Nothing Special   »   [go: up one dir, main page]

Financial Innovation

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 33

Financial Inclusion –

measuring progress and progress in measuring

Thorsten Beck*

This version: 21 November 2016

Abstract: This paper documents and discusses recent advances in measuring financial
inclusion and takes stock of the literature on the impact of financial inclusion on individual
and aggregate welfare. Theory and empirical evidence has shown that financial deepening
(more than financial inclusion) has a critical impact on structural transformation and poverty
alleviation in developing countries. Among different financial services, expanding access to
payment services seems to provide the biggest and most immediate impact on individual
welfare. Financial innovation, including new delivery channels, new products and new
intermediaries, have helped increase financial inclusion dramatically in some countries over
the past decade, but also has repercussions for how we measure financial inclusion. The
recent progress in measuring and tracking financial inclusion has been important for policy
analysis and the setting of targets. However, caution is advised in over-interpreting headline
indicators.

JEL codes: G21, G23, G28, O16


Keywords: access to finance, financial inclusion, poverty alleviation, economic development

* Cass Business School, City, University of London, CEPR, and CESifo. Contact
information: Cass Business School, 106 Bunhill Row, London EC1Y 8TZ, UK. Email:
TBeck@city.ac.uk. This paper was written for the Fourth IMF Statistical Forum “Lifting the
Small Boats: Statistics for Inclusive Growth”. I would like to thank Stijn Claessens, Patrick
Honohan, Leora Klapper. Sole Martinez Peria, and participants at the Forum for useful
comments.

1
1. Introduction

Financial inclusion has increasingly moved to the top of the policy agenda in many
developing countries, reflected in several G20 statements (most recently in 2016 in
Hangzhou), establishment of financial inclusion units in Central Bank and Ministries of
Finance and specific financial inclusion targets. One important aspect of formulating policy
goals, however, is the ability to measure progress in achieving these goals. Over the past
decade, enormous progress has been made in measuring financial inclusion across the globe.
At the same time, being able to measure financial inclusion has allowed us to gauge the
progress due to financial innovation and policy interventions. Critically, as more evidence
becomes available on what dimensions and aspects of financial inclusion are important for
individual welfare and firm growth, data collection can be and has been adjusted accordingly.
This paper takes stock both of the progress in measuring financial inclusion as well as the
literature on the impact of financial inclusion on individual and aggregate welfare.

Financial inclusion refers to the access by enterprises and households to reasonably priced
and appropriate formal financial services that meet their needs. Access to financial services
can be defined along several dimensions, including geographic access (i.e. proximity to a
financial service provider) and socio-economic access (i.e. absence of prohibitive fees and
documentation requirements). Appropriate design of products that meet the needs of clients,
are sustainable for both providers and users, but do not involve abusive pricing, are other
important aspects.1 Financial inclusion is a broader concept than microfinance, which often
refers to the provision of products to specific groups at the lower end of the market, using
specific delivery techniques and institutions.

Financial inclusion is part of a broader financial deepening agenda that focuses on ensuring
the efficient and sustainable provision of financial services to households, enterprises and
governments, while minimizing the risk of fragility. While an extensive literature has
established a positive relationship between financial depth (as measured by aggregate
measures such as Private Credit to GDP) and economic growth that holds even when
controlling for estimation biases arising from reverse causation, measurement and omitted
variables (see Levine, 2005 and Beck, 2009, for surveys), evidence on a positive impact of


1
See, for example, CGAP (2011), which defines financial inclusion as a “state in which all working age adults
have effective access to credit, savings, payments and insurance from formal service providers” and defines
effective access as “convenient and responsible service delivery, at a cost affordable to the customer and
sustainable for the provider…”

2
financial inclusion on individual and aggregate welfare has been much less conclusive. One
important lesson learned in this literature is to differentiate between different types of
services. It is also important to understand that the development and efficiency of financial
systems can have an impact not only on aggregate growth, but also on tightening income
distribution and helping people out of poverty, even without providing them with direct
access to credit services.

Financial inclusion has become an important part of the development agenda that aims at
reducing poverty levels further. It is therefore critical to understand what works and what
does not work in financial inclusion. This is important for both formulating policy priorities
and allocating scarce government and donor resources. Properly measuring financial
inclusion and the barriers to it and relating them to real sector outcomes is therefore a priority
for research. In this context it is important to stress that financial inclusion is not an objective
in itself, but only to the extent that it helps improve individual and aggregate welfare.

While ten years ago, data on financial inclusion were scarce and limited to country-specific
survey evidence, the past decade has seen substantial progress in this area.2 Financial depth
indicators have been complemented with cross-country data on branch, ATM and account
penetration. More importantly, two waves of the Global Findex surveys have provided very
detailed insights not only in the share of population with a bank account but also the use of
different financial services. These data also allow detailed analysis of variation in financial
inclusion across different groups within the population.

Financial inclusion targets have become increasingly popular over the past years, including
the Universal Financial Access Goal, as formulated by the World Bank Group in 2013, that
“by 2020, adults, who currently aren't part of the formal financial system, have access to a
transaction account to store money, send and receive payments as the basic building block to
manage their financial lives.” As much as the recent progress in measuring financial
inclusion helps formulate and monitor progress in achieving these targets, setting such targets
has also helped provide impetus for additional attempts at measurement. However, while
measuring financial inclusion and thus tracking progress is important for policy formulation
and implementation, it is important to keep in mind Goodhart’s law that “when a measure
becomes a target, it ceases to be a good measure.” It becomes open to political interference


2
October 2004 saw a first high-level gathering at the World Bank to discuss data needs to better measure
financial inclusion, in the context of the Year of Microcredit 2005. World Bank (2006 a, b) are some of the early
technical pieces outlining was what available at that point in time and requirements for data collection.

3
(or at least interpretation) if not manipulation. In this context the question on a proper
benchmarking arises, i.e., whether we can expect the same level and progress in financial
inclusion in different types of countries, and whether we care so much about account
ownership rather than use of formal financial services.

This paper documents the progress that the global community has made on measuring
financial inclusion over the past decade and – using these data – the progress in financial
inclusion itself. I will also discuss the important role of financial innovation in the increasing
financial inclusion, especially the role of technology. One important aspect I will stress that
over all the attention put on financial inclusion one should not ignore the critical role that
financial deepening per se, i.e. more efficient financial intermediaries and markets have on
structural transformation of economies and, ultimately, on poverty alleviation.

This paper focuses primarily on the measurement of financial inclusion while at the same
time discussing the role of financial inclusion goals in the broader financial development
agenda. It should not be seen as a comprehensive literature survey on access to finance (see
Karlan and Morduch, 2010, Beck, 2015, World Bank, 2014, among others).

The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 discusses the relationship
between financial development and poverty alleviation and the role of financial inclusion in
this relationship, relating both to theory and empirical findings. Section 3 presents the
progress the global community has made in measuring financial inclusion. Section 4
discusses the role of financial innovation in financial inclusion. Section 5 discusses the
importance of a proper benchmark when comparing financial inclusion rates across countries
and over time. Section 6 focuses on the role of gender in the financial inclusion debate.
Section 7 concludes and looks forward.

2. Finance and the Poor – two different concepts

As discussed above, financial inclusion is part of a broader financial development agenda,


which also includes the development of efficient financial intermediaries and markets to
support economic growth. In this section, I will make an important distinction between two
different channels through which – in theory - financial development can reduce poverty
levels across the globe and discuss empirical evidence for both channels.

