Chapter 9
Chapter 9
Chapter 9
ASIAN REGIONALISM
Learning objectives
At the end of the course the students should be able to:
Define regionalism;
Understand regionalism in the Asia and the Asia-Pacific; and
Articulate a stance of regional trading agreement and be able to enumerate the
different organizations in the region and their functions.
REGIONALISM
Regionalism is in vogue, and it is here to stay, however, in the ultimate analysis, it is no
substitute for globalism. Given that the global economy is not governed by free market rules,
regionalism and globalism can function in a complementary manner, regionalism that is not
open, and is devoid of globalism, is antithetical for maximizing the global output, and therefore,
for global economic welfare. As we shall see in Section 7, open regionalism was pioneered by
Australia and New Zealand and id being practiced by the APEC forum. The paper begins with an
introduction of the contemporary regionalism, provides a definition of regionalism, and delves
into its various characteristics as well as the diversity of its texture. Relative to other regions,
the Asia-Pacific region caught on to regionalism late. In its institutional form, Asian
policymakers ignored the concept for a long time. Economic growth in Asia has a certain
characteristic pattern to it. Over the preceding half century, the high performing Asian
economies adopted outward-oriented strategies, promoting trade and foreign investment.
After a lag, this led to the expansion of intra-regional trade and investment. Asia-Pacific
regionalism was essentially market-led. Regional production networks were the consequence of
market-led economic dynamics of the region. Large corporations, including transnationals,
contributed to the growth of pan-Asian industrialization process. The institutional
arrangements followed the market initiatives. Some regional initiatives were taken, which are
operating with varying degrees of success. These regional initiatives can coexist with globalism
and serve as “building blocs.”
The fourth tier is a common market and is considered the first deep integration stage.
This stage attempts to harmonize some institutional arrangements and commercial and
financial laws. Beyond free exchange of goods and services, a common market entails free
movement of factors of production. The fifth stage is the economic union and goes a step
ahead of the free movement of goods, services and factors. An economic union, the last tier,
involves integrating national economic policies, including taxes and a common currency.
The new regionalism has several distinctive characteristics. First, while old regionalism
was essentially confined to RTAs between industrial economies or the developing economies,
the new regionalism is known for cross alliances between developing and industrial economies.
The new bonds forged by developing and industrial economies offer considerable potential for
gains from trade. The flip side is that this new relationship also has a great deal of potential for
adjustment problems and trade tensions. Second, while old regionalism was essentially limited
to RTA formations by contiguous economies, the new regionalism does not seem to be limited
to neighboring economies. In some recent or proposed cases, RTAs are intercontinental.
Although there may be coordination related problems, from the gains-from-trade perspective
this could be a healthy development. Third, under the new arrangement RTAs are not exclusive,
meaning thereby one country can simultaneously be a member of more than one RTA. This may
eventually turn out to be an aid in promoting multilateralism through RTAs. Fourth, while old
regionalism was limited to shallow integration, the new regionalism is more ambitious. A
number of recent agreements aspire for deep integration, with commitments to harmonization
of regulatory measures, freeing factor movements, and other close integrating measures.
Implications of RTAs for the global trading system have been extensively debated in
economic literature. More than 210 RTAs have been notified to the GATT and the WTO. Some
no longer exist. Many of the discontinued RTAs were superseded by redesigned agreements
among the same signatories. A large number of RTAs were concluded in the decade of the
1990s. Between 1995 and 2000, 90 RTAs covering goods or services, or both, have been notified
to the WTO. Currently, over 130 agreements are in force (WTO, 2000). The global network of
RTAs is highly complex, and many countries are members of several agreements, sometimes
with very different rules. Shallow integration is far more common than deep. A large majority of
existing RIAs is free trade areas. The only customs unions are the EU, the South African Customs
Union (SACU), MERCOSUR in South America, and CARICOM in the Caribbean. The ANDEAN Pact
and CACM have common partial tariffs. The EU now has 15 members and is moving ahead to
form a common market and further on to be an economic union, having a single currency. A
Eurozone of 12 economies already exists.
The enlargement of the EU is looming. Economic and political momentum behind EU
expansion is powerful. Prospects of doubling its current membership to 28 or even 30 before
2010 are clear. When the new members join in, it would be much more than a mere change of
scale. In late 2000, the front runners for joining the EU were Cyprus, Estonia, Poland, the Czech
Republic, and Slovenia. Eight more countries were applicants and likely to join later (Vedrine,
2000). The next wave of EU expansion would increase the union’s population by 30 percent, to
more than half a billion people, twice the total of the US. This would dwarf any previous
expansion. More importantly, the integration of the EU with emerging Europe is an economic
quantum leap. When Spain and Portugal joined the EU, their GDP per capita was already 70
percent of the EU average in purchasing power parity terms. The 1995 accession countries even
produced a higher output per capita than the existing union. The thirteen present candidates
post a purchasing-power adjusted GDP per capita of less than 40 percent of the EU average. In
Euro terms, this ratio is as low as 15 percent. Also, Central and Eastern Europe’s financial
sectors are far less developed than their EU counterparts (Suppel, 2000). The EU also has
known plans to bring the North African economies into its fold in the future.
ANZ-CERR
Australia and New Zealand were known for their long-standing deep-rooted protectionist
policies. Until the 1970s, they had the highest average levels of protection for their import-
competing manufacturing industries in the OECD countries. Economists cited them as examples
of slow-growing countries with high levels of protection and an inability o adjust to changes. In
1965, Australia and New Zealand agreed on the establishment of a free trade area. This was the
first formal RTA in the Asia-Pacific region. Technically a CER (which is the same as ANZCER) is a
free trade area because each country retains independence in its trade policies with non-
members. During the decades of the 1980s and 1990s, the two economies pursued sets of
trade policies which shares many elements and which together represent a style of trade policy
that is distinctive. The common elements included a fast clip unilateral reduction in barriers to
trade with other nations, a sharp movement away from NTBs, particularly from QRs. The earlier
agreement was superseded by the 1983 CER agreement, which was intended to put the CER on
an auto-pilot. The provisions of the agreements were substantially widened and deepened. The
“negative list” still covered some 40 percent of trans-Tasman trade in manufactured goods. The
last QRs were not due to be removed until 1995. All border restrictions were to be ended within
twelve years. Tariffs were to be phased out by 1988, performance-based export incentives by
1987, and QRs and tariff quotas by 1995. In reality, these targets were met by July 1990, some
five years ahead of schedule. Besides, anti-dumping actions against the trans-Tasman partner
ceased from the same date.
