-dimensioning of the territorial scale of the co-operative action.
These findings were supported by a round of thorough interviews with most
of the managers of the Aquitanian co-operatives created by merger between
1994 and 2006.
Chapter 18 deals with the diversity as a specificity of the wine market.
There are an extremely large variety of wines, as well as producers who make
them. What is important to understand about this diversity is that it is orga-
nized. Diversity is embedded in a complex set of social relationships and is
governed by various institutions. From this perspective, the organization of
this level of variety can be seen as a historical process. The actors involved
constantly seek to ensure their business models are coherent with the current
production and market environment. To achieve this, they do not simply
adjust their own strategy or the way they implement it but also try to change
the environment, where it is needed, by interacting with other decision mak-
ers. In the wine industry this manifests itself as the power game between wine-
growers and merchants. The wine region of Bordeaux is a striking example of
how historically organized diversity can be transformed into the basis of suc-
cess on the wine market. At the same time, this example shows the fragility of
a regional production system which is only temporarily coherent.
References
Cadot, J., A. Alonso Ugaglia, B. Bonnefous, and B. Del’homme. 2016. The horizon
problem in Bordeaux wine co-operatives. International Journal of Entrepreneurship
and Small Business 29 (4): 651–668.
Corade and Lacour. 2015. Les trajectoires d’évolution des coopératives vinicoles
girondines. Canadian Journal of Regional Science 38 (1/3): 29–37.
Couderc, J.P. 2008. Manifeste pour un aggiornamento commercial dans la filière vin
en France. In Introduction, Bacchus 2008, 336p. Paris: Dunod.
Delord, B. 2011. Faits et chiffres : La forte dispersion des revenus dans la viticulture
française. Économie rurale 324 (juillet-août): 60–70.
Lueck, D. 2002. The nature of the farm: Contracts, uncertainty, and organization.
Cambridge: MIT Press.
Martin, J.C. 2008. Terroir et stratégies du négoce dans la filière vitivinicole : une
approche historique. In Bacchus, 2008, 19–38. Paris: Dunod.
Pesme, J.O., M.C. Bélis-Bergouignan, and N. Corade. 2010. Strategic operations
and concentration in the Bordeaux-Aquitaine region. International Journal of
Wine Business Research 22 (3): 308–324.
mmorag@uchile.cl
16
The Organization of Vineyards
and Wineries
Douglas W. Allen and Dean Lueck
That the vineyard, when properly planted and brought to perfection, was the most
valuable part of the farm, seems to have been an undoubted maxim in the ancient
agriculture, as it is in the modern through all the wine countries. … The vine is
more affected by the difference of soils than any other fruit tree. … vineyards are in
general more carefully cultivated than most others, …. In so valuable a produce the
loss occasioned by negligence is so great as to force even the most careless to attention.
[Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations, Book One, Chapter 11].
16.1 Introduction
It is not surprising that Adam Smith would include a discussion of wine in his
great treatise—after all, wine has been in the hearts of poets and at the center
of civilization since the beginning of cultivation. Nor is it surprising, indeed
almost predictable, that Smith would also focus in on the critical economic
aspects of wine. Although most of his discussion relates to the political econ-
omy of old vineyard interests, as opposed to the planting of new vines in an
effort to protect their rents, there is mention of three critical features. First,
wine is a valuable commodity. Second, wine output and quality are heavily
D. W. Allen (*)
Department of Economics, Simon Fraser University, Burnaby, BC, Canada
e-mail: allen@sfu.ca
D. Lueck
Indiana University, Bloomington, IN, USA
mmorag@uchile.cl
326 D. W. Allen and D. Lueck
16.2 T
he Allen and Lueck Framework
of Agricultural Organization
Allen and Lueck (2002) created a general framework for examining farm
organization that relied on three key features. First, all parties involved choose
the organizational structure that maximizes the expected value of the produc-
tive relationship. Second, Nature plays an important twofold role: creating
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Organization of Vineyards and Wineries 327
uncertainty in the year-to-year outputs that masks the actual inputs used in
production and creating predictable seasonal stages of production through
crop cycles, stages, and timeliness. Third, all parties are risk neutral, concerned
only with the expected net value of production. These three features allow the
development of simple models within the context of a specific crop that
depend mostly on the transaction cost constraints of the crop in question.
Difficulties that arise over strategic behavior or risk aversion are avoided, and
straightforward comparative statics are forthcoming.
In the Allen and Lueck framework, output is: Q = h(l, e, k) + θ, where Q is
the observed harvested output which is assumed to have a unit price and l is
land attributes, e is labor effort, k is other capital, and θ ~ (0, σ2) is the ran-
domly distributed composite input of Nature. Any given input can only be
measured with error or might even be unobservable. Because the human
actions h(l, e, k) and the actions of Nature θ cannot be separately identified,
the conditions for transaction costs are present. The logic then is for the par-
ties to choose the form of organization that maximizes the value of this output
subject to the transaction costs that are created with any given type of
organization.1
Allen and Lueck stressed that in agriculture the critical transaction costs
result from conditions “close to the ground” or “at the field level.” Thus, the
ability of farmers to exploit the difficult-to-measure land attributes, underre-
port the crop output, over-report crop inputs, or shirk their labor duties to
their advantage act as major constraints to contracting and vertical integra-
tion. Likewise, land and other capital owners can exploit the labor inputs of
farmers or shirk on the application of their capital inputs. The role Nature
plays at the field level varies by crop, time of year, and over time. When it
comes to the organization of vineyards and wineries, our focus is on the spe-
cific features of grapes and fermentation that allow parties to exploit one
another.
1
“Organizations” can be thought of as a collection or distribution of property rights. Transaction costs are
defined as the costs of establishing and maintaining a distribution of property rights (Allen 1991).
mmorag@uchile.cl
328 D. W. Allen and D. Lueck
product. Wine comes (mostly) from grapes through a process of natural fer-
mentation. If ripe grapes are placed in a container, they begin to break down,
and the natural yeast on the skin interacts with the sugars in the juice to pro-
duce an enzyme to initiate the chemical reaction into alcohol. The fermenta-
tion process stops when all the sugar is converted or the alcohol content is
high enough to kill the yeast. Thus, unlike other so-called processed foods,
wine almost produces itself.2
Unlike most agricultural commodities where the quality range is quite nar-
row, with wine there is an enormous quality dimension, and only the highest
end is fit and desired for human consumption. Thus, although most wine
comes from just one vine species (Vitis vinifera), these produce hundreds of
thousands of wines.3 These various wines differ in appearance (color, clarity),
aroma (intensity, types such as earthy or floral), and taste (sweetness, body,
acidity, tannins, flavors). These in turn are determined by the location of vine-
yard, terrain, viticulture, vinification, storage, and transport. Each of these
general inputs is the result of hundreds of decisions, some of which are
observable.
16.3.1 Vineyards
Unlike other fruits and vegetables, grapes do not like nutrient-rich soils, and
they do well on steeply sloped hillsides due to the enhanced drainage and
sunshine.4 The limited locations for growing grapes fit for wine increase the
scarcity and price of wine land.5 For a given location, the soil fertility, acidity,
heat retention, and soil type determine the best variety, vine density, row
direction, spacing, vine training, pest control, and winter protection. Many of
these decisions are made at the start of the vineyard, but many, like canopy
management, pruning, and timing of harvest involve ongoing on-the-spot
decisions.
Vines, if properly looked after, can produce for 50–100 years. Much of the
processes of layering to fill in gaps and pruning are done by hand and are
almost art forms based on skill and knowledge. Pruning too much can reduce
2
Thornton (2013) has a detailed description of the science of fermentation.
3
Thornton (p. 55, 2013) notes there are many varieties, perhaps in the thousands using a narrow defini-
tion of variety.
4
Thornton (p. 60, 2013).
5
As noted in several chapters of this book, across the world wine is one of the most valuable crops per
acre. The high value of wine land means that the costs of abusing such land are also high.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Organization of Vineyards and Wineries 329
yield, while too little pruning can lower the fruit quality. Likewise canopy
management is critical: too little sun prevents grape growth and composition,
but too much can burn and dehydrate the grapes. Thinning, another hand
process, removes some immature grapes during the growing season to improve
the quality of remaining grapes. Every vineyard manager must decide on the
optimal quantity-quality trade-off. As grapes ripen the acid content starts to
fall, but the sugar content increases, creating another trade-off that has to be
managed to produce the appropriate sugar-acid balance. Grape tasting,
another difficult-to-measure skill, is still the best way to determine the opti-
mal time to harvest.
In each stage of grape production, the conditions for rather large transac-
tion costs exist. Vineyards are location-specific firms that rely on critical natu-
ral ingredients that vary from location-to-location, year-to-year, and
day-to-day. These measurement problems (Barzel 1982) allow costly actions
to hide behind the random inputs of Nature. Vineyards also produce a grape
whose value depends on its quality, and although the quality of the grape can
be measured at some cost, the human inputs required to produce high quality
are difficult to measure.6 When difficult to measure, suppliers of high-quality
inputs have moral hazard incentives. Finally, the grapes themselves are small
and costly to divide at the vineyard and are therefore easy to hide or steal.7
16.3.2 Wineries
Once the grapes are picked, they begin to decay immediately. Because of this
perishability, it is important for them to be crushed soon so fermentation
starts within a proper window. Wine quality at this stage depends heavily on
the ability to manage yeasts, bacteria, sugars, and other chemical elements. In
contrast to the vineyard side of production, where grapes are still grown under
natural conditions similar over the past few centuries, a technical revolution
has taken place in wineries.
Prior to 1850 almost all vineyards were integrated with the winery—the wine
being produced in the farmer’s cellar. Knowledge of the fermentation process
was weak, control of temperature was difficult, and the role of natural elements
was enormous. The result: much of production was not palatable.8 Wine quality
6
Goodhue et al. (2003) note the difficulty of measuring these qualities.
7
Simpson (p. 4, 2009), notes “But transaction costs in viticulture were higher than with most other forms
of agriculture, because nature influenced considerably both the size and quality of the harvest.”
8
Simpson (pp. 5–7, 2009).
mmorag@uchile.cl
330 D. W. Allen and D. Lueck
was so variable and difficult to verify that fraud was common as various impos-
ters sold products under the guise of noted or reputable producers.9
By 1900, technological changes in the form of thermometers, refrigerators,
continuous presses, aero-crushing turbines, sterilizers, and pasteurizers altered
wine production and organization.10 Further innovations came in the form of
cultured yeasts, which are more predictable than the natural yeasts present on
the grapes. Cultured yeasts produce wine with a smaller variance in output
quality. Likewise, the introduction of stainless steel tanks allowed for better
control of temperature, oxygen exposure, and speed of fermentation, reduc-
ing the variance in the flavor of the wine. These innovations not only created
elements of economies of size but drastically reduced the role of Nature in
production. Although the fermentation process remained complicated and
continued to require extreme monitoring, these processes could be directly or
indirectly measured for most qualities of wine.
Because of these technological changes, there has been an interesting orga-
nizational difference between vineyards and wineries. Whereas, at one time
they were both stages of wine production in which Nature (and therefore
transaction costs) played a large role, in the mid-nineteenth and early twenti-
eth century technical innovations occurred that reduced the transaction cost
environment at the winery stage, but not at the level of the vineyard. In the
next section we show how the presence and transformation of transaction
costs have shaped the organization of the wine industry.
Vineyards have historically been family farm operations. Even today, vine-
yards remain relatively small compared to the dramatic increases in farm sizes
9
Simpson (p. 11, 2009) notes that in the late nineteenth century artificial wines made from raisins mixed
with water and sugar accounted for one-sixth of French and one-quarter of Spanish wine consumption.
10
Simpson (p. 9, 2009).
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Organization of Vineyards and Wineries 331
for grains and other important crops. Also as the quality of grape produced at
a given vineyard increases, so does the likelihood of family organization on
that vineyard. In modern times there are large vineyards, often organized
along corporate lines, but they mostly produce low-quality grapes.
In Allen and Lueck (2002), contracting arises when labor, land, and other
capital is owned by different parties and can be combined in low transaction
cost settings. In agriculture, land (and the assets attached to the land) is
often combined with labor through cash rent or share contracts. In a cash
rent contract, the labor owner (the farmer or grower) uses the attributes of
the land assets in exchange for some fixed dollar rent per acre. At the margin,
the price of any given attribute, such as moisture or canopy size, is zero. This
means that when cash rent contracts are used, they provide the farmer with
an incentive to exploit the landowner’s land attributes to increase output and
income to the farmer. Hence, for a grain crop under conventional tillage, the
farmer might cultivate the cash-rented land in such a way that excessively
uses the moisture and soil nutrients to increase the short-run harvest at the
long-run expense to the landowner. If a landowner is able to measure or
monitor this exploitation, this moral hazard could be eliminated. In agricul-
ture, this transaction is simply the cost of doing business with the cash rent
contract.
The most common alternative to cash renting is a share contract, in which
the farmer pays his rent in a fraction of the output rather than in cash. In a
share contract, farmer moral hazard is reduced compared to a cash rent. Even
though the farmer uses the land attributes at a zero marginal price, the mar-
ginal returns of this exploitation are now lowered by the “tax” of the share.
This “tax effect” also reduces the labor effort incentive of the farmer and cre-
ates an incentive to underreport the crop. The potential for underreporting
can be a serious problem for share contracts when the output is easy to hide
and valuable.11
In cases in which crop production has just one major transaction cost prob-
lem: either soil exploitation is important, farmer labor is vital, or crop theft is
critical. When there is just one particular problem at hand, then one of these
two—contracts cash rent or crop share—is often sufficient to manage the
contracting arrangement. For example, alfalfa is a hay crop that is planted
(often not annually), cut periodically throughout the year, baled or stacked,
and sold. For alfalfa, soil exploitation is limited because the farmer has limited
Umbeck (1977) noted that the problem of underreporting in gold mining made share contracts were
11
mmorag@uchile.cl
332 D. W. Allen and D. Lueck
access to the soil nutrients, but crop theft is possible given the size of bales.
Under these conditions, a cash rent contract works well, and virtually all
alfalfa contracts are cash rents. On the other hand, sugarcane grants the farmer
full access to the soil but is impossible to steal given coordination and indus-
trialization required to harvest and process it. For sugarcane, there is also just
one major transaction cost problem (soil exploitation) and virtually all sugar-
cane contracts are crop-share contracts.
In some situations, like the production of grapes, all of the transaction
cost effects are present: land attributes can be exploited, farmer labor easily
shirks, and outputs can be stolen. In these cases the simple one- or two-
dimensional contract used in most agriculture becomes incomplete and
incapable of managing the transaction costs at hand. In these cases, con-
tracting is unlikely.
Consider a vineyard available for contracting with a viticulturist-farmer.
The viticulturist’s incentives are not incentive compatible with the long-
term maintenance of the vines and grape stocks, and moral hazard results.
To enhance the short-term goals, the farmer will engage in pruning, can-
opy management, tilling, and pest control that will increase the short-term
crop yield but harm the long-term viability of the vine stock and lead to
years of recovery. Indeed, it is hard to imagine another crop where the cost
of mis-attention and poor incentives are higher—as noted above long ago
by Adam Smith. Any use of (short-term) cash rent contracts in the leasing
of vineyard land would adversely affect the longevity of the vines.
Crop sharing also has substantial transaction costs. As noted, grapes are
highly sensitive to the quality of labor effort applied during the growing sea-
son. When crops are shared, the viticulturist has an incentive to lower his
quality and quantity of labor input, including the maintenance of the vines.
There also is the potential for grape theft. Grapes are small and vary in quality
across the entire crop. Given their high value, a farmer working on a share
contract would have a strong incentive to collect those grapes of high quality
for himself and leave the poorer grapes for the landowner.
With both cash rent or crop-share contracts in there remain are poten-
tially large transaction costs. These costs include the resource costs and
deadweight losses arising from measuring the timeliness and quality of
farmer effort and the hidden land attributes. These costs also include the
resource costs and deadweight losses arising because Nature contributes to
variation in the volume and quality of the harvest. Given that vineyards
are subject to so many types of transaction cost problems, it is not surpris-
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Organization of Vineyards and Wineries 333
ing that contracting over the vineyard stage of production was rare histori-
cally and today.12 Vineyards are mostly operated by owner-operated family
farms.
Interestingly, on these small family run vineyards, the use of wage labor,
especially during harvest, is common. Wage workers are paid by time and
have an incentive to slow down and work with reduced efforts. Wage labor is
used for simple tasks where output is highly correlated with time and effort
reasonably easy to monitor. These tasks bear little in common with the viticul-
ture tasks of the owner. During harvest, the use of wage labor for high-quality
grapes has two major benefits. First, workers who slow down and “take their
time” are not “dirty pickers” who pick just the low-hanging visible fruit. The
slow wage picker is more likely to pick all of the grapes on the vine. Second,
the wage picker has no incentive to mishandle and bruise the fruit out of
haste. Thus, as grape quality increases, more harvest workers on the vineyard
are used and paid by the hour.
Allen and Lueck note that the size and organization of the farm is determined
by some fundamental trade-offs. On the one hand, the random role of Nature
raises the costs of monitoring and measuring such inputs as labor effort, land
use, and capital exploitation—leading to small firms controlled by a single
residual claimant. In addition, the predictable seasonal elements of agriculture
often prevent any gains from specialization found in large-scale operations—
12
Carmona and Simpson (2012), mostly relying on our theory laid out in The Nature of the Farm, do an
excellent job in describing the problem of underreporting grape quantity and quality and use this as a
base for explaining why sharecropping was so little used historically. They also go into considerable detail
in terms of how contracts were modified away from the standard simple share contracts to accommodate
the special circumstances of grapes.
mmorag@uchile.cl
334 D. W. Allen and D. Lueck
again, leading to small firms. When a farmer has to change tasks every few
weeks due to the changing seasons that drive the biological aspects of produc-
tion, there is little point in specializing in any given task. Large roles of Nature,
on both the random and seasonal dimensions, encourage small family farms.
On the other hand, whenever Nature can be removed from production, then
some type of larger firm often emerges. When random elements are eliminated,
then contracting over labor, land, and other inputs becomes routine. When the
seasonal elements of production are reduced or eliminated, then larger scales of
operation are common with corporate structures.
Consider the facts noted above in the production of high-quality grapes.
These grapes tend to be produced on steep hillsides where machinery has a
difficult time operating. They are produced in regions that rely on natural
weather patterns and not irrigation.13 They rely on hand pruning, thinning,
and picking. Each stage requires care and attention which are difficult to
monitor.14 Under such circumstances, the moral hazard problems are so great,
and the gains from specialization of a given task are so small that each farm is
limited by the capabilities of a single residual claimant. High-quality vine-
yards will be small farms operated mostly by one family.
In most wine regions, there are a small number of vineyards that make up
large fractions of the total acreage used and tonnage produced. For example,
in California these vineyards tend to be located in the central valley where the
land is flat, the vines irrigated, and the pruning and picking are mostly done
by machine.15 The flat land allows for the use of machines and for certain
types of irrigation, both of which reduce the role of Nature and allow for large
numbers of wage employees to be used. Since wage employees cannot be
expected to take extreme care of the grapes, these large vineyards tend to pro-
duce a lower-quality, lower-variance grape. Taken together, the reduced
measurement costs allow corporate structures to exist, with wage labor and
larger plantation-style organization.
13
Indeed, in France the high-quality grapes are not allowed (by law) to be irrigated, (see Ugaglia,
Cardebat, and Jiao, this volume). Irrigation reduces variance in both yields and quality. Hence, other
things equal, increased irrigation should also be correlated with vertically integrated wineries and
vineyards.
14
In the chapter on Chinese wines (this volume), Jiao and Ouyang note that in the Ningxia region of
China the climate is such that the high-quality vines must be covered each winter to prevent damage from
the cold.
15
Lapsley, Alston, and Sambucci (this volume). They also note that in the US just three firms (Gallo,
Wine Group, and Constellation) produce or import 50% of wines consumed. The 20 largest firms in the
US have a market share of 90%, dominated by the low-priced segment of the market (Thornton, pp. 2–3,
2013). Albisu et al., in this volume, note that in Spain 84% of wineries are small, with less than ten work-
ers, while four large firms do the bulk of exporting, most of which is considered low-quality cheap wine.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Organization of Vineyards and Wineries 335
The second phase of wine production involves the winery, the place where the
harvested grapes are converted into wine. Historically the winery was also a
family run affair (indeed, it was the same family) with no contracting.16 The
Allen and Lueck framework provides an explanation for this historical vertical
integration. Prior to the mid-nineteenth century, the role of Nature in the
fermentation process was enormous and mostly misunderstood by those in
the industry. The grapes were perishable and fermentation starts almost imme-
diately after harvest, and any delays in production could mean a vast reduc-
tion in wine quality.17 During this era, wine making was by guess and by God,
depending on Nature and ill-defined skills associated with experience and
personalized knowledge.
As noted above, a series of innovations throughout the nineteenth century,
including increased understanding of the biochemistry of fermentation, allowed
for better control and actual measurement over the fermentation process. The
result was a great reduction in the role of Nature in the winery. What had at one
time been a mysterious process became understood and controllable. At the
same time, the efficient size of a modern winery increased, both in terms of
physical and human capital. This increased fixed physical and human capital
resulted in falling average costs. Large wineries were able to exploit the econo-
mies using hired wage labor, which could be more cheaply monitored given the
reduced role of Nature. Even in the sensitive areas of blending and timing, low
monitoring costs allowed for high-quality wage labor to be engaged.
Beginning in the mid-nineteenth century and carrying on for the next 100
years, wineries vertically disintegrated with vineyards.18 Once produced,
high-quality grapes could be measured (unlike the inputs used to produce
them), and so it was possible for vineyards to supply wineries with grapes—
especially for medium- to low-quality grapes. As a result, large wineries are
16
Fernandez-Olmos et al. (2008) explain this by focusing on the asset specificity of grapes and vines.
Presumably either side of the vineyard/winery transaction could conceivably hold the other side hostage
given the importance of asset and timing specificity. However, given the repeated nature of wine produc-
tion, the importance of reputation, and the ease of the law in regulating such behavior, this seems an
unimportant transaction cost source to explain the vertical integration. It also seems unable to explain the
vertical disintegration we explain below.
17
Franken and Bacon (p. 107, 2014).
18
Knox (1998) argues that in Europe it was the rise of wine cooperatives that separated the vineyard from
the winery to increase marketing and transfer rents. This fails to explain why the separation took place in
other parts of the world where contracts between vineyards and wineries were used instead of coopera-
tives. Simpson (pp. 1–2, 2009) has a discussion of the relationship between family vineyards and coop-
erative wineries in Europe.
mmorag@uchile.cl
336 D. W. Allen and D. Lueck
16.5 Conclusion
The organization of vineyards and wineries can understood using the
transaction costs framework of Allen and Lueck (2002).23 These transac-
tion costs arise when individual farmers and capitalists to alter their inputs
in ways that enhance their own wealth at the expense of each other. In
agriculture, the v ariability of Nature introduces random elements into
production and prevents the parties from deducing the inputs of others
and the seasonal aspects of Nature that limit the ability to exploit gains
from specialization.
19
Thornton (p. 66, 2013) notes that 90% of California grapes are sold by contract to wineries.
20
Dramatic reductions in transportation costs have allowed the expansion in world trade, but it is not
clear how this change has effected wine and vineyard organization. Unsurprisingly, it has increased the
size of the industry.
21
Even in China, where the wine industry is the youngest, the best wines have integrated vineyards and
wineries. Jiao and Ouyang state:
When it comes to the elite Chinese wineries, the wineries in Ningxia are best representatives. All
wines are produced by the grapes cultivated in their own vine-yards with certain requirements in
quality thus to reflect of its origin. [this volume]
Robinson (p. 779, 2006).
22
Simpson (2011) examines related issues, stressing path dependence, and political economy forces.
23
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Organization of Vineyards and Wineries 337
Although most of the chapters in this volume are concerned with the funda-
mentals of quantity and price of wines around the world, each chapter contains
some information on the organization of the wine industry. We have used these
studies to examine three common features of wine production around the world:
the limited role of contracting, the negative correlation of vineyard size with grape
quality, and the general separation of vineyards from wineries over the past 150
years. In each case the observed behavior is well explained by an understanding of
the transaction costs involved, and a recognition that the organization of the
industry results from an attempt to mitigate these transaction costs.
References
Allen, Douglas. 1991. What are transaction costs? Research in Law and Economics 14
(Fall): 1–18.
Allen, Douglas, and Dean Lueck. 2002. The nature of the farm: Contracts, uncertainty,
and organization. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Barzel, Yoram. 1982. Measurement costs and the organization of markets. Journal of
Law and Economics 25 (1): 27–48.
Carmona, Juan, and James Simpson. 2012. Explaining contract choice: Vertical coor-
dination, sharecropping, and wine in Europe, 1850–1950. Economic History
Review 65 (3): 887–909.
Fernandez-Olmos, M., J. Rosell-MartÌnez, and M. Espitia-Escuer. 2008. Quality and
governance mode choice: A transaction cost approach to the wine industry.
Research in Agricultural & Applied Economics 1–6.
Franken, J., and K. Bacon. 2014. Organizational structure and operation of the
Illinois wine industry. Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 43: 104–124.
Goodhue, Rachel, Hyunok Lee DaleHeien, and Daniel Sumner. 2003. Contracts
and quality in the California Winegrape industry. Review of Industrial Organization
23: 267–282.
Knox, Trevor. 1998. Organization change and vinification cooperatives in France’s Midi.
Working paper 7-1, University of Connecticut.
Robinson, J., ed. 2006. The Oxford companion to wine. 3rd ed. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Simpson, James 2009. Old world versus new world: The origins of organizational diver-
sity in the international wine industry, 1850–1914. Working papers in economic
history, 09–01, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid.
———. 2011. Creating wine: The emergence of a world industry, 1840–1914.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Thornton, James. 2013. American wine economics. Berkeley: University of California
Press.
Umbeck, John. 1977. A theory of contract choice and the California Gold Rush.
Journal of Law and Economics 20 (2): 421–437.
mmorag@uchile.cl
17
Wine Co-operatives and Territorial
Anchoring
Marie-Claude Bélis-Bergouignan and Nathalie Corade
17.1 Introduction
Since the beginning of the 2000s, the French wine sector has been facing a
brutal crisis, in sharp contrast to the euphoria of the 1990s. The nature of its
problems is twofold as the underlying fall in French domestic demand, whose
fragility has been observed near unanimously, is coupled with a decline in
external markets, this within a context of global market oversupply. Producers,
unions or inter-branch organizations have reacted1 and have begun to develop
a response. Generally speaking it involves two strategic orientations focused
on future penetration of external markets: total or partial reorganization of
production models directed simultaneously toward rejuvenating supply and
improving attractiveness via efforts on quality and marketing and incitement
from regulatory and administrative bodies to increase groupings in produc-
tion areas and institutional territories of reference, in other words the AOC
(Appellation d’Origine Contrôlée).
mmorag@uchile.cl
340 M.-C. Bélis-Bergouignan and N. Corade
Co-operatives are not exempt from these trends with the recent Pomel
report (2006, p. 23) highlighting the need for mergers. These recommenda-
tions reflect a process which has long been observable. Indeed, in Aquitaine
where the wine co-operative, an important element at the “heart of the wine
sphere” (Doucet 2002), represents 45% of farms and 28% of volume pro-
duced; grouping processes (most of which are mergers) have already started
and their number has increased over the last decade (Table 17.1). Thus, of the
17 mergers carried out since 1968, 9 have been completed since 2000: they
have involved 22 co-operatives, reducing the total number from 77 in the
1990s to 64 in 2006.
As they have triggered a noticeable change in the co-operative system,
these mergers are frequently analyzed as the destructive vector in their con-
stitutive territorial attachment (Chiffoleau et al. 2005). Undeniably, wine
co-operatives are deeply rooted in their territory due to both their locally
based mutual governance and their products’ characteristics. It is also unde-
niable that territorial attachment can represent a constraint on their global
integration. We believe that this analysis is questionable because the opposi-
tion between territorial attachment and a globally oriented merger strategy is
excessive. A priori, the logic behind merger processes involves loosening
mmorag@uchile.cl
Wine Co-operatives and Territorial Anchoring 341
2
This work was carried out with the financial participation of the Aquitaine region within the framework
of research projects attached to the Institut des Sciences de la Vigne et du Vin de Bordeaux.
3
The studies, having been carried out in January 2006, with the latest merger to date, between the co-
operatives of Landerrouat/Durasand of Cazaugitat, having taken place in March 2006, we did not study
it as such but we were informed of the project by the Landerrouat Director, who explained the reasons
for its creation and its future methods.
4
Among the seven mergers studied, there is one which concerns two co-operatives initially belonging to
the same commercial union and whose manager is also director of the commercial union. This particular
case provided the opportunity, at the same time, to study the grouping that union toward co-operative
constitutes.
mmorag@uchile.cl
342 M.-C. Bélis-Bergouignan and N. Corade
17.2 T
he Merger: The Favored Way to Loosen
Territorial Constraint
The merger, whether it be a merger-acquisition or a pure merger,6 is the opera-
tion by which two or more companies bring their assets and liabilities together
to create a new structure with the commitment of each party being irrevers-
ible, contrary to that which characterizes a simple strategic alliance. In
Aquitaine, more than 60 years after their creation and following a path marked
by the creation of commercial unions or alliances—frequently leading to a
later merger—mergers are, to the detriment of alliances, the favored response
of co-operatives to the shocks generated by the recent globalization of the
wine market. These mergers can be interpreted as the co-operative’s way to
loosen its territorial attachment, which is seen as a constraint in the global
context of the sector where organizations with less dependency on a territorial
logic are shown to be efficient.
5
The logic of similarity refers to the fact that the players share the same representation system, the same
beliefs and the same knowledge, independently of their affiliation to a specific organization.
6
In the last case, the two organizations disappear to rebuild a new one.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Wine Co-operatives and Territorial Anchoring 343
A priori, we can only be struck by the similarity of situation which led to the
creation of wine co-operatives in Aquitaine in the 1930s and their mergers in
recent years. The crisis is the common denominator of both movements.
Thus, wine co-operatives were created to respond to a double problem: a tech-
nical problem since wine-making requires heavy investment (in winery equip-
ment) and a capacity to innovate in the technological and oenological fields
and a commercial problem because with the slowdown in sales opportunities
and overproduction, concentrating the supply is a means to increase both
their bargaining power and their ability to adapt and innovate (Hinnewinkle
and Roudié 2001).
Moreover, the crisis, as an upheaval in market conditions and a danger to
their existence, seems as accurate a description of the wine-making situation
in the 1930s as in the 2000s. The need to unite seems to have been simply
reactivated by the current context. This substantiates the idea put forward by
Draperi (Draperi and Touzard 2003, p. 77) that “the market place is central
to explaining changes in co-operatives”. Subsequently nevertheless, the com-
parison made between these two movements suggests the existence of funda-
mental differences, with globalization leading toward market re-dimensioning
strategies linked to the need for diversification and greater supply flexibility.
Thus, a merger expresses less the need to lighten the costs uniting geographi-
cally close entities and more that of reaching a “critical” size in order to posi-
tion one’s product on a global market and break free from a territorial
constraint which hinders competitive efficiency.
The current wine crisis originates in the redefinition of the rules governing
competition. Formerly, the competitiveness of French wines, and notably
those with an AOC, suffered little on world markets, but now it is being chal-
lenged by the success of wines coming from traditionally non-producing
countries. These so-called New World countries or new producing countries
(Australia, South Africa, United States, Chile, New Zealand) have doubled
both their production between 1990 and 2000 and their exports between
1980 and 2000. During the same time period, traditional producer countries
have only seen their exports rise by 20%. If, as regards world exports, Europe
and countries such as France and Italy have confirmed their domination, this
mmorag@uchile.cl
344 M.-C. Bélis-Bergouignan and N. Corade
7
“The market share in volume of New World countries in trade exchanges increased from 4% in 1990 to
14% in 1997 and 19% in 2001.”
8
OIV: Organisation Internationale de la Vigne et du vin, in charge of defining international norms in
order to protect producers and consumers.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Wine Co-operatives and Territorial Anchoring 345
(Pomel 2006), certainly in order to survive but, above all, to respond to the
demands, defined as such, of the world wine market.
9
According to Colletis and Pecqueur (2004, p. 4): “By asset we mean factors ‘in activity’, whilst by
resources it is a question of factors to exploit, organise or still to be revealed.”
10
“A generic factor is independent of the ‘spirit of the place’ where it is produced” (Colletis and Pecqueur
2004, p. 4).
mmorag@uchile.cl
346 M.-C. Bélis-Bergouignan and N. Corade
We know of current thinking (2006) concerning merger projects in the l’Entre-Deux-Mers region.
11
mmorag@uchile.cl
Wine Co-operatives and Territorial Anchoring 347
because they can increase the scale of the partnership networks, be they client
and distribution networks or ones with suppliers.
17.2.2 M
atching the Market, the Mergers’ Primary
Objective
17.2.2.1 F
rom a Grouping to a Merger: From Connective Forms
of Logic to Additive Ones
mmorag@uchile.cl
348 M.-C. Bélis-Bergouignan and N. Corade
17.2.2.2 M
ergers: Between Defensive Strategies and Offensive
Ones
The answers to the first three questions on our interview grid indicate that the
groupings, and more precisely the mergers, are effectively perceived as means
to eliminate the territorial constraint described above—at least partially.
Indeed, thanks to the first question, we can identify the initial causes which
led to the merger. By grouping these causes, linked to the history of the orga-
nizations concerned and of the objectives finally put forward at the time of
the merger (question 2), we can show that today, mergers have become the
favored route (question 3) to break free from territorial constraint, hindering
co-operative development (Table 17.2).
mmorag@uchile.cl
Wine Co-operatives and Territorial Anchoring 349
Table 17.2 Mergers’ initial causes and final objectives (number of answers to these
items/number of co-operatives studied)
Merger cause Merger type Objectives
Difficulties to sell: 7/7 Defensive: due to the Save a co-operative: 5/7
Difficulties linked to demand of structure(s) in Increase volumes to tackle
quality and difficulty, 4/7 large- and medium-scale
technical problems: Offensive: initiated by a retailers or penetrate the
4/7 structure anticipating international market: 3/7
Difficulties linked difficulties to come, 1/7 Develop the bottled-wine
directly to volumes Mixed: meeting between market: 3/7
(insufficient size to structures having Widen the range with the
sell well on difficulties and those extension to new AOCs: 2/7
markets): 2/7 anticipating future Rationalize the link between
Difficulties linked to difficulties, 2/7 production site/product: 1/7
the absence of Decrease the number of
reputation: 1/7 competitors: 3/7
Reach a sufficient size to develop
quality and integrate
traceability: 2/7
The mergers we studied are mostly justified by the will to “save” an organi-
zation in difficulty or in need of support. The current context is an important
lever in the decision to implement these mergers. Indeed, it forces the organi-
zations to consider productive and commercial strategies with the potential to
stand together in the face of current market conditions. Thus, it is always the
emergence of a problem which leads to the thinking process and then to the
triggering of the merger process, with the “crisis” making the idea of a merger
more obvious and more immediate.
