Abstract
In this paper, we study a two-stage model in which a manufacturer expands to a new market through a local retailer and has private information on the advertising effectiveness. The manufacturer chooses the information sharing format with the retailer, either no information sharing or mandatory information sharing. Under no information sharing format, the manufacturer and the retailer play a signaling game. We derive both separating and pooling equilibria and conduct equilibrium refinements for the signaling game. Under mandatory information sharing format, the manufacturer simply informs the retailer the advertising effectiveness. We also establish the stylized model and derive the optimal advertising effort. By comparing the manufacturer’s ex ante profit under the two information sharing formats, we find that the manufacturer always prefers mandatory information sharing, under which both the advertising effort and profit can be higher. We also observe that unlike the common case that the channel members may have different preference over the information sharing formats, the manufacturer and the retailer can actually achieve alignment. While some previous studies suggest that the manufacturer and the retailer may have different preference over the information sharing formats, we find that they can actually achieve alignment with asymmetric information on advertising effectiveness.
Similar content being viewed by others
References
Anand, K. S., & Goyal, M. (2009). Strategic information management under leakage in a supply chain. Management Science, 55(3), 438–452.
Arnold, D. (2000). Seven rules of international distribution. Harvard Business Review, 78(6), 131–137.
Bakshi, N., Kim, S. H., & Savva, N. (2015). Signaling new product reliability with after-sales service contracts. Management Science, 61(8), 1812–1829.
Chen, F. (2003). Information sharing and supply chain coordination. Handbooks in Operations Research and Management Science, 11, 341–421.
Chiu, C. H., Choi, T. M., Dai, X., Shen, B., & Zheng, J. (2018). Optimal advertising budget allocation in luxury fashion markets with social influences. Production and Operations Management, 27(8), 1611–1629.
Chod, J., Trichakis, N., & Tsoukalas, G. (2019). Supplier diversification under buyer risk. Management Science, 65(7), 2947–3448.
Choi, T. M., Wang, M., & Yue, X. (2016). Emerging production optimization issues in supply chain systems. Annals of Operations Research, 240(2), 381–393.
Desai, P. S. (2000). Multiple messages to retain retailers: Signaling new product demand. Marketing Science, 19(4), 381–389.
Dong, C., Liu, Q., & Shen, B. (2019). To be or not to be green? Strategic investment for green product development in a supply chain. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, 131, 193–227.
Dong, C., Shen, B., Chow, P. S., Yang, L., & Ng, C. T. (2016). Sustainability investment under cap-and-trade regulation. Annals of Operations Research, 240(2), 509–531.
Dong, C., Yang, Y., & Zhao, M. (2018). Dynamic selling strategy for a firm under asymmetric information: Direct selling vs. agent selling. International Journal of Production Economics, 204, 204–213.
Ebrahim-Khanjari, N., Hopp, W., & Iravani, S. M. (2012). Trust and information sharing in supply chains. Production and Operations Management, 21(3), 444–464.
Gal-Or, E., Geylani, T., & Dukes, A. J. (2008). Information sharing in a channel with partially informed retailers. Marketing Science, 27(4), 642–658.
Gou, Q., Zhang, J., Liang, L., Huang, Z., & Ashley, A. (2014). Horizontal cooperative programmes and cooperative advertising. International Journal of Production Research, 52(3), 691–712.
Guo, X., & Jiang, B. (2016). Signaling through price and quality to consumers with fairness concerns. Journal of Marketing Research, 53(6), 988–1000.
Interband. (2019). Best global brands 2019: Iconic moves transforming customer expectations. https://www.interbrand.com/best-brands/best-global-brands/2019/.
Jiang, B., Ni, J., & Srinivasan, K. (2014). Signaling through pricing by service providers with social preferences. Marketing Science, 33(5), 641–654.
Jiang, B., Tian, L., Xu, Y., & Zhang, F. (2016). To share or not to share: Demand forecast sharing in a distribution channel. Marketing Science, 35(5), 800–809.
Jiang, B., & Yang, B. (2018). Quality and pricing decisions in a market with consumer information sharing. Management Science, 65(1), 272–285.
Lai, X., Tao, Y., Wang, F., & Zou, Z. (2019). Sustainability investment in maritime supply chain with risk behavior and information sharing. International Journal of Production Economics, 218, 16–29.
Lal, R., & Narasimhan, C. (1996). The inverse relationship between manufacturer and retailer margins: A theory. Marketing Science, 15(2), 132–151.