Individuals can benefit directly from gaining access to specific financial services. First, more
efficient payment systems can help individuals by allowing better integration into modern

4
market economies. Not having to rely on cash, but rather using safer, less costly and swifter
means of transferring payments allows more economic transactions across greater geographic
distances. This can have a direct impact on income earning opportunities and thus incomes
of the poor. Second and related to the intermediation function of the financial system,
gaining better access to savings and credit services enables the poor to pull themselves out of
poverty by investing in human capital accumulation, thus reducing aggregate poverty (Galor
and Zeira, 1993). Similarly, gaining access to credit services allows the poor to invest in
their micro-enterprises, again gaining broader income earning opportunities and ultimately
higher incomes (Banerjee and Newman, 1993). Interestingly, a similar argument has been
made for access to savings services; by protecting resources from intra-family claims through
formal savings accounts, micro-entrepreneurs can invest more in their businesses (Dupas and
Robinson, 2013). Third, access to efficient savings, credit and insurance services allows the
poor to smoothen consumption when hit with income or expenditure shocks (Jappelli and
Pagano, 1989; Bacchetta and Gerlach, 1997; Ludvigson, 1999). The most obvious example is
the need to keep children at home for work purposes rather to send them to school; being able
to access efficient savings, credit and insurance services to smooth income or expenditure
shocks reduces the need to do so (Beegle, Dehejia and Gatti, 2007). Financial inclusion, i.e.,
expanding access to financial services to previously unbanked population segments, which
are typically poorer and live in more remote areas, can thus help pull these people out of
poverty. By better using human resources in an economy, there is also an aggregate positive
effect on economic growth.

The evidence on the effects of financial inclusion on poverty alleviation has been mixed and
varies across different financial services. For credit, there seems no clear-cut case for access
to credit having long-term and transformational positive repercussions, at least on average,
though with some evidence that a certain share of the targeted micro-entrepreneurial
population can benefit quite a lot. As summarized by Banerjee, Karlan and Zinman (2015) in
their introductory paper on a special issue of the AEJ: Applied Economics, there is “a
consistent pattern of modestly positive, but not transformative, effects.” There are several
reasons for this limited impact (Banerjee, 2013). First, micro-entrepreneurs might not be
credit constrained and/or other constraints within the business environment might be more
binding, which might also explain the limited take-up of microcredit. Second, there might be
rapidly diminishing returns, in the form of an S-shaped production and micro-enterprises’
capacity to grow might thus be limited. In this context, one also has to distinguish between

5
life-style or subsistence entrepreneurs and transformational entrepreneurs. Many of the
micro-enterprises are set up out of lack of alternative employment options for the owner in
the formal sector and rely almost exclusively on the owner, maybe with support from family
members and/or friends.3 This indicates that a large share of microenterprise owners may be
running their business to make a living while they are looking for a wage job and may not
have plans for expanding the business (Emran, Morshed and Stiglitz, 2007). The lack of
finding indications of transformative effects of microfinance in field studies is matched with
aggregate results that show very small if any positive effect on aggregate growth, though
some effects on redistribution (Buera, Kaboski and Shin, 2013; Kaboski and Townsend,
2011, 2012).4

Studies assessing the impact of providing access to savings products are, on average, more
positive than the literature on the impact of microcredit. However, they also show the need
for very specific products and techniques to overcome constraints of low-income households
and micro-entrepreneurs (Karlan, Ratan and Zinman, 2014). Specifically, geographic
barriers, high costs in terms of opening balances and fees, documentation requirements,
behavioral constraints in the form of present-bias and intra-household conflicts, and the lack
of financial knowledge are important constraints to expand the use of formal savings products
by low-income households. An expanding literature has explored different forms of
subsidies, novel delivery channels and the use of commitment devices and nudges to
overcome such constraints.

Given the evidence so far (which is just emerging), the strongest case can be made for
expanding payment services on a large scale to previously unbanked segments of the
population in developing countries. Several studies show that the use of more effective
payment methods cannot only reduce costs and connect more people to national and
international payment systems, but also allow more effective inter-personal exchange and
risk sharing across space and over time (e.g, Blumenstock, Eagle and Fafchamps, 2013; Jack
and Suri, 2014). Access to more efficient payment services can also expand access to non-
bank external funding, such as trade credit, by reducing uncertainty of repayment (Beck et


3
For example, Hsie and Klenow (2009) show that 90% of all enterprises in India never grow. De Mel,
McKenzie, and Woodruff (2010) show that only 30 percent of microenterprise owners in Sri Lanka have
characteristics like large firm owners, whereas 70 percent are similar to wage workers. Bruhn (2013) finds that
about 50 percent of a sample of Mexican micro-entrepreneurs are similar to wage workers.
4
There is an additional concern in terms of credit inclusion related to stability and the risk of overindebtedness
of households and enterprises. See Beck (2015) for a longer discussion on this.

6
al., 2016b). Finally, expanding payment services also provide relatively easy and immediate
gains, as the example of several African countries with mobile money accounts has shown.

Beyond financial inclusion, more efficient financial intermediaries and markets can also have
an impact on poverty alleviation through effects on labor and good markets. Through
structural transformation of the economy and allowing more entry into the labor market by
previously unemployed or underemployed segments of the population, financial deepening
(more efficient financial institutions and markets) can help reduce income inequality and
poverty. By doing so, financial deepening can help achieve more inclusive growth and also
help overcome spatial inequality in growth benefits. It is thus important to understand that the
effects of financial deepening on employment and poverty alleviation do not necessarily
come through the “democratization of credit” but rather a more effective credit allocation
within the economy.

Recent empirical evidence has confirmed the importance of this channel. Gine and Townsend
(2004) compare the evolution of growth and inequality in a dynamic general equilibrium
model with the actual development in the Thai economy and show that financial
liberalization and the consequent increase in access to credit services can explain the fast
GDP per capita growth, rapid poverty reduction and initially increasing but then decreasing
income inequality. Underlying these developments are occupational shifts from the
subsistence sector into the intermediated sector and accompanying changes in wages. Net
welfare benefits of increased access are found to be substantial, and, though they are
concentrated disproportionately on a small group of talented, low wealth individuals who
without credit could not become entrepreneurs, there are also benefits to a wider class of
workers because eventually wage rates increase as a result of the enhanced access to credit by
potential entrepreneurs. Beck, Levine and Levkov (2010) find similar evidence for the U.S.,
where branch deregulation in the 1970s and 1980s resulted in lower income inequality. Credit
expansion following deregulation led to an increase in labor demand, which fell
disproportionately on unskilled, lower-income households whose wage rates and working
hours increased. These labor market reactions to financial liberalization can thus explain the
tightening in income inequality. Ayyagari, Beck and Hoseini (2013) find a strong negative
relationship between financial deepening, rather than financial inclusion, and rural poverty,
following financial liberalization in 1991 in India. They also find that financial deepening
reduced poverty rates among the self-employed, and also supported an inter-state migration
from rural areas into the tertiary sector in urban areas.

7
In summary, there are two channels through which financial deepening can reduce poverty
levels – through improving direct access to finance and, indirectly, through structural
transformation. Empirical evidence on the first channel is most robust for savings and
payments services and less so for credit services. Evidence on the second channel point to
important effects on the labor market as mechanism through which financial deepening can
reduce poverty. In terms of policy implications for the financial inclusion agenda it is
important to look beyond credit to other financial services that are needed by the poor, such
as simple transaction or savings services. While it should be a goal to achieve access to basic
transaction and savings services for as large a share of the population as possible to thus
enable them to participate in the modern market economy and help smooth their
consumption, the agenda in boosting access to credit should focus on improving the
efficiency of this process, replacing access through political connection and wealth as it still
happens in many developing countries with access through competition. By channeling
society’s resources to the most credit-worthy enterprises and project, the financial system can
enhance inclusive growth.

3. Measuring financial inclusion – from proxies to granular data

An extensive and still growing literature has related financial depth (proxied by money stock
indicators, such as M2/GDP, or intermediation measures, such as Private Credit to GDP) to
an array of real sector outcomes, most prominently GDP per capita growth, productivity
growth but also international trade patterns (Levine, 2005). From early on it was understood
that these indicators of financial development are very crude proxies for an underlying
concept of financial development. High levels of Private Credit to GDP are associated with
financial systems that offer a variety of products, at different maturities, including long
maturities, at reasonable costs to a large share of the firm and household population.
However, indicators such as Private Credit to GDP are clearly focused on the overall volume
of financial intermediation in an economy and not on the distribution of services. Until ten
years ago, no systematic data collection exercise focused on such data, neither on the country
nor global level. The recent decade has seen progress in collecting data from regulators,
suppliers and users of financial services. While the initial distinction was between access to
and use of financial services, more recently attention has turned to extensive vs. intensive
margins, i.e., pure account ownership versus intensity of use.