If the notion of crisis implies a difficult situation, be it experienced or antic-
ipated, it is noticeable that all the cases we studied came under this logic. Even
when the merger appears as more “natural”, like in those cases between com-
mercial unions and their affiliated co-operatives, it is the “crisis” which trig-
gers the “enactment”.
Henceforth, mergers or groupings appear as survival operations where “ill”
organizations lead “healthy” ones to consider a merger. Indeed, we have only
found one example of a co-operative seeking a merger partner before a co-
operative in difficulty came to see it first. The result of this is a majority of
merger-acquisitions, even if most of the production sites are preserved.
In all circumstances, the economic difficulties are defined as difficulties to
sell: they are directly or indirectly related to problems of size and/or production
volumes. Indeed the commercial problems are generally associated with dif-
ficulties to improve the quality of products, which translates either into items
mmorag@uchile.cl
350 M.-C. Bélis-Bergouignan and N. Corade
unsold or sold at very low prices or low bargaining power on the market
linked to weak negotiable volumes, themselves leading to low valuation of the
products. Mergers are therefore considered as a means to “bypass” the obstacle
of size which was generated in part by territorial constraint.
Thus the examples studied show that mergers are carried out to rationalize
the organization of the co-operative fabric rather than to go on the offensive.
Notwithstanding, these mergers are an opportunity to define or redefine stra-
tegic choices, notably for the “acquiring” organizations. Thus, if the principal
causes of mergers stem from a crisis situation, one that needs to be addressed
or anticipated, little by little, during the merger process, they transform into
more offensive strategic objectives.
Equally, the merger (or the grouping) is always justified by the will, experi-
enced as a necessity, to reach a size considered more satisfactory to be “better”
from a commercial point of view. In fact, it ends up being seen as a genuine
opportunity to commit to more offensive commercial strategies. It is therefore
less a question of achieving internal economies of scale in the strict sense than
reaching a “critical” size enabling the acquiring companies to embark upon
actions which they would never have been able to perform alone.
On this point, the co-operatives’ managers are unanimous: a merger does
not generate economies of scale per se. On the contrary, it first of all feeds into
the development of new functions and new actions, and even when redeploy-
ments of activities are put into place, this implies extra costs. However, after a
while, the learning effects can lead to co-operatives benefitting from econo-
mies of scale. A priori, these propositions are confirmed in the cases we ana-
lyzed by the improvement of merged co-operatives’ performances in terms of
volumes and turnover. The recovery in productive performances, whether it
be attributable to the mergers we studied or also the result of processes put in
place before the merger, still leaves strong disparities between merged co-
operatives, either in terms of member numbers (an order of 1–5), areas culti-
vated (of 1–13), in crop volumes (1–11) or turnover (1–18).12
Increase in volumes and rationalization of the co-operative organization, in
particular regarding the link between production site and product, enabling
diversification, eventual broadening of the product range, development of
sales in bottles and development of quality are therefore the key words of the
mergers we observed in Aquitaine. Thus, according to Christensen et al.
12
The qualitative approach carried out here does not allow us to go beyond the highlighting of stylized
effects that a later quantitative approach should lend support to.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Wine Co-operatives and Territorial Anchoring 351
(2002), in fine, merger strategies in Aquitaine are less about the search for
economies of scale and to a greater extent concern the will to adapt to market
conditions which are sometimes volatile and within which New World pro-
ducers have triggered genuine ground-changing innovation.13
For this reason, reaching a “critical” size is considered as a means to grow
by uniting the co-operatives’ bargaining power against large retailers whom
they now wish to deal with directly. These strategies to increase size very often
involve the association of a large organization with one (or many) much
smaller ones. Increase in size is therefore not exclusive of composition effects.
The merger seemingly grants leadership to the largest organization, probably
considered as the best placed to energize the others without incurring the risk
of power struggles which are too symmetrical and therefore destabilizing for
the merged structure.
The elimination of competitors and the anticipation of an improvement in
the competitive position are also arguments put forward in favor of a merger,
with the expected beneficial results being seen ex post in reality. De facto, a
merger is preferred to an alliance or a commercial union because by eliminat-
ing structures, it is reputed to reduce the level of competition between co-
operatives, which, a priori, according to merger managers, a simple commercial
union cannot achieve. From this point of view, competition on the wine mar-
ket and competition for control of resources are linked. Indeed, a merger is a
means to reach these objectives by building upon a tighter control of the
vineyard, tipping the balance on whether to merge or not in its favor.
Obviously, it cannot guarantee there will be no competition at all as co-
operatives must still compete with independent organizations. However, it
does minimize competition between co-operatives which is not the case of a
commercial union since the latter brings together entities which remain
autonomous. Thus, accessing a broader market or at least being better armed
to compete in a more aggressive market is seen as the major stakes for
mergers.
Moreover, as major problems in co-operatives stem from their size which is
considered too small, a merger is the means to preserve sufficiently high
13
A groundbreaking innovation puts a product onto the market which can be seen as intrinsically “less
good” than certain products dominating the market at present. Therefore, for this reason, it cannot be
sold to the usual consumers. But it is simpler and more approachable and therefore establishes itself in a
part of the market which, up to then, did not reveal demand. Subsequently, the product improves to
overlap the preoccupations of the more demanding segments of the market and by doing so, helps to
remodel the whole market, thereby triggering an upheaval in it.
mmorag@uchile.cl
352 M.-C. Bélis-Bergouignan and N. Corade
v olumes in order to have the resources to carry out a number of actions with-
out which it would now be difficult to be well positioned on the market and,
at a minimum, maintain the bargaining power to sell products at a reasonable
price. A merger is also associated with a search for resources to fight back
against new, aggressive, commercial strategies. Indeed, co-operatives often do
not possess the financial resources to invest in quality, commercial communi-
cation and promotion. By merging, they can be more efficient in this field
than by a simple gathering of means through a strategic alliance.
A merger is therefore considered as a way to compensate for the obstacle of
spatial lock-in. As it is irreversible compared to the connective logic of the
commercial-alliance type, by gathering agents with potentially different inter-
ests under a single structure, it minimizes, a priori, problems of opportunism
induced by a simple alliance. Nevertheless, certain risks remain as mergers
between co-operatives or, otherwise, lead to “organizational upheavals”
(Samuel 2003).
Thus, in a first approach, we can bear witness to the role of territorial con-
straint in the decision to merge. As it limits the growth and development
potential of co-operatives’ activities in a context where size effects are crucial,
the territorial link forces organizations to go beyond an alliance logic and seek
a merger. This explains the unanimity of merged organizations’ managers we
interviewed regarding this ineluctability of the processes. Two of the manag-
ers, even if they represent co-operatives positioned on very different products,
went as far as to say that mergers represent “the future in the wine-co-operative
world”. A more refined analysis shows that this loosening does not rhyme
with a disappearance of the territorial constraint: in reality, it is more a ques-
tion of a re-dimensioning of the territorial scale of a co-operative’s action.
17.3 D
imensioning the Territorial Scale
of the Co-operative Action
Mergers are co-operatives’ favored way to recover room for maneuver hin-
dered by territorial constraint. However, in spite of the fact that they are justi-
fied by the will to break free of this constraint, the underlying logic reaffirms
their attachment to the territory. The re-dimensioning of the territorial scale
of the co-operative action is seen first of all in the complementarity of geo-
graphical and organized proximities during the choice of the right partner to
merge with. This re-dimensioning is then seen in the efforts engaged by the
merged co-operative to maintain and rebuild itself as a territorialized unit.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Wine Co-operatives and Territorial Anchoring 353
17.3.1 C
omplementarity of Geographical and Organized
Proximities in the Choice of the Merger Partner
17.3.1.1 A
Priori, Geographical Proximity Underlies the Choice
of the Partner
mmorag@uchile.cl
354 M.-C. Bélis-Bergouignan and N. Corade
17.3.1.2 P
roximity of Similarity at the Heart of the Commitment
to a Merger Process
The reasons given by the managers to explain the choice of a given merger
partner are in reference to the dimensions of organized proximity. The com-
mitment to the merger process is mostly determined by the existence of prox-
imity of similarity between the potential partners. A priori, it comes into play
from the moment the merger is envisaged but also during the merger process
itself via respective learning phases put in place to guarantee the success of the
operation (Table 17.3).
Firstly, in the Aquitaine co-operative context as in the co-operative world
in general, mergers take place between co-operatives. They have in common
their way of working which characterizes their status: de facto, belonging to
the co-operative milieu itself constitutes an element of proximity. Thus, at
least for the moment, they do not consider merging with non-co-operative
organizations. Moreover, with the exception of a merger between a wine co-
operative and a co-operative supplying cereal farms, the only mergers com-
pleted have been between wine co-operatives.
This last statement is less trivial than it may seem if we consider the hetero-
geneity of the organizations sharing the co-operative status, whether they
mmorag@uchile.cl
Wine Co-operatives and Territorial Anchoring 355
belong to the same sector or not. In this respect, the exception described
above is instructive. Despite a common co-operative culture, the organiza-
tions, beyond the fact that they belong to different sectors, had neither the
same structures nor the same internal working procedures, which certainly
caused difficulties. Thus the merger triggered a cultural transformation since
it implied moving from a “family way of working to one whose management
methods are inappropriate to the way small wine co-operatives operate”.
A contrario, belonging to the same sector strengthens the similarities but
does not guarantee that the union between wine co-operatives “goes without
saying”. The numerous merger projects between wine co-operatives which
never saw the light of day attest to this. Thus, belonging to the co-operative
world, and moreover to the wine co-operative world, most probably facilitates
mergers but it still remains that proximity of similarity does not suffice in
predicting with certainty whether the merger will go ahead or not.
A priori, proximity of similarity is a necessary condition to begin the merger
process. Nevertheless, the cases we studied show that it does not become a
sufficient condition, once the risks of “unnatural” partnerships have been
minimized. Indeed, the merger project only appears possible or worth consid-
eration when the “cultural” gaps are narrow, which confirms the idea that
across a merger, breaking free from spatial lock-in goes together with a loosen-
ing of cognitive obstacles too.
Consequently, many mergers are the result of a series of meetings enabling
the parties to know each other better and a number of test appointments to
“feel” whether there is affinity with the intended partner. It is the reason why
mergers are not completed with the geographically closest potential partner as
the geographical proximity does not compensate for cultural or organizational
distance. Thus, we have frequently been told that “knowing one another”, and
for that, often “learning to know one another”, is a vital pre-requisite for a
merger approach. In the same way, “very different ways of working” are
enough to break the desire to become partners and move to the final step: a
merger.
Henceforth, procedures which lead to most of the mergers we studied are
relatively heavy. With the exception of two cases (Table 17.4), the mergers
were preceded by audits and the setting up of commissions to analyze the
ways of working and the company’s results. Each of these procedures brings
together all the members of each organization, co-operative members and
employees, which results in making the grouping mechanisms slower and
more complex.
In our case, when the approach procedures did not take place, the recipro-
cal ignorance of the partners, and the absence of transparency which resulted
mmorag@uchile.cl
356 M.-C. Bélis-Bergouignan and N. Corade
Table 17.4 Similarity, learning processes and success conditions for merger
A posteriori analysis of
Processes prior Success/ the difficulties A posteriori analysis of the
to merger failure encountered conditions for success
Audits, Success: Difficulty to make those Prior existence of common
commissions, 4 who are doing ways of working (e.g.,
organized well—or who think commercial union). Do not
working they are—understand join a structure which is too
groups: 5/7 the benefits. Difficulty “ill”. Do not pass a limit, in
to convince the other terms of volumes, beyond
party that no site will which the structure becomes
close. Fear of being put too complex to manage.
far from the center of Generates strong
decisions communication tools
Failure: Problems financing the Do not make alliances with
1 project. Departures of partners too distant in their
co-operators way of working
No audits, Failure: Poor reciprocal Carry out an audit. Get to
simple 1 knowledge. Discovery know one another. Establish
situation once the merger was transparency regarding
analysis: 2/7 made of differences in decisions and strategy. Have
working methods and the same ways of doing
of problems. things and of thinking
Departures of about the product
co-operators
Success: None Approval from members
1 necessary. Generate strong
communication tools
from this, was analyzed a posteriori by the current managers as the essential
reason for the failure to merge. For examples we studied, even when the orga-
nizations know each other well, analysis and thinking procedures were put in
place to finalize the merger. Even when the thinking took place after the
action, and where, we were told, “you must not think too much as you risk
taking no action”, several meetings were set up.
Common “ways of doing things”, close working methods (such as work
times and salary systems) and similar viewpoints on the product therefore
appear as minimum guarantees to establishing confidence between the poten-
tial partners, activating learning processes with the goal of building the merger
process.
These journeys are often described as being chaotic: between those which
begin with the idea of a simple grouping and end up with a merger; those
which begin with the idea of a partnership with the co-operative which seems
the most natural fit, because the closest geographically, and which conclude
with co-operatives that were not considered at the outset; those which develop
mmorag@uchile.cl
Wine Co-operatives and Territorial Anchoring 357
from a heavy process and those which are completed without too much
thought; and those which are carried out with a precise idea and others which
are done a little by a non-choice; the journeys leading to a merger are diverse.
If the choice of partners appears guided by a combination of forms of geo-
graphical and similarity proximity, mergers are also the opportunity to rebuild
a territorialized co-operative entity structured around the proximity of
belonging.
17.3.2 T
he Merger, the Opportunity to Rebuild
a Territorialized Co-operative Entity
The success of a merger requires going beyond prior learning, even if this is
thorough. The proximity of belonging therefore comes into play to analyze
the manner in which mergers favor the emergence of a new territorialized co-
operative entity: they bring about a redefinition of the rules and the local
compromises since from this belonging to a new entity, they reorganize the
proximity between actors who were historically distinct.
17.3.2.1 R
endering the Co-operative Organization Viable
Through a Rebuilding of Rules
14
Term borrowed by a person interviewed.
mmorag@uchile.cl
358 M.-C. Bélis-Bergouignan and N. Corade
and so on. For others, it was a question of taking what was good from each
co-operative according to the principle that “not all is good in an organisation
doing well and not everything is to be discarded from one doing badly”.15
The solution, if it does not always seem easy to put in place, resides never-
theless in conciliating differentiated forms of company culture, with varying
degrees of success and conflict. Moreover, this has led certain authors to say
that “mergers form ‘tests’ which reveal sustainability criteria, because it is nec-
essary to rebuild a collective project and the rules associated with it” (Chiffoleau
et al. 2005).
In all cases, mergers translate into a necessity to rebuild around a new
entity, securing a specific common adherence in order to establish a new ter-
ritorial attachment.
17.3.2.2 M
ergers Lead to a Rebuilding of Co-operative
Territorial Legitimacy
mmorag@uchile.cl
Wine Co-operatives and Territorial Anchoring 359
mmorag@uchile.cl
360 M.-C. Bélis-Bergouignan and N. Corade
Other mergers have not modified their initial structural organization. Still oth-
ers in longer-established mergers have ended up abandoning production sites.
Thirdly and finally, reconfiguring resources involves relationships with
members. What happens to these members in the new organization? Ruffio
et al. (2001) identify two types of organization. A first type is based upon a
plan where the member is seen as means to achieve a certain level of economic
efficiency, provoking a change in the nature of the link with the member. On
the contrary, a second type builds on a strengthening of the co-operative’s
interface role between the co-operator and the market. “In this model, the
co-operative … is at the centre of a network built on a double organisation,
relational (with the member) and economic, whose relations with the terri-
tory are different. The first level maintains the local level while the second
operates in a larger territorial context (regional or inter-regional).”
While it is difficult to classify the mergers observed into one of the two mod-
els, especially because the groupings are recent, the second form seems to pre-
vail. However it is established in different ways. For some, the distribution of
functions or at least the internal reorganization of the structure is done with the
will not to lose links with the co-operators. In others, the reorganization induced
by the merger was not seen by the co-operators as a way to cement relations
between them and the structure and this led to co-operators leaving. For still
others, the question of the link with the co-operator was not addressed in this
way, either because the structure that was built did not fundamentally change
the link with the co-operator or because the link was considered above all in
terms of a capacity to pay the members better and that henceforth, the efficiency
of the structure (whose effectiveness cannot be predicted in advance) is the
essential condition in the preservation of the link. Henceforth, the departure of
members following a merger does not seem to result from a deliberate choice on
the organization’s part and therefore do not fall under logic of exclusion.
17.4 Conclusion
Thus, contrary to an image which is too widespread, mergers of wine co-
operatives are far from signing a death warrant to co-operative territorial
attachment. If this attachment turns out to be a constraint, it nevertheless
remains a significant and positive element in co-operative strategy. Admittedly,
this significance can be altered according to the vineyards studied. Thus, when
the co-operative has a near monopoly of the AOC, which is the case of a few
co-operatives in Aquitaine, the strategy of loosening the ties can lead to their
elimination, all the more so as it is easier to carry out in the absence of “close”,
competitors in all the senses of the term. A contrario, mergers with companies
mmorag@uchile.cl
Wine Co-operatives and Territorial Anchoring 361
which are better equipped from a commercial point of view but further away
in terms of organized proximity can, once a learning process has been success-
fully completed, lead to a strengthening of the territorial attachment.
All these elements lead us to qualify the restrictive dimension of the attach-
ment, with our analysis showing that via mergers, co-operatives rebuild their
links to the terroir through an effective expression of the co-operative interest
with those of their members. The analysis of the merger processes in terms of
geographical and organized proximity allows us to appreciate the permissive
character of geographical and similarity proximities insofar as the proximity
of belonging alone can release the spatial, cognitive and organizational lock-
ins which threaten the sustainability of the co-operative structure. This con-
firms the idea that, to a certain extent, the proximity of belonging dominates
the other forms of proximity with which it combines in the merger process.
The “right merger”, enabling co-operatives to increase their influence and
position themselves in a better way cannot, for all that, free co-operatives
from ongoing issues of territory (maintaining small-sized farms or balancing
power with négociants) and trade (competitive positioning of the whole sector
in Aquitaine). If merging with close players solves certain problems, the ques-
tion of the limit of these strategies remains. Will the predictable strengthening
of the globalization movement in the wine sector force co-operatives to envis-
age alliances with players further away if their strategies move closer and closer
toward the world market? Therefore, in a context of increased concentration
in the wine sector, the question regarding the direction of change for these
co-operative organizations remains open.
References
Benkala, A., and J.-P. Boutonnet. Proximité et signalisation de la qualité, approches
croisées pour l’étude d’une AOC, le cas de Pellardon, 4e Journée de la proximité,
06-18-2004, 14 p.
Berthomeau, J. 2001. Comment mieux positionner les vins français sur les marchés
d’exportation? Rapport remis au Ministre de l’Agriculture, juillet.
Boschma, R. 2005. Proximity and innovation: A critical assessment. Regional Studies
39 (1): 61–75.
César, G. 2002. L’avenir de la viticulture française, rapport d’information, Sénat, n°
349.
Chiffoleau, Y., F. Dreyfus, M. Filippi, J.-M. Touzard, and P. Triboulet. 2005. “Réseaux
d’entreprises et réseaux sociaux dans le développement des coopératives agricoles:
enseignements des recherches PSDR en Midi-Pyrénées et Languedoc-Roussillon”,
Communication pour le Symposium international “Territoires et enjeux du dével-
oppement régional”, Lyon, 9–11 mars 2005.
mmorag@uchile.cl
362 M.-C. Bélis-Bergouignan and N. Corade
mmorag@uchile.cl
18
Diversity and a Shifting Power Balance:
Negociants and Winegrowers in Bordeaux
Sofya Brand
18.1 Introduction
In the beginning of the new millennium, the ways to make French wines
more competitive were at the center of debate as the industry was losing its
place on global markets. Concentration and integration of the very frag-
mented wine sector was widely seen as the most efficient way to cut costs, to
gain economies of scale and scope and, more globally, to follow the lead of
main foreign competitors (Berthomeau 2001; César 2002; Pomel 2006).
Since then some companies merged, some have been acquired, others gone
bankrupt. However, many companies not only managed to survive but also
preserved their independence. After all, as we will discover in this chapter,
winemaking in France has its traditions and particularities.
Bordeaux is one of the most notable examples. Diversity is the key word
when describing the winemaking industry of this region. “Bordeaux as a ter-
ritory created a platform for the generation of variety on an unprecedented
scale. … Bordeaux’s territorial identity depends more on an integration of
variety than in homogeneity” (Patchell 2011, pp. 41–42).
Diversity in Bordeaux manifests itself through wide range of products but
also various actors involved in making and marketing them. All those actors
have different strategies, internal organizations and complex relationship. The
very complex nature of regional’s wine sector is imminently rich of divisions:
professional, qualitative and territorial. Professional division—between grape
S. Brand (*)
Département MMS, Institut Mines Télécom – Business School, Paris, France
mmorag@uchile.cl
364 S. Brand
growers and merchants, while very present throughout the whole history of
Bordeaux as a wine region—helps in a manner to overcome two other ones.
In this chapter, we aim to focus on the essence of negociants’ profession
and its evolution. Given that nowadays some factors, which have played a
fundamental role in shaping wine production systems as well as relationships
between their actors, are no more that crucial (e.g. transport costs), we try to
understand why the value chain structure split between grape growers and
negociants persists and is presumably a part of Bordeaux’s performance.
Our analysis belongs to the tradition of historical institutionalism. Thus, to
understand the existing value chain structure in Bordeaux, we begin with a
brief historical review focused on merchants’ role in developing the industry,
then we dress a picture of what Bordeaux wine region actually is and finally
we focus on the different types of merchants present these days in Bordeaux.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Diversity and a Shifting Power Balance: Negociants… 365
long period of time wines from Bordeaux, the so-called clarets, were not of
high quality, hence they could not be stored or transported for long distances.
Merchants even had to blend them with wines from neighboring regions to
improve their quality bypassing protectionist measures lobbied by Bordeaux
vineyards’ owners.
In 1453, after the Hundred Years war was over, France got the Aquitaine
territory back and restored its rule over wine market in Bordeaux. As a result,
wine trade with England declined and British merchants gave way to Dutch,
Hanseatic and Breton ones. These new buyers needed different types of wine:
whites for distillation, sweet whites and reds fit for transportation on long
distances. Merchants from Holland settled in Bordeaux in order to oversee
operations and prospect supply market for better deals. They also introduced
new production techniques, and “new French clarets”, more quality wine,
which could also be stored for longer time, appeared in the seventeenth–eigh-
teenth century. The move brought fame to the region as a whole but also to
the separate local crus, that started gaining reputation. From now on some
wines originated from Medoc and Graves were identified by the name of vine-
yard’s owner or cru. The eighteenth century also saw Bordeaux and its wine
prospering, thanks to massive colonial trade traffic with Antilles Islands.
The French revolution marked a new period for the regional wine industry.
All tax advantages, which Bordeaux enjoyed for many years, were abolished.
As if this was not enough of the challenge, the cancelation of Privilège de
Bordeaux meant the region’s opening up to wines from neighboring vineyards
and other parts of France. Now, merchants were officially free to buy wines
from wherever they like. Merchants, who are usually quick to adapt to new
realities, used non-Bordeaux wines for their blends in order to improve qual-
ity, ensure consistency and adjust quantity. They were selling their branded
wines under Bordeaux name regardless of real origin of wines. Merchants’
warehouses were full of wine, even Grands crus were bottled in those ware-
houses until the middle of the twentieth century.
After the Revolution Bordeaux continued to develop its territorial identity
distinguishing itself from other wine regions by building up a qualitative
image of its wines. Three major factors contributed (Réjalot 2007). First, after
the revolution Bordeaux regional vineyard got precise delimitation. After
France has been divided into departments, Bordeaux wine region began to be
strongly associated with Gironde. Secondly, the concept of “chateau”—a
wine-producing estate using exclusively its own grape—started to spread in
Gironde from 1850s. Last but not least, Bordeaux Wine Official Classification
of 1855 of chateaux in Medoc and Sauternes that was drawn up for the
mmorag@uchile.cl
366 S. Brand
mmorag@uchile.cl
Diversity and a Shifting Power Balance: Negociants… 367
mmorag@uchile.cl
368 S. Brand
mmorag@uchile.cl
Diversity and a Shifting Power Balance: Negociants… 369
18.3 D
iversity and Divisions in Bordeaux
Vineyard Now: Products, Actors,
Performance
With its 111,0003 hectares (ha), Bordeaux is the biggest wine region produc-
ing AOC wines. It represents 1.5% of the worldwide vineyard, 15% of the
total French vineyard and 25% of country’s AOC vineyard. It is planted
mostly with Cabernet Sauvignon, Merlot and Cabernet Franc in reds and
Sauvignon Blanc and Semillon in whites. Wine is fundamental for region’s
economy representing 78% of its agricultural production. Bordeaux produces
about 769 millions of bottles yearly, mostly red wines, which is 85% of its
total production. The region counts 65 appellations.
Bordeaux sells its wines in 150 countries all over the world for €3.65 billion
a year. It exports 42% of its production volume mostly in Europe (43%), Asia
(35%) and Northern America (12%). The wines exports from Bordeaux rep-
resent over one third of total French wine exports. Its five top destinations are
China, Belgium, the United States, the United Kingdom and Germany. In
France 46% of Bordeaux wines are sold in supermarkets, 9% in hard dis-
counts and 45% in wine shops, on-trade market, online and so on.
Bordeaux wine production industry is a very fragmented one: it counts
6300 winegrowers with an average farm size of 17.6 ha, 33 cooperatives with
3 unions, 300 merchants and 82 brokers. Twenty-five organizations for
defense and management (ODG) represent the interests and self-govern the
65 appellations. As seen above, the CIVB, created in 1948, is a central regula-
tion body of wine industry in Bordeaux. It has the role to unify and balance
divergent interests of all actors. It has four missions: economic, marketing,
technical and representation of Bordeaux’s interests on national and interna-
tional political arenas (Smith et al. 2007). CIVB is the biggest inter-professional
board in French wine industry with its total budget reaching almost €36 mil-
lion (including member’s fees and EU subsidies).
Bordeaux wine industry has several divisions that are mediated by various
institutions. The industry needs institutional mediation firstly to balance the
power between winegrowers and merchants who have always struggled for
control on markets, margins, product, influence and so on. They also repre-
sent two opposed product concepts: chateau wines versus branded wines. As
mentioned above in 1970s chateau concept prevailed over the traditional
mmorag@uchile.cl
370 S. Brand
approach when merchants used to sell the majority of wines under their own
names. Currently, only few Bordeaux brands are known internationally, with
Mouton Cadet being the most known example. The brand owes its popularity
to its elder brother—Chateau Mouton Rothschild. On the national market
Castel is an undisputed leader with the brands such as Roche Mazet, Cambras,
Ormes de Cambras, Baron de Lestac, Vieux Papes, La Villageoise and so on.
During the last 25 years Bordeaux wine industry undergoes concentration
process on both sides. Winegrowers have seen their number to divide by more
than twice and the average farm size to grow from 7 to 17 ha. Merchants and
cooperatives have been also consolidating over this period (Pesme et al. 2010).
However, the industry remains very fragmented and thus the coordination
between winegrowers and merchants is a very critical issue.
Another notable feature of the industry is the quality split: Bordeaux is
mostly known for its top wines that only represent a tiny part of regional wine
production. These luxury wines are able to find their clients almost at all mar-
ket condition. However, most of the industry winegrowing estates are occu-
pied producing ordinary wines, which are heavily dependent on market
fluctuations. According to Jean-François Moueix,4 one of the most influential
merchant in Bordeaux: “The difference was such big that I couldn’t see what
could allow normal coexistence in the long term. The palaces cannot prosper
nearby favelas.” At the same time the whole region takes profit from the aura
of these wines. The quality division is represented by different kinds of catego-
rization and hierarchization of thousands of different wines produced in
Bordeaux. Different types of product identification juxtapose: AOC, brand,
chateaux and so on. Three main classifications represent the region’s patri-
mony: Bordeaux Wine Official Classification of 1855, The Graves
Classification and The Saint-Émilion Classification. All three together unite
over 100 estates. These top wines are mainly distributed internationally—80%
exported, according to the Union of Grands Crus, which is much above the
average Bordeaux wine exports figures.
Finally, Bordeaux is divided into many wine-producing territories.
Bordeaux is actually represented by 65 appellations grouped together in 6
regions: le Medoc, Blaye et Bourg, le Libournais, l’Entre-Deux-Mers, Les
4
Interview, Christian Seguin “Bordeaux partout, voilà la Vérité” in the newspaper Sud-Ouest, Thursday
14 June 2007, p. 7. Original version: “Le fossé était tel que je ne voyais pas ce qui pouvait permettre une
cohabitation normale, de longuedurée. Les palais ne peuvent pas s’épanouir à côté des favelas. Cet état de
fait était intolérable. La comparaison entre lesdeux mondes de Bordeaux avait quelque chose d’indécent,
d’inacceptable. Alors je me dis qu’il y a toujours un canyon, mais au moins, de l’autre côté je vois une vie
à l’endroit où l’on entrevoyait la désertification. Je trouve qu’il est bien queles grands crus puissent servir
d’exemple, de référence à un territoire qui a échappé à la fossilisation.”
mmorag@uchile.cl
Diversity and a Shifting Power Balance: Negociants… 371
Graves et Sauternais. The biggest and most powerful appellations are Bordeaux
and Bordeaux Superieur; they represent about a half of the total vineyard area
and can be produced all over Bordeaux wine region.
These self-governed wine territories are very heterogenic in terms of reputa-
tion, production volume and type, organization, aspirations and market suc-
cess. Vineyard prices and their evolution in diverse appellations reflect
differences between them. Vineyards priced above €200,000/ha (Saint-
Émilion, Pessac-Léognan, Pomerol, Margaux, Saint-Estèphe, Saint-Julien and
Pauillac) regroup 10% of the vineyard surface but 75% of its value (compared
to only one third in 1991). Average appellation vineyard price in Gironde has
grown by one quarter between 2000 and 2016. While top wines are experi-
encing a price hike, some appellations were trading at much smaller price in
2016 as opposed to 2000 (Table 18.1). Sauternes, for example, suffered a lot
from road safety legislation: drivers started sacrificing aperitifs and digestives
(Sauternes is usually consumed as such), hence creating a sharp fall in demand.
The diversity of Bordeaux wines can be considered as a market advantage as
it is satisfying the demand for diversity and penetrates all market niches. On
the other hand, it does not always aid the clear positioning and commercial
strategy. Moreover this quite complicated hierarchized offer, which is not nec-
essarily expressed by clear price positioning, cannot always be easily decrypted
by consumer because it requires specific knowledge.
Is complicated Bordeaux system performant? Do the institutions in place
assure its longevity? There are no standard indicators for measuring perfor-
mance knowing that a wine-producing region cannot be considered from a
pure economic point of view only but is a complex social organism having
different challenges in front of it. The answer is probably yes, but not for
everyone. Some less renowned appellations had to join their efforts creating
associations (Cotes de Bordeaux or sweet wines) to compete on the national
and international markets and improve their bargaining power vis-à-vis
mmorag@uchile.cl
372 S. Brand
New strategic plan “Bordeaux, ambitions 2025” has been launched in 2018.
5
mmorag@uchile.cl
Diversity and a Shifting Power Balance: Negociants… 373
In 2012 Pauillac first cru Chateau Latour left the en primeur system.
6
mmorag@uchile.cl
374 S. Brand
450
400
350
Price, euro/hectolitre
300 Bordeaux/Bordeaux
sup.
250
Medoc
200
St Emilion/St Emilion
150 Grand Cru
100
50
0
01/02
02/03
03/04
04/05
05/06
06/07
07/08
08/09
09/10
10/11
11/12
12/13
13/14
14/15
15/16
16/17
Campain
investment. This guise of Grands Crus fuels this traditional practice. Futures
market is a key element of the existence of the Bordeaux wine market: “if the
‘en primeur’ market ceases to be, then Grands crus brokers will disappear.
Campaign brokers will remain but they will not arbitrate mechanisms funda-
mentally. In Bordeaux all is judged and done in relation to the purchase.
Futures market is consubstantial to merchants’ existence itself. Middlemen
are its lever. This is an ancestral system that could seem closed, but which
shouldn’t be dismantled.”7
The quite specific futures market of Grands Crus Classés does not exist
autonomously; it is tightly related to the overall Bordeaux wine market in a
sense that merchant’s position in Grands Crus business can influence its over-
all market power and potential investment attractiveness. Although en
primeur market plays a very significant role, the majority of Bordeaux wines
are not sold over this system and pass through different value chains. Firstly,
7
J.-Fr. Moueix, interview with Christian Seguin “Bordeaux partout, voilà la Vérité” in the newspaper
Sud-Ouest, Thursday 14 June 2007, p. 7. Original version: “Si les ventes en primeur disparaissent, les
courtiers des grands crus disparaîtront. Il restera des courtiers de place qui feront de la vente de place,
mais qui n’arbitreront plus les mécanismes en profondeur. Or, à Bordeaux, tout se juge et se réalise par
rapport à l’achat. Les primeurs sont consubstantiels à l’existence même du négoce de place de Bordeaux.
Les courtiers en sont le levier. C’est un système ancestral qui peut sembler fermé, mais qu’il ne faut pas
démonter.”
mmorag@uchile.cl
Diversity and a Shifting Power Balance: Negociants… 375
grape growers can act independently and market their wines directly. They
can also sell their harvest to a cooperative, which can also market wines on its
own. However, more often they all sell their wines to merchants. In this case
the wines they supply can be either contracted or sold on the spot market (in
bulk or bottled). Bordeaux wines offer vary considerably from year to year in
terms of quality and quantity. If on the futures market the price is fixed by the
producer, on the spot market it is regulated by the balance of the offer and the
demand. The variability of quality, quantity and price affects the relationships
between actors, making them quite tight in the situation of overproduction or
scarcity. The following chart (Fig. 18.1) shows bulk wine price fluctuations of
some AOC in Bordeaux:
The price fluctuations which have a direct effect on the grape growers’ and
merchants’ income can be so important that they can provoke serious con-
frontation between actors. In such cases CIVB or appellation syndicates have
to intervene. The inconsistency of the spot market deals is a main preoccupa-
tion of all actors and governing structures.