A comprehensive review of the CER was conducted in 1988, in which the two
governments among other things addressed the issue of domestic production subsidies. This
issue had caused a great deal of angry discussions in the mid-1980s. In 1988, the two partners
of the CER decided that industry assistance should be avoided where it would have a distortive
impact over the trans-Tasman competition Australia’s Export Facilitation Scheme for passenger
motor vehicle was initially excluded from this arrangement, but the exclusion was later
withdrawn. During the late 1980s, there was a change in the mindset of the policymakers. Both
Australia and New Zealand became fairly aggressive trade reformers. Building on the
achievements of free trade in goods, the two governments raised their sights to the more
ambitious objective of creating a single trans-Tasman market. An important condition for the
creation of a “single market” is the removal of administrative and the so-called “behind-the-
border” impediments to trade and investment flows. The process of removing these
impediments has come to be described as “facilitation,” to distinguish it from the removal of
traditional trade barriers, described as “liberalization”. The CER used facilitation well through
measures such as liberalization and integration of purchasing procedures, harmonization of
standards and conformance procedures, harmonization of some aspects of business law, and
streamlining and harmonization of customs procedures (BIE, 1995). Further facilitation
measures continued to be introduced, with notable addition being the agreement on food
standards in 1996 and food standards measures.
A Protocol on Services was concluded in 1988, providing for MFN and national treatment
for services providers in both the countries, albeit with some exceptions. The “negative” list of
services excluded from free trade is limited and more transparent than the “positive” list
approach adopted by the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS). However, some
frictions are remaining in the CER over liberalization of some services sectors and investment
regulations in Australia. A review of this agreement was carried out in 1992. It led to several
modifications being made, including the commitment to harmonize business law and
competition policy.
The CER is well advanced as an RTA. It has enjoyed smooth and uncontroversial progress
towards a single market because of the unilateral liberalization and deregulation that has
occurred in Australia and New Zealand over the last 15 years. The common system of
government, law and customs and a shared language have been important. The CER agreement
contained provisions on the application of countervailing measures, subsidies and government
procurement, As noted, antidumping provisions do not apply to trade between Australia and
New Zealand. This is an important innovative step in CER and has attracted international
attention. Any “unfair trade” claims are treated according to national competition laws in the
country where the complaint occurs. Disputes are settled by consultation. An important feature
of this progress is that it was achieved with simple rules. There is no administrative organization
or secretariat to supervise the agreement. Lloyd (1997) described CER as the “most clean and
most outwardly open of all the RTAs approved under the GATT.” Lloyd also considers CER
among the regional trading arrangements second only to the EU, particularly in its development
of facilitation measures.
A notable feature of the CER is that it has been achieved by strong unilateral movements
towards free trade and deregulation in both the partner economies. It exemplifies “open
regionalism” because regional liberalization in CER has progressed with liberalization vis-à-vis
countries outside the region. The other region, perhaps the only other, regional trading
arrangement in the world that achieved substantial regional liberalization along with
substantial unilateral liberalization is ASEAN.
As the CER is an RTA of an advanced variety, it needs to be judged by standards of a
highly-developed regional arrangement like the EU or NAFTA. Intra-CER trade is a small share of
each partner’s total trade. Although Australia is New Zealand’s largest trading partner, in the
1990s its share of New Zealand’s exports ranged between 18 and 21 percent, with its share of
New Zealand’s imports only slightly higher at 20 to 22 percent. The only aberration was 1996
when the share of New Zealand’s imports shot up to 24 percent. As opposed to this, New
Zealand’s share in Australia’s trade has remained even lower. During the 1990s, New Zealand
accounted for 4 to 5 percent of Australia’s imports and 5 to 7 percent of its exports (Scollay,
2000). Also, the growth in the share of intra-CER trade of the two countries total trade has not
been dramatic. The significance of intra-trade and CER rises markedly when trade in
manufactured goods is taken into account. Manufactures dominate the intra-trade of Australia
and New Zealand, which is completely unlike their pattern of exports to the rest of the world.
Another interesting feature is that whereas Australia is a net importer from the rest of the
world as a whole in each of thirteen major categories of manufactured goods, it is a net
exporter to New Zealand in all but three of those categories (Scollay, 2000).
McMillan (1993) and Scollay (1994) have inferred that significant reduction in external
barriers against third countries has accompanied the elimination of boundaries between the
two partner economies of the CER. This is a welfare-enhancing condition. Substantial unilateral
trade liberalization took place in Australia and New Zealand, while they eliminated trade
barriers between each other. The efficiency improvements imposed on the manufacturing
sector through unilateral trade liberalization thus helped to ensure that the manufactured
goods trade stimulated by CER would also be primarily welfare enhancing.
Using the gravity model for the CER, Frankel (1997) reports CER as being highly significant
statistically. It had a slight upward trend, reaching 1.7 in 1970. Empirical tests show that the
antipodean pair trades 5.5 times as much as an otherwise similar pair of countries. The
openness term shows that trade by Australia and New Zealand with other partners is
consistently low. However, the openness term has no discernible impact on the block
coefficient. In the future, further rationalization in the trans-Tasman market place would not
only integrate the two partner economies closer, and it would help them in making the
profound adjustments that would be required as the APEC vision of free trade and investment
in the Asia-Pacific region.
AFTA
The second RTA in the Asia-Pacific region was related to ASEAN countries. In August 1967,
ASEAN was established between five Southeast Asian economies, namely, Indonesia, Malaysia,
the Philippines, Singapore, and Thailand. As the earlier regional initiatives among developing
economies were not known for their success, ASEAN restricted its scope to cooperation on
strategic and political. Its objectives were to promote peace, stability. It needs to be
emphasized that ASEAN was not born as a sub-regional economic organization. Brunei
Darussalam joined ASEAN in 1984. Strengthening trade and economic linkages did not occur to
ASEAN economies until 1978 when ASEAN put into force an Agreement on ASEAN PTA. This PTA
granted 10 to 15 percent margins of preferences on 71 commodities and industrial products. A
stronger free-trade proposal had fallen through during the negotiations. The PTA was weak and
inconsequential, as the most important sectors were exempted from the system of preferences
that they were supposed to grant each other. Product-by-product nature of negotiations,
nongenuine offers of preferences, high domestic content requirements, and the limited nature
of preferences themselves rendered the PTA little ineffective. It had little impact over trade
between ASEAN countries. In an infamous example, Indonesia removed mutual trade barriers
on the imports of snow shovels. Over the 1985-87 period, the ASEAN leaders agreed to Expand
the list of sectors covered by the PTA and also to increase the margin of preferences. However,
until the end of the 1980s, the fraction of goods eligible regional preferences was. still only of
the order of 3 percent of the total. Thus, ASEAN had little success on the economic integration
front. Between 1967 and 1992, it remained more or less a political organization.
In January 1991, the ASEAN countries agreed to upgrade the PTA and establish an ASEAN
Free Trade Area (AFTA). The proposal was made by Thailand and accepted by all the members a
year later during the fourth ASEAN Summit meeting in Singapore in January 1992. It breathed a
new life into ASEAN. The original goal of AFTA was to reduce tariff rates on intra-ASEAN trade
to between zero and 5 percent within 15 years beginning 1993. The principal instrument for
adopting this objective was the common effective preferential tariff (CEPT) plan. The CEPT plan
divided goods into two categories: (i) the fast-track goods whose tariffs would be reduced to 0
to 5 percent within 7 to 10 years depending upon whether the initial tariff was below or above
20 percent, and (ii) the normal track goods on which taxes would be reduced more slowly and
in two stages. Subsequently, during the 1993 and 1994 ASEAN summit meetings the rate of
planned tariff liberalization was accelerated and other changes were adopted, whereby 11,000
tariff items―which included 20 percent of total tariff lines―were to reduce tariffs by January
1994. Members decided that the fast-track tariff lines would be liberalized by 2000 and
standard track tariff reductions would be achieved by the year 2003 instead of 2008. Vietnam,
which joined ASEAN in 1995 and AFTA in 1996, was granted a ten-year implementation period
ending 2006. By 2000, the membership of ASEAN had expanded to ten with the inclusion of
Laos Peoples Democratic Republic, Myanmar, and Cambodia.