8
3.1.Aggregate indicators of financial inclusion

The International Year of Microcredit 2005 put the emphasis on the lack of data on financial
inclusion. First attempts at the World Bank in collecting proxy indicators of financial
inclusion included measures such as total branches and ATMs as well as the total number of
loan and deposit accounts (Beck, Demirguc-Kunt and Martinez Peria, 2007), normalized by
population, thus capturing the access dimension to financial services (branches and ATMs)
and usage. While Honohan (2006) and World Bank (2007) show a non-linear relationship
between these measures financial inclusion measures from household surveys for a small
number of countries (and undertaken very differently), it is noisy one, which might be hard to
use for out-of-sample predictions.5 This data collection effort has in the meantime been
mainstreamed in the form of Financial Access Survey (FAS) at the IMF, with data available
for more than 10 years for a broad cross-section of countries. This global data collection
exercise has obviously also triggered data collection exercises on the national level, mostly at
central banks, across the globe.

While using such aggregate indicators of financial inclusion constitutes a major step forward,
there are measurement problems with such indicators. In the case of branch and ATM
penetration, there is too strong a focus on (i) traditional delivery channels, ignoring
innovative channels, including agency or correspondent banking and digital finance, (ii) a
focus on geographic access, ignoring other barriers to access., and (iii) on regulated entities.
While this can be addressed in the form of adjusting definitions, this might in turn pose
problems of cross-country comparability as well as comparability over time. In the case of
deposit and loan account per capita measures, these indicators do not take into account that
individuals might have several accounts across different banks. It might also be very difficult
to differentiate across different groups of account owners, such as men and women or income
groups. One big advantage that should be mentioned is the high frequency, timeliness and
limited costs with which such data can be collected, especially compared to survey-based
gauges of financial inclusion discussed below.

Looking at these aggregate indicators over time shows a clear increase in branch penetration
in the median country in Latin America, Central and Eastern Europe and Sub-Saharan Africa,


5
Similarly, Beck, Demirguc-Kunt and Martinez Peria (2007) showed correlation with firm-level access
indicators.

9
and little changes in the median country in South Asia, East Asia and Pacific and Middle East
and North Africa (Figure 1). Notably, the median branch penetration in high income
countries has declined since 2008, possibly as consequence of the Global Financial Crisis.

Figure 1: Branch penetration over time and across regions

30

25

20

15

10

0
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015

East Asia & Pacific Europe & Central Asia High income Latin America & Caribbean

Middle East & North Africa South Asia Sub-Saharan Africa

Source: Financial Access Survey, IMF and calculation by author. The graph shows the median in branches of
commercial banks per 100,000 adults across the six World Bank regions and the group of high-income
countries.
Figure 2: Deposit account penetration over time and across regions

1400

1200

1000

800

600

400

200

0
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015

East Asia & Pacific Europe & Central Asia High income

Latin America & Caribbean Middle East & North Africa South Asia

Sub-Saharan Africa

Source: Financial Access Survey, IMF and calculation by author. The graph shows the median in deposit
accounts of commercial banks per 1,000 adults across the six World Bank regions and the group of high-income
countries.

Considering the median for deposit account penetration over time across the different regions
shows an increase in most though not all regions (Figure 2). Notably, the median country in

10
the Middle East and North Africa region has seen quite some variation over time in deposit
account penetration. It is important to stress, however, that data for deposit account
penetration are available for fewer countries than branch penetration data and variation over
time might therefore be driven by outliers in some of the smaller regions.

A related, but separate data collection exercise has been going on to gauge the size and effect
of barriers, such as costs of opening and maintaining accounts and documentation
requirements. Such data has to be collected directly from banks across countries. Specifically,
Beck, Demirguc-Kunt and Martinez Peria (2008a) report on such a collection exercise that
targeted the largest 5 banks across a sample of 80 countries and present indicators for three
types of banking services - deposit, loan and payments - across three dimensions – physical
access, affordability and eligibility. Barriers such as availability of locations to open accounts
and make loan applications, minimum account and loan balances, account fees, fees
associated with payments, number of documents required to open a bank account, and
processing times for loans vary significantly both across banks and countries. Such barriers
can be very constraining for consumers, as the following back-of-the-envelope calculation
shows. Assuming, somewhat arbitrarily, that poor people cannot afford to spend more than 2
percent of their annual income on financial services,6 just the fees on checking accounts can
exclude more than 80 percent of the population in some African countries such as Uganda,
Kenya and Malawi from having a bank account. In a follow-up survey, Beck, Demirguc-
Kunt and Martinez Peria (2008b, 2011) focus on bank-level barriers and lending techniques
for SME finance across banks and countries.

Data collection efforts on access barriers based on bank-level surveys face several
implementation constraints. First, unless channeled through regulatory entities, there is the
risk of low response rates. Second, the comparability of such data might be limited given
different account types and fee structures across banks and countries. There have been
several attempts at similar data collection exercises; however, with limited success. In
general, this approach seems more adequate to undertake on the country-level, managed or
supported by a regulatory entity and reducing problems of comparability.

In summary, these supply-side data collection efforts have provided critical insights into the


6
The 2 percent limit is based on unpublished research by the South African Universal Services Agency in the
context of a mandated rolling-out of telecommunications service to lower-income families. As both financial
transaction accounts and telecom service can be considered network products, similar assumptions on
affordability for both services seems reasonable.

11
high variation in access to and use of financial services across countries. However, they have
given a rather blurred picture of the ultimate metric we are interested in: the share of
population in a country that uses different types of financial services.

3.2.Survey-based indicators of financial inclusion

Given the nature of financial inclusion focusing on individuals having access to and use
financial services, more accurate measures of financial inclusion have to focus on users of
financial services, in the form of surveys. While household surveys have a long tradition in
development economics, including the LSMS used to measure poverty levels, they rarely
included questions on access to or use of financial services. Early surveys focused on
financial access by individuals are the Finscope and Finaccess surveys across several African
countries, with similar stand-alone financial access surveys in several Latin American
countries. What these surveys and datasets provided in depth for individual countries, they
often missed in cross-country consistency.7 Based on the information on the use of different
types of financial services, these surveys can be the base for “access strands”, which measure
people’s financial inclusion status according to the most formal form of service that they use,
including formal prudential (such as banks), formal non-prudential (such as mobile money
providers or postal savings banks), formal registered (such as SACCOs or MFIs) and
informal service providers.

The World Bank, with support from the Bill and Melinda Gates Foundation, has undertaken
over the past years a broad cross-country exercise – Global Financial Inclusion Survey - by
including financial questions in an existing Gallup global poll to generate baseline data on
financial inclusion levels across 150 countries, using samples of 1,000 persons per country.
The survey is to be undertaken every three years to measure and track specific data on
people’s use and access to formal and informal financial services; the first wave was
conducted in 2011, the second wave in 2014, with a third wave planned for 2017. Experience
with data from the first wave and the ongoing discussion on financial inclusion has led to
adjustments and expansion in the questions for the second wave.

Figure 3 shows the share of adults with a bank account in 2011 and 2014 as well as mobile
money account penetration in 2014 across different regions in the world. It documents a
significant increase in the share of households with a bank account, between 2011 and 2014.

7
Honohan and King (2012) discuss differences in survey design and variables across countries.

12
This graph shows the median value across the six regions of the developing world (as
classified by the World Bank) and the high-income country group. There has been a general
increase in financial inclusion, as measured by this variable across most regions, with the
notable exception of the Middle East and North Africa region. The increase in Latin America
has been especially notable. The one dimension where Sub-Saharan Africa stands out is the
share of population with a mobile-phone based account (only data for 2014 are available),
where the median is significantly higher than in other regions except for high-income
countries.