Li, Q. (2018). The optimal multi-period modular design with fairness concerns. International Journal of Production Economics, 206, 233–249.
Li, Z., Gilbert, S. M., & Lai, G. (2014). Supplier encroachment under asymmetric information. Management Science, 60(2), 449–462.
Li, Q., Li, B., Chen, P., & Hou, P. (2017). Dual-channel supply chain decisions under asymmetric information with a risk-averse retailer. Annals of Operations Research, 257(1–2), 423–447.
Li, L., & Zhang, H. (2008). Confidentiality and information sharing in supply chain coordination. Management Science, 54(8), 1467–1481.
Li, G., Zheng, H., Sethi, S. P., & Guan, X. (2018). Inducing downstream information sharing via manufacturer information acquisition and retailer subsidy. Decision Sciences, 51(3), 691–719.
Li, Q., & Zhou, J. (2019). A horizontal capacity reservation game under asymmetric information. International Journal of Production Research, 57(4), 1103–1118.
Lu, L., Gou, Q., Tang, W., & Zhang, J. (2016). Joint pricing and advertising strategy with reference price effect. International Journal of Production Research, 54(17), 5250–5270.
Ma, S., Li, G., Sethi, S. P., & Zhao, X. (2019). Advance selling in the presence of market power and risk-averse consumers. Decision Sciences, 50(1), 142–169.
Mailath, G. J., Okuno-Fujiwara, M., & Postlewaite, A. (1993). Belief-based refinements in signalling games. Journal of Economic Theory, 60(2), 241–276.
Nair, A., & Narasimhan, R. (2006). Dynamics of competing with quality-and advertising-based goodwill. European Journal of Operational Research, 175(1), 462–474.
Pepper, J. (2012). Russian tide: Building a leadership business in the midst of unprecedented change. Cincinnati, OH: John Pepper.
Riley, J. (2013). How did P&G reach the top in China? https://www.tutor2u.net/business/blog/how-did-pg-reach-the-top-in-china.
Shen, B., Choi, T. M., & Chan, H. L. (2019a). Selling green first or not? A Bayesian analysis with service levels and environmental impact considerations in the big data era. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 144, 412–420.
Shen, B., Choi, T. M., & Minner, S. (2019b). A review on supply chain contracting with information considerations: Information updating and information asymmetry. International Journal of Production Research, 57(15–16), 4898–4936.
Shen, B., Liu, S., Zhang, T., & Choi, T. M. (2019c). Optimal advertising and pricing for new green products in the circular economy. Journal of Cleaner Production, 233, 314–327.
Shi, X., Chan, H. L., & Dong, C. (2020). Value of bargaining contract in a supply chain system with sustainability investment: An incentive analysis. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics: Systems, 50(4), 1622–1634.
Sun, X., Tang, W., Chen, J., Li, S., & Zhang, J. (2019). Manufacturer encroachment with production cost reduction under asymmetric information. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, 128, 191–211.
Tian, L., & Jiang, B. (2017). Comment on “Strategic information management under leakage in a supply chain”. Management Science, 63(12), 4258–4260.
UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development). (2019). Key statistics and trends in international trade 2018: International trade rebounds. https://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/ditctab2019d2_en.pdf.
WTO (World Trade Organization). (2019). World Trade Statistical Review 2019: Highlights of world trade. https://www.wto.org/english/res_e/statis_e/wts2019_e/wts2019chapter02_e.pdf.
Xie, J., & Wei, J. C. (2009). Coordinating advertising and pricing in a manufacturer–retailer channel. European Journal of Operational Research, 197(2), 785–791.
Yan, Y., Zhao, R., & Lan, Y. (2017). Asymmetric retailers with different moving sequences: Group buying vs. individual purchasing. European Journal of Operational Research, 261(3), 903–917.
Zhang, J., Gou, Q., Liang, L., & Huang, Z. (2013). Supply chain coordination through cooperative advertising with reference price effect. Omega, 41(2), 345–353.
Zhang, J., Li, S., Zhang, S., & Dai, R. (2019). Manufacturer encroachment with quality decision under asymmetric demand information. European Journal of Operational Research, 273(1), 217–236.
Zhao, D., & Li, Z. (2018). The impact of manufacturer’s encroachment and nonlinear production cost on retailer’s information sharing decisions. Annals of Operations Research, 264(1–2), 499–539.