AFTA can indeed make a useful contribution to trade and welfare in the region. However,
CEPT has severe limitations. First, it emphasizes on tariffs, which have become less important
relative to regulatory NTBs as impediments to trade in the ASEAN countries. Second, CEPT also
focuses on merchandise trade, which has been declining in importance relative to trade in
services and investment. Third, most analysts consider the CEPT timetable to be slow. The
justification given was that it would provide business enterprises time to adjust and restructure.
Besides, the AFTA economies have not overcome all their disagreements. More importantly,
the CEPT agenda covered less than half of intra-ASEAN merchandise trade. Broadening CEPT to
give a more comprehensive coverage of intra-ASEAN trade is vitally important. At the time of
the creation of ASEAN, most member economies had only embarked on their industrialization
programs and lacked the confidence to let their tariff barriers and NTBs down: They have now
developed a great deal of confidence, thanks to rapid outward-oriented industrial
development. Many member economies have succeeded in learning about global trade
regulations and negotiations. AFTA has begun addressing trade facilitation issues. An ASEAN
Consultative Committee on Standards and Quantity was established to work on harmonization
of standards, testing, and accreditation of laboratories, conformity assessment, and technical
information. A Consultative Forum on FDI met in 1993, and there were plans to hold
macroeconomic consultations. However, the trade facilitation agenda was slow to get off the
ground. To make things worse, it was overtaken by that of the APEC forum. Disagreements
among members have persisted. During the October 2000 meeting of the ASEAN, Malaysia
scuttled the timetable for lowering tariff barriers. There was a possibility of a Chain reaction
whereby other members could decide to keep tariffs on favored local industries (AWSJ, 2000).
As noted above, the gravity model for AFTA shows evidence that the ASEAN bloc is highly
open (Frankel and Wei, 1997). It has been found that the dummy for ASEAN is extremely large
and statistically significant. Two ASEAN economies, literally interpreted, trade 600 percent
more than two economies otherwise identical. Since Singapore plays an entrepot role, its
exports and imports exceed its GDP. Hence, Singapore’s extreme openness can be reflected in
the Bias within ASEAN. A Singapore dummy was added to Singapore to examine this, which was
found to have a positive and substantial coefficient. The ASEAN dummy coefficient was reduced
but remained large and statistically significant quantitatively. Thus, one can infer that the
extreme openness of Singapore did not explain all the ASEAN countries ‘ inward bias and that,
despite the multitude of problems and delays, the ASEAN economies are likely to tend to
expand their trade with each other.
ASEAN: overview
1. Association of Southeast Asian Nations
2. Ten member states
Brunei, Cambodia, Indonesia, Laos, Malaysia, Myanmar, Philippines, Singapore,
Thailand, & Vietnam
3. home to 600 million people
4. collective GDP of US$2 trillion
ASEAN: founding (1967)
1. Five founding members:
Thailand, Malaysia, Singapore, Indonesia, Philippines
2. Bangkok Declaration of 1967:
accelerate economic growth
promote regional peace and stability
contain the spread of communism
End of Cold War
1. ASEAN Free Trade Area
2. initiated at ASEAN summit in 1992
3. a comprehensive program of regional tariff reduction
4. the program later broadened and accelerated
5. reaffirmed during the Asian Financial Crisis of 1997-98
Expansion of ASEAN
1. 1995: Vietnam
2. 1997: Laos
3. 1997:Myanmar
4. 1999: Cambodia
ASEAN: external links
1. A joint forum with Japan was established in 1977
2. A cooperation agreement with the European Community was signed in 1980
3. “ASEAN + 3”: regular series of meeting at the cabinet and head-of-government levels
with Japan, China, and South Korea since 1997
ASEAN and the U>S>
1. Investment:
U.S. direct investment of US$157 billion in ASEAN
nearly three times more than in China
Ten times more than in India
2. Trade:
4th largest export market ($76 billion) for the U.S.
U.S. imported $123 billion from ASEAN
Northeast Asia
1. Japan, South Korea, North Korea
2. Mainland China, Hong Kong, Taiwan
3. Mongolia, Russia
4. Compared with Southeast Asia and Western Europe, Northeast Asia has lagged behind
in developing mechanisms or institutions
of coordination, cooperation, or integration
5. especially considering the immense economic potentials in the region
natural resources
human infrastructure
APEC
The forum of APEC was launched in 1989. Australian Prime Minister Bob Hawke launched
the idea of creating a multilateral forum to enhance economic cooperation between Asia and
Pacific economies. Australia and Japan co-sponsored the concept. APEC’s genesis lies in the
particular circumstances of the late 1980s. The EU promised to reinforce its customs union and
create SEM, Canada, and the US were negotiating NAFTA expansion of their free trade area,
and the Uruguay Round was stumbling. In a period when the failure of the multilateral trading
system was a real threat, Asian economies were afraid of being left out of the move towards
RTAS. Australia was concerned about being left out of an Asian regional body, which was being
suggested by Malaysia.
APEC had a fairly humble beginning and was initially greeted with sufficient skepticism.
Initially, the basic objectives of the APEC forum were economic cooperation and consultation.
Although APEC was born as a regional arrangement of sorts, it had adopted the difficult, if
somewhat paradoxical, the mission of combating preferential regionalism. Accordingly,
members explored various ways in which regionalism can be open. As noted above, this kind of
open regionalism was pioneered by CER.
APEC began with foreign and economic ministers meetings and several relatively small
projects. Since then, however, it has grown in scope and prominence and, with the agreement
to hold annual summit meetings of heads of state, has achieved a more significant status. The
first such meeting was held in Seattle on Blake Island in 1993. At the 28th launch time, APEC
had twelve members. Five of them were industrial economies (Australia, Canada, Japan, New
Zealand, and the United States), six members of ASEAN (Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines,
Singapore, Thailand, and Brunei Darussalam) and the Republic of Korea. Between 1989 and
1994, six more countries joined APEC, increasing membership to eighteen (China, Hong Kong
SAR, and Taiwan in 1991 and Mexico, Papua New Guinea and Chile in 1994). A moratorium on
membership for three years was adopted in 1996. Peru, Russia, and Vietnam were admitted to
APEC as soon as it came to an end, bringing their membership to 21. The inclusion criterion was
that the aspiring member must be on the Pacific Ocean and have close relationships with
existing members as well as accepting the 2020 goal of trade liberalization (see Bogor targets
below). Although membership for the next ten years has now been closed, APEC represents the
largest and most diverse group of countries ever assembled. Spanning both sides of the Pacific
Ocean and incorporating two of the four global trade superpowers―the US and Japan―APEC
encompasses 40% of the world’s population in 2000, 54% of global GDP, and 42% of its trade.