Figure 3: Account penetration across regions

120

100

80

60

40

20

0
East Asia and Pacific Europe and Central Asia High income Latin America & the Middle East and North South Asia Sub-Saharan Africa
Caribbean Africa

Account penetration 2011 Account penetration 2014 Mobile account penetration 2014

Source: Global Findex Survey, World Banks and calculation by author. The graph shows the median in account
penetration across the six World Bank regions and the group of high-income countries.
While Figure 3 shows the overall share of population that has an account, the Global Findex
data also allows digging deeper into the distribution of formal financial usage across
geographical units, income strata, educational groups, and gender. It thus allows to answer
the questions of where the underserved or excluded are located, in geographic and socio-
economic terms and thus identify policy priorities.

As such surveys are only available every 3 years, the question arises whether more frequently
data such as branch or account penetration data can be used to extrapolate trends on an
annual basis. Figure 4 (Figure 5) compare the log change in the share of adults with a bank
account and the percentage change in branches per capita (deposit accounts per capita)
between 2011 and 2014. In both cases, there is a positive but very noisy relationship.

13
Figure 4: Branch penetration vs. account penetration

2.00

1.50

1.00

0.50

0.00

-0.50
-1.00 -0.50 0.00 0.50 1.00 1.50
branch growth

pen_growth Fitted values

Source: Financial Access Survey, IMF, Global Findex, World Bank and calculation by author. The graph
shows log changes in a country’s branch penetration between 2011 and 2014 and log changes in account
penetration between 2011 and 2014.
Figure 5: Deposits per capita vs. account penetration

1.50

1.00

0.50

0.00

-0.50
-0.50 0.00 0.50 1.00 1.50 2.00
deposit growth

pen_growth Fitted values

Source: Financial Access Survey, IMF, Global Findex, World Bank and calculation by author. The graph
shows log changes in a country’s deposit account penetration between 2011 and 2014 and log changes in
account penetration between 2011 and 2014.

14
One important methodological question is whether the survey should try to capture access to
financial services by the household or by individuals within the household. Cull and Scott
(2010) use a randomized experiment in Ghana to test whether the identity of the respondent
affect reported rates of use of financial services. Rates of household use are almost identical
whether the head reports on behalf of the household or whether the rate is tabulated from a
full enumeration of household members. A less complete summary of household use of
financial services results, however, when a randomly selected informant and non-head of
household provides the information. In short, who is asked the questions and how the
questions are asked both matter for capturing the degree of financial inclusion of a household.

While the original focus of the financial inclusion debate has been on having an account,
more recently the attention has shifted more towards the actual use of such accounts. While it
might be easy to open an account, there might be limited use. Anecdotal evidence suggests a
large share of dormant accounts, which were used to undertake one or two transactions and
then never used again. This brings me back to an important observation: we do not care
about financial inclusion per se, but only as it enables financially included to participate
better in modern market economies. It also reinforces the early point that one has to look
beyond headline indicators used to define and measure financial inclusion target. Even if an
almost complete financial inclusion is achieved along the dimension of account ownership,
this does not imply a de facto financial inclusion of similar extent.

The Global Findex survey also includes questions on the reason for not having an account,
which allows to identify barriers from the user side (similar to barriers on the supply side
mentioned above) and well as voluntary versus involuntary exclusion. While lack of need or
indirect access through family members are quantitatively important factors, costs,
geographic distance and lack of necessary documentation are also stated as important.
Finally, trust in financial institutions poses a major concern in some economies, possibly
related to socio-cultural barriers or recent banking crises and bank failures.

A very different but also important data source are the financial diaries (Collins et al., 2009).
These field studies documenting the financial life of poor households over longer time
periods have shown that the poor use an array of informal financial services and access an
array of informal providers of financial services, including money lenders, deposit collectors,
stores providing credit, pawnshops, and friends and family. One important insight from these
diaries is that that poor households see credit and savings as substitutes, where the former has
a large pay-out at the beginning of the contract, while the latter has the payout at the end, and

15
focus more on the cash flow (Collins et al., 2009). While not providing headline indicators,
financial diaries can provide important input into the formulation of broader financial
inclusion surveys and identify critical barriers to inclusion.

3.3.Measuring firm access to finance

The literature on firms’ access to financial services has somewhat preceded progress in the
literature on households’ access to finance, although for many years the focus was mostly on
large listed companies, given data constraints. While not the focus of this paper, I would like
to mention recent progress in measuring access to finance by enterprises. Based on the
World Business Environment Survey (WBES) in 1999/2000 across 80 developed and
developing countries, the World Bank has undertaken the Enterprise Surveys across more
than 100 countries. The most consistent effort has been in the Central and Eastern Europe and
Central Asia region, where data have been collected every three to four years across all
countries, including a panel dimension for a subset of firms (i.e., the same firms being
surveyed every three or four years). Such a panel dimension is now also being introduced in
other regions of the world.

While the initial use of these enterprise surveys has mostly used information on the actual use
of a loan or credit line or self-reported financing constraints, more recent versions also allow
distinguishing between demand and supply factors in the use of external finance.
Specifically, in addition to asking whether a firm has applied and been approved for a loan
over the past year, a question is asked on the reasons if a firm has not applied for a loan. One
of the option – no demand – allows to differentiate between the lack of demand as reason for
not having a loan or credit line or supply side constraints. More importantly, one can
distinguish between rejected and discouraged borrowers, where the latter would include firms
that answered the question on the reasons for not applying with: “Interest rates are not
favorable”; “Collateral requirements are too high”; “Size of loan and maturity are
insufficient”; or “Did not think it would be approved”.8


8
Among the papers that have distinguished between the demand and supply-side factors, using a Heckman
model, are Popov and Udell (2012) and Beck et al. (2016a). In the context of both papers that gauge differences
in access to finance between the boom and bust period in Central and Eastern Europe (2005 and 2008/9,
respectively), this distinction is important. An analysis of enterprise surveys shows that between 2005 and 2008,
the share of firms with no demand for a loan or credit line increased from 30 to 38%. At the same time, the
share of rejected or discouraged firms increased from 34% to 40%. Not distinguishing between supply and
demand factors would thus overestimate the effect of any structural change.

16
It is important, however, not to overestimate the degree to which such survey data allow to
differentiate between pure demand and bankable demand. One distinction that can be made
is using the response “Interest rates are not favorable” to above question as indication that
the expected return on the investment project for which financing was rejected was too low.

One of the less ideal elements is that there is no distinction between full and partial
satisfaction of loan demand. The Survey on Access to Finance by Enterprises conducted by
the ECB includes a question on this distinguishing between full and partial fulfillment of
financing needs.9

One important methodological challenge relates to the representativeness of the sample of


surveyed firms. It is important to not underestimate the challenges for getting a
representative picture, where survey companies often have to rely on rather unreliable
company registers.

As already mentioned, a still growing literature has explored enterprise survey data over the
past 20 years to gauge the relationship between access to finance and firm investment and
growth (e.g., Beck, Demirguc-Kunt and Maksimovic, 2005), bank competition and market
structure and firms’ access to finance (Beck, Demirguc-Kunt and Maksimovic, 2004; Clarke,
Cull and Martinez-Peria, 2006; Love and Martinez Peria, 2015) but also contagion of
financial crisis (Popov and Udell, 2012) and the effect of different lending techniques (Beck
et al., 2016a).

As an alternative to survey data, one can use financial statement data. However, these
provide much less insights into the obstacles encountered by enterprises, as they only report
the equilibrium outcome (even if constrained equilibrium) of demand and supply. Recently,
such data has also become available for non-listed private firms, across many countries (e.g.,
Orbis database). While these databases do not allow to link individual firms to specific banks,
credit registry data allow to do so, which allows the testing of very rich and detailed
hypotheses such as differentiating between different clienteles of banks (Mian, 2005) and the
use of different lending techniques by different types of banks (Beck, Ioannidou and
Schaefer, 2017). On the other hand, credit registries only include actual borrowers (or
sometimes also applicants as in the case of Spain), but not discouraged enterprises.