Acknowledgements
This research was supported in part by the National Natural Science Foundation of China under the Grant Nos. 71871052, 71832001, the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities and DHU Distinguished Young Professor Program.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Appendix
Appendix
Proof of Proposition 1
Recall that the retailer’s best response retailing price to the manufacturer’s advertising effort \( e \) is \( p_{j} \left( {e;w} \right) = \frac{{a + \beta_{j} e + bw}}{2b} \), and given this price the manufacturer’s profit \( {{\Pi }}_{ij}^{M} \left( {e;w} \right) \) is given by (1). We then derive the manufacturer’s optimal advertising effort by maximizing \( {{\Pi }}_{ij}^{M} \left( {e;w} \right) \). Taking the first- and second-order derivatives over \( e \) on Eq. (1), we have
Thus, for any given \( w \), \( {{\Pi }}_{ij}^{M} \left( {e;w} \right) \) is concave in \( e \), and the optimal advertising effort can be obtained by solving \( \frac{{d{{\Pi }}_{ij}^{M} \left( {e;w} \right)}}{de} = 0 \). We have \( e_{ij} \left( w \right) = \frac{{\left( {2\beta_{i} - \beta_{j} } \right)w}}{4k} \). Substituting it to \( p_{j} \left( {e;w} \right) \), we have \( p_{j} \left( w \right) = \frac{{4k\left( {a + bw} \right) + \left( {2\beta_{i} - \beta_{j} } \right)\beta_{j} w}}{8kb} \). The manufacturer and the retailer’s profits can then be obtained directly by using \( e_{ij} \left( w \right) \) and \( p_{j} \left( w \right) \). □
Proof of Proposition 2
Recall that we consider the following belief structure for the retailer: If \( e \le \hat{e}^{sep} \), then the retailer believes that the advertising effectiveness is \( \beta_{l} \); and if \( e > \hat{e}^{sep} \), then the retailer believes that the advertising effectiveness is \( \beta_{h} \). Under this belief structure, a perfect Bayesian separating equilibrium exists if and only \( \hat{e}^{sep} \ge 0 \) and the following constraints are satisfied
and
Condition (A1) requires that the \( h \)-type manufacturer cannot make a higher profit if it mimics the \( l \)-type one, and condition (A2) requires that the \( l \)-type manufacturer cannot make a higher profit if it mimics the \( h \)-type one. These two conditions guarantee that the manufacturer can achieve separating.
Consider condition (A1). For any belief structure with \( \hat{e}^{sep} \ge e_{hh} \), we have
where the first inequality holds because \( \hat{e}^{sep} \ge e_{hh} \) and \( e_{hl} > e_{hh} \), the second inequality holds because \( {{\Pi }}_{hl}^{M} \left( e \right) > {{\Pi }}_{hh}^{M} \left( e \right) \) for any \( e \), and the last inequality holds because \( \hat{e}^{sep} \ge e_{hh} \); see also Fig. 2 for illustration. In this case, condition (A1) can never be satisfied. Thus, we restrict our attention to the case \( \hat{e}^{sep} < e_{hh} \), with which \( \mathop {\hbox{max} }\limits_{{e > \hat{e}^{sep} }} {{\Pi }}_{hh}^{M} \left( e \right) = {{\Pi }}_{hh}^{M} \). Then, from (1) and (2), condition (A1) can be rewritten as
which implies that
See Fig. 2 for the illustration. This threshold corresponds to \( x \)-axis value of the intersection point that the horizontal line \( y = {{\Pi }}_{hh}^{M} \left( {e_{hh} } \right) \) crossing the curve \( {{\Pi }}_{hl}^{M} \left( e \right) \).