8
Unlike the majority of merchants in Bordeaux, the portfolio of these two companies is much diversified
and the wines from Bordeaux represent less than a half of it.
mmorag@uchile.cl
376 S. Brand
mmorag@uchile.cl
Diversity and a Shifting Power Balance: Negociants… 377
9
We excluded three companies’ members or former members of UMB because spirits and not wine rep-
resent their main focus.
10
Considering the unavailability of the employees’ related data for the majority of analyzed firms, it was
not included in data analysis.
mmorag@uchile.cl
378 S. Brand
2. Companies of more modest size but still big with the turnover over €100
million dealing with “exploration” category and having more focused port-
folio than the previous group.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Diversity and a Shifting Power Balance: Negociants… 379
clients portfolio to whom they offer high standard services and range of
products.
18.6 Conclusion
To conclude we would like to cite again Jean-François Moueix11: “Diversity
makes the wealth of Bordeaux. Willing to proceed by concentration would be
an enormous mistake. It would kill the distribution. Omnipresence of prod-
uct all over the world is an imperative. Bordeaux, Bordeaux, Bordeaux every-
where.” This point of view can be questioned of course. Nevertheless, Bordeaux
wine region represent a very complex production system with many divisions
to settle. It is populated by much atomized though concentrating actors on
both sides—production and distribution. They propose on the global market
an heterogeneous product portfolio with rather complex identification juxta-
posing several attributes: appellation, brands, classifications and so on. While
generally producers control the product, they do not control distribution and
on the contrary merchants who control distribution do not control produc-
tion. Therefore, coordination between them and the whole production system
governance remain the issue of critical importance. While divide between
grape growers and merchants is still on the agenda, it has started to blur, as
many grape growers set up their own commercial companies as well as mer-
chants acquire vineyards. Also, socially these two professional groups are often
linked by family or financial ties.
J.-Fr. Moueix, interview with Christian Seguin “Bordeaux partout, voilà la Vérité” in the newspaper
11
Sud-Ouest, Thursday 14 June 2007, p. 7. Original version: “C’est la diversité qui fait la richesse de
Bordeaux. Vouloir procéder à des concentrations constituerait une énorme erreur. Ce serait nécroser une
distribution. L’impératif c’est l’omniprésence du produit dans le monde. Bordeaux, Bordeaux, Bordeaux
partout.”
mmorag@uchile.cl
380 S. Brand
References
Berthomeau, J. 2001. Comment mieux positionner les vins français sur les marchés
d’exportation? Rapport remis au ministre de l’agriculture.
Butel, P. 2008. Les dynasties bordelaises: splendeur, déclin et renouveau. Paris: Perrin.
César, G. 2002. L’avenir de la viticulture française entre tradition et défi du Nouveau
Monde. Rapport d’information n° 349 (2001–2002) de M. Gérard CÉSAR, fait
au nom de la commission des affaires économiques, déposé le 10 juillet 2002.
Sénat.
Chauvin, P.M. 2009. Le marché de réputations. Cadres, chiffres et entrepreneurs de répu-
tation sur le marché des Grands Crus bordelais LAPSAC. Bordeaux, Université
Victor Segalen Bordeaux 2. Doctorat en sociologie.
Colman, T. 2008. Wine politics: How governments, environmentalists, mobsters, and
critics influence the wines we drink. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Hadj Ali, H., S. Lecocq, and M. Visser. 2010. The impact of gurus: Parker grades and
en primeur wine prices. Journal of Wine Economics 5 (1): 22–39.
Jullien, B., and A. Smith, eds. 2008. Industries and globalization: The political causality
of differences. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Patchell, J. 2011. The territorial organization of variety: Cooperation and competition in
Bordeaux, Napa and Chianti Classico. Farnham/Burlington: Ashgate.
Pesme, J.-O., M.-C. Belis-Bergouignan, and N. Corade. 2010. Strategic operations
and concentration in the Bordeaux-Aquitaine region. International Journal of
Wine Business Research 22 (3): 308–324.
Pomel, B. 2006. Réussir l’avenir de la viticulture de France. Propositions présentées
par Bernard Pomel, préfet, chargé de la coordination nationale des comités de
bassin viticole pour la mise en oeuvre d’un plan national de restructuration de la
filière vitivinicole française, mars 2006.
Réjalot, M. 2007. Les logiques du château: filière et modèle vitivinicole à Bordeaux,
1980–2003. Pessac: Presses universitaires de Bordeaux.
Roudié, Ph. 1994. Vignobles et vignerons du Bordelai: 1850–1980. Talence: Presses
universitaires de Bordeaux.
Smith, A., J. de Maillard, and O. Costa. 2007. Vin et politique: Bordeaux, la France,
la mondialisation. Paris: Sciences Po, Les Presses.
Stanziani, A. 2003. La falsification du vin en France, 1880–1905 : un cas de fraude
agro-alimentaire. Revue d’histoire moderne et contemporaine 50 (2): 154–186.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Part IV
Backward Vertical Integration
mmorag@uchile.cl
19
Introduction: Outsourcing Versus
Integration, a Key Trade-Off for Wine
Companies?
Georges Giraud
G. Giraud (*)
AgroSup, Graduate School of Agronomy and Food Science,
University Bourgogne Franche-Comté, Dijon, France
e-mail: georges.giraud@agrosupdijon.fr
© The Author(s) 2019 383
A. Alonso Ugaglia et al. (eds.), The Palgrave Handbook of Wine Industry Economics,
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-98633-3_19
mmorag@uchile.cl
384 G. Giraud
main categories of wine grape growers exist: those who focus on grapevine
cropping alone and those who also integrate the winemaking, whom we will
refer to here, respectively, as viticulturists and winemakers. Several recent
publications found that profitability increases with winemaking process inte-
gration (Cadot 2013; Castriota 2018; Corsi 2013).
The effect of terroir is based on pedo-climatic conditions (Atkinson 2011;
Gade 2004) in combination with local winemaking practices and traditions.
We can thus assume that terroir acts on firms’ strategies not at the parcel level
but at the appellation’s one. In the forthcoming case studies, the contributors
will investigate whether the choice between integrating winemaking process
versus outsourcing depends upon the land availability where the wine estate is
located. This assumption is supported by the findings of Cross et al. (2011),
who found that the influence of terroir on vineyard prices (in the Willamette
Valley of Oregon) was more strongly related to appellation designations than
to locational attributes such as slope, aspect, elevation or soil type.
The bond between terroir and high-quality wine is not always well estab-
lished through the appellation labeling scheme. With respect to grape pro-
curement, brokers are said to be key and efficient substitutes for merchants in
monitoring the winemaking process on the estates (Fares 2009). These find-
ings suggest that, both upstream and downstream from the winemaking stage,
outsourcing may be a factor of improved efficiency within the wine industry,
especially for those among the companies employing a strong branding
strategy.
Dilger (2009) found that in Germany, winegrowing estates led by salaried
managers are more likely to bottle and sell wines of higher quality at higher
prices and in lower quantities than estates led by their owners themselves. As
a corollary to this finding, we may expect to find small winegrowers produc-
ing grapes of medium quality more prone to contract with external winemak-
ers, whereas small growers who are able to produce top-quality wine should
integrate added value through bottling on their own estates.
Visser and de Langen (2006) have pointed out that, in the case of Chile,
the efficiency of a wine sector, within a given district, is strongly related to
close networking and cooperation between that district’s companies. This
means that the outsourcing dilemma is not a simple to make or to sell deci-
sion for the core producers focused on winemaking but also includes R&D
facilities, training facilities, the providers of dry materials, distribution chan-
nels and wine tourism activities (Visser and de Langen 2006).
These findings are congruent with those of Amadieu and Viviani (2011)
who have demonstrated that a high level of intangible expenses has a positive
impact on wine companies’ performance by increasing expected profit and
mmorag@uchile.cl
Introduction: Outsourcing Versus Integration, a Key Trade-Off… 385
reducing variance risk. In addition, the authors indicate that, when R&D
expenses are low in the wine industry, intangible expenses are mainly related
to promotion and marketing and tend to be outsourced to independent mar-
keting agencies (Amadieu and Viviani 2011).
Between integrating winemaking process in the estate and outsourcing to
traders, a medium business model is provided by the cooperative scheme. The
winegrower members of a cooperative delegate the winemaking process to this
cooperative winery, in which they are collectively owners. They can focus on
vine growing and use contractual commitment to sell their harvest to the
cooperative as fresh grape or must. Cooperatives are key actors in the wine
industry.
Market access for small grape-wine growers is often considered by literature
through the case of cooperative wineries (Del Campo et al. 2009). Cooperatives
are an alternative business model between small independent estates, making
their own wine, and grape-wine growers selling fresh harvested grape or must
to traders. This medium position between integration and outsourcing of
winemaking seems to perform well for medium-range wines and innovative
wines but does not fit with top-quality wines such as premiers crus or grands
crus (Chiffoleau et al. 2007).
The literature review carried out here points to the fact that while outsourc-
ing is considered to be a basic principle of good management for modern
companies, it is sparsely applied in the wine industry with respect to the core
stage of winemaking, although it is likely to be used for peripheral activities.
Given that the majority of wine estates are not loss-producing, our goal is to
study whether outsourcing or vertical integration of the wine companies is a
factor of growth and profitability.
This objective will be achieved thanks to the oncoming four case studies.
The case study made by G. Giraud and A. Diallo focuses on the effect of ter-
roir on integration versus outsourcing strategies adopted by winemakers in
Burgundy region, where the mosaic of vine parcels, so-called Climats de
Bourgogne, is quite salient. The authors indicate that choosing between stay-
ing winegrower versus becoming a winemaker mainly depends on the terroir
where the wine estate is located and influences its profitability. Clustering of
wines based on Appellation d’Origine Contrôlée leads to village-based wine seg-
mentation and also depends on export capability and distribution strategy at
estate level.
The second case study explores the strategies chosen by cooperative compa-
nies in order to secure wine or grape procurement and analyzes how these
choices influence the wine industry organization and profitability, since land
regulation often aims at preserving the already existing winegrowers, instead
mmorag@uchile.cl
386 G. Giraud
References
Amadieu, P., and J.L. Viviani. 2011. Intangible expenses: A solution to increase the
French wine industry performance? European Review of Agricultural Economics 38
(2): 237–258.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Introduction: Outsourcing Versus Integration, a Key Trade-Off… 387
Atkinson, J. 2011. Terroir and the Côte de Nuits. Journal of Wine Research 22 (1):
35–41.
Cadot, J. 2013. Agency costs, vertical integration and ownership structure: The case
of wine business in France. In AAWE 7th Annual Conference, Stellenbosch, June.
Castriota, S. 2018. Does excellence pay off? Quality, reputation and vertical integra-
tion in the wine market. AAWE Working paper, 227, March, 46 p.
Chiffoleau, Y., F. Dreyfus, R. Stofer, and J.-M. Touzard. 2007. Networks, innovation
and performance, evidence from a cluster of wine cooperatives in Languedoc,
France. In Vertical markets and cooperative hierarchies, ed. K. Karantininis and
J. Nilsson, 35–59. Dordrecht: Springer.
Corsi, A. 2013. To make wine or to sell the grapes: Determinants of on-farm wine-
making in Piedmont. In AAWE 7th Annual Conference, Stellenbosch, June.
Cross, R., A.J. Plantinga, and R.N. Stavins. 2011. The value of terroir: Hedonic esti-
mation of vineyard sale prices. Journal of Wine Economics 6 (1): 1–14.
Del Campo, F.J.G., D.B. López Lluch, and F. Vidal Jiménez. 2009. Corporate and
farmer objectives in the wine business: The key to success of failure. International
Journal of Wine Research 1: 27–40.
Dilger, A. 2009. In vino veritas: The effect of different management configurations in
German viticulture. Journal of Wine Research 20 (3): 199–208.
Fares, M. 2009. Brokers as experts in the French wine industry. Journal of Wine
Economics 4 (2): 152–165.
Fill, C., and E. Visser. 2000. The outsourcing dilemma: A composite approach to the
make or buy decision. Management Decision 38 (1): 43–50.
Gade, D.W. 2004. Tradition, territory, and terroir in French viniculture: Cassis,
France, and appellation contrôlée. Annals of the Assoc. of American Geographers 94
(4): 848–867.
Kremic, T., O.I. Tukel, and W.O. Rom. 2006. Outsourcing decision support: A sur-
vey of benefits, risks, and decision factors. Supply Chain Management: An
International Journal 11 (6): 467–482.
Maumbe, B.M., and C. Brown. 2013. Entrepreneurial and buyer-driven local wine
supply chains: Case study of Acres of Land Winery in Kentucky. International
Food and Agribusiness Management Review 16 (1): 135–157.
Pappalardo, G., A. Scienza, G. Vindigni, and M. d’Amico. 2013. Profitability of
wine grape growing in the EU member states. Journal of Wine Research 24 (1):
59–76.
Visser, E.J., and P. de Langen. 2006. The importance and quality of governance in the
Chilean wine industry. Geojournal 65 (3): 177–197.
mmorag@uchile.cl
20
To Make or to Buy? A Managerial Trade-
Off of Winemaking Process
in the Burgundy Vineyards
Georges Giraud and Abdoul Diallo
20.1 Introduction
Located between the cities of Paris and Lyon, in the northeast quarter of
France, the Burgundy wine-grape growing area occupies 31,470 hectares (ha)
and includes 3430 wine estates employing 11,300 farmers and other workers.
It produces 1.5 million hectoliters (hl) of wine, selling for €1.2 billion in 17
million cases, of which 48% are exported. Burgundy is a small wine-producing
region in terms of geographic area but produces great wines, highly priced.
From 2000 to 2010, the share of the total harvest sold as fresh grapes, grape
must or juice increased from 10% to 16% (Bruley 2011). This new trend
toward outsourcing pertains to the core stage of business for wineries, since
winemaking outsourcing can lead to a loss of control for the wine-grape grow-
ers. Questions arise as to how wine-grape growers are coping with this new
business model and conversely how winemakers can keep the quality of their
raw materials under control when buying freshly harvested grapes or must on
the open market.
The present study explores the strategies of wine estates with respect to
outsourcing versus integration of the winemaking process through an analysis
G. Giraud (*)
AgroSup, Graduate School of Agronomy and Food Science,
University Bourgogne Franche-Comté, Dijon, France
e-mail: georges.giraud@agrosupdijon.fr
A. Diallo
AgroSup, Dijon, France
mmorag@uchile.cl
390 G. Giraud and A. Diallo
of original and recent data from the Burgundy wine industry. The data analy-
sis seeks to establish well-identified clusters among wine estates with respect
to their choice of outsourcing versus integration.
Our research questions are: (i) does the choice of business model, between
staying a viticulturist and also becoming a winemaker, matter with respect to
profitability? (ii) Does terroir act on firms’ strategies? Such hypothesis suggests
that wine estates’ strategies will be different from one vineyard to another and
not only among estates of different sizes. We will investigate these questions
within the mosaic of the vineyards in Burgundy.
mmorag@uchile.cl
To Make or to Buy? A Managerial Trade-Off of Winemaking Process… 391
mmorag@uchile.cl
392 G. Giraud and A. Diallo
This high pricing situation applies for prestigious, elegant and top-ranked
wines such as Chablis, Meursault or Pommard. Some of these wines come
from small- or medium-sized wineries, and others are issued by traders who
are in some cases less inclined to brand their wines under the appellation
d’origine labeling policy, preferring instead to promote their own brands.
Benefiting from deep-rooted traditions based on more than a millennium
of know-how in the pristine mosaic of Climats de Bourgogne, the top-ranked
wines bearing premier cru or grand cru appellation are both exported and sold
on the highly demanding domestic market. These wines are made according
to a long process in which quality control and the specifications attached to
the appellation are extremely strict. This means that winemakers must tightly
control every stage of the process via integration. At the other end of the mar-
ket range, wines from the regional appellation face strong competition on
both the export and domestic markets and have to contend with price pres-
sure on large volumes. Consequently, keeping costs under control is more
important for those winegrowers who are more oriented toward large-scale
production. Efficient processing and modern management approaches,
including outsourcing, are used in order to maintain profitability.
The results from the other wine-grape-growing areas (Mâconnais, Côte Chalonnaise and Grand
2
mmorag@uchile.cl
To Make or to Buy? A Managerial Trade-Off of Winemaking Process… 393
Fig. 20.1 HAC dendrogram of wine business models in Chablis. (Source: Authors)
mmorag@uchile.cl
394 G. Giraud and A. Diallo
winemaking to other actors. This dominant scheme does not cover the whole
spectrum of wine production in Chablis. Some farmers have wine as their
main business. This is at least the case of the 16% of the winegrowers from
Chablis belonging to cluster 3.
Within the five clusters identified as significant by HAC among the 627
winegrowers from Côte & Hautes Côtes de Nuits, cluster 1 includes 50% of
the observed estates (Fig. 20.2). The main business model of clusters 1 and 5
is based on bottling wine on the estate (Appendix 1). However, a notable
share of wine produced in this area is sold as fresh grapes or must (clusters 2
and 3), and cluster 4 is differentiated by selling wine in bulk.
Although producing red wine is their dominant feature, the winegrowers of
cluster 2 are the most diversified, with 44% of their production in white wine
and 18% in sparkling wine. Cluster 2 provides wine for the regional appella-
tion with 78% of its production. The winegrowers of other clusters are also
diversified with respect to the level of appellation d’origine they use. Those of
cluster 3 sell 94% of their production as fresh grapes or must. Two-thirds of
their production is for the village appellation and 26% for the regional one.
The winegrowers of cluster 4 sell wine in bulk and provide 30% of their pro-
duction to premiers crus and grands crus. Cluster 5, the smallest one, bottles
67% of its production and produces mostly (81%) grands crus.
Almost two-thirds of the winegrowers from Côte & Hautes Côtes de Nuits
are also crop farmers. This may explain why the dominant business model is
to sell freshly harvested grapes and must or wine in bulk for three of the five
clusters.
Fig. 20.2 HAC dendrogram of wine business models in Côte & Hautes Côtes de Nuits.
(Source: Authors)
mmorag@uchile.cl
To Make or to Buy? A Managerial Trade-Off of Winemaking Process… 395
Among the 1137 wine estates established in Côte & Hautes Côtes de
Beaune, HAC analysis allows us to distinguish five meaningful clusters
(Fig. 20.3). The winegrowers of clusters 1 and 5, accounting for 45% of the
estates, bottle their own wine, mostly red, and notably for premiers crus
(Appendix 1). Those of cluster 3 (16% of the estates) also make primarily red
wine, selling it in bulk for any level of appellation d’origine. The estates of
clusters 2 and 4 sell, respectively, 90% and 87% of their production as freshly
harvested grapes or must and make white wine for 55% of their output. The
winegrowers of cluster 2 (25% of the estates) supply the regional appellation
with 55% of their production, whereas those of cluster 4 (14% of the estates)
are oriented toward premiers crus for 57% of their output.
The estates in Côte & Hautes Côtes de Beaune are the most focused on
wine-grape growing among the farmers belonging to the Burgundian wine
sector. They are also the least specialized in terms of the type of wine they
produce, making both red and white wines (Appendix 1).
In each of the three wine-grape-growing areas described above, no signifi-
cant correlation exists between the business model with respect to outsourcing
versus integration of the winemaking process and the appellation profile of
the clusters. The propensity to bottle one’s own wine on the estate seems to be
higher for the premiers crus and grands crus. However, some clusters working
with regional or village appellations also bottle their own wine.
The choice of business model does seem to be related to the color of wine
produced. Among the winegrowers making red wine from 60% to 99% of
Fig. 20.3 HAC dendrogram of wine business models in Côte & Hautes Côtes de
Beaune. (Source: Authors)
mmorag@uchile.cl
396 G. Giraud and A. Diallo
their production, 56% bottle their own wine. For the winegrowers making
white wine from 66% to 100% of their production, 50% sell their harvest as
fresh grapes or must. This is surprising with respect to certain financial impli-
cations. While white wine is usually sold within two years after harvest, red
wine can be kept for longer and can benefit from cellaring. One consequence
of this is that producing white wine may be considered as more favorable in
terms of cash flow. There is thus a kind of paradox in red wine-grape growers
bottling their own wine: by doing so, they tie up capital and create a cash-flow
requirement for their estates. White wine-grape growers, on the other hand,
can be seen as facilitating the raising of easy cash for the traders and the coop-
erative wineries by selling their production prior to the winemaking stage.
Another salient relationship found was between the bottling process and the
rate of direct export. Of the winemakers bottling their own wine, from 69%
to 93% had a rate of direct export ranging from 6% to 62%. This does not
mean that the other winegrowers were unable to export. By outsourcing the
bottling stage, however, these wine-grape farmers have to export indirectly by
means of agents, most often the traders who buy their harvest or wine in bulk.
Within each Burgundian wine-producing area, winegrowers who bottle
their own wine achieve noticeable rates of exportation. This means that bot-
tled wine has been the standard for foreign shipping, in accordance with
traceability requirements from distant markets. This situation may change in
the near future given the cost of shipping glass with weight and no value,
compared to shipping wine in bulk. The decision to ship bottled wine is easy
to understand for top-ranked wines with premium prices such as premiers crus
or grands crus. At high price points, the weight sensitivity of shipping is low.
The trade-off between bottles and bulk for foreign shipping may be less clear
for medium-range wines, which make up the majority of business today, espe-
cially for distant markets such as Asia.
Overall, the HAC employed identifies the differences among clusters
within each wine-producing area. A more complete perspective is needed for
deeper analysis.
Carried out with data from the previously identified clusters across all of
Burgundy, a PCA yields interesting results (Fig. 20.4). The three most impor-
tant factors extracted, with Eigen value > 1.5, explain 67.6% of the overall
variance, which is strongly significant (Appendix 2).
The first acting factor, explaining 28.1% of the overall variance, is com-
posed of winegrowers making red wine versus white wine. Red wine is gener-
ally bottled on-estate, whereas white wine is more often sold as fresh grapes or
must. The second factor differentiating winegrowers explains 22.7% of the
variance and is made up of winegrowers making sparkling wine bearing the
regional appellation (such as Crémant de Bourgogne) versus those producing
mmorag@uchile.cl
To Make or to Buy? A Managerial Trade-Off of Winemaking Process… 397
mmorag@uchile.cl
398 G. Giraud and A. Diallo
Table 20.2 Efficiency and profitability of wine estates according to size and business
model
Burgundy 2011 Turnover/expenses Rate of return of assets
Viticulturists Winemakers Δ Viticulturists Winemakers Δ
1st quartile −10% −6% 4 −3% +3.5% 6.5
Last quartile +15% +22% 7 +6.5% +14% 7.5
Δ 25 28 9.5 10.5
Wine estates μ size μ yield μ sales Income/
working unit
1st quartile 8 ha 47 hl/ha 5700 cases €57,000
Last quartile 34 ha 62 hl/ha 14,100 cases €47,000
Source: Author’s elaboration from Brivet data (2013)
Δ = |x−y| is the difference of value between the categories or the quartiles, that is, 4
= |−10% − (−6%)| and 25 = |−10% − 15%|
The estates belonging to the last quartile have an average size of 34 ha, pro-
duce 62 hl/ha and sell 14,100 cases of 12 bottles each. The average size of
estates from the first quartile is 8 ha; they produce 47 hl/ha and sell 5700
cases. Surprisingly, estates in the first quartile earn €57,000 per working unit,
whereas large estates earn €47,000. The ability to address niche markets and
to export directly may be determining factors with respect to profitability
among Burgundian wine producers.
The range of efficiency and profitability is sensitive to the size of the estates,
but it also depends on the business model. The difference (Δ) is larger accord-
ing to size within the same business model than it is between business models
within the same size category.
20.4 Limitation
The first limitation of such results is based on the way data are defined.
Extracted from wine cellar registers, the data employed here do not include
the final destination of the merchandise. Fortunately the location of the
company is given, allowing an analysis of the effect of appellation on business
strategy in the wine industry in Burgundy.
Another limitation is the absence of records indicating the financial links
between wine companies. As a result of local land pressures, expected incomes
from wine in Burgundy and the funds needed to run a wine business with
important stocks of (usually red) wine for long-term cellaring, it is prudent
for winegrowers to clearly separate their different ownerships. It is now com-
mon to have two or three different companies operating within the same
estate: one owns and manages the vineyard, a second oversees winemaking in
mmorag@uchile.cl
To Make or to Buy? A Managerial Trade-Off of Winemaking Process… 399
a dedicated building, separate from the owners’ home, and a third one man-
ages the wine cellar and handles the marketing and selling of the wine. Some
of the exchanges recorded in the dataset thus represent contracts between dif-
ferent companies within the same holding rather than genuine outsourcing.
A similar limitation relates to the close relationships between some traders
and estates. Formerly distinct, these businesses are nowadays more strongly
interrelated. In order to secure high quality and minimum quantities of grapes
at harvest, it is now common to find traders who own parcels of vines in part
or in full. In this case, the sales of fresh grapes or must and the shipping of
wine in bulk to the trader cannot be seen as pure outsourcing practices. They
are internal sales within different titular ownerships of the same wine com-
pany. The reverse situation occurs as well. Some winemakers, in addition to
bottling their own wine, also buy fresh grapes or must from other viticultur-
ists in order to produce a broader portfolio of different wines. In doing so,
they become traders in their own right.
20.5 Conclusion
Instead of identifying the best way to manage a profitable business in the
Burgundy wine industry, our study highlights the diverse possible ways of
doing so. Our results indicate that the diversity of wines and the mosaic of
small and large estates are not limiting factors for making excellent wines and
running a viable business simultaneously. Within this diversity, the terroir of
origin is a key factor in the choice of business models according to the long
experience of the winegrowers.
The more prestigious the wine is and the higher its price, the better inte-
grated the winemaking process is likely to be. This correlation is stronger for
the red wine sector than it is for the white wine sector, where the relationships
are a bit more complex. In any case, this indicates that outsourcing, although
used occasionally, is not the dominant path to business profitability within
the French wine industry, at least for top-quality wines such as the grands crus
and premiers crus of Burgundy.
Although congruent with previous studies and a good depiction of the
mosaic of wine businesses in Burgundy, the results found here suggest the
need for further investigation and additional data in order to arrive at a better
understanding of wine-grape growers’ business model decisions. A more com-
plete dataset based not only on cellar registers but supplemented by a specific
survey would be useful in order to confirm or refute the present findings. It
would also be interesting to carry out similar surveys in wine-producing areas
other than Burgundy.
mmorag@uchile.cl
ppendix 1: Sales’ Breakdown of 3430 Wine Estates According to Clusters and
A
Wine-Grape-Growing Areas
400
Beaune 3 26 13 61 73 26 1 45 37 17 1 3 182
Beaune 4 9 87 4 45 55 0 6 19 57 18 3 159
Beaune 5 93 5 2 52 47 1 20 41 37 2 62 114
Chablis 1 2 92 6 0 99 1 2 86 11 1 0 223
Chablis 2 19 13 68 0 100 0 2 85 11 2 4 91
Chablis 3 78 9 13 2 97 1 12 64 22 2 34 66
Chablis 4 1 93 6 0 100 0 21 3 63 13 0 33
mmorag@uchile.cl
Chalon 1 79 10 11 63 32 5 35 44 21 0 9 152
Chalon 2 19 28 53 70 20 10 85 11 4 0 1 112
Chalon 3 4 91 5 5 6 89 98 1 1 0 0 54
Chalon 4 6 77 17 24 75 1 34 28 38 0 0 43
Macon 1 20 43 37 12 77 11 82 18 0 0 3 247
Macon 2 5 70 25 0 100 0 8 91 1 0 1 196
Macon 3 89 5 6 13 85 2 48 52 0 0 20 190
Nuits 1 79 9 12 91 8 1 28 46 21 5 27 315
Nuits 2 27 64 9 38 44 18 74 16 8 2 5 120
Nuits 3 3 95 2 96 4 0 26 65 7 2 0 108
Nuits 4 8 1 91 97 3 0 18 52 23 7 1 52
Nuits 5 69 27 4 99 1 0 2 12 5 81 42 32
Note: breakdown of wine sold (%) as bottled/fresh grape/wine in bulk; red/white/sparkling; regional/village/premier cru/grand cru
appellation; number of estates in the cluster
To Make or to Buy? A Managerial Trade-Off of Winemaking Process… 401
References
Abdi, H., and L.J. Williams. 2010. Principal component analysis. Computational
Statistics 2 (4): 433–459.
Brivet, H. 2013. Résultats économiques 2011 des vignerons bourguignons. CER 71,
Vinomarket, BIVB 28 janvier, 19 p.
Bruley, S. 2011. La viticulture en Bourgogne, RGA 2010. Agreste Bourgogne 125, 6 p.
Cadilhon, J., O. Catrou, and A. Renaud. 2011. Strong geographical identities,
Census agriculture 2010, Wine industry. Agreste Primeur 271, 4 p.
Gordon, A.D. 1999. Classification, monographs on statistics & applied probability. 2nd
ed. London: Chapman & Hall/CRC.
mmorag@uchile.cl
21
Vertical Integration and Financial
Performance of French Wine Farms
and Co-operatives
Adeline Alonso Ugaglia and Julien Cadot
A. Alonso Ugaglia (*)
Bordeaux Sciences Agro, University of Bordeaux, Gradignan, France
e-mail: adeline.ugaglia@agro-bordeaux.fr
J. Cadot
Institut Supérieur de Gestion (ISG), Paris, France and Department of Agricultural
and Applied Economics at Virginia Tech, Blacksburg, USA
e-mail: juliencadot@vt.edu
mmorag@uchile.cl
404 A. Alonso Ugaglia and J. Cadot
This is the concept of “entrenchment” of managers, formalized by Shleifer and Vishny (1989).
1
mmorag@uchile.cl
Vertical Integration and Financial Performance of French Wine… 405
21.2 D
escription of the Samples: French Wine
Farms and Bordeaux Wine Co-operatives
21.2.1 French Wine Farms
The pairing of the FADN and the CVI allows us to create a file with 801
winegrowers. We exclude the farms with less than three registered years and
the wine farms from the Champagne and Poitou-Charentes5 (mainly Cognac)
regions, to set a sample of 684 wine farms, including 258 wine co-operative
members, 108 wine farms selling mainly bottled wine (“bottle”), 137 wine
farms selling bulk wine (“bulk”) and 111 “mixed” wine farms (Table 21.1).
Thirty-eight percent of the wine farms deliver most of their grapes to a wine
3
ETO: economic and technical orientation.
4
CVI: computerized vineyard register in France.
5
The financial characteristics of Champagne and Cognac farms are fundamentally different from the
average French wine farms in terms of strategy.
mmorag@uchile.cl
406 A. Alonso Ugaglia and J. Cadot
co-operative. Fifty-two percent process wine and sell the wine in bulk or in
bottles, by themselves or through intermediaries (negociants or wholesalers).
The remaining 10% are composed of a variety of models and it is difficult to
classify them (fresh harvest as the main activity or as an addition to wine sell-
ing). We do not present the results for this latest category which is very
heterogeneous.
Appendix shows the distribution of these wine farms by wine region.
In 2010, the Bordeaux wine region encompasses 7400 farms cultivating vine-
yards, with 5700 farms specialized in wine growing. The vineyard covers
124,000 ha (about 50% of the agricultural area of the Gironde department)
and generates 90% of this area’s agricultural value. Two thousand four hun-
dred and sixty winegrowers are co-operative members. They operate 24,279 ha,
that is, 20% of the wine area in this department. The 39 Bordeaux co-
operatives process about 36% of the 5.8 million hectoliters (hl) of the wine
produced. The average size of farms exclusively making wine through the co-
operatives is about 10 ha (DRAAF 2011).
There is no official database about co-operatives in France, so we used a
survey to extract economic and financial information on all the Bordeaux
wine co-operatives. This original database includes accounting data and infor-
mation on the distribution channels and the volumes (both from the déclara-
tion de récolte), the number of co-operative members and the area they operate
in. Some questions (such as investment or winemaking costs per hl) are
directly answered by the co-operative accountants. As a result, we are able to
compute the sales per hl as well as the price paid to producers per hl and to
make the link with the distribution channel, general co-operative features and
financial ratios for the 2005–2010 period.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Vertical Integration and Financial Performance of French Wine… 407
mmorag@uchile.cl
408 A. Alonso Ugaglia and J. Cadot
21.3 W
ine Farms’ Performance and Vertical-
Integration Level
21.3.1 Ratios
mmorag@uchile.cl
Vertical Integration and Financial Performance of French Wine… 409
of the year6 and, following Delord (2011), two specific balances in the finan-
cial analysis of farms, total income and family income for farms according to
their degree of vertical integration.7 The most relevant and operational mea-
sure of family income is the current income before tax (Chassard and Chevalier
2007; Delord 2011). The current income before tax, the sum of operating
income and the financial result of the firm, corresponds to the benefit that can
be assigned to the remuneration of the manager and self-employed caregivers
who work on the farm. It is useful to analyze the ability of farms to generate
income for all permanent workers, paid or unpaid, through the total income
registered with the FADN. It is the amount of family income (not employees)
and all expenses for employees, salaries and benefits, expressed per annual
work unit (Delord 2011). The annual work unit represents the number of
hours for a person employed full time for one year on a farm.
To explore the financial structure, we then propose an analysis of simplified
average operating balances by wine farm category. We present, on one hand,
the economic assets, defined by the consideration of two aggregates, fixed
assets and working capital requirements (WCR).8 Secondly, we present the
financial liability which includes equity and net debt.9 We propose to analyze
financial performance by type of operation from average financial characteris-
tics. To this end, we decompose the profitability of the activity depending on
the margin and capital turnover, following a fairly standard approach in finan-
cial analysis, which can be applied to the analysis of farms (Barry and Ellinger
2012). We present an analysis of WCR in days of turnover10 and debt ratios
by measuring the amount of debt to equity and the debt ratio on the result.
Finally, we look at two ratios that approximate the maturity of the debt to that
asset: the medium- and long-term debts on the amount of assets and short-
term debt on WCR.
6
The production of the year is the aggregation of production sold, inventory variations, capitalized pro-
duction, production and own consumption of various products from inseparable secondary activities, less
purchases of animals. Production for the year does not include subsidies.
7
We are interested in co-operative members as a reference, bulk, mixed and bottled private cellars.
“Other” farms represent a minority and are not considered in the analysis of the degree of vertical
integration.
8
The need for working capital is the sum of trade receivables and payables less stocks. This is the amount
necessary to fund the business operating cycle, that is to say, the gap between cash expenses incurred for
the production and receipts from sales of products.