Until 1994, despite the creation of the Secretariat of APEC and the Group of Eminent
Persons, APEC remained a rather loose consultative forum in line with the original goals behind
its creation. This was the prerequisite for ASEAN economies continued participation in APEC. It
was criticized as a mere “talking shop” by scholars in the early 1990s (Pomfret, 1995). Initially,
ASEAN members were hesitant to join APEC because they feared being overshadowed by a
larger group of large industrial economies. Since then, though, they have adopted the cause of
APEC as their own. Part of the responsibility for upgrading ASEAN PTA to ASEAN Free Trade
Area or AFTA was to join APEC. A significant development of the early 1990s was the more
active involvement of Australia in Asian economies and economic diplomacy.
APEC’s nature, training, and operating process differed fundamentally from that of the EU
or NAFTA. These differences came from the three main driving forces behind APEC’s creation.
First, post-war growth and integration had a unique process for Asian economies. As
explained above, this was the market-led process of economic integration. Second, there were
huge stakes in the global trading system in many of the regional economies. Despite their
diversity, dynamic Asian economies under the aegis of the GATT were more firmly committed
to the multilateral trading system than the other developing economies. In the GATT system,
they saw several tangible advantages. First, under the aegis of the GATT, they benefited from
lowering tariff barriers under different rounds of MTNs. Several of them also benefited from the
“special and differential treatment” under Part IV of the GATT Articles of Agreement. These
economies, therefore, enjoyed considerable scope for autonomy in domestic policy.
Moreover, while Asian economies remained avid GATT supporters, they looked with
suspicion at regionalism in other parts of the globe. After forming a formal RTA, they were
neither totally convinced of the benefits nor passionate (Lawrence, 1996). They considered
RTAs to be unnecessary dependence on large economies. To the extent that Mexico or Canada
depends on the US market, developing Asian economies did not depend on the Japanese mark
There was no political logic for the Asian economies that primarily brought the EU economies
together in the form of an inward-looking RTA. Unlike Europeans, the dream of eventually
becoming a United States of Asia was nurtured by a few Asians. To support such regional
arrangements, historical, cultural and economic differences between Asian economies are far
too high. Political power distribution in Asia has been and continues to be, highly skewed.
Japan’s economic prowess or China’s geopolitical power would long dominate the region. In the
context of APEC, the US would be economically and geopolitically the most powerful country.
These considerations have been important in shaping the Asia Pacific region’s major
regional arrangement initiative. Consequently, APEC was neither conceived as an RTA nor had a
treaty underpinning its plan for trade, liberalization. Funabashi (1995) accused APEC of “four
noun-searching adjectives.” This criticism was unfair as members of the APEC agreed to form a
“community.” They were also clear about their community definition. It was not meant to be a
quasi-federal arrangement community like the EU, nor was it intended to set up a large
organization. It was also not to be a common market or a customs union in the foreseeable
future. Instead, it was decided that APEC would promote trade and investment through a mix
of trade liberalization, trade facilitation, and economic cooperation policies. Initiatives to
streamline standards, improve customs procedures, coordinate competition policies, and
mediate disputes included trade facilitation. Economic cooperation included support for
development and cooperation on human resources, infrastructure, energy, and environment
projects. Trade facilitation related research under APEC is widely regarded as pioneering and
respectable, including by the WTO (Moore, 2000).
APEC progressed gradually ahead of its initial goals, better organized and structured,
starting with areas where members agreed. A significant point of time for APEC was 1993 when
the US hosted the first Seattle Economic Leaders Meeting and suggested that APEC aim to
create an Asia-Pacific economic community, something like an Asia-Pacific EU. Since then, APEC
has made significant progress in trade liberalization and facilitation. The ambitious Bogor
Declaration was adopted by members at the Sixth Ministerial and Leaders Meeting in 1994,
with specific targets for trade liberalization in the region. The 18 participating leaders declared
their intention to turn the APEC forum into a free trade and investment area. The goals
Included trade liberalization for the five industrial economies by 2010 and the remaining
members of the APEC by 2020. During the Seventh Ministerial and Leaders Meeting, the
guidelines for implementing the Bogor Plan were embodied in the 1995 Osaka Action Agenda.
During
the formulation of the Manila Action Plan (Yamazawa, 2000), they were further refined at the
eighth meeting of ministers and leaders in 1996.
The commitment from Bogor presented both risks and opportunities. The main advantage
could be to achieve improved market access beyond what was feasible under WTO regulations.
APEC’s size has significant political implications. Lawrence pointed out that at a single point in
time, the GATT or WTO never set a complete schedule for achieving global free trade. When
APEC members committed themselves as a long-term goal to free trade, they are likely to focus
on making progress in small steps towards free trade. This would create momentum for trade
barriers to be reduced, starting with the least political resistance from sectors. This, in turn,
could push free trade into the global trading system.
Moreover, many Asian economies were concerned about being shut out of the NAFTA
market after NAFTA was created, but since both Canada and Mexico are part of APEC, an APEC-
wide free trade area would not allow that to happen. Similarly, some Asian economies
apprehended that the US might lose interest in the Asia – Pacific region, but the initiatives of
APEC would once again help to keep the US involved. Unlike these plausible advantages, the
risk lay in more promising and losing credibility in the process (Lawrence, 1996).
There are two remarkable APEC features. Unlike other free trade agreements, the
achievement of Bogor’s objectives has so far been based on (i) individual or national action
plans rather than rigid target application to all Member States, and (ii) concessions to all non-
Member Trading Partners in terms of reducing trade and non-trade barriers have been
extended. This is based on the open regionalism principle noted above 15. This strategy runs
contrary to the 1950s and 1960s closed regionalism. There are misperceptions about the term
open regionalism because there have been few attempts to define the term systematically.
Some people love an oxymoron. The argument went as follows: how can it be confined to a
region if an arrangement is open?
Two remarkable attempts were made to the President of the United States by the
Eminent Persons Group (APEC, 1994) and the Council of Economic Advisors (CEA. 1995). There
are two similar definitions. The CEA definition reads as follows: “Open regionalism refers to
non-exclusive and open-minded multi-stakeholder agreements. First, it requires that multi-
stakeholder initiatives fully comply with Article XXIV of the GATT, which prohibits an increase in
common external barriers.
Moreover, plurilateral agreements do not require members to pursue additional
liberalization either on a reciprocal or unilateral basis with non-members. Since member
countries can unilaterally select their external tariffs, open agreements are less likely to develop
into competing blocs of bargaining. Finally, open regionalism implies that plurilateral
agreements both enable and encourage non-members to join. “At its Osaka meeting in 1995,
APEC formally embraced open regionalism and the Osaka Action Agenda was based on the
voluntary nature of the APEC process, an essential corollary to the idea of open regionalism
(APEC, 1995a). APEC took the view that liberalization can be achieved only through individual
members ‘ voluntary actions. As the members level of economic development was diverse, it
was believed that having one set of rules would not be effective for all members. This thought
was contrary to the WTO’s position, married to the principle of “single undertaking” and tariff
binding.
Accordingly, one of the most important open regionalism criteria is the freedom for
member countries to further liberalize unilaterally or on a reciprocal basis with non-members.