Regarding the \( h \)-type manufacturer’s profit, we can easily check that
Clearly, it is optimal for the \( h \)-type manufacturer to set \( e_{h}^{sep} = \frac{{\beta_{h} w}}{4k} \). Regarding the \( l \)-type manufacturer’s profit \( {{\Pi }}_{ll}^{M} \left( e \right) \), Proposition 1 shows that \( {{\Pi }}_{ll}^{M} \left( e \right) \) is concave in \( e \) and \( \arg \mathop {\hbox{max} }\limits_{e} {{\Pi }}_{ll}^{M} \left( e \right) = \frac{{\beta_{l} w}}{4k} \). Thus, the \( l \)-type manufacturer’s decision depends on the magnitude between \( \frac{{\beta_{l} w}}{4k} \) and the threshold \( \bar{e}^{sep} . \)
-
If \( \bar{e}^{sep} \le \frac{{\beta_{l} w}}{4k} \), i.e., \( 1 < \theta \le 3 \), then \( {{\Pi }}_{ll}^{M} \left( e \right) \) increases for \( e \le \hat{e}^{sep} \), and thus \( \mathop {\hbox{max} }\limits_{{e \le \hat{e}^{sep} }} {{\Pi }}_{ll}^{M} \left( e \right) = {{\Pi }}_{ll}^{M} \left( {\hat{e}^{sep} } \right) \). In this case, condition (A2) is more likely to be satisfied with a larger \( \hat{e}^{sep} \). Thus, we can set \( \hat{e}^{sep} = \bar{e}^{sep} \), and let \( e_{l}^{sep} = \hat{e}^{sep} \) to get the most profitable equilibrium outcome for the manufacturer.
-
If \( \bar{e}^{sep} > \frac{{\beta_{l} w}}{4k} \), i.e., \( \theta > 3 \), then \( {{\Pi }}_{ll}^{M} \left( e \right) \) reaches its global maximum value for \( e \le \hat{e}^{sep} \), i.e., \( \mathop {\hbox{max} }\limits_{{e \le \hat{e}^{sep} }} {{\Pi }}_{ll}^{M} \left( e \right) = {{\Pi }}_{ll}^{M} \left( {\frac{{\beta_{l} w}}{4k}} \right) \). In this case, condition (A2) is clearly satisfied. See Fig. 2 for the illustration. Thus, it is most profitable for the manufacturer to set \( \hat{e}^{sep} = \frac{{\beta_{l} w}}{4k} \), and then let \( e_{l}^{sep} = \hat{e}^{sep} \).
To summarize, Proposition 2 is proved. □
Proof of Proposition 3
Recall that the retailer’s belief structure on pooling is as follows. If \( e \le \hat{e}^{pool} \), then the retailer cannot update his prior belief; and if \( e > \hat{e}^{pool} \), then the retailer believes that the advertising effectiveness is \( \beta_{h} \). Under this belief structure, there exists a perfect Bayesian pooling equilibrium if and only if \( \hat{e}^{pool} \ge 0 \) and the following constraints are satisfied
and
Conditions (A4) and (A5) ensure that both the \( h \)-type manufacturer and the \( l \)-type manufacturer achieve the most profitable outcome at \( \hat{e}^{pool} \). Condition (A6) guarantees that the \( h \)-type manufacturer wants to pool, because pooling is more profitable than separating; and condition (A7) makes sure that the \( l \)-type manufacturer also wants to pool, because pooling is more profitable than being regarded as the \( h \)-type one.
Before investigating the conditions (A4)–(A6), we first show the relation among the profit functions \( {{\Pi }}_{ih}^{M} \left( e \right) \), \( {{\Pi }}_{il}^{M} \left( e \right) \), and \( {{\Pi }}_{ip}^{M} \left( e \right) \) for \( i = h,l. \) From (1) and (5), it is easy to show that
and \( e_{il} \left( w \right) > e_{ip} \left( w \right) > e_{ih} \left( w \right) \). See Fig. 6 for the illustration.
Consider conditions (A4) and (A5). From (5), it is easy to see that when the \( i \)-type manufacturer chooses to pool, the profit \( {{\Pi }}_{ip}^{M} \left( e \right) \) is concave in \( e \), and the first best advertising effort is \( e_{ip} = \frac{{\left( {2\beta_{i} - \mu } \right)^{ + } w}}{4k} \), where \( i = h.l \). Then, to have the conditions (A4) and (A5) be satisfied, we must have
Next, we discuss the conditions (A6) and (A7).