As households, firms in developing countries, especially smaller firms, rely on an array of


informal non-bank financing sources, including own resources, those of family and friends,

9
For more detail, see here: https://www.ecb.europa.eu/stats/money/surveys/sme/html/index.en.html

17
but also trade credit and informal providers (Beck, Demirguc-Kunt and Maksimovic, 2008).
Trade credit is often seen as a substitute for bank credit (Fisman and Love, 2003), with some
trickling down effect from larger firms with access to bank credit to smaller firms with no
such access, with the important exception of post-crisis periods (Love, Preve, Saria-Allende,
2007). While young and small enterprises in developed economies, especially in the U.S.
often rely on personal credit (including credit card debt) for funding, much less is known
about financing of young entrepreneurs in developing countries.

4. Benchmarking financial inclusion

Tracking indicators of financial inclusion over time is an important starting point. However,
it does not allow us to necessarily attribute this broadening process to specific interventions
or policy changes. Financial inclusion, as captured by these indicators, can change over time
for many reasons unrelated to interventions and policies, including due to demand factors or
changing technology. A more proper way to track financial inclusion is therefore to compare
the development relative to peer countries. Researchers and practitioners alike generally rely
on one-dimensional comparators, typically differentiating by stage of economic development
or considering neighboring countries. While such restricted comparisons make sense on
account of obvious similarities by country group, they fail to account for the fact that, as
shown below in more detail, many other factors explain cross-country, cross-time variation in
financial inclusion. Moreover, they fail to exploit the broader similarities between financial
systems across the world that provide a richer basis for cross-country comparisons.
Following Beck et al. (2008), Barajas et al. (2013) and Beck and Feijen (2013), I would
therefore like to suggest an alternative synthetic benchmark that compares a country in a
given year to a benchmark derived from multi-dimensional cross-country comparisons.

This benchmarking exercise is related to the concept of the access possibilities frontier, as
introduced by Beck and de la Torre (2007). This frontier can be seen as rationed equilibrium
of potential supply and demand, variously affected by market frictions, including the fixed
cost component of financial service provision and the risk of providing financial services,
especially lending and insurance services, due to information frictions and limitations in
perfectly diversifying idiosyncratic risks. This access possibilities frontier is determined by
state variables, such as (i) structural characteristics of the socio-economic environment in
which financial institutions and markets operate and which impose a limit on their

18
development and (ii) long-term policy variables that either foster or limit financial deepening.
Points below the frontier point to policy restrictions that prevent a country from achieving the
constrained maximum while a very low frontier points to fundamental deficiencies in the
macro-economic and institutional framework. Points above the frontier point to an
unsustainable overshooting, either due to subsidies or a credit boom that might end in
systemic bank fragility.

In the following, I will focus on structural characteristics and define the structural depth line
as the level of financial development predicted by structural country characteristics that are
not directly related to policies and/or the financial sector. The gap between the actual level of
financial development and the structural depth line can then be related to different policies
and institutions. The analysis is based on the following simple regression model:

FDi,t = βXi,t+εi,t (1)

where FD is the log of an indicator of financial development, X is an array of structural


country-specific factors, and the subscripts i and t relate to countries and years, respectively.
The regression includes several country characteristics that theory predicts to be associated
with the level of financial development in a country: (i) the log of GDP per capita and its
square (to account for possible non-linearities) proxy for general demand and supply-side
constraints related to low income; (ii) the log of population proxies for market size, in line
with the above discussion on scale economies; (iii) the log of population density proxies for
geographic barriers and thus the ease of financial service provision; (iv) the log of the age
dependency ratio is included to capture demographic trends and corresponding savings
behaviour; and (v) dummy variables for off-shore centers, transition countries and fuel-
exporting countries are included to control for specific country circumstances, as these
countries face specific challenges and development experiences that impact their financial
systems.

Figures 6 and 7 shows the actual and predicted value for account penetration in 2011 and
2014, respectively, for the median country across different regions. As can be seen, the
median country in the high-income group, in South Asia and even in Sub-Saharan Africa had
a higher account penetration in 2011 than predicted by the benchmark model, with the
median country in East Asia and Pacific being at the expected level and the median country
in the other three regions having an account penetration below the expected value. The

19
situation in 2014 is somewhat similar, though the gaps between actual and predicted value for
the median country in each region are smaller.

Figure 6: Actual and predicted account penetration across regions in 2011

100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0

account benchmark

Source: Global Findex and FinStats, World Bank, and calculation by author. The graph shows the median in
account penetration and the predicted median across the six World Bank regions and the group of high-income
countries for 2011.
Figure 7: Actual and predicted account penetration across regions in 2014

100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0

account benchmark

Source: Global Findex and FinStats, World Bank, and calculation by author. The graph shows the median in
account penetration and the predicted median across the six World Bank regions and the group of high-income
countries for 2014.

20
Very obviously, behind these medians is a large variation across countries within regions.
Figure 8 shows the actual and predicted value for account penetration across African
countries in 2014. The four countries with highest level of account penetration are well above
their respective benchmarks (especially Kenya, most likely due to M-Pesa), while Botswana,
the fifth one has a level of account penetration as predicted by the benchmarking model.
Most but not all countries with lower levels of account penetration are predicted to have
higher levels according to their structural characteristics. Mauritania, Tanzania and Togo
have relatively higher actual values than predicted, possibly due to their low population
density, which reduces predicted account penetration.10

Figure 8: Actual and predicted account penetration across countries in Africa in 2014

90

80

70

60

50

40

30

20

10

0
NER MDG GIN BDI TCD ZAR CMR SEN MLI BFA SLE CIV SDN BEN MWI COG TGO TZA MRT ETH UGA AGO GAB ZMB GHA RWA NGA BWA KEN NAM ZAF MUS

account benchmark

Source: Global Findex and FinStats, World Bank, and calculation by author. The graph shows the median in
account penetration and the predicted median across Sub-Saharan African countries for 2014.
This benchmarking model is not a perfect one and depends on the number of countries and
the variables included in the model. But it provides the important message that any financial
inclusion headline indicator has to be interpreted in context. In the context of the above
examples, the gap between actual and predicted value can be used to identify policies and
institutions that either explain why the actual level of financial inclusion is higher than the


10
Allen et al. (2014) show that branch penetration is more closely linked to population density in Africa than in
other regions.

21
predicted or vice versa. It allows a first step towards defining a policy and institutional
reform agenda for increasing financial inclusion.

5. The role of financial innovation

As discussed above, transactions costs and risk are two major market frictions that have
prevented traditional financial intermediaries, including banks, to reach out to customers
characterized by (i) the need for small and infrequent transactions because of low and volatile
income and (ii) high risk profile due to lack of formal identification, address and work place.
As discussed in section 3, this results in bank fees excluding a large share of population
across many low- and lower-middle-income countries and documentation requirements being
too burdensome for large parts of populations in developing economies. Similarly, high risks
of entrepreneurs working in the informal and/or rural economy results in credit rationing a la
Stigliz and Weiss (1981) rather than attracting higher interest rates.

On a positive note, the financial system across the globe has critically changed over the past
decade in the way it has reached out to lower market segments and the previously unbanked
population. This is driven mainly by financial innovations helping to reduce costs and
manage risks more effectively. Some of these “innovations” rely on business models applied
by the cooperative movement in Continental Europe in the 19th century, including the use of
joint liability, peer pressure and social collateral, as applied by many microfinance
institutions across the globe (Ghatak and Guinanne, 1999).