9
Net debt is the sum of financial debt less cash operating assets (cash and securities). Debt allows us to
consider only the debts that cannot be repaid immediately by farms.
10
As seen above, the working capital is a highly dependent variable of the position of the companies in
their sectors. Considering vertical integration leads us to attend to this aggregate.
mmorag@uchile.cl
410 A. Alonso Ugaglia and J. Cadot
Table 21.3 shows the average data for four aggregates of the farm balance
sheet. Co-operative members correspond to grape farms that combine the
least assets (€250,000 against €440,000 for the entire sample). In particu-
lar, they have a much lower WCR compared to the amount of capital assets,
while WCR is roughly equivalent to the amount of capital assets for all
farms. The co-operatives are also the farms for which the net debt is the
lowest since it only represents 13% of the financial liability (Fig. 21.1). At
first reading, we see that the wine farms are well capitalized since the
amount of equity is higher than the average capital assets (balance sheet
analysis above), indicating that the working capital is necessarily positive.
The debt level is generally low; it is generally less than one third of the total
economic record.
The balance sheet of private cellars bottling their wine (“bottle”) is over
three times that of co-operative members (€870,000 against €250,000 on
average). WCR represents 52% of total assets and 320 days of sales, which
is higher than the average of the sample. Net debt represents 30% of the
balance sheet, which is higher than that observed for all other wine farms.
The balance sheet of wine farms processing and selling bulk wine (“bulk”)
is closer to the one of co-operative members. Fixed assets are higher
(€213,915 against €152,567) and WCR as well (€156,355 against €94,490).
The share of assets (58%) is also higher than the WCR in the economic
assets (42%). Net debt is also quite low: 16% of the financial liability.
“Mixed” wine firms have an amount of assets which is quite close to the one
of private cellars processing and selling bulk wine (“bulk”), but the WCR is
much higher. It represents 57% of the balance sheet and in days of turnover,
mmorag@uchile.cl
Vertical Integration and Financial Performance of French Wine… 411
1,000,000
900,000
800,000
700,000
600,000
Euros
500,000
400,000
300,000
200,000
100,000
0
Assets Libilities Assets Libilities Assets Libilities Assets Libilities
Co-operative Bulk Mixed Bottle
members
Fig. 21.1 Economic balance by level of vertical integration. (In dark gray, “high bal-
ance” on the asset and liabilities, respectively, corresponds to fixed assets and equity.
In light gray, the “low balance” to match assets and liabilities, respectively, in WCR and
net debt)
and it is equivalent to the “bottle” wine farms’ (318 against 320 days). The
level of debt, 24% of the balance sheet, is as close to these same wine firms
bottling the wine.
The analysis of the production, the results and the financial structure allows
us to calculate financial ratios. For the total sample, the average margin (fam-
ily income over production) is 20% (Table 21.4). The capital turnover ratio is
mmorag@uchile.cl
412 A. Alonso Ugaglia and J. Cadot
21.3.3.1 C
o-operative Members: A Significant Working Capital
Requirement and Very Limited Bank Financing
mmorag@uchile.cl
Vertical Integration and Financial Performance of French Wine… 413
his production to the co-operative and his income is smoothed over the whole
year, usually with a delay of three months. Conversely, the farmer gets the
amount of production sold in the weeks following the transaction if the wine
sold by the co-operative is bulk wine. Ultimately, the efficiency obtained is
11.82%, which is greater than for the entire sample. This result, however, is
relative: if we take into account an income of €20,000 for the farmer, the
economic profitability drops to 4% and the return on equity would be only
4.82%, which seems very low to cover the risk associated with the activity.
The debt level is low, with net debt representing 15.56% of equity. It rep-
resents a little more than the result of a year. But if we take into account an
income of €20,000 for the farmer, it represents 3.56 times the result, which is
not negligible. Net assets are financed for less than a third of the debt in the
medium and long term, and short-term debt represents only 5.8% of the
WCR. These figures can be explained in two ways: a low level of investment,
which can be alarming for the future of the co-operative system whose base is
the competitiveness of co-operative producers, or a limited banking support.
Note that members do not present short-term financial risks. The analysis
shows that they have a short-term debt margin in the eventuality of tempo-
rary difficulties.
21.3.3.2 Th
e Wine Farms Selling Bulk: Low Profitability
and Low Debt
The margin obtained by “bulk” wine farms is lower on average than the one
obtained by the “bottle” wine farms, with a capital turnover that is not better.
Economic profitability falls to 8.74% but amounts to only 3.12% when con-
sidering an income of €20,000 for the farmer, which is not nearly enough to
offset the economic risk on the activity. Thirty-six percent of the capital is
financed by medium- and long-term debts which are slightly higher than the
amount observed for co-operative members but very far from wine farms bot-
tling the wine. However, the debt represents 1.82 times the family’s income
and 4.82 times the adjusted result, which is by far the highest ratio.
21.3.3.3 Th
e “Mixed” Wine Farms: An Interesting Profitability
but a Risk on WCR
The margin of “mixed” private cellars is between that of “bulk” private cellars
and “bottle” ones. However, the capital turnover ratio is higher than that of
mmorag@uchile.cl
414 A. Alonso Ugaglia and J. Cadot
these two categories of wine farms, which is explained both by the value added
by the integration and the relatively small amount of assets (closer to
"bulk" wine farms than "bottle" ones). Therefore, the “mixed” private cellars
have an economic profitability of 11.96%, which is close to the profitability
achieved by the “bottle” wine farms. The total debt level is 32%, which is just
in between the “bulk” and the “bottle” wine farms. One point must be
noticed: these wine farms are those with the highest WCR, with 309 days of
production, and working capital financing rate of short-term debt is the high-
est (14.18%). Among the various types of wine farms observed in the sample,
“mixed” private cellars are those that are most at risk of short-term failure.
Note, however, that by correcting the result of a minimum income of €20,000
for the farmer, the result net debt ratio of these operations is better than the
ratio for “bulk private” cellars or co-operative grape growers.
21.3.3.4 Th
e Wine Farms Bottling and Selling the Wine:
An Interesting Profitability and a Reasonable Debt
mmorag@uchile.cl
Vertical Integration and Financial Performance of French Wine… 415
the bottling activity improves the income of the wine farms and the profit-
ability of the farm. But they face difficulties to manage their WCR. As a result,
these farms are the ones facing the highest risk of bankruptcy. In this context,
supply is an important issue for wine co-operatives and trading companies
(negociants), not only in a long-term development perspective but also to
avoid facing production overcapacity. Our analysis shows that co-operative
members have a large debt capacity, probably due to lack of investment
dynamics. The positive point is that this debt capacity makes it possible to
finance their development if co-operatives are able to provide attractive growth
prospects. Co-operatives can adopt strategies involving a partnership with
trading companies, where one of the sources of supply, the “bulk” private cel-
lars, is drying up.
21.4 V
ertical Integration by the Wine-Processing
Firms: Economic and Financial Performance
in Bordeaux Wine Co-operatives
21.4.1 Descriptive Statistics
mmorag@uchile.cl
416 A. Alonso Ugaglia and J. Cadot
21.4.2 T
he Co-operatives and Vertical Integration: Alone
or Through a Union?
mmorag@uchile.cl
Vertical Integration and Financial Performance of French Wine… 417
However, when considering the interaction terms of margin with the down-
stream strategies, we observe that the premium for “vertically integrated” co-
operative members disappears, which means that the surplus obtained by
these producers is directly related to them. The price paid to producers is
highly sensitive to the margin for co-operatives in “union” and less for “tradi-
tional” co-operatives. This may reveal a stronger connection between the co-
operatives’ capacity and the cash transfer to producers for co-operatives in
“union”, explaining why these latter are less risky than “traditional” co-
operatives. For “vertically integrated” co-operatives, the more comfortable
margins may provide a slack, making the price paid to producers independent
of the yearly variations of margin.
There is an almost negligible difference between the price paid to producers
in “traditional” co-operatives, that is, those which sell bulk wine to nego-
ciants, and the price paid to producers in co-operatives which have chosen to
federate into a “union”. By contrast, the “vertically integrated” co-operatives
are able to offer a significantly better price for the production of the co-
operative members. This research shows that “traditional” co-operatives pri-
oritize payment to producers over renewal of assets, while co-operatives in
“union” seem to anticipate the need for investment by a decrease of the price
paid to producers when the capital obsolescence reaches a certain level. This
mechanism would reveal a form of financial constraint which is not observed
mmorag@uchile.cl
418 A. Alonso Ugaglia and J. Cadot
21.5 Conclusion
Altogether, these results show that vertical integration for wine-grape produc-
ers can be carried out at the farm level or collectively via co-operative mem-
bership. In both cases, it seems that operating on the bulk-wine market is not
profitable. Indeed, bulk-wine producers display low financial performance,
and “traditional” co-operatives seem to be affected by short-termism, by pri-
oritizing the payment to producers over the co-operative’s sustainability. As
such, vertical integration appears an efficient way to create value for wine-
grape producers, but it should not stop at the bulk-wine production stage.
They should rather bottle the wine. Moreover, vertical integration requires a
full consideration of costs and investments necessary to perform well. In our
view, this implies specific learning and presents wine-grape producers with
new challenges, whether they choose to perform vertical integration alone or
within a wine co-operative.
Co-operative
members Bulk Mixed Bottle Others Total
Alsace 13 0 11 8 10 42
Val de Loire Centre 1 14 14 10 12 51
Bourgogne-Beaujolais-Jura- 8 9 15 28 27 87
Savoie
Bordeaux Aquitaine 31 51 39 26 5 152
Sud-Ouest 6 9 5 1 3 24
Vallée du Rhône-Provence 94 18 17 14 6 149
Languedoc-Roussillon 100 32 6 12 7 157
Corse 5 4 4 9 0 22
Total 258 137 111 108 70 684
mmorag@uchile.cl
Vertical Integration and Financial Performance of French Wine… 419
References
Barry, P.J., and P.N. Ellinger. 2012. Financial management in agriculture. 7th ed,
Boston: Prentice Hall, 408p.
Bijman, J., C. Ilopoulos, K.J. Poppe, C. Gijselinck, K. Hagedorn, M. Hanish,
G. Hendrikse, R. Kühl, P. Ollila, P. Pyykönen, and G. Van der Sangen. 2012.
Support for farmers’ cooperatives – Final report, European Commission, 127pp.
Cadot, J. 2015. Agency costs of vertical integration—The case of family firms,
investor-owned firms and cooperatives in the French wine industry. Agricultural
Economics 46 (2): 187–194.
Cadot, J., and J.L. Viviani. 2013. Contraintes financières et ordre de financement
hiérarchique des entreprises agroalimentaires: une approche par données d’enquête.
Economies et Sociétés – Systèmes Agroalimentaires 11–12: 1909–1929.
Cadot J., A. Alonso Ugaglia, B. Bonnefous, and B. Del’homme. 2016. The horizon
problem in Bordeaux wine cooperatives. International Journal of Entrepreneurship
and Small Business, Special Issue on Wine 29(4): 651–668. https://doi.
org/10.1504/IJESB.2016.10000526.
Cadot, J., Ugaglia A. Alonso, and J.P. Serra. 2017. Les effets de l’intégration verticale
sur els revenus et les performances financières en viticulture française. Economie
rurale, Faits et chiffres 360: 85–104.
Chassard, M., and B. Chevalier. 2007. Un large éventail de revenus agricoles. In
L’agriculture, nouveaux défis, 2007th ed., 31–45. Paris: INSEE.
Cook, M.L. 1995. The future of US agricultural cooperatives: A neo-institutional
approach. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 (5): 1153–1159.
Couderc, J.P., G. Giordano, and H. Remaud. 2010. Les entreprises de la filière vin.
In: La vigne et le vin: mutations économiques en France et dans le monde, Les
études de la documentation française, 99–156.
D’Aveni, R.A., and D.J. Ravenscraft. 1994. Economies of integration versus bureau-
cracy costs: Does vertical integration improve performance? Academy of
Management Journal 37 (5): 1167–1206.
Delord, B. 2011. Faits et chiffres: La forte dispersion des revenus dans la viticulture
française. Économie rurale, n 324, juillet-août, 60–70.
DRAAF. 2011. Modernisation, valorisation, restructuration, October [online] http://
draaf.aquitaine.agriculture.gouv.fr/IMG/pdf/ DRAAF-Vitietats_generaux_signa-
tures_cle4dc613-1.pdf. Accessed 22 Dec 2014.
Jensen, M.C., and W.H. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour,
agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–360.
Shleifer, A., and R. Vishny. 1989. Management entrenchment, the case of manager-
specific investments. Journal of Financial Economics 25: 123–139.
Traversac, J.-B., M. Aubert, J.-P. Laporte, and P. Perrier-Cornet. 2007. Deux décen-
nies d’évolution des structures de la viticulture française. Chapitre supplémentaire
(web). In Couderc J.P., Hanin H., d’Hauteville F., Montaigne E. (dir.), Bacchus
2008, Dunod 2007, 32p.
Vernimmen, P., P. Quiry, and Y. Le Fur. 2015. Finance d’Entreprise 2016 « le
Vernimmen », Dalloz, 1 199p.
mmorag@uchile.cl
22
The Prosecco Superiore DOCG Industry
Structure: Current Status and Evolution
over Time
Eugenio Pomarici, Luigino Barisan, Vasco Boatto,
and Luigi Galletto
22.1 Introduction
In the international wine market, Prosecco is known as the wine produced in
a delimitated area located in Northeastern Italy using at least 85% of Glera
grapes.1 Such area includes nine provinces in the Veneto and Friuli-Venezia
Giulia regions, and the concerned area under vines covers about 28,000
hectares.
According the EU regulation, Prosecco is a wine with a protected designa-
tion of origin (PDO),2 so named because the delimited production area
includes the village of Prosecco (near Trieste), from where the Glera p
roduction
spread out over part of the Veneto and Friuli-Venezia Giulia areas. Prosecco is
produced as sparkling (spumante), semi-sparkling (frizzante) or still wine;
currently nearly all the production is sparkling. The sparkling wine is obtained
1
Other local varieties commonly used are Bianchetta, Verdiso and Perera.
2
According to Reg. 1308/2013, a PDO wine is a wine named with a geographical name identifying the
production area, produced complying with a product specification (disciplinare di produzione in Italian),
that is, a set of rules concerning the production area and grape varieties, yield per hectare and analytical
parameters in wine.
mmorag@uchile.cl
422 E. Pomarici et al.
by the Martinotti (or Charmat) method; the still wine is obtained by a pri-
mary fermentation (base wine) which then undergoes a secondary fermenta-
tion in pressure tanks, after which it is bottled with an isobaric filling machine
(De Rosa 1987).
Prosecco sparkling wine is one of the most interesting success cases in the
wine business of recent years (Boatto et al. 2016; Rossetto et al. 2011). The
Prosecco success is witnessed by the dramatic increase in supply: the aggregate
supply of sparkling Prosecco wine was about 512 million bottles in 2016, a
fivefold growth compared to 2000.
In the production process of the sparkling Prosecco, it is possible to recog-
nize three main phases technically separable: grape production, processing
(primary fermentation) of grapes to produce base wine, second fermentation
of wine and bottling.3 A production process thus structured allows for the
existence of two intermediate markets for the intermediate outputs: grape
market and base wine market.
Currently the Prosecco production involved 14,500 grape-producing
farms, 1700 plants producing base wine and 600 plants performing sec-
ond fermentation and bottling. Likewise in the whole Italian wine indus-
try, the connection among all these technical units displays a wide variety
of forms of production organization. These are allowed by the existence of
some production phases which can be performed by independent agents
and by the interaction between market segments and not uniform con-
straints determined by production technology in general and economies
of scale in particular (Pomarici et al. 2008; Schamalensee and Willig
1989).
The whole Prosecco production is split into two categories: Prosecco with
denominazione di origine controllata (Prosecco DOC) and Prosecco with
denominazione di origine controllata e garantita (Prosecco DOCG), which, in
the sparkling version, is named Conegliano Valdobbiadene Prosecco Superiore
DOCG (from here CVPS DOCG). DOC and DOCG are the two categories
laid down by Italian wine law4 in order to establish a distinct hierarchy
among Italian PDO wines. DOCG wines include wines of particular value,
whose product specification must fulfill particularly severe requirements. The
Prosecco DOC product specifications require a maximum yield per hectare
equal to 18 tons of grape and in sparkling wine a total acidity content of not
less than 4.5 grams per liter. The CVPS DOCG product specifications
Law 238/2016.
4
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Prosecco Superiore DOCG Industry Structure: Current Status… 423
100
Prosecco Superiore DOCG
90
Conegliano Valdobbiadene Prosecco Docg
Wine production (million bottles)
80
Sparkling's
50
40
30
20
10
0
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
Fig. 22.1 Conegliano Valdobbiadene Prosecco DOCG: trends in sparkling wine market
(bottles), 2003–2016. (*Sparkling: Prosecco Superiore DOCG and Superiore di Cartizze
DOCG; Source: Data processing C.I.R.V.E., Conegliano, 2018)
require that grape production is carried out in a particular area inside the
larger DOC production area, corresponding to the Conegliano Valdobbiadene
hills; moreover, it requires a maximum yield per hectare equal to 13.5 tons of
grape and, in sparkling wine, a total acidity content of not less than 5 grams
per liter.
Currently the CVPS DOCG’s production (about 90 million bottles) repre-
sents a share over the total Prosecco supply of about 18%; such relatively small
share represents the top-quality Prosecco, which is rooted in a specific tradi-
tion, terroir and landscape. Also the CVPS DOCG’s production has grown
dramatically in the recent past (Fig. 22.1) being supplied both to the domestic
market (60% in 2016) and to foreign markets (40% in 2016) (Fig. 22.2).
As part of whole Prosecco industry, the Prosecco Superiore DOCG’s supply
involves a smaller number of actors. Referring to 2016 are operating: 3387
grape-producing farms5 (with 7549 hectares), 433 plants producing base
wine, 181 plants performing second fermentation and bottling. Such hierar-
chy of figures reflects that existent in Italy, and the plants working at the end
of the supply chain are connected to the upper echelons through different
organization models.
5
Specialized firms in grape production linked to private and cooperative wineries.
mmorag@uchile.cl
424 E. Pomarici et al.
60.0
Italy Export
50.0
40.0
Million bottles
30.0
20.0
10.0
0.0
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
Fig. 22.2 Conegliano Valdobbiadene Prosecco DOCG: trends in sparkling wine sales
on domestic and foreign markets, 2003–2016. (Source: Data processing C.I.R.V.E.,
Conegliano, 2018)
The aim of the current chapter is to analyze the evolution and the current
structure of the Prosecco Superiore DOCG’s industry, giving qualitative and
quantitative evidence to the role of the different models of supply chain illus-
trated in Chap. 3 and shedding light on the interaction connecting the differ-
ent supply chains via the intermediate markets of grape and base wine.
Already in 1976, Merlo and Favaretti offered a framework for understand-
ing the Prosecco DOCG’s supply chain, raising a number of research ques-
tions (Merlo and Favaretti 1976). Later, starting in 2003, the organization of
the Prosecco production in the Conegliano Valdobbiadene area was continu-
ously monitored in order to give an informative support to the activity of the
local producer consortium (Consorzio di Tutela Vini Conegliano
Valdobbiadene Prosecco DOCG).
(a) AGEA (national agency in charge of monitoring the wine market), for
data concerning official declaration about harvested grapes and wine
production
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Prosecco Superiore DOCG Industry Structure: Current Status… 425
The analysis of the last database lets us classify the CVPS DOCG bottling
wineries according to one of the supply chain models existing in the Italian
wine industry, as identified in Chap. 3:
The agricultural supply chain or wine growers chain, which represents an inte-
grated vertical coordination model based on bottlers directly controlling the
whole production process and delivering to the final market wine obtained
mainly from self-produced grapes.
The cooperative supply chain, which represents an integrated vertical coordi-
nation models led by the wine cooperatives with bottling facilities controlling
the whole production process and delivering to the final market wine pro-
duced from grapes harvested by cooperative members.
The industrial supply chain or transformer-bottlers’ chain, which represents a
de-integrated vertical coordination model characterized by actors performing
mainly grape processing and sparkling wine production, with no or rather
small vineyards. Transformer-bottlers are supplied by specialized grape growers
or even by firms belonging to the agricultural supply chain.
The bottlers’ supply chain or plain bottlers’ chain, which in the case of the
CVPS DOCG’s industry represents the de-integrated vertical coordination
model characterized by actors performing mainly second fermentation and
bottling. Plain bottlers are mostly supplied by vintners or by wine growers and
wine cooperatives.
The association to the different supply chains of private wineries was car-
ried out considering the main source of grape and wine. Only wineries bot-
tling wine coming exclusively or mainly from grape of own production were
classified as typical agricultural firms.
Data coming from AGEA and Valoritalia allowed the understanding of the
quantitative consistency and the role in terms of production of the upward
agents: grape growers and base wine producers (vintners).
The Interdepartmental Centre for Research in Viticulture and Enology (CIRVE) of the Padova
7
mmorag@uchile.cl
426 E. Pomarici et al.
22.3 T
he Conegliano Valdobbiadene Prosecco
Superiore DOCG Industry Structure in 2016
22.3.1 Firm Models in the Industry
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Prosecco Superiore DOCG Industry Structure: Current Status… 427
Base wine Processed grape (t) 22,834 33,155 17,487 17,939 6,026 97,441
production Produced base wine (hl) 159,838 232,085 122,409 125,572 42,182 682,086
Fig. 22.3 Conegliano Valdobbiadene Prosecco DOCG’ supply chains, 2016. (*Prosecco
Superiore DOCG Sparkling; = Production linked to the related own firms;
Source: Data processing C.I.R.V.E., Conegliano, 2018.)
22.3.2 S
upply Chains’ Features and Contribution
to Industry Supply
mmorag@uchile.cl
428 E. Pomarici et al.
the wine cooperatives transfer a share of the base wine to other wine coopera-
tives or to the de-integrated supply chains.
Transformer-bottlers contribute to supply nearly one-fifth in volume and a
higher share in value. The average production by firm is about 500,000 bottles, a
relatively small quantity but higher than wine growers. Anyway, some wineries
belonging to this supply chain are among the top bottlers. Specialized grape
growers mostly supply transformer-bottlers (accounting for 91% of their needs)
and therefore these actors lead a partially de-integrated supply chain, where the
coordination of wineries and grape producers is sought after by the grapes inter-
mediate market. In the bottling process, some of the actors integrate the self-
produced base wine with purchases on the base wine intermediate market; but
others are not able to sell as bottled wine all the base wine they produce and,
consequently, sell wine on the intermediate base wine market. Transformer-
bottlers own, in few cases, small vineyards, usually dedicated to special products.
Plain bottlers contribute with the larger share to supply 44% in volume and
almost the same in value. The average production by firms is quite large, the
second in the industry, about 1.2 million bottles. They are mostly supplied by
vintners (accounting for 70% of their needs) and therefore these actors lead a
de-integrated supply chain where the coordination of bottling wineries with
upward actors or actors belonging to other supply chains is sought after in the
intermediate market of base wine. Also plain bottlers own in few cases small
vineyards and grape processing, usually dedicated to special products.
The analysis of average prices for direct sales and sales to commercial chan-
nels reveals some differences in product differentiation strategies of the con-
sidered supply chains, which are more evident in direct sales (Table 22.1). The
transformer-bottler wineries appear more oriented to high prices, while wine
cooperatives show lower prices.
Table 22.1 Prosecco Superiore DOCG price differentiation by type of supply chain,
wine destination and sizea on domestic market, 2016
Total Very big Big Medium Small
Wine growers Direct sale 6.14 7.35 6.74 6.20 5.89
Wholesales 5.31 5.28 5.32 5.37 5.21
Cooperatives Direct sale 5.60 5.71 – – 4.50
Wholesales 4.55 4.55 – – –
Transformer-bottlers Direct sale 7.11 8.73 6.33 6.52 5.49
Wholesales 5.31 5.44 5.09 5.31 5.09
Plain bottlers Direct sale 7.06 7.24 6.02 7.32 5.22
Wholesales 5.17 5.13 6.04 4.98 4.42
a
Bottling sizes (bottle × 1000 by year): very big > 1000; big 1000–500; medium
500–150; small < 150
Source: Data processing C.I.R.V.E., Conegliano, 2018
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Prosecco Superiore DOCG Industry Structure: Current Status… 429
All the supply chains contribute to the delivery to domestic and foreign mar-
kets but with some differences. Plain bottlers are more oriented to export, while
transformer-bottlers are more oriented to the domestic market (Fig. 22.3).
A last element of differentiation among supply chains is the share of pro-
duction bottled for third parties (large retailer or other traders), which deliver
to the market the wine with their own brands. Wine growers and plain bot-
tlers in the interest of third parties contribute a relatively small share of their
production, respectively, 20% and 12%, while wine cooperatives and
transformer-bottlers in the interest of third parties contribute a larger share of
their output, about 60%.
Since the de-integrated supply chains contribute to the final output of the
industry by 62%, the intermediate markets assume a structural role in the
CVPS DOCG’s industry. In fact, as already indicated, they allow not only
vertical relations but also transfers between firms belonging to different sup-
ply chains or the same supply chain. Anyway, in spite of the fact that exchange
flows among individual actors have many trajectories, flow analysis shows that
the integrated chains are net suppliers of actors operating in the non-integrated
production chains as transformer-bottlers and plain bottlers.
The grapes intermediate market relies largely (93% of the net exchange) on
the supply of 824 simple grape growers. Minor suppliers are farms belonging
to the wine grower chain; their contribution as suppliers varies every year
according to price evolution and the quantity of their harvest. Main purchas-
ers are the transformer-bottlers (62% of the net exchange), while minor pur-
chasers are firms belonging to the wine grower chain looking for grapes in case
the customers’ demand exceeds their own grape availability, and, in a few
cases, plain bottlers, owners of pressing facilities, intervene as grape buyers.
Total net exchanges represent about 25%8 of the whole grape production,
while total exchanges are near 30%. Transactions are of on-the-spot ones or,
in many cases, based on long-lasting contracts or informal agreements.
Intermediaries play a relevant role.
The base wine intermediate market is supplied by different types of actors.
The largest suppliers are vintners followed by wine growers, while wineries
belonging to the plain bottlers’ chain are the main purchasers. The most impor-
tant marketplace is at the Camera di Commercio in Treviso. Exchanges of grapes
8
Grapes delivered by cooperative members to the cooperative processing facilities are kept out of this
estimation.
mmorag@uchile.cl
430 E. Pomarici et al.
and wine are negotiated there each Tuesday. Some brokers are recognized as the
most influential in the base wine market. Total net exchanges represent about
32% of the full production, while total exchanges are likely near to 50%.
22.3.4 S
upply Concentration and Analysis by Winery
Dimension
100
90
80
Volume (cumulaive rates)
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
110
120
130
140
150
160
170
180
Number of firms
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Prosecco Superiore DOCG Industry Structure: Current Status… 431
Table 22.3 Prosecco Superiore DOCG producers’ distribution by type of supply chain
and bottling sizea, 2016
Total Very big Big Medium Small
Wine growers N. 111 3 6 21 81
% 61.3% 10.0% 28.6% 52.5% 90.0%
Cooperatives N. 7 6 0 0 1
% 3.9% 20.0% 0.0% 0.0% 1.1%
Transformer-bottlers N. 31 5 10 10 6
% 17.1% 16.7% 47.6% 25.0% 6.7%
Plain bottlers N. 32 16 5 9 2
% 17.7% 53.3% 23.8% 22.5% 2.2%
Total N. 181 30 21 40 90
% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%
a
Bottling sizes (bottle × 1000 by year): very big > 1000; big 1000–500; medium
500–150; small < 150
Source: Data processing C.I.R.V.E., Conegliano, 2018
22.4 E
volution of the Industry over Time
(2010–2016)
The output of all supply chains increased substantially over the period
2010–2016, but with a different rate (Table 22.4). The production of wine
growers and transformer-bottlers shows a higher increase than average (47%),
while the wine growers’ expansion was lower than average. Anyway, these
differences in the growth rate caused only small changes in the share of the
four supply chains on total production, with only a slight increase of
transformer-bottlers and decrease of plain bottlers and wine growers.
The number of wineries belonging to the four supply chains changed dif-
ferently. Wineries belonging to the wine growers and plain bottlers’ supply
chains increased (respectively, by 16% and 14%), while wine cooperatives
decreased by one unit and transformer-bottlers by 9%. The interaction
between changes in aggregate production and number of wineries of the sup-
ply chains determined different changes in the average production of winer-
ies. The average production of wineries belonging to plain bottlers’ supply
mmorag@uchile.cl
Table 22.4 Prosecco Superiore DOCG industry structure: evolution over the period analyzed, 2010–2016
Changes (%)
2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2010–2016a
432
Average Prosecco DOCG sold per winery (0.000 bottles) 87 97 88 102 111 110 101 16.1%
Bottling under contract (%)a 12.9% 13.1% 7.0% 9.4% 7.2% 19.9% 6.70% −6.2%
Wine cooperatives:
Prosecco Superiore DOCG wineries (units) 8 8 8 7 7 7 7 −12.5%
Volume sold (million bottles) 14.4 14.1 15.4 16.3 17.3 19.6 21.2 47.2%
Grapes processed (%) 30.7% 31.4% 32.4% 30.8% 28.1% 30.5% 34.0% 3.3%
Bottled market share (%) 25.0% 23.1% 24.5% 24.6% 23.6% 25.0% 24.9% −0.1%
Average Prosecco DOCG sold per winery (0.000 bottles) 1862 1677 1877 2324 2372 2816 3029 62.7%
Bottling under contract (%)a 12.4% 18.5% 21.5% 33.8% 41.8% 60.7% 65.9% 53.5%
mmorag@uchile.cl
Transformer-bottlers:
Prosecco Superiore DOCG wineries (units) 34 28 27 28 28 30 31 −8.8%
Volume sold (million bottles) 8.3 8.1 9.8 10.5 10.5 12.2 15.3 84.3%
Grapes processed (%) 15.1% 13.7% 16.1% 17.0% 14.9% 13.6% 17.9% 2.8%
Bottled market share (%) 14.40% 13.2% 15.7% 15.8% 14.4% 15.5% 18.00% 3.6%
Average Prosecco DOCG sold per winery (0.000 bottles) 243 291 364 373 375 403 494 103.3%
Bottling under contract (%)a 5.7% 15.9% 12.8% 16.5% 56.4% 64.2% 34.6% 28.9%
Plain bottlers:
Prosecco Superiore DOCG wineries (units) 28 32 32 30 36 35 32 14.3%
Volume sold (million bottles) 26.7 29.3 28.7 29.0 33.2 34.0 37.5 40.4%
Grapes processed (%) 4.1% 4.7% 3.3% 4.4% 5.1% 4.3% 6.2% 2.1%
Bottled market share (%) 46.3% 47.8% 45.7% 43.6% 45.2% 43.3% 44.0% −2.3%
Average Prosecco DOCG sold per winery (0.000 bottles) 946 903 908 955 912 958 1172 23.9%
Bottling under contract (%)a 5.3% 9.4% 6.1% 10.1% 8.0% 11.6% 14.4% 9.1%
a
Share on total bottles of Prosecco Superiore DOCG sold without own brands
Source: Data processing C.I.R.V.E., Conegliano, 2018
The Prosecco Superiore DOCG Industry Structure: Current Status… 433
mmorag@uchile.cl
434 E. Pomarici et al.
brands to the product. If the interest of large retailers is growing in the Italian
wine industry as a whole, their growth rate has been particularly high for all
brands of Prosecco, as a consequence of the exceptional success of this wine,
which relies on the fact that the Prosecco name is working as a brand on the
market.
The CVPS DOCG’s industry appears to be, today, in excellent condition
and represents, together with the Prosecco DOC, the most dynamic element
of the Italian wine industry. Nevertheless, the likely evolution of the market
in the next future will cause significant stress to this industry. The availability
of grapes and wine will be a crucial element in Prosecco Superiore DOCG’s
business as the competition among bottlers will increase. In addition, the
extremely high cost of vineyards entitled to produce CVPS DOCG and the
difficulties to obtain the authorizations for planting new vineyards make
almost prohibitive the establishing of new large fully integrated wineries.
In this scenario the crucial element for large players will be the ability to
further develop the current network of loyal suppliers (grapes, base wine or
sparkling wine), motivating them with adequate contracts and incentives. In
this perspective, a key factor of success will be the possibility to enjoy econo-
mies in the distribution and marketing phases. This would determine suffi-
cient added value to share with suppliers and the possibility to assist suppliers
in delivering particular types of Prosecco.
References
Boatto, V., L. Barisan, and E. Pomarici. 2016. Posizionamento rispetto al mercato. In
Rapporto Annuale 2016. Dalla Denominazione al mondo: il successo internazionale
del Conegliano Valdobbiadene Prosecco Superiore Docg, 34–71. Pieve di Soligo
(Treviso): Conegliano Valdobbiadene Prosecco DOCG.
De Rosa, T. 1987. Tecnologia dei vini spumanti. Brescia: Aeb.
Galletto, L., and F. Bianchin. 2009. Le aziende vitivinicole del Distretto del Prosecco
DOC di Conegliano Valdobbiadene: un’analisi campionaria delle innovazioni, dei
rapporti distrettuali e del posizionamento strategico. Economia e Diritto
Agroalimentare 14 (1): 77–97.
Lambert, D.M., and M.C. Cooper. 2000. Issues in supply chain management.
Industrial Marketing Management 29 (1): 65–83. https://doi.org/10.1016/
S0019-8501(99)00113-3.
Merlo, M., and G. Favaretti. 1976. Effetti economici della legge sulla denominazione
d’origine dei vini. Il Prosecco di Conegliano e Valdobbiadene. Agricoltura delle
Venezie XXX (4): 122–164.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Prosecco Superiore DOCG Industry Structure: Current Status… 435
Pomarici, E., S. Raia, and R. Tedesco. 2008. Dimensione ottimale delle imprese nel
mercato vitivinicolo: riflessioni su alcuni casi di studio. Bulletin de l’OIV 81 (926):
261–268.
Rossetto, L., V. Boatto, and L. Barisan. 2011. Strategies and interpreting models of a
reformed DOC: The prosecco case study. Enometrica 4 (1): 57–77.
Schamalensee, R., and R.D. Willig. 1989. Handbook of industrial organisation.
Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Silvestre, J. 1987. Economies and diseconomies of scale. In The New Palgrave: A dic-
tionary of economics, 80–84. London: The Macmillan Press Ltd.
mmorag@uchile.cl
23
International Perspectives on Backwards
Vertical Integration
Alfredo Coelho and Etienne Montaigne
23.1 Introduction
This chapter provides a broad understanding of the motivations and debates
related to vertical integration backwards, through concrete examples or prac-
tical cases. Vertical integration backwards in the wine industry was extensively
discussed in the literature (see, e.g. Sidlovits and Kator 2007). However, those
contributions focus on one region or country or a particular type of firm (e.g.
wine co-operatives).
Without pretending to cover all the dimensions of vertical integration, we
introduce hereafter, through several examples, the causes or consequences that
lead firms to practice vertical integration.
Conceptual approaches to vertical integration were already discussed else-
where. Briefly, the literature on vertical integration of firms points out two
main explanations for the adoption of such a strategy. Noneconomic theo-
ries—mainly institutional theory and the theory of the dependency of the
resources (DiMaggio and Powell 1983; Pfeffer and Salancick 1978)—state
that organizations engage on vertical integration without taking into account
the efficiency criteria. By contrast, theories on economics argue that
A. Coelho (*)
Bordeaux Sciences Agro, Gradignan, France
e-mail: alfredo.coelho@agro-bordeaux.fr
E. Montaigne
Department of Agricultural Economics, Montpellier Supagro, Montpellier, France
e-mail: etienne.montaigne@supagro.inra.fr
mmorag@uchile.cl
438 A. Coelho and E. Montaigne
23.2 V
ertical Integration Backwards in the Top
International Wine Firms
Vertical integration is a common practice among international wine firms.
Integration strategies are not new phenomena in this industry because histori-
cally most wine firms always tried to control the production potential (sourc-
ing of wines or grapes). For example, Geraci (2004) explains the trend toward
vertical integration in Californian vineyards and wineries since the 1970s as a
means to improve firms’ efficiency—all sizes concerned—and firms’ resilience
toward production cycles.
This chapter will address only the strategies of vertical integration back-
wards concerning grape growing and other vineyard-related operations; how-
ever, vertical integration at the upstream of the value chain may involve other
operations, substituting some of the activities involving suppliers and services
outsourced. Among the most well-known examples, we can point out the case
of E&J Gallo who built a glass factory at Modesto (California) to produce
glass bottles close to the winemaking and bottling facilities. Other examples
include wine firms acquiring shareholdings in oak barrels manufacturers,
nurseries, or cork manufacturers.
The comprehension of vertical integration strategies backwards can be
achieved through the analysis of the motivations for the restructuring of the
leading wine firms in the last three years. Those motivations can be synthe-
sized as follows (see, e.g. Coelho and Rastoin 2004):
mmorag@uchile.cl
International Perspectives on Backwards Vertical Integration 439
mmorag@uchile.cl
440 A. Coelho and E. Montaigne
Wines sold more than 800 hectares of vineyards in California in 2010 to the
real estate investment firm Realty Income and then signed a 20-year lease-
back deal (with an option to extend it to more 80 years).
Among the major wine firms, firms focus primarily on the management of
the wine brands and establish long-term contracts with key and high quality
wine suppliers in different geographies to ensure icon wine, variety and secure
the sourcing. In the USA, E&J Gallo adopted this strategy for some of its core
brands. Among the wines imported by E&J Gallo from third countries, it
includes the following brands owned by Gallo: Italy (Ecco Domani, Bella
Sera, Da Vinci, etc.), France (Red Bicyclette and Pont d’Avignon), Chile
(Viña Chilcaya), Australia (Black Swan), and so on. This strategy provides
more flexibility and a focus in the management of the brands as the compa-
nies do not need to ensure the management of the vineyards, which are man-
aged by third parties (costs and risks related to the management of the
vineyards are shared or transferred to partners).
Mergers and acquisitions are also a means for diversifying grape supplies
beyond firms’ home country. For example, when Foster’s Group (Australia)
bought Beringer in California (Château Saint Jean, Chateau Souverain,
Meridian Vineyards, Beringer Vineyards, Stag’s Leap, and St. Clement
Vineyards) (2000), it became less dependent on the supplies of grapes and
wine produced in Australia through its own wine branch (Mildara Blass). The
new entity was renamed Beringer Blass and became the world’s largest pre-
mium wine company. In an opposite move, Constellation Brands (USA)
acquired BRL Hardy (Australia) in 2001 creating at the time the largest wine
company in the world.
The supply of wines from third parties is a strategic choice helping firms to
expand on emerging markets. For example, the case of a Chinese leading firm
who has signed two partnerships: one in Canada for the export of ice wine to
China and, in another case, in New Zealand for the export of wines to China.
This strategy entails some constraints such as transportation costs and national
or regional excise duties (e.g. in the case of the states of Karnataka and
Maharashtra in India) which may reduce margins considerably.
Vertical integration upstream is an important issue in some protected
designated areas (PDOs) (e.g. Champagne). The cases of the Lanson
International and Taittinger illustrate this issue. Grapes in Champagne are a
unique and relatively scarce resource. Initially, when the champagne house
Lanson International was put on the market for sale in 2005, it attracted
many potential bidders. However, Lanson International did not directly
own any vineyards (grapes were sourced through contracts). At the same
time, another champagne house was put on the market for sale—Taittinger—
mmorag@uchile.cl
International Perspectives on Backwards Vertical Integration 441
which controlled more than 60% of the volume of grapes needed for its own
production. Therefore, most potential buyers for Lanson International
moved away as the size of the vineyard owned by the competitor Taittinger
represented an exceptional and unique opportunity to control a vineyard in
Champagne. Vineyard control in Champagne is of particular interest as
beyond the constraints related to the scarcity of vineyards available for pur-
chase, both the price of grapes (roughly around €5/kg) and the prices of
land with vineyards (average prices reaching more than €1.2 million/hectare
in 2016) are extremely high.
In the case of a champagne maker, the non-integration of grape production
decreases investments (in vineyards) and ensures flexibility, but it becomes a
risky strategy whenever harvests are low. Moreover, the absence of direct own-
ership over the grapes can prevent firms’ expansion plans.
Buying wine from the vineyards of New World producing countries or
from traditional producing countries and the transportation of those wines to
major importing markets (USA, UK, Germany), supplying the main brands,
particularly for the entry-level still wine ranges, translate into an emerging of
international wine sourcing.
These two examples—vertical integration upstream and sourcing region-
ally and globally—illustrate two types of strategies, often interlinked, charac-
terizing today’s global wine industry:
mmorag@uchile.cl
442 A. Coelho and E. Montaigne
23.2.1 B
ackward Vertical Integration: Lessons
from the Top 40 World Wine Firms
Among the top 40 world wineries (see Coelho and Rastoin 2004; Coelho
2013), we identified the top 12 vineyard owners. The top holders include a
second-tier French co-operative (Vinadeis) and three Italian three-tier co-
operatives (Caviro, Cavit, Riunite & Civ + GIV). Co-operatives are ‘hybrid’
organizations and their vineyards tend to be directly owned by members, not
by the co-operatives themselves. However, in the last few years, the advanced
average age and retirement of members (lack of successors and new young
grape growers) and major grubbing-ups of vineyards in Southern European
countries (France, Spain, and Italy) (shrinking of the sourcing potential) led
these co-operatives to purchase or lease land with vineyards. The direct
involvement of wine co-operatives in the control of vineyards is a growing
movement, but at the very beginning. The vertical integration backwards by
wine co-operatives is still influenced by strong legal, institutional, and finan-
cial constraints (Fig. 23.1).
Concerning other leading wine firms (i.e. non-co-operatives), the above
table suggests a link between vineyard ownership and the internationalization
of firms. At first, the internationalization of wine firms through the ownership
of vineyards contributes to diversify the supply of wines from different geog-
raphies and origins. At the international level, Cavit (Italy) is the only wine
co-operative owning wine-related assets outside the home country, which
owns a major shareholding in the German sparkling wine producer Kessler
(Württemberg).
International wine brands need to ensure a stable quality of wines and vol-
umes to supply buyers. Most of the international wine firms are not com-
pletely autonomous as they need to purchase grapes or bulk wine through
contracts or in the spot market.
Vertical integration backwards also allows companies to diversify the geog-
raphies of the vineyards through different varietals, soils, and microclimates.
This strategy is particularly developed by the leading Chilean wine
firms (Concha y Toro, Viña San Pedro Tarapacà Wine Group).
mmorag@uchile.cl
International Perspectives on Backwards Vertical Integration 443
Caviro (ITA)
Vinadeis (FRA)
Fig. 23.1 The 12 leading world wine producers by vine surfaces in 2016 (ha). (Source:
Annual Reports, International press)
23.2.2 E
xpanding Vertical Integration: Greenfield
Investments or Mergers and Acquisitions?
International wine firms have the opportunity to integrate vertically the vine-
yards through two main strategies, either greenfield (ex nihilo) investments or
mergers and acquisitions (brownfield investments). Both strategies are suit-
able and can be successful for the world leading wineries; however, mergers
and acquisitions tend to be more expensive and risky. Among the top world
wine firms, Constellation Brands (USA) and Treasury Wine Estates (TWE)
(Australia) expanded their vineyard surfaces through major mergers and
acquisitions of wineries in different locations (see hereafter).
mmorag@uchile.cl
444 A. Coelho and E. Montaigne
Due to the absence of vine planting rights schemes similar to the one in the
European Union (EU), leading Chilean wine producers expanded their vine-
yard plantings through different investments in Chile and Argentina. Concha
y Toro expanded in the home country and in Argentina mainly through the
planting of new vineyards. This strategy enables to company to have a ‘com-
plete control of the productive process and supply chain’ (Concha y Toro
2015) (cf. Exhibit 23.2).
mmorag@uchile.cl
International Perspectives on Backwards Vertical Integration 445
Table 23.2 Concha y Toro: expansion of vineyard surfaces in Chilean valleys 2005–2015
(ha)
Chilean valleys (ha) 2005 2010 2015 Change 2005–2015
Limarí 313 896 965 186.3%
Casablanca 339 415 424 22.4%
Leyda – 130 130 –
Aconcagua – – 100 –
Maipo 620 974 853 57.1%
Cachapoal 611 1306 1463 113.7%
Colchagua 636 1757 2163 176.3%
Curicó 442 666 683 50.7%
Maule 1584 2300 2413 45.2%
Source: Own elaboration based on annual reports
mmorag@uchile.cl
446 A. Coelho and E. Montaigne
The two examples above illustrate the main paths undertaken by leading
wine firms around the world to expand vertical integration backwards.
In contrast with the Chilean example, the major wine firms in the EU,
particularly in France (see Montaigne et al. 2012, about the restrictions of the
mechanism for the distribution to structure the vine planting rights scheme in
France), tend to expand dominantly through mergers and acquisitions in
order to expand the vineyard basis.
23.3 T
he Planting Rights Scheme: A Look
into the European Constraints to Vertical
Integration Backwards
As we discussed in the previous part of the chapter, at the international level,
the access to raw materials—wine grapes—is a key point for firms’ success
across the wine chain. However, over time firms need to redefine their bound-
aries through a proactive and intentional approach as a reaction to changes in
the competition environment.
In the EU, vine planting rights were a means adopted by legislation to help
industry to better manage the production potential (i.e. grape growing) and
regulate the supply of wines. The wine common market organization (CMO)
framework, established in 1970, introduced this policy measure in 1976 to
better regulate the wine production by limitation of the potential, after two
‘wine wars’ between Italy and France. This legislation applies to the firms
operating vineyards within the EU. However, even if the planting rights
scheme concerns all vine-producing countries, the transposition of European
rules into national legislations diverges across countries (see Montaigne et al.
2012).
The case of the transposition of European rules into French vineyards illus-
trates how the system blocked the distribution of sizeable areas of vine plant-
ing rights among vine producers. The transposition of the European rules of
vine planting rights to France is unique. For example, in the last 30 years, in
the Languedoc-Roussillon—the largest French vineyard region—there was
not any greenfield investment to establish a single vineyard above 3 hectares.
In contrast, many studies document many greenfield investments to establish
large vineyards above 50 hectares in other European countries (e.g. in the
Douro valley or Hungary) (see Delord et al. 2015). Those cases illustrate the
influence of the French legislation, creating barriers preventing firms to
increase vertical integration backwards. Firms planning to extend the vineyard
mmorag@uchile.cl
International Perspectives on Backwards Vertical Integration 447
surfaces could only purchase each year a tiny amount of vine planting rights
in the open (‘spot’) market. As an alternative, firms could vertically integrate
vine production—at a significant cost—through mergers and acquisitions. In
the most prestigious protected designated areas such as Champagne, Bordeaux,
and Burgundy, land prices and the scarcity of the grape supply were two of the
main barriers for investors.
23.3.1 T
he Vine Planting Scheme in France: An Atypical
Case of Redistribution
Most often, vineyard extension in France requires grape growers use the most
traditional approach, that is, the purchase of plots already planted (brownfield
investment). The decision to acquire vineyards depends not only on vine
planting rights but it also took into account the location (closeness to grape
farms), the value of land in the land market, the value of the products into
consumer markets, and the patrimonial approach characterizing the behavior
of grape growers. The availability of vine plantings influenced the price but
the French national reserve set up a common price for the planting rights sold
through the reserve. In protected designation areas, the scarcity of land is the
main factor explaining the price of vine planting rights.
In France, there was an important wine crisis at the early start of the twen-
tieth century. As a consequence, France introduced a vine planting rights
scheme in 1931. Six decades later, French legislation adapted to the most
significant wine reform at the European level in 1999 by introducing the
‘reserve’ mechanism for vine planting rights. The national reserve for the
management and distribution of vine planting rights became a tool of the
public policy under the supervision of the Ministry of Agriculture.
By law, all vine plantings should be justified through proprietorship.
Changes in the wine policy created two types of planting rights in France:
those originated from the uprooting vine plots and those distributed through
the national reserve. Growers who uprooted vine plots or the entire vine sur-
faces on a wine estate could sell the planting rights on the open market during
eight years.
In this case, the national reserve was a tool to administer vine planting
rights originated through the uprooting of vine planting rights not replanted
within the eight-year lifespan. The reserve also hosted new planting rights,
granted by the EU to each individual country within the framework estab-
lished through the CMO for wine reform in 1999.
mmorag@uchile.cl
448 A. Coelho and E. Montaigne
The national reserve provided free planting rights for young farmers. The
remaining grape growers could acquire planting rights from the national
reserve at a cost. In the spot market, transactions for vine planting rights
could proceed directly, that is, between two grape growers or through the
intermediation of a broker.
The price for the sale of vine planting rights derived from the national
reserve was established at approximately €1750/ha in the first four campaigns
(2002/2003–2005/2006). Prices decreased to €1500/ha in the following four
campaigns and reached €1000/ha in the campaign of 2011/2012. As each
grape grower could sell his planting rights to the national reserve, the main
consequence was those prices became also the key reference for the prices of
vine planting rights in the free market. The main outcome of this process was
the complete disconnection between the amount paid for planting rights and
market prices for land. Champagne was the most striking example, as the
prices of vine planting rights were completely insignificant when compared to
the price of land.
Therefore, whenever French grape grower plans to increase the vineyard sur-
faces of his own estate, he needed to acquire a planting right to plant vines in
the free plot. In addition, the proprietorship of vine planting rights was not the
only necessary condition to be allowed to plant a vine. The scheme also required
an ‘authorization’ to plant vines. In practice, with the exception of wines with-
out geographic indications (i.e. the former ‘table wines’) excluded from the
planting rights scheme from 1999 to 2015, the two other European categories
of wines (PDO and Protected Geographic Indications (PGI)) were able to
control their production potential through a board—Organisme de défense et de
gestion (ODG), that is, syndicats de cru—governing each PDO and each
PGI. The board (ODG) established an annual quota of authorization for each
PDO or PGI in order to prevent excessive growth of the production potential
not in line with the specific PDO or PGI market demand. The ODG (board)
distributed the quota in proportion to the individual demands of grape grow-
ers. In addition, there was a maximal cap of three (five for collective programs)
hectares/farmer/year for each area producing wines under PGI and one hect-
are/farmer/year for wines under PDO. This maximum annual expansion was
the source of major controversies among the wineries wishing to establish ex
nihilo vine projects. Major wineries recognized the planting rights scheme in
France as a barrier to vertically integrate the vineyard. The greatest controversy
concerned the American Mondavi company undertaking to create a 50-hect-
are vineyard in Aniane, a typical tiny village in Languedoc (Torres 2005).
What is the economic rationality behind the French scheme? The planting
rights scheme involves three different levels among decision-makers. The first
mmorag@uchile.cl
International Perspectives on Backwards Vertical Integration 449
mmorag@uchile.cl
450 A. Coelho and E. Montaigne
reach economies of scale. This argument was clearly refuted in the literature
(Delord et al. 2015). The planting rights scheme privileges already established
vineyard owners and their successors. The scheme requires an authorization
for extending the surfaces through a ‘democratic’ approach limiting the vine
surfaces distributed to each individual.
The decision-making process for the allocation of vine planting rights was
a major constraint for the establishment of ex nihilo vine projects among
French vineyards. Major French wine firms (Castel, Grands Chais de France,
Boisset, Baron Philippe de Rothschild, Advini, etc.) perceived the planting
rights scheme as a barrier for expansion and for the integration of the upstream
of the wine chain. A close look into the strategies of the leading French wine
firms shows the expansion and progressive integration backwards of vineyards
was achieved essentially through mergers and acquisitions.
23.4 Conclusion
This chapter discusses the motivations and strategies followed by the leading
international wine firms to vertically integrate the vineyards. We compare the
approaches used by the wineries in the New World—where there is no legal
system or institutional system to manage the production potential—and the
vine planting rights in Europe, particularly in France. These two contrasting
situations explain how institutional rules may shape the strategies of firms to
integrate the vineyards. The above reflection suggests how important it would
be to integrate the different approaches and constraints into the public debate
to raise the competitiveness of European vineyards.
References
Codron, J.M., E. Montaigne, and S. Rousset. 2013. Quality management and con-
tractual incompleteness: Grape procurement for high-end wines in Argentina.
Journal on Chain and Network Science 13 (1): 11–35.
Coelho, A. 2013. Concentration des grandes firmes vitivinicoles. Le Progrès Agricole
et Viticole 12: 11–18.
Coelho, A., and J.-L. Rastoin. 2004. Stratégie des grands groupes internationaux:
vers l’émergence d’un oligopole mondial du vin? In Bacchus 2005: enjeux, stratégies
et pratiques dans la filière vitivinicole, ed. F. D’Hauteville, J.-P. Couderc, H. Hannin,
and E. Montaigne, 79–99. Paris: Dunod.
Concha y Toro. 2015. Annual reports, several years.
mmorag@uchile.cl
International Perspectives on Backwards Vertical Integration 451
Delord, B., E. Montaigne, and A. Coelho. 2015. Vine planting rights, farm size, and
economic performance: Do economies of scale matter in the French wine sector?
Wine Economics and Policy 4 (1): 22–34.
DiMaggio, P.J., and W.W. Powell. 1983. The Iron cage revisited: Institutional iso-
morphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological
Review 48 (2): 147–160.
Franken, J.R.V. 2012. Quality considerations for coordination of the California wine-
grape supply chain, American Association of Wine Economists. AAWE Working
Paper, No 99, February.
Geraci, V.W. 2004. Salud! The rise of Santa Barbara’s wine industry. Reno: University
of Nevada Press.
Gereffi, G. 1999. A commodity chains framework for analyzing global industries.
Durham: Duke University.
Goodhue, R.E., D.M. Hejen, H. Lee, and D. Sumner. 2002. Contract use in wine
grape industry. California Agriculture 56 (3): 97–102.
Longbottom, M., C. Simos, M. Krstic, and D. Johnson. 2013. Grape quality assess-
ments: A survey of current practice. Wine & Viticulture Journal 28: 33–37.
Montaigne, E., and D. Sidlovits. 2003. Long term contracts and quality in the wine
supply chain: Case of the Appellation “Vins des Sables du Golfe du Lion”. In
Budapest, ISNIE, 7th Annual Conference of the International Society for New
Institutional Economics, September 11–13, 20p.
Montaigne, E., D. Sidlovits, and G.G. Szabó. 2005. Examination of contracting rela-
tionships in the Hungarian Wine industry. In Budapest, Hungary: 2nd International
Conference on Economics and Management of Networks, September 15–17, Corvinus
University of Budapest, 27p.
Montaigne, E., S. Rousset, and J.-B. Traversac. 2007. Quelles perspectives pour les
contrats en raisin entre production et négoce? in Bacchus 2008: enjeux, stratégies et
pratiques dans la filière vitivinicole. Paris: Dunod, Chap. 3.3.
Montaigne, E., A. Coelho, B. Delord, and L. Khefifi. 2012. Etude sur les impacts
socio-économiques et territoriaux de la liberalization des droits de plantations viticoles,
Rapport d’étude. Presented at the international board of the Association of
European Vine and Wine Regions (AREV), Brussels.
Nelson, R.R., and S.G. Winter. 1982. An evolutionary theory of economic change.
Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.
Pfeffer, J., and G.R. Salancik. 1978. The external control of organizations: A resource
dependence perspective. New York: Harper & Row.
Sidlovits, D., and Z. Kator. 2007. Characteristics of vertical coordination in the Hungarian
wine sector. Paper presented at the joint IAAE – 104th EAAE Seminar Agricultural
Economics and Transition: “What was expected, what we observed, the lessons
learned.” Corvinus University of Budapest, Budapest, September 6–8, 28p.
Torres, O. 2005. La guerre des vins: L’affaire Mondavi. Mondialisation et terroirs. Paris:
Dunod.
Williamson, O.E. 1975. Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications.
New York: Free Press.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Part V
Efficiency of the Business Models in
the Different Wine Industries
mmorag@uchile.cl
24
Introduction: Does a National Model Exist
Which Favors Trade Performance?
Jean-Marie Cardebat
The previous parts (Parts I and III) reveal the multiplicity of organization
models existing in the wine sector. Choosing the degree of vertical integration
therefore appears as a crucial factor for these organization models (Part IV). At
present we need to appraise the efficiency of these models. The key question to
be asked revolves around the existence of a model which will dominate the
others in terms of efficiency and economic performance, a model toward
which all wine companies should eventually converge. This question is partic-
ularly relevant in Europe where the global model is heavily based upon the
collective management of the company’s reputation through the Protected
Designation of Origin (PDO), small-scale properties and upstream rather than
downstream integration. This model has been, in part, challenged by New
World competition which relies on strong brands free of PDO constraints,
large estates which are able to exploit economies of scale and tight control of
sales via downstream rather than upstream integration. We therefore introduce
the hypothesis that a difference exists here, on average, between the Old and
the New World concerning the elements just specified above. The New World’s
commercial success since the 2000s has led to the Europeans questioning their
organization model. However, is the Manichean opposition occasionally made
between the two models founded? Must the Old World move toward a brand
model to preserve its world-leader status in the wine sector?
mmorag@uchile.cl
456 J.-M. Cardebat
mmorag@uchile.cl
Introduction: Does a National Model Exist Which Favors Trade… 457
25,000
253%
35%
20,000
34%
15,000
660%
10,000
589%
532%
5,000 65% 148%
12% 3065%
739%
0
Italy France Spain Germany Argentina USA Chile Australia South New China*
Africa Zeland
1995 2017
Fig. 24.1 Change in exports in volume between 1995 and 2017. (Source: OIV [Wine
International Organization] statistics. Note: the percentages reported correspond to
growth rates between 1995 and 2017. (*) For China, the data are from 1995 to 2014)
mmorag@uchile.cl
458 J.-M. Cardebat
as regards value creation, according to which the New World exports high
volumes of low-value wine while the Old World exports high-value wines.
The second piece of information from Fig. 24.1 is that the New World is
catching up given the strong increase of its countries between 1995 and 2017.
The growth of exports in volume from Chile or Australia is spectacular. The
export growth rate is even more impressive from countries which were only
minor exporters in 1995. This is especially the case for New Zealand which
has, in the space of two decades, established itself as a significant exporter on
the same level as Argentina or the USA. Moreover, New Zealand exports
high-value wines. The average price of its exports places it in second position
behind France’s (see Table 24.1). The cases of Chile (New World leader in
volume) and New Zealand (leader in average price) are clearly the most sig-
nificant to indicate how the New World is catching up with the Old.
A flat analysis of the wine-producing countries’ export statistics therefore
provides a contrasted outcome and does not allow us to identify one model as
more efficient than another. Indeed, a weaker progression in volume was in
part compensated by increased added value (i.e. average price) of the wines
exported.
Fig. 24.2 Exportation rate in 2014 in function of origin indicators. (Source: OIV statis-
tics. Note: on the x-axis we find the number of PDOs (for the European countries) or
that of simple origin indicators (DO for New World countries). The triangles indicate
European countries (except Georgia) and the circles represent New World countries
(including Georgia))
mmorag@uchile.cl
Introduction: Does a National Model Exist Which Favors Trade… 459
To go deeper into the analysis of trade performance, Fig. 24.2 presents the
exportation rate of the major producers (a country’s exports in volume divided
by its production volume). This exportation rate is cross-referenced with the
number of origin indicators per country recorded by the OIV. These are the
PDOs for the European countries and simple Denominations of Origin (DO)
for the New World. The PDO system is historically linked to the European
agricultural regulation (Meloni and Swinnen 2014). Most of the other coun-
tries and notably those of the New World use a simple origin indicator which
is nonrestrictive from the technical point of view. A linear trend can be added
for each of the two groups of countries (European and New World) which
shows the global link between the origin indicators and the exportation rate.
Figure 24.2 provides different information to the previous graph. Indeed,
this time, the New World countries dominate the Old World. The leading
country is Chile which exports 80% of its production. Next come Australia
and New Zealand with an exportation rate close to 60%. The European coun-
tries, with the exception of Spain, lag behind on this measure with the major-
ity of their production being sold on their national market, even if the latter
has continued to shrink since the 1960s. Regarding the linear trends expressed
by dotted lines on Fig. 24.2, the other lesson concerns the negative relation
between the origin indicators and the exportation rate, although the low
number of points does not allow us to draw a statistically significant conclu-
sion. The vertical and horizontal lines appearing in Fig. 24.2 represent, respec-
tively, the averages of the number of DOs (151) and of the exportation rate
(34%). These lines allow us to isolate four quadrants. Among the major wine-
producing countries, those having the lowest number of DOs (lower than the
average on the left side) have the highest exportation rate (higher than the
average at the top). With the exception of Italy, all the countries are in fact
located either in the northwest or in the southeast of these quadrants. However,
the Old World and New World countries fall into each of these two quadrants
and are therefore not polarized. Once again we need to note, however, that
this type of analysis does in no way lead us to a conclusion concerning the
causality between these variables.
Figure 24.3 provides supplementary information. It no longer simply con-
siders the exportation rate but the trade balance relative to national produc-
tion, still cross-referenced with the number of PDOs and DOs. It also shows
changes in this ratio between 1995 and 2014. Between these two dates we can
observe a significant progression of the New World countries with the excep-
tion of the USA. New Zealand’s performance appears the most impressive.
On the contrary, Germany is the country whose trade performance has wors-
ened the most followed by the USA. As above, it is not possible to isolate a
mmorag@uchile.cl
460 J.-M. Cardebat
100%
Chile 2014
-50%
Germany 1995
-100%
Germany 2014
-150%
Fig. 24.3 Trade balance relative to production volume (y-axis) in function of the num-
ber of PDOs and DOs (x-axis) for a selection of countries between 1995 and 2014.
(Source: OIV statistics. Note: the ratio is calculated on the basis of the trade balance
divided by the production of each country, with all the variables expressed in volume.
On the x-axis we find the number of PDOs (for the European countries) or that of
simple origin indicators (DO for New World countries). The triangles indicate European
countries (except Georgia) and the circles represent New World countries (including
Georgia). Linear trends are given for the year 2014)
model which seems more efficient than another. Old and New World coun-
tries have had very diverse trajectories within each group of countries.
Similarly, there is no clear relation between the number of origin indicators
and trade performance.
This simple statistical analysis of international trade in wine points there-
fore appears to conclude that there is no link between business models—
approximated by belonging to the Old or New World or by the number of
origin indicators—and trade performance, approximated by very simple indi-
cators of exportation and trade balance. We must remain cautious given the
limits of this study which remains highly descriptive. Nevertheless, this work
probably invalidates the Manichean idea, according to which the New World
is outperforming the Old in terms of export performance. In the same way, as
regards the average price of exported wines, it is difficult to support the idea
that the Old World remains the bastion of value creation compared to the
mmorag@uchile.cl
Introduction: Does a National Model Exist Which Favors Trade… 461
Reference
Meloni, G., and J. Swinnen. 2014. The rise and fall of the world’s largest wine
exporter-and its institutional legacy. Journal of Wine Economics 9 (1): 3–33.
mmorag@uchile.cl
25
Individual and Collective Reputations
in the Wine Industry
Florine Livat
25.1 Introduction
At first glance, the wine world seems characterized by two different models of
reputation that reflect varying cost structures, wine technologies, and wine
styles. The so-called New World1 (Argentina, Australia, Chile, New Zealand,
South Africa, and the United States) is known to promote private brands and
non-blended wines with varietal labeling that are easy for buyers to recognize.
The Old World (European and Middle Eastern countries with a long-
established history of wine production, since at least Roman times) produces
wines characterized by a profusion and even proliferation of geographic indi-
cations (GIs) and appellations of origin (AOs). GIs and AOs have some com-
mon attributes. Wines with this kind of identity are owned and marketed
collectively by unions, associations, trade bodies, or other kinds of coalitions.
1
According to Banks and Overton (2010), the Old World–New World dichotomy, which structures
much of the thinking about the wine industry, is not relevant anymore. Indeed, this segmentation neither
represents the complexity of production and marketing in these broad regions, which are not homoge-
nous, nor takes into account the rapidly expanding wine production and consumption in China and
India, and even Brazil. These authors suggest the addition of a “Third World” category. Some other
authors recommend creating a new niche in the global wine markets, a “Historic World,” which is dedi-
cated to wine-producing countries using mostly indigenous grape varietals, such as Armenia, Georgia, or
Israel (Keushguerian and Ghaplanyan 2015).
F. Livat (*)
Kedge Business School, Bordeaux, France
e-mail: florine.livat@kedgebs.com
mmorag@uchile.cl
464 F. Livat
2
“The term ‘reputation’ expresses what is generally said or believed about the abilities and/or qualities of
somebody or something” (Belletti 2000, p. 239).
mmorag@uchile.cl
Individual and Collective Reputations in the Wine Industry 465
enhance the image of wines produced in the Tuscany wine region benefit-
ing from the Brunello di Montalcino denominazione di origine controllata
e garantita (DOCG), a local AO.
–– Single wineries provide individual reputations. Quite often, individual
reputation is conveyed and even incarnated by the brand name. Yellow Tail
is one of the biggest wine brands; Shalauri Cellars is another one, produced
in the Kakheti region of Eastern Georgia. A single winery can provide sev-
eral individual brands, each with a specific blend or varietal.
Examples of the three sources of reputation in the wine sector can be drawn
from Old and New World countries, suggesting a strong interpenetration of
both reputational models.
In this chapter, we focus mainly on institutional and collective reputation,
given that the role of brands is extensively analyzed in the marketing litera-
ture: how it emerges and which effects are produced. Considering reputation
effects, origin and brands can be conciliated. In Sect. 25.2, we present briefly
some historical elements to understand why appellations and brands and vari-
etals prevail in, respectively, the Old and New Worlds. In Sect. 25.3, we pres-
ent how appellations act in wine markets. In Sect. 25.4 we discuss how origin
can be seen as a brand, and in Sect. 25.5 we present some failures of collective
reputation. We conclude our thoughts in Sect. 25.6.
mmorag@uchile.cl
466 F. Livat
mmorag@uchile.cl
Individual and Collective Reputations in the Wine Industry 467
3
“Fraud involved selling wine under the label of a private brand such as Moët & Chandon, or collective
regional brands (Bordeaux or Champagne) when it had been produced elsewhere. Adulteration, by con-
trast, consisted of adding ingredients that were considered illegal or ‘unnatural’ to wine and the wine-
making process like resin, honey, herbs but also lead and lead compounds” (Simpson 2011a, p. 7). For a
series of examples, see Holmberg (2010).
mmorag@uchile.cl
468 F. Livat
4
Simpson (2005) shows that if establishing regional appellations has helped growers in winning back
market power in the Bordeaux and Champagne vineyards, another response was shown in the Midi
region (Languedoc area): the creation of producer cooperatives, better equipped than merchants to clas-
sify wines and guarantee quality for consumers, has provided incentives to plant quality vines and allow
growers to capture the growing economies of scale in wine production and marketing. This creation
occurred because the sector was united (small and large growers and even merchants also affected by low
prices) and mass demonstration in 1907, previously unknown in France.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Individual and Collective Reputations in the Wine Industry 469
sealed with a numbered governmental seal across the cap or cork, which
results in a paper strip if torn out during opening. For a presentation of the
EU wine classification, see Delmastro (2005, p. 2).
The economic and institutional features of the European wine industry,
generated at least partly by some natural constraints, have allowed for the
emergence of the appellation system as a support for collective reputation and
to provide information about the products. The New World history is
different.
Simpson (2011b) studied the exogenous changes that occurred in the wine
industry between 1870 and 1914 in California, Australia, and Argentina,
which evolved from a traditional viti-viniculture to a new organization of the
commodity chain. By the beginning of the twentieth century, this chain was
dominated by large industrial wineries producing wines that could be branded.
In the New World, grape production was a specialist activity whereas wine-
making and marketing were integrated into a single business.
In the 1850s, the New World wine industry was small scale. By 1900, in
Australia, California, and Argentina, grape growing was a specialist activity
and grapegrowers sold their grapes to winemakers, who also made a business
of wine. Indeed, in the New World, climatic conditions made the vines much
easier to grow than in the Old World. Harvest failures and diseases were far
less frequent, and grape quality was more stable and less heterogeneous from
one harvest to the next than in the Old World (Simpson 2011b). As depicted
by Simpson (2011b), New World grapegrowers met with few problems, need-
ing little capital to create new vineyards and other employment opportunities.
Wineries need winemaking facilities, and their investments are linked to
credit availability. When the market downturns, low prices do not allow for
capital-intensive wineries to purchase grapes from independent grapegrowers
who, as a consequence, crush the grapes themselves: the wine supply is not
diminished but at the same time quality declines as independent grapegrowers
are not necessarily skilled in winemaking. This increased separation between
grape growing and winemaking has led to unbalanced growth between grape
growing and winemaking.