It should be noted that individual members are not allowed to lower their tariffs in a customs
union. A common customs union external tariff cannot be lowered unless all members agree on
it. Political commitments are voluntary under open regionalism and are not legally binding. This
voluntary liberalization strategy was considered unprecedented when adopted. In addition to
reducing tariffs and NTBS and removing barriers to trade in services, its comprehensive
coverage also requires harmonization of rules and standards and other facilitation measures.
Until a country group attempts to form an economic union, the last named ones will not be
attempted. All the eighteen members announced their action plans (LAP) during the APEC
meeting in Manila and started implementing IAPs in January 1997. Some scholars view these
features of APEC as positive and likely to lead to significant progress towards Bogor’s goals,
although with some modifications (Petri, 1997). Others, however, disagree and see these
characteristics as obstacles to serious liberalization and negotiations. The earlier apprehension
about the APEC forum persists in some quarters, and some analysts still believe that APEC can
be reduced to little more than a “chat forum” with such characteristics (Flamm and Lincoln,
1998).
It was noted above that APEC’s immediate agenda includes trade liberalization,
facilitation of trade and economic cooperation. Monetary and macroeconomic cooperation and
development projects and technical cooperation have been launched accordingly. Many of
these policy measures came from the deeper integration agenda and may be more feasible
than a formal RTA. In some areas, therefore, APEC could be more successful in achieving deeper
integration than in achieving shallow integration. The Pacific Business Forum, which was
formed after the Seattle Summit in 1993, promoted several of these issues with great
enthusiasm. This forum includes representatives of businesses from across the APEC region.
The business leaders also presented a vision paper that included, among other things, calls for
rapid trade liberalization, a peaceful investment code, facilitating customs procedures, setting
up a business-person visa, and setting up a small and medium-sized business foundation.
If the members of APEC go beyond tariffs and NTBs dismantling and consider agreements
on domestic practices that reinforce market forces, trade with an entry of non-members would
become easier, which in turn would have trade creation effect rather than trade diversion
effect. For instance, harmonized regulations, more efficient customs procedures, or increased
regulatory transparency would automatically help both insiders and outsiders in APEC. This
would also impart new meaning to open regionalism. In many Asian economies interest in
deregulation has grown. Some countries might find it easier to undertake these measures if
they were part of a regional agreement.
APEC declarations and statements recognized the superiority of the global trading system,
permitted by the WTO, and stressed the need to implement regional trade liberalization within
the WTO, framework. APEC Ministerial Declaration recognized the WTOS primacy and the need
to strengthen the multilateral trading system after the conclusion of the Uruguay Round. (The
1995b APEC). After 1996, the APEC changed its position and called for regional and multilateral
cooperation on trade liberalization. At this stage, APEC appeared more inclined towards its
regional identity and was even keen to highlight its WTO differences. Ministers noted in the
Vancouver Declaration that”... regional and multilateral trade and investment initiatives
complement and support each other” (APEC, 1997)
The gravity model was maintained until 1992 for the APEC trade flows for the members of
the APEC (Frankel and Wei, 1997)
Results reveal that the APEC group, which includes the US as its member, is one of all
possible implicit trade blocs in the Asia-Pacific region that shows the strongest intra-regional
bias. This exercise of regression revealed that two members of the APEC trade 200 percent
more than two economies otherwise identical. Controlling for an APEC effect has significantly
reduced the coefficient on the bloc in East Asia: it has become marginally significant at 10
percent. This suggested that East and Southeast Asian economies did not trade substantially
more than other APEC countries, although they traded a lot among themselves. There was a
pan-Asia block effect even after controlling for an APEC effect that exhibited a strong inward
bias.
Regionalization has late, lost momentum through APEC, and APEC has become almost
moribund, if not an “ailing regional organization.” One of the concerns at the APEC leaders’
Summit of 2000 was backsliding on the agreements made during the previous APEC meetings.
As the APEC agreement to achieve free trade and investment by 2010 and 2020 was non-
binding and voluntary, in the wake of the 1997 Asian crisis, this agenda fizzled, flapped and
collapsed completely. Serious problems faced the IAPs. In the absence of credible progress
towards the objective of free trade and investment, some members of the APEC are turning to
subregional arrangements to achieve these objectives (discussed below). The private sector,
APEC Business Advisory Council found in 2000, in an assessment of three key areas, that in
many cases the IAPs contained incomplete information on how members intend to fulfill their
commitments. The culpability for the stagnation of APEC lies with Japan and the US, the two
largest economies. They showed little leadership, which APEC so desperately needed. US
policymakers allowed global liberalization to stagnate as they lost domestic policy control by
pandering to particular interests. Japan has blocked attempts to pursue a sectoral liberalization
approach within APEC (Wain, 2000). Partly out of frustration with APEC, members have been
pursuing increasingly alternative institutional arrangements to achieve their priority economic
goal. They took the form of sub-regional commercial and financial pacts, discussed in detail
below. These initiatives took place primarily within East Asia and the Pacific but also included
some of the APEC’s trans-Pacific members. To ensure that the proliferating sub-regional
arrangements do not eventually serve to fragment the APEC initiative, immediate scrutiny of
the organization’s progress and achievements is warranted.
NAFTA+3.ASEAN+3
Grouping is the newest idea in regional integration in Asia. In 1998, this group held its first
summit and two more in the years that followed. The membership includes the economies of
ASEAN, plus China, Japan, and (Republic of) Korea. The solutions applied by the IMF and
Western governments to resolve the Asian crisis disappointed Asian governments. Therefore,
regional governments turned to creating home-grown solutions to their potential future
economic and financial problems. The failure to reform the global financial architecture has
created a push for greater cooperation between ASEAN+3 countries in the monetary and
economic spheres (FT, 2000). This group has started to hold regular meetings with their finance
ministers and has a “vision group” to guide their work. With more sophisticated machinery than
NAFTA (Economist, 2000b), it has become the most active RTA outside Europe. The coin’s flip
side is that it is still at an early stage and the three new partners have not been integrated. In
financial matters, ASEAN+3 is proceeding faster than in trade. This emphasis is blamed for the
Asian crisis of 1997-98. Members of this group announced a regional system of currency swaps
in the Chang Mai Declaration (1999) to help them deal with future Asian crises. This facility was
created for economies of ASEAN+3, although there was no formal institution. This plan is similar
to that drawn up in the early 1960s by the Group of Ten Industrial Nations when they faced the
post-war era’s first global monetary hiccups. The institutions of Bretton Woods expressed
strong support for expanding financial cooperation on the Chiang Mai initiative. They see it as a
complement to the IMF’s financial aid to the Asian economies that undertook financial and
corporate restructuring (Kohler, 2001).
Also evolving are sub-regional financial structures. ASEAN has created a surveillance
mechanism to use sophisticated early-warning indicators to try to anticipate and prevent future
crises. The economies of Northeast Asia are jointly keeping an eye on short-term movements of
capital in their economies and nearby. Much is said about common currency baskets and joint
intervention arrangements to replace both the past discredited dollar pegs and the expensive
free floats imposed by the Asian crisis. Japan has actively promoted the creation of a currency
swap network to protect Asian economies from Speculative attacks (FT, 2000).