One important change has been the move away from the branch model to agency banking (in
Latin America sometimes also referred to as correspondent banking) to lower the fixed costs
of financial service provision. Brazil is a striking example for the promise of expanding the
footprint of banks beyond brick-and-mortar branches subject to high, partly regulation-
induced, costs. In 2000, almost 40% of municipalities did not have a bank outlet. In 1999, the
Central Bank allowed banks to use non-banking establishment to provide basic financial
services. By 2007, there were 8,000 bank correspondents, four times as many as branches,
and – more importantly-, only 207 out of 5507 municipalities did not have any bank outlet
(Assuncao, 2013). However, the agency model is not necessarily only about geographic
distance but can also help overcome social distance by attracting clientele who do not feel
comfortable entering a bank branch. Moving away from the brick-and-mortar branch model
to an outsourcing model also has to come with changes in costumer identification. There

22
have been two opposing trends over the past 15 years: on the one hand, there has been a push
towards more identification in the context of AML-CFT. On the other hand, as such an
approach would exclude large parts of the currently unbanked population who have limited
documentation as already discussed above and/or would undermine the agency model, a more
risk-based approach has been proposed that excludes customers with account sizes and
transactions below a certain threshold.

An even more revolutionary trend has been towards digital finance, i.e., access to basic
payment or even savings services through mobile phones, possibly even without having to
have a bank account. The most prominent example has been M-Pesa in Kenya, but several
other countries have followed suit, with different models and varying success. Bourreau and
Valletti (2015) distinguish between five different models, ranging from the MNO-led model,
with minimal cooperation with, such as M-Pesa in Kenya and Tigo Pesa in Tanzania over the
bank-led model, with minimal cooperation with MNOs, such as the mobile payments services
offered by Stanbic IBTC Bank in Nigeria, and different degrees of integrated models with
cooperation between banks, MNOs and possibly other players. In general, the MNO-led
model has led to a dramatic expansion in account penetration in countries like Kenya and
Tanzania.

There are also financial innovations in credit and insurance services, including the use of
psychometric assessments as a viable low-cost, automated screening tool to identify high-
potential entrepreneurs and agricultural insurance based on objective rainfall data. The
former allows for the use of additional data beyond scarce hard data, while the latter
overcomes the cost inefficiency of individual insurance incident verification. In the area of
small business lending, reverse factoring is promising where small enterprises can discount
invoices for larger enterprises, thus effectively financing themselves based on their larger
buyers’ reputation than their own (Klapper, 2006).

Beyond new delivery channels and products, new types of financial intermediaries can also
be a critical financial innovation, especially in terms of bringing new competition into the
financial system. These can be micro-deposit-taking institutions that graduate from semi-
formal but non-regulated NGO status into regulated financial institutions or telecoms that
offer mobile money services, such as in Uganda and Kenya, respectively.

How does financial innovation come about? Incumbent financial institutions are not
necessarily interested in innovating unless forced to do so by competitive pressure coming

23
from, e.g., new entrants into the financial system. Importantly, financial innovation cannot be
introduced per regulation, but is rather introduced by market players – mostly private, though
not always profit-oriented. Such innovation often comes from unexpected quarters. In Kenya,
Equity Bank transformed itself from an underperforming building society into an innovative
bank and is now the largest bank in the country in terms of clientele. It did this by offering
new delivery channels, such as mobile branches, by targeting a new clientele, and by
focusing on the quality of service delivery (Allen et al., 2013). These experiences suggest that
an open, contestable banking system is needed and that new providers might come from
outside the established market.

While regulation cannot drive innovation, it can encourage or prevent it. There are different
regulatory approaches towards innovation. The traditional regulatory approach is that of
“proper sequencing” - legislation-regulation-innovation. This process can take years,
however. An alternative approach is one of try-and-see or test-and-see, as applied by
regulators in Kenya with respect to M-Pesa. Such an approach is not to be confused with a
laissez-faire approach. It requires an open and flexible regulatory and supervisory approach
that balances the need for financial innovation with the need to watch for fragility emerging
in new forms. Such an approach can take into account the unexpectedness of innovation, in
terms of needs, technical possibilities and origin. As argued in a recent taskforce report on the
regulation of digital finance, financial innovation calls for a risk-based and functional
approach to regulation, ensuring that functionally similarly service providers are treated
equally as long as they pose similar risks to the consumers of the service or the financial
system as a whole (Center for Global Development, 2016). For example, payment services
should receive identical treatment, whether the provider is a bank or an MNO and whether it
operates online or from a brick-and-mortar office. It also implies that the regulation depends
on the type of services offered by different providers, with only deposit-taking institutions
that are (perceived to be) part of the financial safety net being subject to the same kind of
prudential regulation as banks.

6. The gender dimension

As pointed out throughout the paper, the gender dimension is critical in the discussion on
financial inclusion, both in terms of access to financial services across male and females and

24
in terms of female empowerment being an important outcome variable. This section
summarizes some of the cross-cutting issues in this respect.

First, females are, on average, less likely to have access to formal financial services than
males. At the same time, a large share of self-employed in developing countries is female and
thus in need of financing. Demirguc-Kunt, Klapper and Singer (2013) document a significant
gender gap in individual account holdings, though with significant variation across countries.
Aterido, Beck and Iacovone (2013), however, show for several Sub-Saharan African
countries, that this unconditional gender gap turns insignificant once one controls for other
characteristics, a finding that holds both for individual account holding and entrepreneurial
access to credit. In the case of enterprises, they explain this finding with a selection bias and
in the case of individuals with gender gaps in other dimensions related to the use of financial
services, such income, education, household and employment status. The findings for access
to entrepreneurial credit are matched by Bruhn (2009) for Latin America. However, gender
gaps in critical factors that determine access to formal financial services, including
employment and income status, legal restrictions (such as in asset ownership and holding in
some countries) and education, provide an important justification to focus efforts in financial
inclusion on female individuals and entrepreneurs and look beyond traditional banking
techniques focused on salaried, formally employed and educated individuals.

Beyond the lack of access to formal financial services by women, there are several other
reasons why the microfinance movement has focused on women. It has often been argued
that credit to female borrowers has more direct impact on household welfare than credit to
male borrowers as they care more about children and family. However, there is a trade-off
as documented by Kevane and Wydick (2011); women in childbearing age face higher time
constraints due to family commitments and are less likely to expand employment in their
micro-enterprise with credit than male micro-entrepreneurs or older women. Another reason
is that women are often restricted from access to formal financial services due to intra-
household restrictions, though this might also imply tailored solutions that protect women
against having to share credit or savings proceed freely within the household. Another,
supplier-focused, argument is that female borrowers constitute less of a credit risk, as they

25
are less mobile than men and often more conservative in their investment decision.11
Repayment rates in microfinance are typically higher for women than for men.12

The intra-household dimension has become increasingly important and has been explored in
recent field studies. Just to given some interesting examples: Schaner (2015) finds that well
matched Kenyan couples (in terms of time preferences) are more likely to use joint accounts
instead of costly individual ones. Ashraf (2009) finds in a field experiment in the Philippines
that men or women who do not make the savings decision in their respective households are
more likely to save a grant if given in private while they commit to consumption if given the
grant in public.

7. Conclusions

Improving financial inclusion requires measuring it. We have made enormous progress over
the past ten years in this endeavor but also realize that it is a constant learning process.

The experience over the past decade provides important lessons for data collection going
forward. Measuring financial inclusion accurately has to rely on survey data, which allow a
more in-depth look at the different dimensions of as well as barriers to financial inclusion,
but also requires a constant update in methodology as we dive deeper into the economics and
psychology of financial inclusion. To get a complete picture of access to and use of
financial services and the different barriers faced by individuals in a country, however,
different data sources as outlined in this paper are necessary. It is important to note the trade-
off between the frequency with which data can be collected and the accuracy. Survey-based
data such as the Global Findex can only be undertaken every few years but give the best
approximation to financial inclusion, while proxy indicators such as collected in the Financial
Access Surveys can be collected on a much higher frequency. Complementing both of these
with bank-level surveys would provide an even richer picture of different cost dimensions
and the choice of products available to customers, though such surveys face implementation
challenges as discussed above. Combining supply and demand-side data is critical to get a
complete picture of access to and use of financial services and barriers to it. It also allows the
critical distinction between pure ownership of accounts and their actual use. There is also a


11
For a more in-depth discussion, see chapter 7 in Aghion de Armendariz and Morduch (2007).
12
See for example Beck, Behr and Güttler (2013) with evidence from two MFIs in Albania and Bolivia that lend
to both men and women.