In California by the end of the nineteenth century, facing falling prices and
fraud, winemakers and wine dealers established collective associations to agree
on prices and quantities. After several conflicts, the winemakers’ corporation
disappeared and horizontal consolidation as well as vertical integration
mmorag@uchile.cl
470 F. Livat
allowed the wine dealers’ trust (the California Wine Association) to control
distribution and guarantee non-adulterated wines, while the political climate
was relatively permissive toward big businesses and trusts. This provided the
conditions to develop a mass market for wines and to invest in brand names.
This market is characterized by limited competition, given that investments in
production facilities and brands raise entry costs for potential newcomers.
Australia was the only New World country with a significant export trade,
with a fifth of its national production sold in the United Kingdom. Australia’s
high internal tariffs as well as the narrowness of the domestic market provided
an incentive to export even with high freight costs. But a long sea travel, some
extreme temperatures during it, and a necessary rest of several months on the
arrival of wines caused major quality problems for the wine trade. Simpson
(2011b, p. 55) summarizes that “trusted agents were required at both ends of
the chain: in Australia to check that only well-made wines were shipped; and
in London to determine the appropriate remedies to correct the wines on
their arrival.” Two major London houses dominated trade. They specialized in
Australian wines; invested in vineyards, winemaking facilities, European
methods for viticulture and vinification; and bought large quantities of grapes,
hired agents, and invested in modern techniques of advertising such as point-
of-purchase communication, all necessary conditions to create a standardized
product that could build consumer recognition. Even as the South Australian
government tried to compete, providing incentives to plant vines and creating
a vine depot in London, it failed to improve quality, and by 1911, three big
players dominated the exports from Australia to the United Kingdom and
were able to develop major brands.
A lot of European immigrants moved to Argentina before 1914. They were
accustomed to drinking wine, so wine producers competed on price rather
than on quality. By the end of the nineteenth century, there was a rail connec-
tion between Mendoza and Buenos Aires to take advantage of the good grow-
ing conditions for grapes, the winemakers who learned the needed skills to
produce wines properly in the hot climate and use the upgraded winemaking
equipment (Blanchy 2010). Grape growing is a specialist activity and grapes
were sold to wine producers, who could sell large quantities of ordinary wines
to agents, intermediaries, and/or retailers. Wine had been a basic beverage in
the Argentine diet, and leaders such as Peròn as well as the military dictator-
ship encouraged the supply of plentiful cheap wines.
But during the twentieth century, the growth of the wine industry was very
slow due to isolationist and protectionist policies enacted during the 1950s
and, as a result, the Argentinian wine industry lacked innovation (Townsend
and Tiefenbacher 2011). Facing a falling demand, the Argentinian wine s ector
mmorag@uchile.cl
Individual and Collective Reputations in the Wine Industry 471
destabilized, and in the 1980s, 36% of all vineyards were eradicated (Pont and
Thomas 2011). The modernization of the wine industry started in the 1990s
with the replacement of traditional varietals such as Criolla with Malbec. The
focus of production has shifted from low-cost quantity to quality. The open-
ing of international markets; some technology transfers; foreign investments
by big, recognized players such as Mondavi, Lurton, and Chandon; the arrival
of maverick winemakers; as well as the peso devaluation in 2002 (Mount
2012; Pont and Thomas 2011), even if disadvantageous to most citizens,
made wines highly competitive in foreign markets and enabled the recogni-
tion of Malbec to become the emblematic variety of Argentina. If Malbec is
not a brand, it has a strong economic and emotional connection to Argentina,
where 70% of the world’s Malbec vineyards are now planted.5
25.3 G
eographic Indications and Collective
Reputation
A DO is used traditionally to suggest specific production practices or look for
natural endowments to positively affect wine taste. In the wine sector, empha-
sizing the place of origin as an indicator of quality is one way to differentiate
products (Stasi et al. 2011), especially for connoisseurs (Atkin and Johnson
2010).
5
See https://historyandwine.com/2014/07/02/cahors-france-the-french-malbec-story/; retrieved September
15, 2016.
mmorag@uchile.cl
472 F. Livat
25.3.1 C
oalition of Economic Agents and the Collective
Reputation Effect
6
A great growth, such as Château Mouton Rothschild in Bordeaux, indicates the Pauillac appellation in
the label, but it doesn’t make any explicit reference to Bordeaux as a collective umbrella.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Individual and Collective Reputations in the Wine Industry 473
Fig. 25.1 Denominations of origin. (Source: Addor and Grazioli 2002, p. 870)
25.3.2 A
Regulation to Increase Welfare and Efficiency
that Generate Profits
mmorag@uchile.cl
474 F. Livat
also apply before obtaining an AOC designation. Since 2008, the system is
similar to that of taxes: winemakers must declare that their wine has been
produced in accordance with AOC requirements; to assure this, wines are
subject to random tests by an expert from a public agency. A given wine can
lose its appellation status for a given vintage if it doesn’t achieve the appella-
tion criteria.7
Geographic indications (GIs) are viewed as public goods (Schamel and
Anderson 2003) because they are used simultaneously by many firms that are
free to enter and exit the market, provided that all the requirements are met
(Moschini et al. 2008). Rangnekar (2004) views them as “club goods,” non-
rival, congestible, and excludable, and producers are free to decide the size of
the club. Binding a brand to a territory also generates a profit for some groups
of producers who have access to key assets or skills required to get the certifi-
cation or the AOC, such as land and a vineyard that can’t be delocalized or
will damage owners of land and vineyards in neighboring areas where less
reputed and less expensive wines are produced (Meloni and Swinnen 2013).
Castriota and Delmastro (2014) notice that using a well-known geographical
group brand enables small producers to get the benefits of a reputation profit.
But Winfree and McCluskey (2005) show that when a collective reputation
becomes a public good, there is an incentive to free ride, and the provision of
quality decreases as the size of the group increases.
7
See, for instance, Bordeaux producer brand Les Hauts de Pontet-Canet, which is usually awarded with
a Pauillac appellation but didn’t get it for the 2012 vintage:
http://www.decanter.com/news/wine-news/587659/pontet-canet-second-wine-loses-aoc-status?utm_
source=Eloqua&utm_medium=email&utm_content=news+alert+link+24102014&utm_campaign=
Newsletter-24102014
mmorag@uchile.cl
Individual and Collective Reputations in the Wine Industry 475
the production is clearly defined and that the peculiarities of the place are the
guarantee of a minimum of typicality” (Mora 2016, p. 43). Several agricul-
tural products can benefit from that certification of origin: wine, cheese, meat,
lavender, lentils, honey, ham, butter, spirits, and so on. The number of prod-
ucts benefiting from a protected designation of origin is increasing in Europe
(Profeta et al. 2010). Broude (2005) also views GIs as tools to protect cultural
heritage and preserve traditional methods of production or to establish and
preserve an identity. Addor and Grazioli (2002) also note that GIs are based
on collective traditions. Vogel (1995) notices that some people attach value to
regional traditions and are willing to pay a premium for it.
The promotion of a region of origin has a long history in the wine industry.
Schamel (2006) has shown a trend toward more regional differentiation. On
the academic side, origin has often been used as a vector for collective reputa-
tion used in empirical analysis. Indeed, several applications of a hedonic pric-
ing method for wine refer to appellation, which includes group reputation
(see, among others, Delmastro 2005; Landon and Smith 1997; Schamel and
Anderson 2003).
An extensive body of literature has addressed the issue-of-origin effect8 on
wine perception, evaluation, and purchase decisions. Yue et al. (2013) show
that region of origin, specifically geographical indicators, is an efficient tool to
signal good quality. They cite examples such as the Champagne region of
France in which well-known brands have invested in quality and advertising
over a lengthy period, thus building and maintaining a successful collective
reputation for the vineyard as a whole. In research by Batt and Dean (2000),
the origin of wine was found to be a key variable affecting consumer purchase
decisions. An argument for promotion of the region is also given by Hong
and Wyer (1989), who demonstrate that origin has a direct influence on eval-
uation of a product and in addition encourages stronger consideration of the
other attributes of the product. Consumers possess stereotyped beliefs about
the quality of products from a country of origin (Samiee 1994). This is known
as the “halo effect,” suggested by Maheswaran (1994). Huber and McCann
(1982) also demonstrate that origin can provide product quality signals when
consumers are not able to ascertain or are not familiar with the actual quality
8
For a review of the country-of-origin effect on perceived quality, see Verlegh and Steenkamp (1999). For
an analysis of the region-of-origin effect, see Van Ittersum et al. (2003).
mmorag@uchile.cl
476 F. Livat
of the product. This is backed up by research from Elliot and Cameron (1994),
who find that country of origin may be used as a quality indicator when the
product cannot be assessed by objective criteria. As such, the link between
origin and reputation seems obvious: origin is a means to enhance reputation
and its vehicle.
According to Bruwer and House (2003), the image of a region of origin can
be used as a point of differentiation if it can take advantage of the positive
associations consumers have with that region. In some ways, origin acts like a
brand and considering the two models as opposite isn’t really accurate
anymore.
–– The merchant brand: usually blended wines that are made, bottled, and
packaged by merchants and maintain a stable quality.
–– The producer brand: any wine estate that grows vines and has winemaking
facilities can create its own brand name, including using the word château
traditionally in the Bordeaux vineyard or the word domaine in Burgundy.
–– The retailer’s brand: wine that is available only in the outlets of a single
retailer.
At this point, origin and brand cannot be considered as two opposite mod-
els. They are often used jointly. Origin also has some dimensions of brands, as
shown in the next section.
Origin can also affect the concept of a collective brand. Moulard et al. (2015)
show that origin affects consumers’ perceptions of a wine’s authenticity and
their willingness to pay for it, with a positive effect in the case of Old World
mmorag@uchile.cl
Individual and Collective Reputations in the Wine Industry 477
mmorag@uchile.cl
478 F. Livat
The AOC system provides a product certification that acts to transform unob-
servable experiences, but it also gives credence to elements such as origin as
observable search attributes (Auriol and Schilizzi 2003). Auriol and Schilizzi
(2003, p. 3) define certification “as a process whereby an unobservable quality
level of some product is made known to the consumer through some labeling
system, usually issued by a third independent party.” Considering that con-
sumer confidence associated with certification is a major concern, these authors
show that the sunk costs of certification enable the achievement of credibility
and that certification is better accomplished by an independent body, either a
private firm or a public agency. One specificity of GIs is that their recognition,
administration, and control are shared by public and private bodies, depend-
ing on the system of protection (Addor and Grazioli 2002). But frauds still
exist. Indeed, mixing wines from several appellations and mislabeling bottles
regarding their origin are some common types of fraud (Holmberg 2010).
Some winemakers also try to ridicule the appellation system: in the 1990s,
mmorag@uchile.cl
Individual and Collective Reputations in the Wine Industry 479
mmorag@uchile.cl
480 F. Livat
to go it alone in 2009 (see Anson 2013). In the case of Bordeaux wines, in 2004
four appellations created their own subgroup: Côtes de Bordeaux is the umbrella
for Premières Côtes de Blaye, Premières Côtes de Bordeaux, Côtes de Castillon,
and Bordeaux Côtes de Francs appellations, all of whom share “the idea of cre-
ating a common sign of recognition.” They consider that recognition is not
provided by their single AOs, but they remain members of the regional wine
commission (see their website bordeaux-cotes.com).
The AOC, as a coalition, is in charge of generic advertising, thanks to funds
provided by the members. A return on investment is expected because of spill-
over effects from the collective reputation toward the individual reputation of
the winery. In Bordeaux, a breakaway group emerged in 2010 because non-
voluntary (i.e., compulsory) fees are not legal, and they felt that the regional
wine commission was not working in the interests of those who compulsorily
support it financially (Anson 2010). But in 2012, the court ruled that wine-
makers must pay the fees. Hence, in France at least, some actors consider
challenging the coalitions. In US wine regions, Rickard et al. (2015) highlight
that individual reputation outside of the umbrella region can be affected by a
collective reputation, even if these individual producers don’t contribute
financially to the promotional efforts, through a reputation-tapping phenom-
enon. In the case of Bordeaux wines, Gergaud et al. (2017) show that if col-
lective reputation generally provides some benefits to individual group
members, the gains obtained from generic promotion by the wine commis-
sion do not always compensate for the costs of mandatory membership.
25.6 Conclusion
The wine market exhibits several different quality signals: individual and col-
lective, private and public. The number of wines benefiting from a protected
designation of origin is increasing in the Old World (Profeta et al. 2010) as
well as in the New World (Easingwood et al. 2011). Similar to brands, AOs
aim to signal quality. If brands support individual reputation, denominations
of origin are a vehicle for collective reputation. Both coexist more and more
frequently on the same label, suggesting in some way a convergence of both
reputational models. Reputation is not supported by a unique model, neither
in the Old World nor in the New World.
Reputation is a key variable in wine markets. The prolific literature on
hedonic pricing highlights its positive effect on price. Livat (2007) has shown
that consumers substitute Bordeaux appellations with the same level of repu-
tation. Livat et al. (forthcoming) show that they substitute them according to
semantic elements, that is, similar names as carriers of reputation, not accord-
mmorag@uchile.cl
Individual and Collective Reputations in the Wine Industry 481
References
Addor, F., and A. Grazioli. 2002. Geographical indications beyond wines and spirits.
The Journal of World Intellectual Property 5 (6): 865–897.
Anania, G., and R. Nisticò. 2004. Public regulation as a substitute for trust in quality
food markets: What if the trust substitute cannot be fully trusted? Journal of
Institutional and Theoretical Economics 160: 681–701.
Anson, J. 2010. “Cronyist” CIVB to be sued by breakaway group. Decanter, December
10.
———. 2013. Montlouis-sur-Loire cuts itself loose from InterLoire. Decanter,
January 9.
Ashenfelter, O., S. Ciccarella, and H.J. Shatz. 2007. French wine and the US boycott
of 2003: Does politics really affect commerce? Journal of Wine Economics 2 (01):
55–74.
Atkin, T., and R. Johnson. 2010. Appellation as an indicator of quality. International
Journal of Wine Business Research 22 (1): 42–61.
Auriol, E., and S.G. Schilizzi. 2003. Quality signaling through certification: Theory and
an application to agricultural seed markets. IDEI Working Paper, 165. Toulouse:
Institut d’Economie Industrielle (IDEI).
Banks, G., and J. Overton. 2010. Old world, new world, third world?
Reconceptualising the worlds of wine. Journal of Wine Research 21 (1): 57–75.
Barham, E. 2003. Translating terroir: The global challenge of French AOC labeling.
Journal of Rural Studies 19 (1): 127–138.
Batt, P.J., and A. Dean. 2000. Factors influencing the consumer’s decision. Australian
& New Zealand Wine Industry Journal 15 (4): S34–S41.
Belletti, G. 2000. Origin labelled products, reputation and heterogeneity of firms.
Actes et Communications: Institut National de la Recherche Agronomique. Economie
et Sociologie Rurales 17 (1): 239–259.
Blanchy, G. 2010. La construction des vins argentins à travers l’affichage. Sciences de
la Société 80: 60–75.
Bramley, C., E. Biénabe, and J. Kirsten. 2009. The economics of geographical indica-
tions: Towards a conceptual framework for geographical indication research in
developing countries. The Economics of Intellectual Property, 109–141. Available at
http://www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/ip-development/en/economics/pdf/
wo_1012_e.pdf
mmorag@uchile.cl
482 F. Livat
Broude, T. 2005. Taking trade and culture seriously: Geographical indications and
cultural protection in WTO. University of Pennsylvania Journal of International
Law 26: 623.
Bruwer, J., and M. House. 2003. Has the era of regional branding arrived for the
Australian wine industry? Some perspectives. The Australian & New Zealand
Grapegrower & Winemaker, December 1.
Bureau, J.C., and E. Valceschini. 2003. European food-labeling policy: Successes and
limitations. Journal of Food Distribution Research 34 (3): 70–76.
Cardinale, S., B. Nguyen, and T.C. Melewar. 2016. Place-based brand experience,
place attachment and loyalty. Marketing Intelligence & Planning 34 (3): 302–317.
Castriota, S., and M. Delmastro. 2011. Inside the black box of collective reputation (No.
89/2011). Perugia: Università di Perugia, Dipartimento Economia.
———. 2012. Seller reputation: Individual, collective, and institutional factors.
Journal of Wine Economics 7 (01): 49–69.
———. 2014. The economics of collective reputation: Evidence from the wine
industry. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 97 (2): 469–489. https://doi.
org/10.1093/ajae/aau107.
Charters, S., and N. Spielmann. 2014. Characteristics of strong territorial brands:
The case of champagne. Journal of Business Research 67 (7): 1461–1467.
Choi, C.J., S.H. Lee, and D. Oh. 1995. The strategy of grouping and reputation
linkage in clubs and multi-product firms. European Journal of Political Economy 11
(3): 521–533.
Cuellar, S.S., D. Karnowsky, and F. Acosta. 2009. The Sideways effect: A test for
changes in the demand for merlot and pinot noir wines. Journal of Wine Economics
4 (02): 219–232.
Defrancesco, E., J.E. Orrego, and A. Gennari. 2012. Would ‘New World’ wines ben-
efit from protected geographical indications in international markets? The case of
Argentinean Malbec. Wine Economics and Policy 1 (1): 63–72.
Delmastro, M. 2005. An investigation into the quality of wine: Evidence from
Piedmont. Journal of Wine Research 16 (1): 1–17.
Doward, J. 2005. French bitter over wine study. The Guardian, March 20.
Dubois, P., and C. Nauges. 2010. Identifying the effect of unobserved quality and
expert reviews in the pricing of experience goods: Empirical application on
Bordeaux wine. International Journal of Industrial Organization 28 (3): 205–212.
Easingwood, C., L. Lockshin, and T. Spawton. 2011. The drivers of wine regionality.
Journal of Wine Research 22 (1): 19–33.
Edwards, F. 1989. The marketing of wine from small wineries: Managing the intan-
gibles. International Journal of Wine Marketing 1 (1): 14–17.
Elliott, G.R., and R.C. Cameron. 1994. Consumer perception of product quality
and the country-of-origin effect. Journal of International Marketing 2 (2): 49–62.
Fombrun, C., and M. Shanley. 1990. What’s in a name? Reputation building and
corporate strategy. Academy of Management Journal 33 (2): 233–258.
Gergaud, O., F. Livat, B. Rickard, and F. Warzynski. 2017. Evaluating the net bene-
fits of collective reputation: The case of Bordeaux wine. Food Policy 71: 8–16.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Individual and Collective Reputations in the Wine Industry 483
Holmberg, L. 2010. Wine fraud. International Journal of Wine Research 2010 (2):
105–113.
Hong, S.T., and R.S. Wyer. 1989. Effects of country-of-origin and product-attribute
information on product evaluation: An information processing perspective.
Journal of Consumer Research 16 (2): 175–187.
Huber, J., and J. McCann. 1982. The impact of inferential beliefs on product evalu-
ations. Journal of Marketing Research 19: 324–333.
Jacquet, O. 2009. Un siècle de construction du vignoble bourguignon: Les organisations
vitivinicoles de 1884 aux AOC. Dijon: EUD, Collection Sociétés.
Keushguerian, V., and I. Ghaplanyan 2015. Carving out a new market niche: Historic
world of wines. BIO Web of Conferences, 5, 03002.
Landon, S., and C.E. Smith. 1997. The use of quality and reputation indicators by
consumers: The case of Bordeaux wine. Journal of Consumer Policy 20 (3):
289–323.
Livat, F. 2007. Mesure des interactions de prix: Une analyse des modalités de substi-
tution parmi sept vins de Bordeaux. Economie & Prévision 4: 127–145.
Livat, F., J. Alston, and J.-M. Cardebat. forthcoming. Do denominations of origin
provide useful quality signals? The case of Bordeaux wines. Economic Modelling.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2018.06.003.
Lockshin, L., M. Rasmussen, and F. Cleary. 2000. The nature and roles of a wine
brand. Australian & New Zealand Wine Industry Journal 15 (4): S17–S24.
Lockshin, L., W. Jarvis, F. d’Hauteville, and J.P. Perrouty. 2006. Using simulations
from discrete choice experiments to measure consumer sensitivity to brand,
region, price, and awards in wine choice. Food Quality and Preference 17 (3):
166–178.
Maheswaran, D. 1994. Country of origin as a stereotype: Effects of consumer exper-
tise and attribute strength on product evaluations. Journal of Consumer Research 21
(2): 354–365.
Marette, S. 2005. The collective-quality promotion in the agribusiness sector: An over-
view. Ames: Center for Agricultural and Rural Development, Iowa State University.
Marie-Vivien, D. 2010. The role of the state in the protection of geographical indica-
tions: From disengagement in France/Europe to significant involvement in India.
The Journal of World Intellectual Property 13 (2): 121–147.
Meloni, G., and J. Swinnen. 2013. The political economy of European wine regula-
tions. Journal of Wine Economics 8 (3): 244–284.
Menapace, L., and G. Moschini. 2011. Quality certification by geographical indica-
tions, trademarks and firm reputation. European Review of Agricultural Economics
39 (4): 539–566.
Mora, P. 2016. Wine positioning: A handbook with 30 case studies of wine brands and
wine regions in the world. Cham: Springer.
Moschini, G., L. Menapace, and D. Pick. 2008. Geographical indications and the
competitive provision of quality in agricultural markets. American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 90 (3): 794–812.
mmorag@uchile.cl
484 F. Livat
Moulard, J., B.J. Babin, and M. Griffin. 2015. How aspects of a wine’s place affect
consumers’ authenticity perceptions and purchase intentions: The role of country
of origin and technical terroir. International Journal of Wine Business Research 27
(1): 61–78.
Mount, I. 2012. The vineyard at the end of the world: Maverick winemakers and the
rebirth of Malbec. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.
Mueller, S., L. Lockshin, Y. Saltman, and J. Blanford. 2010. Message on a bottle: The
relative influence of wine back label information on wine choice. Food Quality and
Preference 21 (1): 22–32.
Nourrisson, D. 2013. Le buveur du XIXe siècle. Paris: Albin Michel.
Orth, U.R., and P. Krška. 2001. Quality signals in wine marketing: The role of exhi-
bition awards. The International Food and Agribusiness Management Review 4 (4):
385–397.
Pont, P.C.M., and H. Thomas. 2011. The sociotechnical alliance of Argentine quality
wine: How Mendoza’s viticulture functions between the local and the global.
Science, Technology & Human Values 37 (6): 627–652.
Profeta, A., R. Balling, V. Schoene, and A. Wirsig. 2010. Protected geographical indi-
cations and designations of origin: An overview of the status quo and the develop-
ment of the use of regulation (EC) 510/06 in Europe, with special consideration
of the German situation. Journal of International Food & Agribusiness Marketing 22
(1–2): 179–198.
Rangnekar, D. 2004. The socio-economics of geographical indications. UNCTAD-
ICTSD Project on IPRs and Sustainable Development, Issue Paper, 8.
Rasmussen, M., and L. Lockshin. 1999. Wine choice behaviour: The effect of regional
branding. International Journal of Wine Marketing 11 (1): 36–46.
Rickard, B.J., J.J. McCluskey, and R.W. Patterson. 2015. Reputation tapping.
European Review of Agricultural Economics 42 (4): 675–701.
Roberto, M.A. 2011. The changing structure of the global wine industry. International
Business & Economics Research Journal (IBER) 2 (9): 1–14.
Samiee, S. 1994. Customer evaluation of products in a global market. Journal of
International Business Studies 25 (3): 579–604.
Schamel, G. 2006. Geography versus brands in a global wine market. Agribusiness 22
(3): 363–374.
———. 2009. Dynamic analysis of brand and regional reputation: The case of wine.
Journal of Wine Economics 4 (01): 62–80.
Schamel, G., and K. Anderson. 2003. Wine quality and varietal, regional and winery
reputation: Hedonic prices for Australia and New Zealand. Economic Record 79
(246): 357–369.
Simpson, J. 2005. Cooperation and conflicts: Institutional innovation in France’s
wine markets, 1870–1911. Business History Review 79 (03): 527–558.
———. 2011a. Creating wine: The emergence of a world industry, 1840–1914.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Individual and Collective Reputations in the Wine Industry 485
———. 2011b. Factor endowments, markets and vertical integration. The develop-
ment of commercial wine production in Argentina, Australia and California,
c1870–1914. Revista de Historia Económica/Journal of Iberian and Latin American
Economic History (Second Series) 29 (01): 39–66.
Spawton, T. 1986. Understanding wine purchasing: Knowing how the wine buyer
behaves can increase sales. The Australian and New Zealand Wine Industry Journal
1 (2): 54–57.
Stanziani, A. 2004. Wine reputation and quality controls: The origin of the AOCs in
19th century France. European Journal of Law and Economics 18 (2): 149–167.
Stasi, A., G. Nardone, R. Viscecchia, and A. Seccia. 2011. Italian wine demand and
differentiation effect of geographical indications. International Journal of Wine
Business Research 23 (1): 49–61.
Teil, G. 2010. The French wine “appellations d’origine contrôlée” and the virtues of
suspicion. The Journal of World Intellectual Property 13 (2): 253–274.
Tirole, J. 1996. A theory of collective reputations (with applications to the persis-
tence of corruption and to firm quality). The Review of Economic Studies 63 (1):
1–22.
Townsend, C.G., and J.P. Tiefenbacher. 2011. Spatial change in South American
viticulture: Static factors and dynamic processes in past, present, and future
Chilean and Argentinean land use patterns and varietal choices. In Proceedings—
International Geographical Union 2011 Regional Geography Conference, Santiago,
Chile.
Van Ittersum, K., M.J. Candel, and M.T. Meulenberg. 2003. The influence of the
image of a product’s region of origin on product evaluation. Journal of Business
Research 56 (3): 215–226.
Verlegh, P.W., and J.B.E. Steenkamp. 1999. A review and meta-analysis of country-
of-origin research. Journal of Economic Psychology 20 (5): 521–546.
Viot, C., and J. Passebois-Ducros. 2010. Wine brands or branded wines? The speci-
ficity of the French market in terms of the brand. International Journal of Wine
Business Research 22 (4): 406–422.
Vogel, D. 1995. Trading up: Consumer and environmental regulation in a global econ-
omy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Winfree, J.A., and J.J. McCluskey. 2005. Collective reputation and quality. American
Journal of Agricultural Economics 87 (1): 206–213.
Young, A. 1794. Travels during the years 1787, 1788 and 1789, undertaken more par-
ticularly with a view of ascertaining the cultivation, wealth, resources, and national
prosperity, of the Kingdom of France. Vol. 2. Bury St. Edmunds: W. Richardson.
Yuan, J., A.M. Morrison, S. Linton, R. Feng, and S.M. Jeon. 2004. Marketing small
wineries: An exploratory approach to website evaluation. Tourism Recreation
Research 29 (3): 15–25.
Yue, C., S. Marette, and J.C. Beghin. 2013. How to promote quality perception:
Brand advertising or geographical indication? Non-tariff measures with market
imperfections: Trade and welfare implications 12: 73.
mmorag@uchile.cl
26
The Chilean Wine Cluster
Alfredo Coelho and Etienne Montaigne
26.1 Introduction
In a few years, the Chilean wine industry became an example of success and a
serious competitor for the European and international wine producers. The
success of the wine industry can be explained by the way it is organized as a
‘cluster’, through horizontal and vertical linkages, where the main stakehold-
ers in the industry are simultaneously in competition and cooperation, that is
to say, ‘coopetition’ (Nalebuff and Brandenburger 1996). Contrary to the
dominant organization of the European wine industry, the Chilean model is
more ‘relational’ (i.e. driven by relationships across the cluster).
The Chilean wine industry achieved unexpected performances in the last
few decades. The industry demonstrated an extraordinary capacity to pro-
duce, export, and compete in international markets. Those achievements are
related to natural conditions (quality of the soils, climate, land, water avail-
ability, etc.) but also to the way the industry is organized. Following the pio-
neering work of Alfred Marshall in 1890, in the last few years there was a
A. Coelho (*)
Bordeaux Sciences Agro, Gradignan, France
e-mail: alfredo.coelho@agro-bordeaux.fr
E. Montaigne
Department of Agricultural Economics, Montpellier Supagro, Montpellier, France
e-mail: etienne.montaigne@supagro.inra.fr
mmorag@uchile.cl
488 A. Coelho and E. Montaigne
26.2 T
he Wine Cluster as an Institutional
Arrangement
26.2.1 On the ‘Cluster’ Concept
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Cluster 489
26.2.2 T
he Role of Public-Private Partnerships
to Promote Efficiency
26.2.3 A
National Innovation Strategy Adapted
to the Regions
mmorag@uchile.cl
490 A. Coelho and E. Montaigne
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Cluster 491
26.2.4 A
n Innovation Strategy Driven by the Wine
Industry
mmorag@uchile.cl
492 A. Coelho and E. Montaigne
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Cluster 493
Fig. 26.1 An overview of the Chilean wine cluster. (Source: Adapted from Wines of
Chile)
mmorag@uchile.cl
494 A. Coelho and E. Montaigne
In recent years, efforts have been made to strengthen the weak links in the
cluster through innovation and R&D projects (Vinnova, Tecnovid,
CONICYT), an active policy to attract foreign investments to meet the needs
and overcome the weaknesses of the cluster (Prochile, Corfo).
Over the last few decades, the cluster attracted a great number of new firms,
particularly new wineries and grape nurseries (see Fig. 26.2). The number of
new wineries increased particularly in two decades (1990–2009). The estab-
lishment of new firms was significant during the expansion of Chilean wine
exports backed through government initiatives.
A significant number of grapevine nurseries were established after 2001.
Twenty-two new grape nurseries were established after 2001 to supply Vitis
vinifera plants. According to ODEPA (2015), the volume of Vitis vinifera
plants marketed in Chile (7.2 million plants in 2014) is considerably higher
than the plants supplied for the production of table grapes (approximately 3.3
million of plants in 2014). The establishment of a new wave of wineries
increased the needs for the supply of certified vine plants. Therefore, the num-
ber of domestic and international grape nurseries expanded likewise.
Some of the main leading wineries established their own grape nurseries in
the early 2000s: Viña Concha y Toro (Lourdes, 2000) and Viña Santa Rita
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Cluster 495
120
100 98 98
80 75 72
Number of firms
60
48
40
25
20 21
20
8 10 8
1 1 4 2 4 4 2
0
Before 1960 1961-70 1971-80 1981-90 1991-2000 2001-2009 Aer 2010
Fig. 26.2 Establishment dates of grape nurseries and bodegas in Chile. (Note 1: new
wineries include both the bodegas producing more than 300,000 liters and the bode-
gas with an export activity. Data includes established wineries until 2011 (Source: INE);
Note 2: grape nurseries include the suppliers of Vitis vinifera plants and the suppliers
of table wine plants. Some of the grape nurseries supplying plants for table grapes
may also supply Vitis vinifera plants. Data includes established firms in 2015 (Source:
SAG))
(Santa Rita, 2000). Other wineries launched their own nurseries in a later
phase: Viña Undurraga (La Rioja, 2009), Viña Almaviva (2009), and Viña
Santa Carolina (2014). The cluster attracted foreign grape Vitis vinifera nurs-
eries quite early. Two French nurseries established production facilities in
Chile: Pepinières Guillaume in 2001 and Pepinières Richter in 2009.
26.3.3 C
oncentration and Role of the Leading Wine
Firms
mmorag@uchile.cl
496 A. Coelho and E. Montaigne
Table 26.2 Concentration of the market shares in the domestic market of the leading
wine firms in Chile (% of the total volumes)
2005 2008 2010 2013 2015
Concha y Toro 27.1 29.7 30.7 28.5 28.1
Santa Rita 24.4 28.7 29.4 29.5 31.6
San Pedro Tarapacà 21.7 23 24.4 27.3 28.4
Santa Carolina 3.2 2 1.8 1.4 0.6
Others 23.6 16.6 13.7 13.4 11
Source: Concha y Toro
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Cluster 497
26.3.4 T
he Influence of Strategic Alliances and Foreign
Investments
Since the first foreign investment in the Chilean wine production by Miguel
Torres (Spain) in 1979, many foreign investors were attracted by the Chilean
wine cluster. These investments have taken two main forms: greenfield invest-
ments in production and strategic alliances (or joint-ventures).
Chile’s strengths as a wine producer are numerous: low disease pressure in
the vineyard, diversity of climates and soils, lack of constraints for extending
mmorag@uchile.cl
498 A. Coelho and E. Montaigne
According to Torres et al. (2008), during the period 1998–2004, the average
price of wine exported for wineries involved in international joint-ventures
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Cluster 499
projects (US $4.9/bottle) was higher than average prices for the wines pro-
duced through foreign-owned subsidiaries (US $1.6/bottle). Moreover, exports
of wines associated with joint-ventures accounted for price ranging from 23%
to 30% of the market for super-premium wines, while the same segment
accounted only for 9% to 17% of the subsidiaries of foreign-owned firms.
Farinelli (2012, p. 204) explains the main interests of inter-firm agreements
in the Chilean wine cluster:
The main strategic alliances and foreign investments in the Chilean wine
cluster are detailed hereafter (Fig. 26.3).
• 1970: Miguel Torres S.A. (Espagne) (the pionnier) Miguel Torres (Chile)
• Gonzalez Byass (Esp.) Conde de Aconcagua (JV c/ Estampa)
• Guelbenzu (Esp.) Guelbenzu
• Bodegas y Bebidas (Esp.) Selentia (JV c. grupo San Pedro)
• Antinori (Ita.) Haras de Pirque
• Francesco Marone Cinzano (Ita.) Reserva de Caliboro
• Baron Philippe Rothschild (Fra.) Almaviva (JV c/ Concha y Toro)
• Los Vascos (JV c/ grupo Santa Rita)
• Bruno Prats (Fra.) Aquitania (JV)
• Château Dassault (Fra.) Altair (JV c/ grupo San Pedro)
• Marnier Lapostolle (Fra.) Lapostolle
• Boisset (Fra.) Gracia (JV c/ grupo Corpora)
• Château Larose Tritaudon (Fra.) Casas del Toqui
• Laroche (Fra.) (JEANJEAN since OCT. 2009 – Languedoc) Araucano
• Billington (EUA) Billington
• Kendall Jackson (EUA) Calina
• Robert Mondavi (EUA) Caliterra (JV c/ grupo Errazuriz)
• Beringer Blass (EUA) Domaine Conte (JV c/ Santa Carolina)
• Franciscan Vineyards (EUA) Veramonte
• Odfjell (Norvège) Odfjell
• Sogrape (Portugal) Los Boldos
• Accolade Wines (Australia) Anakena
Fig. 26.3 Main joint-ventures and foreign investments in the Chilean wine cluster
(1979–2018). (Source: World Wine Data 2018)
mmorag@uchile.cl
500 A. Coelho and E. Montaigne
26.3.5 P
enetrating International Markets Through Free
Trade Agreements and Generic Promotion
26.4 P
erformances, Risks, and Resilience
in the Chilean Wine Cluster
Collective management of the wine cluster offers significant competitiveness
advantages. We can point out many indicators justifying the success of the
Chilean wine cluster: expansion of production potential, increasing market
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Cluster 501
shares in key export markets (the USA, Canada, the UK, Japan, Brazil, etc.),
international recognition (medals, green awards), attractiveness of the cluster
to foreign investors, financial performance of the wine companies, offering
quality wines at very competitive prices—particularly in the entry-level seg-
ments—and adaptability and innovation among industry firms.