Although the Asian Monetary Fund (AMF) proposal was flatly rejected in 1998, it started
to evolve in the latter half of 2000. China criticized Japan’s original AMF proposal, backed the
initiative firmly in 2000. Hong Kong SAR and the Philippines proposed an Asian currency unit
(ACU) following the euro. This is an idea that will come to fruition for years. However, it
wouldn’t even have been taken seriously by any of the group members a few years ago. As
credible economic initiative, ASEAN+3 emerges. It will only be evident in the medium term
whether it would be a force to reckon with.
CONCLUSION
Somewhat paradoxically, regionalism was on the rise during the 1990s in an otherwise
globally integrating economy. The new regionalism has several distinctive characteristics, which
are discussed in this paper. RTAs take different forms, and each has different implications and
nuances. RTAs are not only accepted by TNCs, but they also have been playing a proactive role
in promoting them. One of the useful instruments was FDI made by TNCs while the other was
regional production networks set up by them. RTAs provide increased access to corporations
and TNCs. Large TNCs tended to move RTAs towards economic integration that was deep.
Intraregional trade played an effective role in promoting regional integration, particularly in
Asia It also impacted the economic structure of the regional economies. The market expansion
that took place in Asia was both vertical and horizontal. Regionalism in the Asia-Pacific region
was essentially market-driven. Although there are not many RTAs in the Asia-pacific region, the
existing ones do show an impressive variety. In chronological order, they include ANZ-CER
agreement, AFTA, APEC and SAPTA. The history and objectives of these RTAs vary widely. Of
these, only ANZ-CER and AFTA can be treated as integrated RTAS. the other RTAs, some are
formal others are not. APEC is wedded to the concept of “open regionalism.” Now all of these
RTAS are successful. Asia economies did not display a great deal of enthusiasm for RTAs
formation until the end of the 20th century. Born out of a perception of a slow pace of global
integration, failure of the new round of ultilateral trade negotiations to take off in Seattle in
1999 and failure of APEC to achieve its objectives in a timely manner, initiatives for bilateral
trade agreements begun to rapidly multiply in the Asia-Pacific region in 2000 and 2001.
APEC
The forum of APEC was launched in 1989. Australian Prime Minister Bob Hawke launched
the idea of creating a multilateral forum to enhance economic cooperation between Asia and
Pacific economies. Australia and Japan co-sponsored the concept. APEC’s genesis lies in the
particular circumstances of the late 1980s. The EU promised to reinforce its customs union and
create SEM, Canada, and the US were negotiating NAFTA expansion of their free trade area,
and the Uruguay Round was stumbling. In a period when the failure of the multilateral trading
system was a real threat, Asian economies were afraid of being left out of the move towards
RTAS. Australia was concerned about being left out of an Asian regional body, which was being
suggested by Malaysia.
APEC had a fairly humble beginning and was initially greeted with sufficient skepticism.
Initially, the basic objectives of the APEC forum were economic cooperation and consultation.
Although APEC was born as a regional arrangement of sorts, it had adopted the difficult, if
somewhat paradoxical, the mission of combating preferential regionalism. Accordingly,
members explored various ways in which regionalism can be open. As noted above, this kind of
open regionalism was pioneered by CER.
APEC began with foreign and economic ministers meetings and several relatively small
projects. Since then, however, it has grown in scope and prominence and, with the agreement
to hold annual summit meetings of heads of state, has achieved a more significant status. The
first such meeting was held in Seattle on Blake Island in 1993. At the 28th launch time, APEC
had twelve members. Five of them were industrial economies (Australia, Canada, Japan, New
Zealand, and the United States), six members of ASEAN (Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines,
Singapore, Thailand, and Brunei Darussalam) and the Republic of Korea. Between 1989 and
1994, six more countries joined APEC, increasing membership to eighteen (China, Hong Kong
SAR, and Taiwan in 1991 and Mexico, Papua New Guinea and Chile in 1994). A moratorium on
membership for three years was adopted in 1996. Peru, Russia, and Vietnam were admitted to
APEC as soon as it came to an end, bringing their membership to 21. The inclusion criterion was
that the aspiring member must be on the Pacific Ocean and have close relationships with
existing members as well as accepting the 2020 goal of trade liberalization (see Bogor targets
below). Although membership for the next ten years has now been closed, APEC represents the
largest and most diverse group of countries ever assembled. Spanning both sides of the Pacific
Ocean and incorporating two of the four global trade superpowers―the US and Japan―APEC
encompasses 40% of the world’s population in 2000, 54% of global GDP, and 42% of its trade.
Until 1994, despite the creation of the Secretariat of APEC and the Group of Eminent
Persons, APEC remained a rather loose consultative forum in line with the original goals behind
its creation. This was the prerequisite for ASEAN economies continued participation in APEC. It
was criticized as a mere “talking shop” by scholars in the early 1990s (Pomfret, 1995). Initially,
ASEAN members were hesitant to join APEC because they feared being overshadowed by a
larger group of large industrial economies. Since then, though, they have adopted the cause of
APEC as their own. Part of the responsibility for upgrading ASEAN PTA to ASEAN Free Trade
Area or AFTA was to join APEC. A significant development of the early 1990s was the more
active involvement of Australia in Asian economies and economic diplomacy.
APEC’s nature, training, and operating process differed fundamentally from that of the EU
or NAFTA. These differences came from the three main driving forces behind APEC’s creation.
First, post-war growth and integration had a unique process for Asian economies. As
explained above, this was the market-led process of economic integration. Second, there were
huge stakes in the global trading system in many of the regional economies. Despite their
diversity, dynamic Asian economies under the aegis of the GATT were more firmly committed
to the multilateral trading system than the other developing economies. In the GATT system,
they saw several tangible advantages. First, under the aegis of the GATT, they benefited from
lowering tariff barriers under different rounds of MTNs. Several of them also benefited from the
“special and differential treatment” under Part IV of the GATT Articles of Agreement. These
economies, therefore, enjoyed considerable scope for autonomy in domestic policy.
Moreover, while Asian economies remained avid GATT supporters, they looked with
suspicion at regionalism in other parts of the globe. After forming a formal RTA, they were
neither totally convinced of the benefits nor passionate (Lawrence, 1996). They considered
RTAs to be unnecessary dependence on large economies. To the extent that Mexico or Canada
depends on the US market, developing Asian economies did not depend on the Japanese mark
There was no political logic for the Asian economies that primarily brought the EU economies
together in the form of an inward-looking RTA. Unlike Europeans, the dream of eventually
becoming a United States of Asia was nurtured by a few Asians. To support such regional
arrangements, historical, cultural and economic differences between Asian economies are far
too high. Political power distribution in Asia has been and continues to be, highly skewed.
Japan’s economic prowess or China’s geopolitical power would long dominate the region. In the
context of APEC, the US would be economically and geopolitically the most powerful country.