26
benefit of combining cross-country data with country-level data collection efforts, where the
latter allow for more in-depth and country-specific questions.

While there is a temptation to summarize the available information into a headline indicator,
a complete picture is better provided through a variety of select indicators that capture
different dimensions, including different barriers to access and inclusion across different sub-
groups of population.

As an increasing amount of data from different sources becomes available, there will be
challenges in how to “combine” them to get a proper picture of financial inclusion in a
country. Administrative and survey data, demand and supply-side indicators, aggregate and
micro-level data are different approaches to the overall puzzle of financial inclusion. As
much as we might wish for always consistent messages provided by these different data
sources, differences between the different sources and their findings might force a dynamic
approach to the gaps in financial inclusion and solutions to fill them. The access possibility
frontier presented above might serve as guiding framework in this context.

The experience with progress in measuring and gauging the effect of financial inclusion also
allows to draw some policy-relevant conclusions for the inclusion agenda. First, as important
as financial inclusion is for the development policy agenda, it is important to not ignore
financial deepening. Structural transformation of economies is more likely to come through
efficient and stable financial intermediaries and markets than by democratizing credit.

Second, within the area of financial inclusion, the empirical evidence so far and a tentative
cost-benefit analysis would point towards payment and savings services as the focus area.
Microcredit and micro-insurance services seem most appropriate if more targeted, such as
towards transformational entrepreneurs. In addition, it is important to look beyond supply
side constraints. While for a long time there has been an almost exclusive focus on supply-
side constraints, we have learned that demand-side constraints are as important. And as
financial innovation changes the nature of financial service provision, this has important
repercussion for measuring and tracking financial inclusion.

Third, following Goodhart’s Law (“When a measure becomes a target, it ceases to be a good
measure”) it would be false to focus exclusively on headline indicators such as the total
population share with a bank account. It is important to understand in this context that a
positive impact of financial inclusion on individual and aggregate welfare does not come
through the pure ownership of accounts but their active use.

27
Fourth and again related to the previous point, it is important to look beyond absolute levels
of the indicators on financial inclusion and benchmark them appropriately to properly assess
progress in inclusion and gauge the effect of policy reforms.

Finally, and discussed less in this paper, there are still important demand-side constraints,
related to culture and literacy that prevent individuals from using formal financial services
and that we still have to understand. Financial literacy – a topic I have not been able to
discuss in this short paper – has been identified as critical constraint, but the profession still
knows frustratingly little on how to improve it.

28
References

Aghion de Armendariz, Beatrix and Jonathan Morduch (2007) The Economics of


Microfinance. MIT Press.

Aker, Jenny, Rachid Boumnijel, Amanda McClelland and Niall Tierney (2013) How Do
Electronic Transfers Compare? Evidence from as Mobile Money Cash Transfer Experiment
in Niger. Tufts University Working Paper.

Allen, Franklin, Elena Carletti, Robert Cull, Jun Qian, Lemma Senbet and Patricio
Valanzuela. 2014. The African Financial Development and Financial Inclusion Gaps, Journal
of African Economies 23, 614-42.

Allen, Franklin, Elena Carletti, Robert Cull, Jun Qian, Lemma Senbet and Patricio
Valanzuela. 2013. Improving Access to Banking: Evidence from Kenya. Policy Research
Working Paper Series 6593, World Bank, Washington D.C.

Ashraf, Nava (2009) Spousal Control and Intra-Household Decision Making: An


Experimental Study in the Philippines, American Economic Review, 99, 1245–77, 2009.

Ashraf, Nava (2009) Spousal Control and Intra-Household Decision Making: An


Experimental Study in the Philippines, American Economic Review, 99, 1245–77, 2009.

Assuncao, Juliano. 2013. Eliminating Entry Barriers for the Provision of Banking Services:
Evidence from ‘Banking Correspondents’ in Brazil. Journal of Banking and Finance 37,
2806-11.

Aterido, Reyes, Thorsten Beck and Leonardo Iacovone (2013) Access to Finance in Sub-
Saharan Africa: Is There a Gender Gap? World Development 47, 102-120.

Ayyagari, Meghana, Thorsten Beck and Mohamad Hoseini. (2013). Finance and Poverty:
Evidence from India. CEPR Discussion Paper 9497.

Bacchetta, Philippe and Gerlach, Stefan (1997). Consumption and Credit Constraints:
International Evidence. Journal of Monetary Economics 40, 207-238.

Banerjee, Abhijit (2013) Microcredit Under the Microscope: What Have We Learned in the
Past Two Decades, and What Do We Need to Know? Annual Review of Economics, 5, 487–
519.

Banerjee, Abhijit V., Dean Karlan and Jonathan Zinman (2015) Six Randomized Evaluations
of Microcredit: Introduction and Further Steps, American Economic Journal: Applied
Economics 7, 1-21.

Barajas, Adolfo, Thorsten Beck, Era Dabla-Norris, and Seyed Reza Yousefi. 2013. Too Cold,
Too Hot, Or Just Right? Assessing Financial Sector Development Across the Globe. IMF
Working Paper 13/81

Beck, Thorsten (2009) The Econometrics of Finance and Growth, in: Terence Mills and
Kerry Patterson (Eds.): Palgrave Handbook of Econometrics, Vol. 2, Palgrave Macmillan.

29
Beck, Thorsten (2012) The Role of Finance in Economic Development – Benefits, Risks, and
Politics, in: Dennis Müller (Ed.): Oxford Handbook of Capitalism, 161-203.

Beck, Thorsten. 2015. Microfinance: A Critical Literature Survey. IEG Working Paper.
Beck, Thorsten, Patrick Behr and André Güttler (2013) Gender and Banking: Are Women
Better Loan Officers?, Review of Finance 17, 1279-1321

Beck, Thorsten and Augusto de la Torre. 2007. The Basic Analytics of Access to Financial
Service. Financial Markets, Institution and Instruments 17, 79-117.

Beck, Thorsten, Hans Degryse, Ralph De Haas and Neeltje van Horen, 2016a, When Arm’s
Length Is Too Far. Relationship Banking over the Credit Cycle. EBRD Working Paper.

Beck, Thorsten, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt, and Ross Levine (2007). Finance, Inequality and the
Poor: Cross-Country Evidence. Journal of Economic Growth 12, 27-49.

Beck, Thorsten, Ross Levine, and Alexey Levkov. (2010). Big Bad Banks? The Winners and
Losers from Bank Deregulation in the United States. Journal of Finance 65, 1637–1667.

Beck, Thorsten, Aslı Demirgüç-Kunt, and Vojislav Maksimovic. 2008. Financing Patterns
Around the World: Are Small Firms Different? Journal of Financial Economics 89,467-87.

Beck, Thorsten, Aslı Demirgüç-Kunt, and Vojislav Maksimovic. 2005. Financial and Legal
Constraints to Firm Growth: Does Firm Size Matter? Journal of Finance 60, 137-177.

Beck, Thorsten, Aslı Demirgüç-Kunt, and Vojislav Maksimovic. 2004. Bank Competition
and Access to Finance: International Evidence, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 36,
627-648.

Beck, Thorsten, Aslι Demirgüç-Kunt and Maria Soledad Martinez Peria (2008a) Banking
Services for Everyone? Barriers to Bank Access and Use around the World. World Bank
Economic Review 22, 397 - 430.

Beck T, Demirgüc-Kunt A, Martinez Peria M 2008b Bank financing for SMEs around the
world: drivers, obstacles, business models, and lending practices. World Bank Policy
Research Working Paper 4785

Beck, Thorsten, Aslı Demirgüç-Kunt, and Maria Soledad Martinez Peria. 2011. Banking
Financing for SMEs: Evidence Across Countries and Bank Ownership Types, Journal of
Financial Services Research 39, 35-54.