In the past, grape plantings in Chile have been steady for many decades as
the legislation established on 1974 banned grape plantings and replanting.
Changes operated in the legislation in 1985 suppressed the barriers to new
plantings and extended the possibility to produce wines from table grapes
(González et al. 2014). In the following years, Chilean wine expanded consid-
erably the surfaces planted with Vitis vinifera grapes. Nowadays, the produc-
tion in the country remains highly dependent on the surfaces of Cabernet
Sauvignon (see Fig. 26.4).
The expansion of surfaces did not spread homogeneously. The main wine
regions remain Maule and O’Higgins, but on an attempt to diversify the sup-
ply of wines and adapt to climate change, the industry also expanded to new
Northern in Southern non-traditional wine regions but which provide a
potential to grow grapes adapted to the palates of international wine markets
(e.g. the production of Riesling and sparkling wines) (see Table 26.3).
The particular case of the Bío Bío region contrasts with the general trend in
Chile as the region shrank by 30.5% its grape surfaces between 2000 and
160000
Total surfaces
140000
Cabernet Sauvignon
120000
100000
80000
60000
40000
20000
0
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
Fig. 26.4 Evolution of wine grape plantings in Chile (ha) (1994–2014). (Source:
Elaborated by authors based on data from ODEPA)
mmorag@uchile.cl
502 A. Coelho and E. Montaigne
Table 26.3 Evolution of wine grape plantings in the main regions in Chile (2000–2014)
(ha)
Var. Var. Var.
2000 2005 2010 2014 00–05 10–14 00–14
Maule 45,050 49,335 45,850 53,496 9.5% 16.7% 18.7%
O’Higgins 29,041 32,553 38,517 47,382 12.1% 23.0% 63.2%
Metropolitana 9450 10,783 12,432 13,398 14.1% 7.8% 41.8%
Valparaiso 4782 5524 9050 10,162 15.5% 12.3% 112.5%
Bío Bío 13,744 13,970 8085 9568 1.6% 18.3% −30.4%
Coquimbo 1804 2197 2766 3383 21.8% 22.3% 87.5%
Other regions 60,630 67,307 79,557 87,469 11.0% 9.9% 44.3%
Total surfaces (ha) 103,876 114,445 122,641 137,582 10.2% 12.2% 32.4%
Source: SAG
Table 26.4 Evolution of grape variety plantings, wine production, and exports in Chile
(2000–2015)
Var. Var. Var.
2000 2005 2010 2015 00–05 10–15 00–15
Surfaces Vitis 103,876 114,448 116,831 135,582 10.2% 16.0% 30.5%
vinifera (ha)
Cabernet 35,967 40,441 38,426 44,176 12.4% 15.0% 22.8%
Sauvignon (ha)
Carmenère (ha) 4719 6849 9502 11,319 45.1% 19.1% 139.9%
País (ha) 15,179 14,909 5855 7653 −1.8% 30.7% −49.6%
Production 6419 7894 8844 12,867 23.0% 45.5% 100.5%
(million hl)
Wine exports 2.65 4.14 7.25 8.75 56.2% 20.7% 230.2%
(million hl)
Wine exports 0.569 0.872 1533 1826 53.3% 19.1% 220.9%
(billion $US)
Source: ODEPA, SAG
2014. This region concentrates the highest percentage of small grape produc-
ers owning less than 1 ha (accounting for 70% of all Chile) and producers face
considerable changes in competitiveness and bargaining power in the market
for grapes.
Grape producers also showed an increasing interest for Carmenère, a tradi-
tional Bordeaux red variety with a high potential to target international mar-
kets (+139.9%). At the opposite, the surfaces of traditional País variety were
cut but half (−49.5%) as it showed little interest for export markets. Therefore,
Chilean wine producers adapted their production potential to the interna-
tional wine demand (see Table 26.4).
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Cluster 503
In addition, the exports in volume and value—in line with the goals defined
in Strategic Plan 2020—had a strong increase (+230% in volume and +220%
in value). These indicators demonstrate how successful Chile was in penetrat-
ing international markets.
In the long run, firms look to increase the average price per case of wine
exported; however, wine exports remain concentrated in the price bracket US
$20–29.9/case (Fig. 26.5). Despite of an internationally attractive bulk wine
market, it does not seem to be a priority for the industry as the average prices
and margins in this market remain low. The bulk wine market is often an
adjustment factor to help the industry to reach market balances (production,
domestic consumption, stocks, volumes exported).
Based on studies on the perception of the actors, Lobos and Viviani (2010)
and González et al. (2014) identified the main sources of risks in the wine
cluster. Those sources include the exchange rate, wine prices, climate change,
and the variability on the profit rates. According to the above authors, small
vineyards attribute more importance to the following factors: wine prices,
climate change, yields (productivity), and food security risks. Small vineyards
attribute less importance to legal and environmental risks as well as the price
of grapes. The coverage of agricultural risks in Chile through insurance or
other derivatives is rare in the country.
Risk is included in the resilience scope (Bhamra et al. 2011). The concept
of resilience was first introduced in the literature by Holling (1973) and led to
an extensive literature (Coutu 2002; Hamel and Valikangas 2003; Bhamra
et al. 2011). We can define resilience as ‘the capacity to continuous recon-
struction’ (Hamel and Valikangas 2003). Sudden changes in the business
environment—turbulences and discontinuities—may impact considerably
the long-term performances of the Chilean wine cluster. Major disasters, such
600 25
Millon cases (12 bot. 750 cc)
500 20
400
Millon USD
15
300
10
200
100 5
0 0
Superior to 100 60 to 99.9 40 to 59.9 30 to 39.9 20 to 29.9 Lower than 20
Vol. 2014 Vol. 2015 Value 2014 Value 2015
Fig. 26.5 Exports of bottled wine from Chile per price bracket (US$/case) (2014–2015).
(Source: ODEPA)
mmorag@uchile.cl
504 A. Coelho and E. Montaigne
26.5 Conclusion
The Chilean wine cluster is an institutional arrangement that promotes com-
petitiveness and strengthens firms’ adaptability and resilience during wine and
economic crises. The Chilean model is unique and difficult to reproduce due
to conditions related to agro-export orientation, concentration of firms, and
public-private partnerships in the cluster. This model is similar to the New
Zealand wine cluster. Nevertheless, beyond the socioeconomic embeddedness
and the specialization in typical grape varieties (Sauvignon Blanc and Pinot
Noir), New Zealand has the highest world average prices for wines exported.
In recent years, Chile achieved significant progress in competitiveness.
Substantial improvements are still needed to ensure the sustainability of the
wine cluster in the long run (Lima 2015).
Efficiency and dynamic institutional arrangements are strongly influenced
by the national and regional political cycles. The financing of innovation and
R&D activities depends largely on the availability of funds provided by inter-
national sales and copper prices.
The asymmetry of power in the negotiations for the payment of wine grapes
or bulk wine frequently challenges small- and medium-sized producers.
Overproduction leads to market imbalances, national wine prices are subject
to high variability, and the domestic demand is unable to absorb the excess of
wines on the market. Those are some of the common challenges the wine
cluster should address in the future.
mmorag@uchile.cl
The Chilean Wine Cluster 505
References
Baritaux, V., M. Aubert, M. Remaud, and E. Montaigne. 2005. Matchmakers in
wine marketing channels: The case of French wine brokers. Agribusiness 22 (3,
Summer): 375–390.
Becattini, G. 1992. Le district marshallien: une notion socio-économique. In Les régions
qui gagnent, ed. G. Benko and A. Lipietz, 37–39. Paris: PUF.
Bell, S.J., P. Tracey, and J.B. Heide. 2009. The organization of regional clusters.
Academy of Management Review 34 (4): 623–642.
Bhamra, R., S. Dani, and K. Burnard. 2011. Resilience: The concept, a literature
review and future directions. International Journal of Production Research 49 (18):
5375–5393.
Castellaci, F. 2015. Institutional voids or organizational resilience? Business Groups,
Innovation, and Market Development in Latin America. World Development 70:
43–58.
Coelho, A., and J.L. Rastoin. 2004. Vers l’émergence d’un oligopole sur le marché
mondial du vin? In Bacchus 2005: enjeux, stratégies et pratiques dans la filière viti-
vinicole, ed. F. D’Hauteville, E. Montaigne, J.-P. Couderc, and H. Hannin. Paris:
Dunod/La Vigne.
Cogea. 2014. Study on the Competitiveness of European Wines. Luxembourg:
Publications Office of the European Union.
Coutu, L.D. 2002. How resilience works. Harvard Business Review 80 (5): 46–55.
Farinelli, F. 2012. Natural resources, innovation and export growth: The wine industry
in Chile and Argentina. Maastricht: Maastricht University.
Fensterseifer, J.E., and J.-L. Rastoin. 2013. Cluster resources and competitive advan-
tage: A typology of potentially strategic cluster advantages. International Journal of
Wine Business Research 25 (4): 1751–1062.
Giuliani, E., and M. Bell. 2005. The micro-determinants of meso-level learning and
innovation. Research Policy 34: 47–68.
González, M.M., G.L. Andrade, and B.S. Morales. 2014. El gran crecimiento de la
industrial del vino chilena. In La Economía del Vino en España y en El Mundo,
Capitulo 17, ed. R.C. Lopez and S. Castillo-Valero, 581–623. Cajamar.
Hamel, G., and L. Valikangas. 2003. The quest for resilience. Harvard Business Review
81 (9): 52–63.
Hennicke, L. 2015. Chile wine production 2015, Gain report, no CI 1502, USDA
Foreign Agricultural Service, Santiago de Chile, March.
Holling, C.S. 1973. Resilience and stability of ecological systems. Annual Review of
Ecology and Systematics 4 (1): 1–23.
Lima, J.L. 2015. Estudio de caracterización de la cadena de producción y comercial-
ización de la agroindustria vitivinícola: estructura, agentes y prácticas, Oficina de
Estudios y Políticas Agrarias (ODEPA). Santiago de Chile: Ministerio de Agricultura.
Lobos, G., and J.-L. Viviani. 2010. Description des perceptions des sources de risque
des producteurs vitivinicoles. Economie Rurale 316: 48–61.
mmorag@uchile.cl
506 A. Coelho and E. Montaigne
Marshall, A. 1920. Principles of economics. 8th ed. London: Macmillan (First edition,
1890).
McDermott, G.A. 2007. The politics of institutional renovation and economic
upgrading: Recombining the vines than bind in Argentina. Politics and Society 35
(1): 103–143.
McDermott, G.A., R.A. Corredoira, and G. Kruse. 2009. Public-private institutions
as catalysts of upgrading in emerging markets. Academy of Management Journal 52
(6): 1270–1296.
Montaigne, E., and A. Coelho. 2012. Structure of the producing side of the wine
industry: Firm typologies, networks of firms, and clusters. Wine Economics and
Policy 1: 41–53.
Nalebuff, B., and A. Brandenburger. 1996. La Co-opétition, une révolution dans la
manière de jouer concurrence et coopération. Paris: Village Mondial.
Oficina de Estudios y Políticas Agrarias (ODEPA). 2015. Actualización de la
Comercialización de Plantas Frutales, Vides y Plantines de Hortalizas en Chile,
Ministerio de Agricultura, Asociación Gremial de Viveros de Chile, Santiago de
Chile, Diciembre.
Porter, M. 1998. Clusters and the new economics of competition. Harvard Business
Review 76 (6): 77–90.
Porter, M.E., and G.C. Bond. 1999. The California Wine Cluster, Harvard Business
School Case 799–124, June 1999 (Revised February 2013).
Santelices, B., F. Lund, T. Cooper, and J.A. Asenjo, eds. 2013. Innovacion basada en
conocimiento científico. Santiago de Chile: Academia Chilena de Ciencias.
Teece, D.J. 2010. Forward integration and innovation: Transaction costs and beyond.
Journal of Retailing 86 (3): 277–283.
Torres, J.P., J.B. Salvagno, and M. Willington. 2008. Joint-ventures y especializacion
productive en la industria del vino en Chile. Estudios Publicos 109: 225–266.
Trejo-Pech, C., R. Arellano-Sada, A.M. Coelho, and R.N. Weldon. 2012. Is the Baja
California, Mexico, wine industry a cluster? American Journal of Agricultural
Economics 94 (2): 569–575.
Visser, E.-J., and P. de Langen. 2006. The importance and quality of governance in
the Chilean wine industry. GeoJournal 65: 177–197.
mmorag@uchile.cl
27
Producing and Consuming Locally:
Switzerland as a Local Market
Philippe Masset and Jean-Philippe Weisskopf
27.1 Introduction
To date the wine economics literature has almost completely neglected
Switzerland and its wines, unlike its neighboring countries France, Italy and
Germany, which have been subject to numerous research papers. There are
several reasons which may justify this lack of interest in Swiss wines.
Switzerland is a small player on the global wine market as it ranks only 24th
in terms of volumes produced (Wine Institute 2014b). Moreover, given its
high consumption of wine per capita (about 40 liters per year and per inhabit-
ant, Wine Institute 2014a), the local production is not sufficient to satisfy the
demand. Thus, exports of Swiss wines are negligible (less than 1%, Bundesamt
für Landwirtschaft 2015). As a consequence, the reputation and visibility of
Swiss wines outside the country itself remain very limited.
Switzerland, nevertheless, displays specificities that warrant a deeper analy-
sis. First, the structure of the Swiss wine industry and the business models
adopted by most wine producers are particular. A large number of small and
family-run wineries, which predominantly sell their wines directly to final
customers, coexist with a few cooperatives and large wineries, which sell most
of their wines through retailers. Second, the production conditions are dis-
tinctive due to both the geography of the country and its high labor costs.
Switzerland’s vineyards spread along Alpine valleys, rivers and lakes and tend
mmorag@uchile.cl
508 P. Masset and J.-P. Weisskopf
Switzerland has a long history of wine growing. Vine plants dating back to the
Iron Age (around 800 BC) have been found in Valais. Under the Roman
1
Switzerland hosts more than 50 indigenous grapes in addition to international varieties.
2
Philippe Bovet, quoted in Mathez de Senger (2015).
3
José Vouillamoz, quoted in Laird (2013).
mmorag@uchile.cl
Producing and Consuming Locally: Switzerland as a Local Market 509
Empire, the production of wine rapidly increased. During the Middle Ages,
abbeys and monks further fostered the production of wine in Switzerland,
notably in the regions of Neuchâtel (Carthusian monastery of La Lance),
Vaud (Abbeys of Aucrêt and Montheron in the Lavaux) and Valais (Abbey of
Saint Maurice, Monastery of Notre-Dame de Géronde). At that time, wine
was mostly produced to satisfy one’s own needs and not for sale. The situation
evolved and, following the 1847 Sonderbund War, entrepreneurs took over
wine production from the monks and turned it into a flourishing business.4
In 1850, vineyards covered 35,000 hectares (ha), more than twice today’s
surface (Swiss Wine 2015). The decline in acreages after 1850 can be attrib-
uted to natural, demographic and economic factors. The natural factor takes
the shape of a deadly foe for vines, the phylloxera. It was first identified in
1854 in New York State and rapidly proliferated. By 1861, it had reached
Europe. In Switzerland, the arrival of the destructive insect is reported a few
years later (Forel 1874). Despite desperate actions from Swiss authorities, it
eventually destroyed much of the existing vineyards (Dumartheray 2012).
During the first half of the twentieth century, the acreages devoted to vines
continued their decline and never recovered from the phylloxera outbreak.
Various demographic and economic factors are partially responsible for
explaining this stagnation (Virieux 1947). The rapid urbanization of
Switzerland and the small surface of the Swiss Plateau (which is both the most
densely inhabited region in Switzerland and also where the vast majority of
the vineyards are located) limit the space available for wine growing.
Insufficient profitability and increased competition from foreign wines put
additional pressure on the Swiss wine industry. Another factor that contrib-
uted to the sluggishness of the Swiss wine sector relates to old succession laws,
which favored the parceling of land. As most wineries in Switzerland are
family-owned, the enforcement of this law has made it difficult for wine pro-
ducers to ensure the financial viability of their operations over the long term.
This law also provides some justification for the relatively small size of winer-
ies in Switzerland. According to Emery (2001), the 5259 ha of wine growing
in Valais are represented by 119,500 parcels owned by about 23,000 propri-
etors. More than half of these proprietors cultivate wine on less than 1000
square meters and only 250 own more than 2 ha.
More recently, the trend of reducing wine-growing areas has not only
receded but has even started to reverse with a timid increase of 4% between
the mid-1980s and 2014. The quantity of wine produced has nevertheless
Zufferey (2010).
4
mmorag@uchile.cl
510 P. Masset and J.-P. Weisskopf
decreased by about one third over the same period (Bundesamt für
Landwirtschaft 2015). This lower productivity per hectare reflects a shift from
a mostly quantity-oriented production toward a more qualitative approach.
At the same time, the decline in productivity also induced an increased
demand for foreign wines, which has led to a more competitive environment.
The progressive liberalization of wine imports has accentuated this phenom-
enon. The past decades have been characterized by a desire by more and more
Swiss producers to boost the quality of their wines. This trend finds its origin
in Valais, the largest wine-producing region in Switzerland, but has since
spread over the whole country. In Valais, Louis Imhof, Simon Maye and
Charles Caloz have played an important role in this evolution. In 1966, they
founded the Saint Théodule Guild, whose primary objective was to foster the
production of high-quality wines in Valais.5 Since 1966, the Guild has seen a
dramatic increase in size, with more and more producers willing to become
members, thereby reflecting their eagerness to provide the market with wines
of high quality. Producers from other parts of the country have also started to
recognize the potential offered by their terroir and some of them (e.g. Daniel
and Martha Gantenbein, Luigi Zanini, Jean-Michel Novelle) have acquired a
strong reputation, not only in Switzerland but also on foreign markets.6
For instance, Daniel and Martha Gantenbein export about two thirds of their production and have
6
made it into Fallstaff’s list of the 100 best wines in the world.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Producing and Consuming Locally: Switzerland as a Local Market 511
mmorag@uchile.cl
512 P. Masset and J.-P. Weisskopf
The Alps and differences in altitudes, soil composition, exposures and hygrom-
etry result in a variety of terroirs and, thus, a surprisingly large number of
wine types can be encountered in Switzerland.
Swiss wine is produced on 14,883 ha of vineyards, mainly located in the
west and in the south of Switzerland. Switzerland is further subdivided into
six wine-growing regions. The canton of Valais (5000 ha) represents the larg-
est wine-growing surface followed by Vaud (3800 ha), the German-speaking
part of Switzerland (2600 ha), Geneva (1400 ha), Ticino (1100 ha) and the
three-lake region (950 ha).7 Some “terroirs” benefit from an especially strong
reputation. This is the case for the canton of Vaud whose Chasselas from
Calamin or Dézaley are well-known. In Valais, the villages of Fully and
Chamoson are well-known for their Petite Arvine and Syrah, respectively. The
cantons of Graubünden and Ticino are recognized for the quality of their
Pinot Noir and Merlot, respectively.
Red wine varieties account for 58% of the total surface and white varieties
for the remaining 42%, with a mixture of international and local varieties,
some of which have been created by the Swiss oenological research center. The
most common international grape varieties include Cabernet Franc, Cabernet
Sauvignon, Gamay, Merlot, Pinot Noir and Syrah for red, and Chardonnay,
Marsanne, Müller-Thurgau, Pinot Gris and Sauvignon Blanc for white. The
country is also home to a variety of “specialties”, that is, indigenous varieties
such as Carminoir, Cornalin, Diolinoir, Gamaret, Garanoir and Humagne
Rouge for red, and Amigne, Chasselas, Humagne Blanche, Païen, Petite
Arvine and Johannisberg for white. Over the past two decades, wines pro-
duced from these varieties have seen their market share increase. These variet-
ies possess the potential to produce wines of great interest but generally require
a lot of attention and are production-wise not always as efficient as interna-
tional varietals.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Producing and Consuming Locally: Switzerland as a Local Market 513
39.2% and 60.8%, respectively, for 2013. Switzerland thus has to resort to
wine imports (1.85 million hl) and is only able to export a marginal fraction
of its production (17,000 hl).
Consumers primarily buy wine in supermarkets, followed by direct pur-
chases from producers and specialty shops. While the latter two remain at a
relatively constant market share, supermarkets have managed to increase their
market share gradually and this distribution channel now represents 42% of
total sales.8 However, wines sold at supermarkets come mostly from abroad or
from large domestic wine producers. Smaller or more renowned producers
tend to sell their production directly to customers, often based on a reserva-
tion system, with a limited quantity that each customer may purchase. In this
section, we first examine the situation of foreign wines in Switzerland and
then move to the analysis of the market for local wines.
27.3.1 S
pecificities of the Market for Foreign Wines
in Switzerland
mmorag@uchile.cl
514 P. Masset and J.-P. Weisskopf
27.3.2 S
pecificities of the Market for Local Wines
in Switzerland
This number probably underestimates the true average price as it is solely based on prices from super-
9
mmorag@uchile.cl
Producing and Consuming Locally: Switzerland as a Local Market 515
a verage hides a contrasting reality: while most wine estates can be considered
as rather small, it is a few larger wineries that retain a substantial market share.
For instance, the Provins cooperative accounts for close to one fourth of the
overall production in Valais (Emery 2001).
The market structure appears to be adapted to the specificities of Swiss
wines. The primary market is relatively homogenous with most small produc-
ers selling the majority of their wines directly to consumers. More popular,
smaller-quantity wines are predominantly sold directly to consumers through
a reservation system which is similar in spirit to the allocation system in
Burgundy. This leads to a situation in which customers remain loyal to wine-
makers. This phenomenon is further enforced by producers who reward loy-
alty in various ways (e.g. by increasing allocations on specific wines or outright
refusing to give the most sought-after wines to customers just ordering these).
Larger producers tend to sell a major part of their harvest through supermar-
kets or specialized wine shops. The distribution is, however, more complex as
larger producers tend to cover the full spectrum of quality levels. They sell
entry-level wines through dedicated brands via hard discounters or supermar-
kets and turn toward a more direct distribution to consumers for high-end
wines (Thomas 2014). On the secondary market, Swiss wines are nearly non-
existent as in general wines are bought to drink and not to sell at a later
period.
Another important attribute of Swiss wines is related to its price. As men-
tioned, Swiss wine is perceived as expensive. This can mostly be attributed to
high production costs and more specifically high labor costs. With minimum
wages starting at around 20 CHF per hour, it is very difficult to produce
cheap wine. This high labor cost is accompanied by legal and geographical
constraints of the vineyards. Due to complex succession laws, parcels are
divided and thus remain very small. Moreover, parcels may often be quite
dispersed and build on hillsides as terraces. This leads to a loss of time when
moving from one parcel to another and makes the use of mechanical equip-
ment nearly impossible. The repair and construction of stone walls needed to
maintain the soils on hillsides further increases costs. According to Emery
(2001), this leads to a production cost of 35,000–55,000 CHF per hectare.
The high purchase power of customers, however, allows vintners to sell their
wines at prices which more or less cover their costs. According to a recent
survey, a majority of customers are ready to spend on average 10–20 CHF for
a bottle of wine (M.I.S. Trend 2013). Interestingly, this amount is quite simi-
lar to the average price at which Swiss producers sell their wines and corre-
sponds to a classic pricing strategy in a competitive market in which marginal
costs are relatively equal to selling prices.
mmorag@uchile.cl
516 P. Masset and J.-P. Weisskopf
Even though prices have largely remained stable in nominal terms and
cover production costs, their positioning compared to foreign wines has var-
ied substantially over the last five years. The 40% appreciation of the Swiss
franc toward the euro has made local wines look relatively more expensive
when compared to foreign wines. At the same time, prices from nearby wine-
producing regions (Burgundy, Piedmont, Rhône and Bordeaux) have strongly
increased over the last decade. These two phenomena result in a market struc-
ture in which Swiss entry-level wines look extremely expensive when com-
pared to their foreign counterparts. On the other hand, prices of the best
Swiss wines have become increasingly attractive to customers as they offer
good quality at a very competitive price when compared to good French or
Italian wines. Thus “as Swiss wineries are less competitive compared to foreign
ones with respect to price levels and topographical conditions, they are forced
by the market to differentiate themselves by creating better value for custom-
ers” (Fueglistaller et al. 2014). This focus and evolution from quantity to
quality allows Swiss wines to enjoy a relatively good level of notoriety within
the country. In fact, only French and Italian wines are better known than local
ones by Swiss wine consumers (M.I.S. Trend 2013). In general, Swiss custom-
ers have a good opinion of “their” wines, with only 5% of people thinking
that foreign wines are of better quality, while 46% strongly disagree with this
statement (M.I.S. Trend 2013).
27.4 B
usiness Models in Switzerland and Their
Respective Performance
The business model applied by Swiss wineries is to a large extent influenced by
two constraints. On the one hand, the historical and geographical context
implies that most wine estates are forced to be of small size. On the other
hand, the strong presence of foreign wines on the market puts pressure on
wine producers and influences their strategies. Generally, two business models
are encountered in Switzerland: small/family wineries which sell most of their
production directly to final consumers and cooperatives/larger wineries which
sell to final consumers mainly through supermarkets and specialty shops. In
the following paragraphs, we present four small examples illustrating different
cases which are representative of the Swiss wine business.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Producing and Consuming Locally: Switzerland as a Local Market 517
40,000 bottles per vintage (Mémoire des Vins Suisses 2015b). He has special-
ized in varieties that are typical for his region and has achieved a considerable
reputation for his Cornalin. He has been following a traditional approach to
wine-making and reaches for the highest quality standards. His wife takes care
of the distribution and welcomes clients picking up their wines at the winery,
which is the norm. The couple is now helped by their daughter and employs
additional personnel for the harvest only. Most clients go to the winery to
collect their wine order and take the opportunity to have a discussion with
one of the three family members to learn more about the wines they purchase
and wine-making in general. Due to his reputation and small-scale produc-
tion, about half of the ten varieties Denis Mercier has on offer are available in
limited quantities only. Prices have somewhat increased with inflation through
time but remain at a very reasonable level considering the quality and work
put into its production. This approach is representative of many small, suc-
cessful Swiss wineries. Family businesses with a direct distribution channel
and warm welcome, rather stable prices through time and a limitation of
quantities, ensure that loyal customers receive at least one bottle of their
desired wine.
Domaine Louis Bovard Louis-Philippe Bovard took over the family domain
in 10th generation in 1983. He cultivates 16 ha and produces around 180,000
bottles annually (Mémoire des Vins Suisses 2015c). His wines are distributed
either directly to visiting consumers or through specialty shops throughout
Switzerland. This is possible due to the segmentation of his wine range which
goes from cheaper entry-level wines to more expensive and prestigious cuvées.
His winery is located in the middle of the Lavaux (Vaud), which is now a
UNESCO World Heritage site and famous for its Chasselas cultivated on
ancient stone terraces. Mr. Bovard is known for his curiosity and innovative
spirit. This has led him to try out different international varieties next to the
classic Chasselas and Pinot Noir grapes of the region. He can build on his
ownership of one of the best known appellations of Switzerland (Dézaley
Grand Cru) which grants him immediate recognition on the Swiss market.
He, furthermore, was mentioned favorably after a recent visit by Stephan
Reinhardt of TWA which granted him visibility at home and abroad (Moginier
2015). Even before this recent acclaim and for the last 15 years, Mr. Bovard
has exported some of his wines, following the trend set by German and
Austrian wineries. He also took part in recent trips to Japan to reinforce his
position there, hoping to sell at least 5000 bottles on this market (Buss 2013).
This example illustrates a willingness to increase exports through more
mmorag@uchile.cl
518 P. Masset and J.-P. Weisskopf
Provins Provins has been the cooperative of the Valais region since 1930. Its
4400 members cultivate around 1100 ha and produce 13–15 million bottles
a year, which corresponds to 23% of the harvest in Valais or 10% of the har-
vest in Switzerland as a whole (Mémoire des Vins Suisses 2015a). Their mem-
bers are compensated per square meter, not kilo, to encourage cooperators to
strive for quality versus quantity. A priori, it may seem as if such a large com-
pany may not be able to produce high-quality wines; however, quite the
opposite is true. Provins has decided to strongly segment their market and
diversify into different lines according to quality and customer. They intro-
duced an entry-level line of wines in supermarkets and for hard discounters at
affordable prices. They further created a “Maitre de Chais” line of wines which
are labeled as premium wines and consist only of the best grapes of excep-
tional parcels. These wines can also be found in supermarkets, specialty shops
and Provins shops and go for about 75% more than the entry-level line.
Finally, it distributes a “Crus des Domaines” line which fetches double the
price of the “Maitre de Chais” line and aims to compete with the world’s top
wines (Provins 2015). In 2014, Provins introduced an iconic wine, named
“Electus” (sold at 190 CHF), to compete with the best wines in the world. In
a tasting by Jancis Robinson in 2014, it reached a good position when opposed
to very good wines from France and Italy (Guertchakoff 2014). This consti-
tutes one of the first attempts at competing at a high price and quality level
with neighboring wine-growing regions. The election of Provins as winemaker
of the year 2013 and of its oenologist Miss Gay in 2008 further shows the
commitment to follow, even as a cooperative, a qualitative path.
Obrist Obrist has taken a different form of expansion and service. This com-
pany started as a wine merchant in Vevey (Vaud) in 1854 but soon under-
stood that having its own vineyards could be beneficial. It therefore started
buying some up in 1896. Since the 1960s, it collaborates with a winery in
Valais to be able to source wines from that region and sell them in their shops.
Nowadays, Obrist is one of the largest wine merchants and producers in
Switzerland with parcels ranging from Lavaux to Valais and covering a total of
55 ha. It sells its wines to restaurants, through specialty shops, its own shops
mmorag@uchile.cl
Producing and Consuming Locally: Switzerland as a Local Market 519
27.5 Conclusion
The wine market in Switzerland is saturated. Local winemakers face several
internal constraints (conditions and costs of production) and external chal-
lenges (proximity to the world’s most reputed wine-growing areas, strong
competition from foreign wines). Consequently Swiss winemakers have no
choice but to focus on quality and rely on a differentiation strategy. There is
no place for mediocrity and no excuse for producing wines of bad quality. In
this context, small wineries seem well armed. But it is crucial for Swiss wines
to improve on their visibility and notoriety, not only to reach foreign markets
but also to remain successful on their own local market. The following eight
points summarize this situation:
mmorag@uchile.cl
520 P. Masset and J.-P. Weisskopf
and the difficulty in growing some of them (e.g. such as Cornalin) justify
higher prices.
4. Small is beautiful: Concentrating on small wineries is a direct response to
growth problems which emanate from two distinct sources. First, high
labor costs impede growth. Up to a certain size, the reliance on cheap (or
free) labor from family members allows winemakers to reduce costs. Many
have understood that growing larger and having to employ one or two
workers may lead to financial difficulties. Second, the difficult succession
laws and high land costs render the purchase of additional parcels compli-
cated. It therefore appears that having small family wineries is the most
efficient way to contain costs.
5. No place for mediocrity: Many producers are having a difficult time since
the Swiss franc surged against the euro. As a consequence, in 2012, the
Swiss Parliament decided to declassify ten million liters of AOC wines to
simple table wines (Herminjard 2013). These difficult times have further
been reinforced by a drop in alcohol consumption on the national market.
As prices of Swiss wines are relatively inelastic due to costs and the desire
to keep loyal customers, a response to these two phenomena has been dif-
ficult. It thus appears that wines of lesser quality or which do not have a
distinctive positioning have difficulties being sold.
6. No excuse for bad quality: The geographical and geological particularities
of Switzerland offer good to excellent conditions for wine growing. Like
some of its closest neighbors (Burgundy and Alsace in France, Mosel and
Nahe in Germany), Switzerland used to have a relatively cold climate. This
made it difficult to ensure a good and qualitatively homogeneous crop
from one vintage to another. Global warming has changed this situation
and has transformed a former weakness into strength. Since the mid-
1990s, very few years have suffered from bad weather, while a number of
vintages have benefited from outstanding conditions (1995, 2000, 2005,
2009, 2010, 2013 in some parts of the country, 2015).
7. Visibility and notoriety: The difficulty in sourcing many wines has led to
a lack of visibility as many are very difficult to obtain or taste. This low
visibility is reinforced by a variety of factors. A unique and clear AOC
system is yet to be developed. Moreover, there is currently a quasi-absence
of wine experts on the market. Hopefully, the situation has started to
change. Vaud and Valais, the two leading cantons in terms of quantity
produced, are now working on classification systems. The recent advent of
expert wine tastings and winery rankings shows that Swiss wines have
evolved qualitatively and are now in a comparable position to good-quality
foreign wines. Especially the favorable mention of the Chasselas grape and
mmorag@uchile.cl
Producing and Consuming Locally: Switzerland as a Local Market 521
Overall, it appears that the idea of producing and consuming locally has
worked for Swiss winemakers. However, the positive developments thus far
should continue to evolve in the future for producers to remain competitive
and profitable.
References
Bundesamt für Landwirtschaft (BLW). 2015. Das Weinjahr 2014 Weinwirtschaftliche
Statistik. Bern: Schweizerische Eidgenossenschaft.
Bundesrat. 2012. Contingents d’importation de vins. Retrieved October 8, 2015, from
http://www.parlament.ch/d/suche/Seiten/geschaefte.aspx?gesch_id=20123482
Buss, P.-E. 2013. L’avenir des vins suisses se joue à l’étranger. Le Quotidien Jurassien,
September 14: 38.
Catry, B. 2009. Viti 2015 – stratégie vitivinicole valaisanne à l’horizon 2015. Lausanne:
Université de Lausanne.
Dumartheray, P. 2012. 1886: très vilain phylloxéra. 24 heures, June 28. Retrieved
from 24 heures: http://www.24heures.ch/vaud-regions/1886-tres-vilain-phyllox-
era/story/12015090
Emery, S. 2001. Enquête sur l’avenir de la viticulture dans les régions alpines et. Sion:
Etat du Valais.