These considerations have been important in shaping the Asia Pacific region’s major
regional arrangement initiative. Consequently, APEC was neither conceived as an RTA nor had a
treaty underpinning its plan for trade, liberalization. Funabashi (1995) accused APEC of “four
noun-searching adjectives.” This criticism was unfair as members of the APEC agreed to form a
“community.” They were also clear about their community definition. It was not meant to be a
quasi-federal arrangement community like the EU, nor was it intended to set up a large
organization. It was also not to be a common market or a customs union in the foreseeable
future. Instead, it was decided that APEC would promote trade and investment through a mix
of trade liberalization, trade facilitation, and economic cooperation policies. Initiatives to
streamline standards, improve customs procedures, coordinate competition policies, and
mediate disputes included trade facilitation. Economic cooperation included support for
development and cooperation on human resources, infrastructure, energy, and environment
projects. Trade facilitation related research under APEC is widely regarded as pioneering and
respectable, including by the WTO (Moore, 2000).
APEC progressed gradually ahead of its initial goals, better organized and structured,
starting with areas where members agreed. A significant point of time for APEC was 1993 when
the US hosted the first Seattle Economic Leaders Meeting and suggested that APEC aim to
create an Asia-Pacific economic community, something like an Asia-Pacific EU. Since then, APEC
has made significant progress in trade liberalization and facilitation. The ambitious Bogor
Declaration was adopted by members at the Sixth Ministerial and Leaders Meeting in 1994,
with specific targets for trade liberalization in the region. The 18 participating leaders declared
their intention to turn the APEC forum into a free trade and investment area. The goals
Included trade liberalization for the five industrial economies by 2010 and the remaining
members of the APEC by 2020. During the Seventh Ministerial and Leaders Meeting, the
guidelines for implementing the Bogor Plan were embodied in the 1995 Osaka Action Agenda.
During the formulation of the Manila Action Plan (Yamazawa, 2000), they were further refined
at the eighth meeting of ministers and leaders in 1996.
The commitment from Bogor presented both risks and opportunities. The main advantage
could be to achieve improved market access beyond what was feasible under WTO regulations.
APEC’s size has significant political implications. Lawrence pointed out that at a single point in
time, the GATT or WTO never set a complete schedule for achieving global free trade. When
APEC members committed themselves as a long-term goal to free trade, they are likely to focus
on making progress in small steps towards free trade. This would create momentum for trade
barriers to be reduced, starting with the least political resistance from sectors. This, in turn,
could push free trade into the global trading system.
Moreover, many Asian economies were concerned about being shut out of the NAFTA
market after NAFTA was created, but since both Canada and Mexico are part of APEC, an APEC-
wide free trade area would not allow that to happen. Similarly, some Asian economies
apprehended that the US might lose interest in the Asia – Pacific region, but the initiatives of
APEC would once again help to keep the US involved. Unlike these plausible advantages, the
risk lay in more promising and losing credibility in the process (Lawrence, 1996).
There are two remarkable APEC features. Unlike other free trade agreements, the
achievement of Bogor’s objectives has so far been based on (i) individual or national action
plans rather than rigid target application to all Member States, and (ii) concessions to all non-
Member Trading Partners in terms of reducing trade and non-trade barriers have been
extended. This is based on the open regionalism principle noted above 15. This strategy runs
contrary to the 1950s and 1960s closed regionalism. There are misperceptions about the term
open regionalism because there have been few attempts to define the term systematically.
Some people love an oxymoron. The argument went as follows: how can it be confined to a
region if an arrangement is open?
Two remarkable attempts were made to the President of the United States by the
Eminent Persons Group (APEC, 1994) and the Council of Economic Advisors (CEA. 1995). There
are two similar definitions. The CEA definition reads as follows: “Open regionalism refers to
non-exclusive and open-minded multi-stakeholder agreements. First, it requires that multi-
stakeholder initiatives fully comply with Article XXIV of the GATT, which prohibits an increase in
common external barriers.
Moreover, plurilateral agreements do not require members to pursue additional
liberalization either on a reciprocal or unilateral basis with non-members. Since member
countries can unilaterally select their external tariffs, open agreements are less likely to develop
into competing blocs of bargaining. Finally, open regionalism implies that plurilateral
agreements both enable and encourage non-members to join. “At its Osaka meeting in 1995,
APEC formally embraced open regionalism and the Osaka Action Agenda was based on the
voluntary nature of the APEC process, an essential corollary to the idea of open regionalism
(APEC, 1995a). APEC took the view that liberalization can be achieved only through individual
members ‘ voluntary actions. As the members level of economic development was diverse, it
was believed that having one set of rules would not be effective for all members. This thought
was contrary to the WTO’s position, married to the principle of “single undertaking” and tariff
binding.
Accordingly, one of the most important open regionalism criteria is the freedom for
member countries to further liberalize unilaterally or on a reciprocal basis with non-members.
It should be noted that individual members are not allowed to lower their tariffs in a customs
union. A common customs union external tariff cannot be lowered unless all members agree on
it. Political commitments are voluntary under open regionalism and are not legally binding. This
voluntary liberalization strategy was considered unprecedented when adopted. In addition to
reducing tariffs and NTBS and removing barriers to trade in services, its comprehensive
coverage also requires harmonization of rules and standards and other facilitation measures.
Until a country group attempts to form an economic union, the last named ones will not be
attempted. All the eighteen members announced their action plans (LAP) during the APEC
meeting in Manila and started implementing IAPs in January 1997. Some scholars view these
features of APEC as positive and likely to lead to significant progress towards Bogor’s goals,
although with some modifications (Petri, 1997). Others, however, disagree and see these
characteristics as obstacles to serious liberalization and negotiations. The earlier apprehension
about the APEC forum persists in some quarters, and some analysts still believe that APEC can
be reduced to little more than a “chat forum” with such characteristics (Flamm and Lincoln,
1998).
It was noted above that APEC’s immediate agenda includes trade liberalization,
facilitation of trade and economic cooperation. Monetary and macroeconomic cooperation and
development projects and technical cooperation have been launched accordingly. Many of
these policy measures came from the deeper integration agenda and may be more feasible
than a formal RTA. In some areas, therefore, APEC could be more successful in achieving deeper
integration than in achieving shallow integration. The Pacific Business Forum, which was
formed after the Seattle Summit in 1993, promoted several of these issues with great
enthusiasm. This forum includes representatives of businesses from across the APEC region.
The business leaders also presented a vision paper that included, among other things, calls for
rapid trade liberalization, a peaceful investment code, facilitating customs procedures, setting
up a business-person visa, and setting up a small and medium-sized business foundation.
If the members of APEC go beyond tariffs and NTBs dismantling and consider agreements
on domestic practices that reinforce market forces, trade with an entry of non-members would
become easier, which in turn would have trade creation effect rather than trade diversion
effect. For instance, harmonized regulations, more efficient customs procedures, or increased
regulatory transparency would automatically help both insiders and outsiders in APEC. This
would also impart new meaning to open regionalism. In many Asian economies interest in
deregulation has grown. Some countries might find it easier to undertake these measures if
they were part of a regional agreement.