Beck, Thorsten, Erik H. B. Feyen, Alain Ize, and Florencia Moizeszowicz. 2008.
Benchmarking Financial Development. Policy Research Working Paper 4638, World Bank,
Washington, DC.

Beck, Thorsten, Erik H. B. Feyen. 2013 Benchmarking Financial Systems: Introducing the
Financial Possibility Frontier Policy Research Working Paper 6615 , World Bank,
Washington, DC.

30
Beck, Thorsten, Vasso Ioannidou and Larissa Schäfer. 2017. Foreigners vs. Natives: Bank
Lending Technologies and Loan Pricing, Management Science, forthcoming.

Beck, Thorsten, Haki Pumak, Ravindra Ramrattan and Burak Uras (2016b): Payment
Instruments, Enforceability and Development: Evidence form Mobile Money Technology,
Tilburg University.

Blumenstock, Joshua, Nathan Engle and Marcel Fafchamps (2013) Risk Sharing and Mobile
Phones: Evidence in the Aftermath of Natural Disasters. Working Paper

Bourreau, Marc, and Tommaso Valletti. 2015. Enabling Digital Financial Inclusion through
Improvements in Competition and Interoperability: What Works and What Doesn’t? CGD
Policy Paper No. 065. Center for Global Development, Washington, DC.

Bruhn, Miriam. (2009). Female-Owned Firms in Latin America: characteristics, performance,


and obstacles to growth. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 5122.

Bruhn, Miriam, (2013). A Tale of Two Species: Revisiting the Effect of Registration Reform
on Informal Business Owners in Mexico. Journal of Development Economics 103, 275-83.

Buera , Francisco J., Joseph P. Kaboski and Yongseok Shin (2012). The Macroeconomics of
Microfinance, NBER Working Paper 17905.

Center for Global Development (2016) Financial Regulation for Improving Financial
Inclusion. Washington DC.

CGAP (2011) Global Standard-Setting Bodies and Financial Inclusion for the Poor: Toward
Proportionate Standards and Guidance. Washington, DC.

Clarke, George, Robert Cull and Maria Soledad Martinez Peria, 2006. Foreign Bank
Participation and Access to Credit Across Firms in Developing Countries. Journal of
Comparative Economics 34, 774-795.

Collins, Darryl, Jonathan Morduch, Stuart Rutherford, and Orlanda Ruthven (2009)
Portfolios of the Poor: How the World’s Poor Live on $2 a Day, Princeton University Press

Cull Robert and Kinnon Scott. 2010. Measuring Households’ Usage of Financial Services:
Does it Matter How and Whom You Ask? World Bank Economic Review 24, 199-233.

De Mel, Suresh, David McKenzie and Chris Woodruff. (2010). Who Are the Microenterprise
Owners? Evidence from Sri Lanka on Tokman v. de Soto. In: Josh Lerner and Antoinette
Schoar (Eds.) International Differences in Entrepreneurship. University of Chicago Press,
63-88

Demirguc-Kunt, Asli and Leora Klapper, (2013). Measuring Financial Inclusion: The Global
Findex Database, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 6025.

Demirguc-Kunt, Asli, Leora Klapper and Dorothe Singer (2013). Financial Inclusion and
Legal Discrimination Against Women. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 6416.

31
Dupas, Pascaline and Jonathan Robinson (2013) Savings Constraints and Microenterprise
Development: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Kenya, American Economic Journal:
Applied Economics, 5, 163–92.

Emran, M. Shahe , A. K. M. Mahbub Morshed and Joseph E. Stiglitz (2007) Microfinance


and Missing Markets. Working Paper

Fisman, Raymond J., and Inessa Love. 2003. Trade Credit, Financial Intermediary
Development, and Industry Growth. Journal of Finance 58, 353–74.

Galor, Oded and Joseph Zeira, 1993, Income Distribution and Macroeconomics, Review of
Economic Studies 60, 35-52.

Giné, Xavier, and Robert M. Townsend. (2004). Evaluation of Financial Liberalization: A


General Equilibrium Model with Constrained Occupation Choice. Journal of Development
Economics 74, 269–307.

Ghatak, Maithreesh, and Timothy Guinnane. 1999. The Economics of Lending with Joint
Liability: Theory and Practice. Journal of Development Economics 60, 195–228.

Hsie, Chang-Tai and Peter J. Klenow. 2009. Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China
and India. Quarterly Journal of Economics 124, 1403-48.

Honohan, Patrick. 2006. Household Financial Assets in the Process of Development. Policy
Research Working Paper 3965, World Bank, Washington DC

Honohan, Patrick and Michael King, 2012.Cause and Effect of Financial Access: Cross-
Country Evidence from the FinScope Surveys, in: Robert Cull, Asli Demirguc-Kunt and
Jonathan Murdoch (Eds.): Banking the World: Empirical Foundations of Financial Inclusion,
45-84

Jack, William and Tanveer Suri (2014) Risk Sharing and Transaction Costs: Evidence from
Kenya’s Mobile Money Revolution, American Economic Review 104, 183-223.

Jappelli, Tullio and Marco Pagano (1989). Aggregate Consumption and Capital Market
Imperfections: An International Comparison. American Economic Review 79, 1088-1105.

Kaboski, Joseph P. and Robert M. Townsend (2012) The Impact of Credit on Village
Economies, American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 4, 98-133.

Kaboski, Joseph P. and Robert M. Townsend (2011) A Structural Evaluation of a Large


Scale Quasi- experimental Microfinance Initiative, Econometrica 79, 1357-1406

Karlan, Dean and Jonathan Morduch (2010) Access to Finance, in: Rodrik, Dani and Mark
Rosenzweig (Eds.): Handbook of Development Economics 4703-84, Elsevier

Karlan, Dean, Aishwarya Ratan and Jonathan Zinman (2014) Savings by and for the Poor: A
Research Review and Agenda, Review of Income and Wealth 60, 36-78.

32
Kevane, Michael and Bruce Wydick (2001) Social Norms and the Time Allocation of
Women’s Labor in Burkina Faso. Review of Development Economics 5. 119-129.

Klapper, Leora. 2006. The Role of “Reverse Factoring” in Supplier Financing of Small and
Medium Sized Enterprises. Journal of Banking and Finance 30, 3111-30.

Levine, Ross. (2005) Finance and Growth: Theory and Evidence. In Handbook of Economic
Growth, ed. Philippe Aghion and Steven N. Durlauf, 865–934. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

Love, Inessa and Maria Soledad Martinez Peria. 2015 How bank competition affects firms'
access to finance, World Bank Economic Review 29, 413-48.

Love, Inessa, Lorenzo A. Preve, and Virginia Sarria- Allende. 2007. Trade Credit and Bank
Credit: Evidence from Recent Financial Crises. Journal of Financial Economics 83, 453–69.

Ludvigson, Sydney (1999). Consumption and Credit: A Model of Time-Varying Liquidity


Constraints. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 81, 434-447.

Mian, Atif. 2006. Distance Constraints: the Limits of Foreign Lending in Poor Economies.
Journal of Finance 61, 1465-1505.

Pagano, Marco and Giovanni Pica (2012): Finance and Employment, Economic Policy 69, 5-
55.

Schaner, Simone (2015) Do Opposites Detract? Intrahousehold Preference Heterogeneity,


Commitment, and Inefficient Strategic Savings, American Economic Journal: Applied
Economics 7, 135-74.

Stiglitz, Joseph, and Andrew Weiss. 1981. Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect
Information. American Economic Review 7, 393–410.

Wydick, Bruce (1999) The Impact of Credit Access on the Use of Child Labor in Household
Enterprises: Evidence from Guatemala. Economic Development and Cultural Change 47,
853-69.

World Bank. 2006a. Measuring financial access: outlining the scope of current data
collection efforts. Washington D.C.

World Bank. 2006b. Indicators of Financial Access. Household - Level Surveys. Washington
D.C.

World Bank. 2007. Finance for All: Policies and Pitfalls in Expanding Access Policy
Research Report.

World Bank. 2013. Global Financial Development Report, Washington, D.C.

33

You might also like