Feuille d’Avis du Valais. 1966. Fondation de la Confrérie des Vignerons. Feuille d’Avis
du Valais, May 9: 1.
Forel, F.-A. 1874. Le phylloxera vastatrix dans la Suisse occidentale jusqu’au 31
Décembre 4874. Bulletin de la Société Vaudoise des Sciences Naturelles 13 (74):
661–683.
FranceAgriMer. 2012. Achats de vins tranquilles par les ménages français pour leur con-
sommation à domicile. Paris: FranceAgriMer.
David Schildknecht, a journalist at TWA, has put four Swiss vintners in his best of 2012 list and, in
10
2015, Stephan Reinhardt, another journalist of the TWA team, wrote two articles fully devoted to Swiss
Chasselas and Pinot Noir, with many scores close to or larger than 90.
mmorag@uchile.cl
522 P. Masset and J.-P. Weisskopf
Fueglistaller, U., A. Fust, D. Burger, J. Varonier, and F. Welter. 2014. How SMEs
differentiate from others in the Swiss wine market with respect to their market
orientation and entrepreneurial orientation. In Rencontres de St.-Gall, 1–21. St.
Gallen: KMU-HSG.
Guertchakoff, S. 2014. L’Electus, ce vin ambitieux qui secoue le vignoble suisse.
Bilan, November 3.
Herminjard, P. 2013. L’économie vitivinicole suisse peine à maintenir ses parts de
marché. Patrons (7–8), p. 7.
Laird, M. 2013. Les vins suisses gagnent une reconnaissance mondiale. April 4. Retrieved
from swissinfo.ch: http://www.swissinfo.ch/fre/economie/dans-le%2D%2Dwine-
advocate%2D%2Dde-robert-parker_les-vins-suisses-gagnent-une-reconnais-
sance-mondiale/35375216
M.I.S. Trend. 2013. Étude sur le marché du vin en Suisse 2013: notoriété, habitudes de
consommation et d’achat, image. Swiss Wine Promotion.
Mathez de Senger, C. 2015. Quelles sont les conséquences du franc fort pour les vins
suisses? Bilan, January 28.
Mémoire des Vins Suisses. 2015a. Producteurs Valais. Retrieved October 8, 2015,
from http://www.mdvs.ch/fr/producteurs/valais/provins.html
———. 2015b. Producteurs Valais. Retrieved October 8, 2015, from http://www.
mdvs.ch/fr/producteurs/valais/anne-catherine-denis-mercier.html
———. 2015c. Producteurs Vaud. Retrieved October 8, 2015, from http://www.
mdvs.ch/fr/producteurs/vaud/domaine-louis-bovard.html
Moginier, D. 2015. L’envoyé de Parker a apprécié les chasselas. 24 heures, March 3.
Obrist. 2015. Notre histoire. Retrieved October 8, 2015, from https://www.obrist.ch/fr
Observatoire des vins en grande distribution en Suisse. 2015. Situation au 31 mars
2015. Sion: Etat du Valais.
Provins. 2015. Retrieved October 8, 2015, from http://www.provins.ch/fr/index.php
Swiss Wine. 2015. Swiss wine history. Consulté le September 15, 2015, sur http://
www.swisswine.ch/: http://www.swisswine.ch/en/wine-tourism/swiss-wine-his-
tory
Swiss Wine Promotion. 2014. Key figures. Retrieved October 8, 2015, from http://
www.swisswine.ch/en/vineyard/the-figures-of-the-swiss-wine
Thomas, P. 2014. Vins suisses: les sept questions qui fâchent. L’Hebdo, April 12:
12–16.
Virieux, R. 1947. De l’économie viticole en Suisse. Revue économique et sociale: bul-
letin de la Société d’Etudes 5 (4): 264–271.
Wine Institute. 2014a. Per capita wine consumption by country. Retrieved September
3, 2015, from Wine Institute: http://www.wineinstitute.org/resources/statistics
———. 2014b. World wine production by country. Retrieved September 3, 2015,
from Wine Institute: http://www.wineinstitute.org/resources/statistics
Zufferey, A.-D. 2010. Histoire de la vigne et du vin en Valais: Des origines à nos jours.
Sierre: Musée valaisan de la Vigne et du Vin.
mmorag@uchile.cl
28
Conclusion: What’s Next?
Adeline Alonso Ugaglia, Jean-Marie Cardebat,
and Alessandro Corsi
This book offered a broad overview of the different business models in the
wine industry worldwide. It showed the diversity of this highly fragmented
and extremely diverse sector. Above all, the different chapters showed that
there is no dominant model and no guarantee of success at national scale in
whatever we are talking about Old, New or New World wine countries. In
particular, this book refutes the idea, however widespread in the Old World,
that the model of the large, vertically integrated industries relying on one or
more strong brands sold internationally would be the unique way for success
in wine-producing countries. Different models coexist at national and inter-
national levels and they are constantly evolving according to the challenges
they already face. Many chapters showed that the actors operating in the wine
industries as the wine industries themselves already adapt their strategies.
Whether the actors within a particular industry or the wine industries grouped
A. Alonso Ugaglia (*)
Bordeaux Sciences Agro, University of Bordeaux, Gradignan, France
e-mail: adeline.ugaglia@agro-bordeaux.fr
J.-M. Cardebat
University of Bordeaux, Pessac, France
INSEEC Bordeaux, Bordeaux, France
e-mail: jean-marie.cardebat@u-bordeaux.fr
A. Corsi
University of Turin, Turin, Italy
e-mail: alessandro.corsi@unito.it
mmorag@uchile.cl
524 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
–– the production of grapes and wine, in a context of climate change for most
of the major producing countries;
–– international wine trade, against the backdrop of possible trade wars and of
de-globalization;
–– the new geography and the new sociology of wine consumption that are
beginning to upset demand;
–– new ways to sell wine and communicate to reach the new consumers.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Conclusion: What’s Next? 525
–– First, the reduction of wine supply in certain regions facing climate change.
In the latter case, the Old World (mainly France, Italy and Spain), the other
countries of Southern Europe, but also Australia, Argentina, South Africa or
California (United States) could appear as the future big losers of global
warming. In addition to global warming, the European countries are particu-
larly subject to extreme events such as late frost or hail storm as shown in
particular by the 2017 vintage in the Bordeaux wine region. The evolution of
viticultural techniques can limit these negative evolutions, for example,
through the emergence of resistant grape varieties to water stress to reduce the
impact of the high temperatures but also to diseases as powdery and downy
mildew. The costs of these techniques, together with the needed organiza-
tional changes, the risk aversion of the winegrowers and their willingness to
change, could then be decisive. As to the consequences of climate change in
traditionally producing areas, a possible adaptation is the change in the vari-
ety mix. Grape varieties traditionally produced in each area of the Old World
are the result of a secular selection of the best fit to the particular local natural
(soil and weather) conditions. There is a wide dispersion in the optimal
weather conditions for the different varieties (Ashenfelter and Storchmann
2016); hence, a rational adaptation strategy could be changing the varieties
choosing the best fit to the new conditions. Nevertheless, such a path does not
go without difficulties. Apart from the needed investments, the main prob-
lems could arise from two sides. One is the difficulty in changing the institu-
tional setting of the regulations concerning appellation wines. For instance, in
Italy and France, many Protected Designation of Origin (PDO) regulations
dictate the varieties that can be used or not according to the area and the type
of wine. Even though regulations can obviously be changed, some producers
may be reluctant to do so, and conflicts on this issue can arise within the com-
munity. A second problem might be the consumers’ acceptance of a change
in taste of traditional wines and, more generally, in the characteristics they
associate with those particular wines. Nevertheless, also consumers’ tastes and
preferences may change, either because of the different availability of wines or
because of simply following new fashion trends. The changing preferences of
English consumers for different wines across time (Ludington 2018) are an
example of such a change. The evolution of wine production since the 1960s
in the Bordeaux wine region from white to red following the evolution of
consumers’ taste is a second one.
mmorag@uchile.cl
526 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Conclusion: What’s Next? 527
mmorag@uchile.cl
528 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
between different beverages (Holmes and Anderson 2017) and would require
a huge change in many countries’ marketing outlets. Just to give an example,
the share of exports over the Italian production, which was around 5 percent
in 1950, is now around 50 percent (Corsi et al. 2018). A strong reconversion
toward domestic consumption is hardly conceivable. But an increase in the
competitive pressure in the international markets is easily predictable,
because most of the changes induced by the changing trade flows will pre-
sumably take the form of trade-diversion effects rather than of a direct sub-
stitution of domestic production for imports.
At micro level, these trends could have different impacts on the different
operators of the chains, depending on the structure of the wine sector in each
country and on the strength of the changes they could have to face. The dis-
tribution of the gains and of the losses from climate change as well as from
trade shrinking will be linked to the organization of the industrial chain and
on the market power of the operators. The more concentrated the wine pro-
cessing, the more it has some market power vis-à-vis the pure grape growers
and hence the possibility to pass the negative effects to them. This is neverthe-
less less obvious when wine cooperatives are important players in the wine
processing. Wine estates producing grapes and wine are more common in the
Old wine countries and on the higher-quality segment. As such, they will suf-
fer more the consequences of climate change (that will affect quality) and less
those of the trade reduction, as compared to the other operators (because of
the lower price elasticity of these wines).
mmorag@uchile.cl
Conclusion: What’s Next? 529
in the form of bottles of wine is both a new way of financing and, perhaps
above all, a new form of selling (eventually, since it is the bottles of future
vintages that are sold). It is a way to bring new consumers to the product of a
specific estate. In addition, we look at community management as being able
to become an essential communication tool for building such a community of
customers, even more than other forms of communication. It is in this con-
text that we can imagine a gradual decline in the number of sales via conven-
tional distribution channels compared to direct sales, interrogating once again
the organization of the wine industries and the relative power that some actors
have. The rise of an expanded wine tourism offer will also go into this
direction.
These types of sales closer to the consumer (direct sales) should be in line
with the evolution of sociology of wine consumers. From a rather old,
European, masculine, not interested in social medias and high-income con-
sumer, the typical wine consumer is becoming (and it will be even more true
tomorrow) younger, international (American and Asian in particular), more
feminine and more connected (Cardebat 2017). Once again, it appears that
social networks and the exchange of information between consumers on the
Internet concerning the quality of wines are likely to become increasingly
important. The notion of community will be all the more affirmed, giving
more importance to the new opinion-makers such as “the wine community”
and the other consumers, much more than the traditional opinion-makers
like newspapers, guides or famous experts. The notion of community does not
necessarily refer to purely local customers in geographic terms but to custom-
ers sharing common values that wine conveys (typical characteristics, societal
and environmental commitments, for landscape preservation or social pur-
poses, etc.). Of course, these trends are not at the same stage everywhere in the
world, much depending on the tradition of drinking wine and on the country
status according to wine production, since the tradition of drinking local
wines is deeply rooted in Old wine countries and can help in facilitating the
creation of wine communities. Though, customers can now be everywhere in
the world, even if a rise in the obstacles to exports can be anticipated. We are
not describing here the end of exports, but an evolution in the way of doing
business at the international level. If exports become more costly, operators
will have to think about how to reach foreign consumers, especially new con-
sumers from New wine countries. Two strategies emerge. The first one is
related to product differentiation: building a strong brand and creating a
strong community that will make consumers willing to pay more for a p roduct
that represents a strong added value for them. The second strategy is about the
“tariff jumping”. If there are barriers to trade, then the players must produce
mmorag@uchile.cl
530 A. Alonso Ugaglia et al.
closer to consumers, as Japanese car companies did in the United States in the
1980s. Absurd as it may seem to some experts for which a wine is attached to
a terroir, this strategy can pay off for generic wines, produced by leading
brands used to using grapes from different terroirs to produce their wines.
This model will be similar to that of the big brewers who produce their beer
locally in the United States, for example (local and craft breweries). We can
therefore anticipate a future growth of foreign direct investments in the wine
sector: greenfield investments, corresponding to the purchase of land and the
pure creation of a new vineyard, but also brownfield investments when brands
buy existing vineyards or create alliances with local brands.
It is therefore self-evident that many variables will affect the future evolu-
tion of the wine industry worldwide, so that an exercise of prediction of the
potential future directions of the wine industry is inherently imperfect and
partial and potentially totally wrong. This is the risk of such an exercise. But
our effort has been to present the most likely evolutions and some hints on
the interplay among the different actors of the industry and to offer a perspec-
tive in terms of breaks of tendency rather than of a plain extension of past
trends. The wine industry is very likely to know several breaks of tendency in
the next 10–15 years and the actors of the industry will need to make strategic
choices.
References
Ashenfelter, O., and K. Storchmann. 2016. The economics of wine, weather, and
climate change. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 10 (1): 25–46.
Bargain, O., J.M. Cardebat, and A. Vignolles. 2018. Crowdfunding in the wine
industry. Journal of Wine Economics 13 (1): 57–82.
Cardebat, J.M. 2017. Économie du vin. Paris: La Découverte.
Corsi, A., E. Pomarici, and R. Sardone. 2018. Italy post 1938. In Wine globalization.
A new comparative history, ed. K. Anderson and V. Pinilla, 153–177. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Holmes, J., and K. Anderson. 2017. Convergence in national alcohol consumption
patterns: New global indicators. Journal of Wine Economics 12 (2): 117–148.
Ludington, C.C. 2018. United Kingdom. In Wine globalization. A new comparative
history, ed. K. Anderson and V. Pinilla, 239–271. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Schultz, H.R. 2016. Global climate change, sustainability, and some challenges for
grape and wine production. Journal of Wine Economics 11: 181–200.
mmorag@uchile.cl
Index1
A China, 369
Acquisition, 140, 211, 342, 349, 376, France, 19, 24–27, 29–33, 39, 43,
386, 439–441, 443–447, 450, 44, 343, 369, 465, 468, 473,
490, 497 479, 480, 511, 520
Agreement, 10, 59, 72, 97, 126, 150, Italy, 343, 468
153, 164, 188, 204, 250–263, South Africa, 343
266, 279, 280, 282, 283n15, Spain, 43, 468
287, 288, 293, 299–301, 302n5, United States (US), 343, 369, 477,
303, 304n6, 306–310, 312, 366, 480
429, 439, 489, 491, 496, Area, 18, 20–22, 24–26, 27n3, 28, 43,
498–500, 514 47–52, 54, 54n3, 56, 57, 62, 64,
Alliance, 35, 141, 260n11, 342, 348, 66–68, 72, 75, 78–81, 84, 86,
351, 352, 356, 361, 497–499, 87, 89, 99–101, 106, 106n1,
530 108, 110, 111, 117, 123,
AOP 132–136, 141–147, 156–163,
Australia, 45 165, 167, 171, 178, 179, 183,
Chile, 45 186, 190, 196, 197, 212, 213,
France, 43, 44 215, 216, 218, 220, 225, 227,
Spain, 43 230, 232, 258, 266n1, 267, 272,
United States (US), 43, 45 272n8, 278, 279, 282, 285, 291,
Appellation d’origine controlee (AOC) 297, 304, 309–311, 320, 335,
Argentina, 477 339, 346–348, 350, 358, 371,
Australia, 343 389–391, 391n1, 392n2,
Chile, 343, 477 393–396, 399–401, 406–408,
mmorag@uchile.cl
532 Index
414, 421, 421n2, 423, 424, 440, 115–121, 126, 164, 169, 171,
446–448, 464, 467, 468, 468n4, 172, 179, 191, 196, 197, 238,
472, 474, 477, 492, 496, 509, 240, 301, 306, 347, 349, 372,
511, 519, 525, 526 376, 377, 384, 390–392, 395,
Argentina/Argentine 396, 405–408, 410–414, 418,
distribution, 174 428, 431, 445, 498, 499, 503,
domestic market, 155, 166, 169, 514, 515, 517
170, 173, 174, 176, 470 bottling, 4, 38, 48, 54n3, 55,
revenue, 9, 168, 170, 174 58–60, 70, 72, 193, 194, 233,
size, 163, 166 240, 279, 321, 368, 377, 384,
technology, 8, 157, 161, 163, 463, 394, 396, 399, 403, 408,
471 410–415, 422, 423, 425–428,
varieties, 156–163, 169, 471, 525 431, 432, 438
vine area, 163 Brand, 205
winemaking sector, 9, 169 Argentina, 6, 174, 463, 469
Australia/Australian Australia, 5–7, 140, 151, 386, 440,
emergence and cyclical growth, 443, 444, 463, 469, 470
132–136 branding, 12, 64, 323, 384, 403,
features in grape growing, 9, 408, 433, 476–478, 524
142–148, 469, 470 Chile, 5–7, 12, 178, 191, 193, 197,
future, 8, 132, 237 440, 456, 463, 464, 478
structure of the wine industry, China, 6, 90, 233
136–142 France, 5, 8, 38, 40, 365, 408, 440,
wine distribution and retailing, 443, 473, 479, 511
148–151 Italy, 56, 64, 68, 440, 442, 444, 464
South Africa, 6, 209, 219, 463
Spain, 90, 99
B United States (US), 5–7, 90, 117,
Barriers, 10, 236, 242, 246, 252, 282, 463, 477
259n9, 260, 262, 262n15, 266, Brexit, 308–310
280, 288, 291–312, 446–448, Broker, 29, 35, 37, 39, 41, 42, 189,
450, 500, 501, 508, 514, 529 243, 244, 369, 373, 374, 384,
tariff, 252, 292–294 430, 448, 488, 497
Bordeaux/Bordeaux wines, 8, 11, 26, Brownfield investments, 386, 443, 447,
28, 37–39, 42, 151, 212, 234, 530
235, 242, 245, 281, 324, Bulk/bulk wine, 4, 6, 12, 19, 23,
363–379, 405–408, 415–418, 36–38, 42, 58, 66–68, 70, 83,
447, 449, 466, 467, 467n3, 88, 89, 93, 94, 97, 99, 100, 108,
468n4, 472, 476, 480, 502, 511, 113, 115, 117, 119, 120, 126,
516, 525 145, 148, 149, 164, 166, 169,
Bottle/bottle of wine, 19, 36–39, 42, 178, 183, 193, 205, 216, 227,
45, 58, 59, 65, 67, 70, 88, 89, 233, 240, 245, 293, 294, 306,
93, 97, 100, 101, 112, 113, 333, 347, 374–377, 390,
mmorag@uchile.cl
Index 533
mmorag@uchile.cl
534 Index
355, 357, 358, 360, 363, 375n8, 258, 259, 273, 277, 280, 294,
376–379, 377n9, 383–386, 390, 296, 310, 321, 328, 330n9, 344,
398, 399, 408, 409n10, 412, 409n6, 463n1, 467, 503, 507,
415, 431, 440, 442, 444, 445, 512–514, 520, 524, 526–528
448, 456, 476, 488, 497, 501, Contract, 23, 33, 42, 48, 59, 71–72,
518, 524, 526, 530 99, 112, 113, 132, 145, 188,
wine, 11, 12, 38, 61–63, 67, 86, 189, 269n3, 311, 320, 326, 331,
136, 141, 185, 194, 230, 235, 331n11, 332, 333n12, 335n18,
383–386, 398, 399, 440, 476, 336, 336n19, 368, 376, 384,
501 399, 429, 432, 434, 439, 440,
Competitiveness, 2, 4, 6, 10, 22, 44, 442, 466, 477
45, 94, 101, 151, 152, 169, 197, Co-operative
201, 214, 215, 218–219, 251, member, 12, 33, 34, 354, 355,
265–268, 273–274, 276 404–408, 409n7, 410–415, 417,
Concentration, 3, 9, 11, 26, 48, 59–63, 418
69, 86, 114, 139, 150, 163, 170, France/French, 348, 404, 406
185, 209, 210, 217, 232, 245, wine, 9, 11, 33–35, 41, 42, 44,
322, 323, 359, 361, 363, 370, 321–323, 339–361, 403–418,
375, 379, 379n11, 430–431, 437, 442
439, 488, 495–497, 504 Cost
Consumer/wine consumer, 2–5, 9, 22, opportunity, 272, 508
23, 35–37, 39, 41, 44, 58, 63, production, 5, 9, 27, 32, 36, 44, 65,
64, 67, 86, 89, 93, 94, 96, 169, 183, 184, 188, 205, 236,
99–102, 105, 106, 118, 240, 321, 386, 449, 508,
123–126, 150, 152, 155, 514–516, 519
160–162, 168, 169, 171, 172, transaction, 11, 323, 326–332,
175, 183, 188, 190–197, 225, 329n7, 335n16, 336, 337, 383,
232, 234, 241–245, 256, 257, 441, 497
261, 272, 273, 281, 282, 285, Crisis, 2, 18, 20, 21, 63, 85, 86, 90,
287, 292, 294, 296, 301–303, 92, 94, 95, 132, 171, 172, 268,
307–309, 312, 320, 344, 344n8, 269n3, 276n9, 277n10, 339,
345, 351n13, 364, 371, 379, 343–347, 349, 350, 366–368,
447, 464, 467, 468, 468n4, 470, 415, 447, 449, 466, 467, 526
473, 475–481, 479n9, 513–517, Crowdfunding, 528
524, 525, 527–530 Cybercommerce, 40–41
Consumption/wine consumption, 6,
18, 20–22, 39, 43–45, 54, 58,
66–68, 66n11, 70, 73, 74, 85, D
85n3, 86, 90–92, 94–98, 100, De-globalization, 524, 526–527
101, 106, 113–121, 124, 126, Demand, 11, 22, 44, 45, 94, 101, 116,
131, 132, 141, 148, 156, 162, 120, 126, 132, 133, 158, 161,
172, 174, 188, 193, 210, 219, 162, 164, 165, 168, 169, 179,
220, 225, 226, 236, 237, 256, 188, 191, 192, 251, 267, 268,
mmorag@uchile.cl
Index 535
mmorag@uchile.cl
536 Index
mmorag@uchile.cl
Index 537
structure, 152, 226, 244, 326, 386, relationships along the chain, 68–73
421–434 supply, 52, 60, 67, 68, 70, 433
Innovation, 5, 18, 44, 45, 73, 94, 163, wine production organization,
177–181, 183, 185, 197, 226, 55–60
240, 254, 266n1, 274, 276, 277,
330, 335, 344, 351, 351n13,
470, 489–494, 496, 498, 501, L
504 Land tenure
Institution, 10, 11, 208, 217, 250, 251, Italy, 51
253–255, 324, 368, 369, 371, Spain, 81
488, 489, 493, 494, 524 Local
International consumer, 58, 516
market, 4, 18, 22, 72, 85, 86, consumption, 527
89–92, 100–102, 156–158, 173,
176–178, 183, 193, 197, 253,
260, 311, 349, 371, 378, 471, M
487, 499, 500, 502, 503, 528 Market
trade, 4, 6, 7, 10, 12, 18, 43, 45, domestic, 45, 64, 90, 94–96, 121,
251, 258, 260, 266, 292, 294, 140, 150, 152, 153, 155, 156,
295, 299, 301, 307, 311n9, 312, 166, 169–176, 178, 193, 195,
456, 460, 526 197, 204, 205, 209, 212, 219,
wine firms, 438–446, 450 220, 265, 367, 390, 392, 423,
International Organisation of Vine and 428, 429, 470, 495, 496, 527
Wine (OIV), 10, 18–22, 21n1, local, 71, 86, 89, 90, 101, 183, 195,
77, 114, 225, 227, 234, 250, 507–521, 527
251, 253–259, 262, 263, 299, niche, 63, 166, 322, 379, 398, 408
299n2, 312, 344, 458–460 wine, 2, 4, 6–8, 10, 17, 21, 23, 26,
Investments, 2, 7, 11, 63, 78, 84, 38, 40, 43, 45, 70–72, 90, 121,
100–102, 132, 151, 152, 157, 124, 151, 155, 164, 170–173,
158, 161–164, 168, 170, 172, 225, 226, 235, 237, 238, 244,
176, 178, 183–185, 208, 220, 251–253, 262, 266, 269, 273,
227, 231, 235, 266n1, 274, 276, 280, 292, 299, 307, 309, 310,
276n9, 277, 280, 343, 359, 374, 312, 324, 342, 345, 351, 365,
404, 406, 413–415, 417, 418, 374, 377, 421–424, 428, 430,
441, 444, 445, 469–471, 478, 433, 449, 463n1, 464, 465, 473,
480, 493, 494, 496–500, 525 479–481, 501, 503, 507, 508,
Italy/Italian 512–513, 519, 524, 526
distribution, 48–52 Merchant, 11, 23, 35, 38, 40, 203,
farm size, 48–52 243, 244, 322–324, 364–370,
land tenure, 51 372–379, 384, 392, 466–468,
marketing, 17, 19, 58, 64, 72, 280 468n4, 476, 508, 518
mmorag@uchile.cl
538 Index
Merger, 11, 123, 140, 209, 322–324, 336n21, 346, 365, 367, 376,
340–361, 341n3, 341n4, 376, 399, 442, 456, 458–460,
386, 440, 443–447, 450, 490, 465–469, 471, 473–480, 524
496, 524 denomination of, 8, 24
Model, 7–13, 29, 40, 43, 48, 55, 75, Outsourcing, 12, 58, 383–386, 389,
82, 112, 122, 185, 214, 239, 390, 392, 395–397, 399, 438
240, 251, 254, 262, 266, 278,
278n11, 279, 326, 327, 339,
360, 377, 379, 406, 423–427, P
455–461, 463–465, 471, 472, Performance, 5, 6, 8–13, 41–44, 65,
476, 477, 480, 487, 492, 504, 84, 85, 185, 197, 220, 235, 254,
527, 530 307, 312, 320, 321, 323, 350,
357, 364, 369–372, 378, 384,
404, 408–418, 455–461, 487,
O 488, 491, 500–504, 508,
OECD, 492 516–519
Oenology, 257n7, 497 Planting rights, 272, 272n8, 287, 386,
Offer, 40, 43, 44, 78, 124, 125, 151, 438, 444, 446–450
164, 166, 189, 190, 234, 252, Plurilateral
280, 292, 305, 312, 371, 375, agreements, 10, 250, 253–263,
378, 379, 417, 426, 472, 500, 301n3
508, 516, 517, 520, 529, 530 trade agreements, 10
Old world/old producing country/ Policy, 10, 21, 23, 43, 64, 72, 73, 119,
traditional producing country 120, 122, 152, 156, 161, 168,
(TPC), 2, 5–11, 17, 43, 91, 145, 169, 173–174, 176, 203, 214,
220, 239, 245, 251, 254, 254n2, 217, 226, 250, 251, 253–255,
263, 319–323, 344, 441, 455, 254n1, 254n2, 265–284, 292,
457–460, 463–469, 463n1, 476, 294–296, 299, 304, 307, 309,
477, 480, 523–525, 527 357, 366, 391, 392, 404, 446,
Organic 447, 470, 489, 493, 494
certification, 30–31 wine, 10, 73, 249–251, 253, 265,
wine, 19, 28, 33, 35, 36, 138, 231, 267, 274, 277, 288, 447
445 Price, 2, 4–6, 9, 10, 19, 36, 39–41, 45,
Organization 60n7, 62, 64, 65, 67–69, 71, 72,
agricultural, 326–327 74, 79, 85, 87, 88, 90, 93,
industrial, 8–11, 13, 22, 132, 96–101, 106–108, 110, 111,
181–190 117, 118, 120–122, 124–126,
Origin, 4, 12, 25, 25n2, 34, 39, 50, 52, 132–136, 140, 142, 150, 153,
54n3, 63, 74, 83, 90, 99, 100, 156, 161, 162, 164, 168–175,
145, 147, 168, 178, 179, 185, 178, 180, 184, 188, 189, 191,
191, 197, 201, 202, 205, 211, 193–196, 204, 205, 208, 216,
212, 215, 220, 233, 238, 242, 219, 220, 233, 236, 238–239,
244, 254, 259–261, 276–279, 241, 242, 245, 251, 266,
281–287, 296, 301, 323, 268–271, 274, 287, 292, 293,
mmorag@uchile.cl
Index 539
296, 297, 321, 327, 328, 331, wine, 56, 64, 71, 73, 74, 82, 83,
337, 350, 352, 367, 371, 87–91, 93, 94, 96, 99, 100, 151,
373–375, 377, 384, 391, 392, 152, 163, 172, 178, 181, 196,
396, 399, 406, 408, 415–418, 205, 214, 220, 226, 240, 251,
428, 429, 433, 439, 441, 442, 266, 268, 271–274, 272n7, 278,
445, 447–449, 457, 458, 460, 278n11, 279, 287, 288, 296, 365,
464, 467–470, 468n4, 477, 479, 367, 384, 385, 399, 440, 464,
480, 497–499, 501, 503, 504, 477, 490, 501, 510, 511, 518
508, 514–518, 514n9, 520, 528
Prosecco, 4, 12, 66, 386, 421–434
Protected designations of origin (PDO) R
Argentina, 8 Regulation, 8, 10, 24, 26, 33, 38, 44,
Australia, 8, 49, 440, 459, 525 64, 72–74, 106, 122, 145, 152,
Chile, 8, 456, 459 153, 156, 212, 219, 234, 242,
China, 8, 19, 440, 526 245, 250, 253, 258, 261–263,
France, 8, 19, 24, 25, 78, 100, 286, 265–284, 294, 296–299, 302,
448, 459, 465, 525 302n5, 305, 310, 311, 369, 385,
Italy, 8, 19, 48, 50, 69, 73, 421, 525 386, 421, 449, 459, 467, 468,
South Africa, 8, 525 473–474, 478, 479, 511, 525,
Spain, 8, 78, 80, 82, 89, 92, 99, 286 527
United States (US), 8, 90, 525 Reputation, 8, 10, 12, 18, 24, 44, 57,
Protected geographical indication 64, 94, 148, 151, 226, 230, 231,
(PGI) 235, 245, 267, 282, 285, 323,
Argentina, 8 335n16, 336, 346, 349, 365,
Chile, 8 371, 373, 456, 463–481, 510,
China, 8 512, 517
France, 8, 19, 24, 25, 27, 33, 42, collective, 12, 64, 463–481
448, 449 Restaurant, 35, 36, 41, 66n11, 68,
Italy, 8, 52, 54n3, 64, 69, 73 100, 101, 118, 172, 179, 183,
South Africa, 8 188, 190, 195, 243, 372, 390,
Spain, 8, 78, 82 518, 519
United States, 8 Retail, 9, 57, 64, 65, 67, 68, 95, 96,
Proximity 99, 112, 117, 118, 121, 122,
geographical, 342, 353–355 125, 137, 140, 145, 148–151,
organized, 342, 352–357, 361 173, 188, 190, 191, 195, 205,
208, 209, 242, 243, 297, 308,
348, 351, 368, 408, 429, 434,
Q 467, 470, 476, 507
Quality Risk, 10, 84, 133, 174, 188, 192,
grape, 11, 51, 56, 57, 71, 72, 99, 271n6, 299, 305, 327, 346, 351,
156, 157, 176, 177, 189, 216, 352, 355, 356, 359, 367, 383,
227, 331, 333–335, 334n13, 385, 386, 412–415, 439, 440,
439, 479 466, 488, 500–504, 525, 526, 530
mmorag@uchile.cl
540 Index
mmorag@uchile.cl
Index 541
mmorag@uchile.cl
542 Index
Vineyard, 2, 4, 7, 11, 20, 21, 23, 24, 321, 384, 385, 389, 390, 392,
26–28, 32, 34, 38, 43, 47–52, 393, 396, 397, 399, 466,
52n3, 54n3, 55, 59, 75, 77–85, 469–472, 474, 478, 480, 498,
87, 100–102, 106, 110–113, 514, 515, 518–521
126, 133, 134, 140, 142–145, winemaking, 7–9, 11, 12, 18, 23,
147, 148, 153, 155–157, 161, 29–35, 38, 39, 42–44, 52n3, 58,
163, 164, 168, 170, 177, 106, 113, 133, 134, 141, 147,
179–181, 183, 184, 188, 189, 150, 156, 157, 165–170, 179,
193, 196, 197, 212, 213, 216, 185, 186, 227–236, 239–240,
217, 225, 229, 231, 233, 235, 244, 245, 261, 301, 323, 363,
236, 240, 245, 266, 272, 272n8, 366, 372, 384–386, 389–399,
273, 277, 279, 323, 325–337, 406, 414, 417, 438, 441, 445,
334n13, 335n16, 335n18, 464, 466, 468–470, 476, 477
336n20, 336n21, 344, 351, 360, winery, 9, 11, 54n4, 55–57, 59,
365–367, 369–372, 376, 378, 63n8, 64, 65, 68–71, 69n13, 75,
379, 383, 384, 386, 389–399, 86–87, 89, 90, 94, 95, 98, 99,
406, 407, 425, 428, 434, 106, 110, 112–114, 116, 117,
438–450, 464, 466, 468n4, 119, 122, 125, 126, 132, 136,
469–475, 492, 496–498, 503, 137, 139–141, 145, 149–151,
507, 509, 512, 515, 518, 527, 153, 155, 158, 160, 162,
528, 530 164–170, 172–176, 185–189,
193–197, 216, 226–237,
239–242, 240n1, 245, 259n9,
W 302, 311, 323, 325–337,
Wholesaler, 42, 44, 67, 68, 71, 74, 334n13, 334n15, 335n16,
121–123, 126, 205, 208, 210, 335n18, 336n21, 343, 385, 389,
297, 321, 348, 376, 378, 406 391–393, 396, 425, 426,
Wine 428–431, 433, 434, 438, 439,
sparkling wine, 42, 54, 65, 66, 68, 442–444, 448, 450, 465, 469,
72, 74, 80, 93, 101, 138, 141, 471, 477–480, 491, 492,
160, 161, 172, 185, 197, 236, 494–498, 507–509, 515–520,
238, 245, 293, 294, 386, 390, 524
394, 396, 421–426, 433, 434, World Trade Organization (WTO),
442, 501 214, 251, 253–255, 254n1, 258,
winegrower, 11, 72, 186–188, 225, 259n10, 261, 262, 266,
230, 239, 240, 245, 321, 324, 279–282, 292, 295, 299, 301,
363–379, 384, 385, 390, 305, 306, 308–310, 312, 513
392–399, 405–407, 467, 468, World Wine Trade Group (WWTG),
525 10, 250, 251, 254, 255,
winemaker, 8, 9, 24, 29, 33–38, 42, 259–263, 299, 301, 301n3
55, 71, 143–144, 170, 183, 186, WTO, see World Trade Organization
188–190, 209, 228, 235, 320, WWTG, see World Wine Trade Group
mmorag@uchile.cl