APEC declarations and statements recognized the superiority of the global trading system,
permitted by the WTO, and stressed the need to implement regional trade liberalization within
the WTO, framework. APEC Ministerial Declaration recognized the WTOS primacy and the need
to strengthen the multilateral trading system after the conclusion of the Uruguay Round. (The
1995b APEC). After 1996, the APEC changed its position and called for regional and multilateral
cooperation on trade liberalization. At this stage, APEC appeared more inclined towards its
regional identity and was even keen to highlight its WTO differences. Ministers noted in the
Vancouver Declaration that”... regional and multilateral trade and investment initiatives
complement and support each other” (APEC, 1997)
The gravity model was maintained until 1992 for the APEC trade flows for the members of
the APEC (Frankel and Wei, 1997)
Results reveal that the APEC group, which includes the US as its member, is one of all
possible implicit trade blocs in the Asia-Pacific region that shows the strongest intra-regional
bias. This exercise of regression revealed that two members of the APEC trade 200 percent
more than two economies otherwise identical. Controlling for an APEC effect has significantly
reduced the coefficient on the bloc in East Asia: it has become marginally significant at 10
percent. This suggested that East and Southeast Asian economies did not trade substantially
more than other APEC countries, although they traded a lot among themselves. There was a
pan-Asia block effect even after controlling for an APEC effect that exhibited a strong inward
bias.
Regionalization has late, lost momentum through APEC, and APEC has become almost
moribund, if not an “ailing regional organization.” One of the concerns at the APEC leaders’
Summit of 2000 was backsliding on the agreements made during the previous APEC meetings.
As the APEC agreement to achieve free trade and investment by 2010 and 2020 was non-
binding and voluntary, in the wake of the 1997 Asian crisis, this agenda fizzled, flapped and
collapsed completely. Serious problems faced the IAPs. In the absence of credible progress
towards the objective of free trade and investment, some members of the APEC are turning to
subregional arrangements to achieve these objectives (discussed below). The private sector,
APEC Business Advisory Council found in 2000, in an assessment of three key areas, that in
many cases the IAPs contained incomplete information on how members intend to fulfill their
commitments. The culpability for the stagnation of APEC lies with Japan and the US, the two
largest economies. They showed little leadership, which APEC so desperately needed. US
policymakers allowed global liberalization to stagnate as they lost domestic policy control by
pandering to particular interests. Japan has blocked attempts to pursue a sectoral liberalization
approach within APEC (Wain, 2000). Partly out of frustration with APEC, members have been
pursuing increasingly alternative institutional arrangements to achieve their priority economic
goal. They took the form of sub-regional commercial and financial pacts, discussed in detail
below. These initiatives took place primarily within East Asia and the Pacific but also included
some of the APEC’s trans-Pacific members. To ensure that the proliferating sub-regional
arrangements do not eventually serve to fragment the APEC initiative, immediate scrutiny of
the organization’s progress and achievements is warranted.
NAFTA+3.ASEAN+3
Grouping is the newest idea in regional integration in Asia. In 1998, this group held its first
summit and two more in the years that followed. The membership includes the economies of
ASEAN, plus China, Japan, and (Republic of) Korea. The solutions applied by the IMF and
Western governments to resolve the Asian crisis disappointed Asian governments. Therefore,
regional governments turned to creating home-grown solutions to their potential future
economic and financial problems. The failure to reform the global financial architecture has
created a push for greater cooperation between ASEAN+3 countries in the monetary and
economic spheres (FT, 2000). This group has started to hold regular meetings with their finance
ministers and has a “vision group” to guide their work. With more sophisticated machinery than
NAFTA (Economist, 2000b), it has become the most active RTA outside Europe. The coin’s flip
side is that it is still at an early stage and the three new partners have not been integrated. In
financial matters, ASEAN+3 is proceeding faster than in trade. This emphasis is blamed for the
Asian crisis of 1997-98. Members of this group announced a regional system of currency swaps
in the Chang Mai Declaration (1999) to help them deal with future Asian crises. This facility was
created for economies of ASEAN+3, although there was no formal institution. This plan is similar
to that drawn up in the early 1960s by the Group of Ten Industrial Nations when they faced the
post-war era’s first global monetary hiccups. The institutions of Bretton Woods expressed
strong support for expanding financial cooperation on the Chiang Mai initiative. They see it as a
complement to the IMF’s financial aid to the Asian economies that undertook financial and
corporate restructuring (Kohler, 2001).
Also evolving are sub-regional financial structures. ASEAN has created a surveillance
mechanism to use sophisticated early-warning indicators to try to anticipate and prevent future
crises. The economies of Northeast Asia are jointly keeping an eye on short-term movements of
capital in their economies and nearby. Much is said about common currency baskets and joint
intervention arrangements to replace both the past discredited dollar pegs and the expensive
free floats imposed by the Asian crisis. Japan has actively promoted the creation of a currency
swap network to protect Asian economies from Speculative attacks (FT, 2000).
Although the Asian Monetary Fund (AMF) proposal was flatly rejected in 1998, it started
to evolve in the latter half of 2000. China criticized Japan’s original AMF proposal, backed the
initiative firmly in 2000. Hong Kong SAR and the Philippines proposed an Asian currency unit
(ACU) following the euro. This is an idea that will come to fruition for years. However, it
wouldn’t even have been taken seriously by any of the group members a few years ago. As
credible economic initiative, ASEAN+3 emerges. It will only be evident in the medium term
whether it would be a force to reckon with.
CONCLUSION
Somewhat paradoxically, regionalism was on the rise during the 1990s in an otherwise
globally integrating economy. The new regionalism has several distinctive characteristics, which
are discussed in this paper. RTAs take different forms, and each has different implications and
nuances. RTAs are not only accepted by TNCs, but they also have been playing a proactive role
in promoting them. One of the useful instruments was FDI made by TNCs while the other was
regional production networks set up by them. RTAs provide increased access to corporations
and TNCs. Large TNCs tended to move RTAs towards economic integration that was deep.
Intraregional trade played an effective role in promoting regional integration, particularly in
Asia It also impacted the economic structure of the regional economies. The market expansion
that took place in Asia was both vertical and horizontal. Regionalism in the Asia-Pacific region
was essentially market-driven. Although there are not many RTAs in the Asia-pacific region, the
existing ones do show an impressive variety. In chronological order, they include ANZ-CER
agreement, AFTA, APEC and SAPTA. The history and objectives of these RTAs vary widely. Of
these, only ANZ-CER and AFTA can be treated as integrated RTAS. the other RTAs, some are
formal others are not. APEC is wedded to the concept of “open regionalism.” Now all of these
RTAS are successful. Asia economies did not display a great deal of enthusiasm for RTAs
formation until the end of the 20th century. Born out of a perception of a slow pace of global
integration, failure of the new round of ultilateral trade negotiations to take off in Seattle in
1999 and failure of APEC to achieve its objectives in a timely manner, initiatives for bilateral
trade agreements begun to rapidly multiply in the Asia-Pacific region in 2000 and 2001.
Name: Section: ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟ ͟
ACTIVITY 9
DIRECTION: Supply the meaning of the following acronyms and give their main purpose or
mission.
1. ASEAN
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟
2. APEC
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟
3. WTO
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟
4. AFTA
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟
5. TNCs
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟
6. EU
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟
7. CACM
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟
8. RTAs
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟
9. NAFTA
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟
10. EEC
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟͟
͟