Recall that \( {{\Pi }}_{hh}^{M} \left( e \right) \) attains the maximum value at \( \frac{{\beta_{h} w}}{4k} \). From (A9) and \( \beta_{h} - \left( {2\beta_{l} - \mu } \right) = \left( {1 + \alpha } \right)\left( {\beta_{h} - \beta_{l} } \right) > 0 \), we have \( \frac{{\beta_{h} w}}{4k} > e_{lp} \ge \hat{e}^{pool} \). Thus, regarding the right-hand side of (A6), we have
Note also that \( {{\Pi }}_{hp}^{M} \left( e \right) \) is concave in \( e \). Thus, (A9) implies that \( {{\Pi }}_{hp}^{M} \left( e \right) \) increases for \( e \le \hat{e}^{pool} \). Thus,
Therefore, from the above two equations,
To have condition (A6) satisfied, we let \( \mathop {\hbox{max} }\limits_{{e \le \hat{e}^{pool} }} {{\Pi }}_{hp}^{M} \left( e \right) - \mathop {\hbox{max} }\limits_{{e > \hat{e}^{pool} }} {{\Pi }}_{hh}^{M} \left( e \right) \ge 0 \) and obtain
Regarding condition (A7), first note from (A9) that \( \mathop {\hbox{max} }\limits_{{e \le \hat{e}^{pool} }} {{\Pi }}_{lp}^{M} \left( e \right) = {{\Pi }}_{lp}^{M} \left( {\hat{e}^{pool} } \right) \). From Proposition 1, \( {{\Pi }}_{lh}^{M} \left( e \right) \) attains the maximum value at \( e_{lh} = \frac{{\left( {2\beta_{l} - \beta_{h} } \right)^{ + } w}}{4k} \le \frac{{\left( {2\beta_{l} - \mu } \right)^{ + } w}}{4k} = e_{lp} \). Thus, the value of the left-hand side of (A7) depends on the magnitude between \( e_{lh} \) and \( \hat{e}^{pool} \) as detailed in the following two subcases.
-
If \( e_{lh} < \hat{e}^{pool} \), i.e., \( \frac{{\left( {2\beta_{l} - \beta_{h} } \right)^{ + } w}}{4k} < \hat{e}^{pool} \), then \( \mathop {\hbox{max} }\limits_{{e > \hat{e}^{pool} }} {{\Pi }}_{lh}^{M} \left( e \right) = {{\Pi }}_{lh}^{M} \left( {\hat{e}^{pool} } \right) \). In this case, condition (A7) turns to be \( {{\Pi }}_{lp}^{M} \left( {\hat{e}^{pool} } \right) \ge {{\Pi }}_{lh}^{M} \left( {\hat{e}^{pool} } \right) \), which clearly holds from (A8); see Fig. 6 for the illustration. Therefore, in this subcase, condition (A7) holds if \( \frac{{\left( {2\beta_{l} - \beta_{h} } \right)^{ + } w}}{4k} < \hat{e}^{pool} . \)
-
If \( \hat{e}^{pool} \le e_{lh} \), i.e., \( \hat{e}^{pool} \le \frac{{\left( {2\beta_{l} - \beta_{h} } \right)^{ + } w}}{4k} \), then \( \mathop {\hbox{max} }\limits_{{e > \hat{e}^{pool} }} {{\Pi }}_{lh}^{M} \left( e \right) = {{\Pi }}_{lh}^{M} \left( {e_{lh} } \right) \). In this case, condition (A7) turns to be \( {{\Pi }}_{lp}^{M} \left( {\hat{e}^{pool} } \right) \ge {{\Pi }}_{lh}^{M} \left( {e_{lh} } \right) \), i.e.,
One can show that only if \( \theta \le 1 + \frac{2}{1 + \alpha } \), the above inequality is valid for the \( \hat{e}^{pool} \) such that
Recall that this subcase requires \( \hat{e}^{pool} \le \frac{{\left( {2\beta_{l} - \beta_{h} } \right)^{ + } w}}{4k} \). It is easy to show that
Therefore, in this subcase, condition (A7) requires that
Combining the above two subcases, if \( \theta \le 1 + \frac{2}{1 + \alpha } \), then the validity of condition (A7) requires that
if \( \theta > 1 + \frac{2}{1 + \alpha } \), then the validity of condition (A7) requires that
To summarize, a pooling equilibrium, if exists, shall satisfy (A9), (A10), and either (A11) or (A12), depending on whether \( \theta \le 1 + \frac{2}{1 + \alpha } \) or \( \theta > 1 + \frac{2}{1 + \alpha } \). If \( \theta \le 1 + \frac{2}{1 + \alpha } \), which implies that \( \theta < 3 \), then we can show that \( \frac{{w\left[ {\left( {2\beta_{h} - \mu } \right) - \sqrt {\left( {3\beta_{h} - \mu } \right)\left( {\beta_{h} - \mu } \right)} } \right]}}{4k} > \frac{{\left[ {\left( {2\beta_{l} - \mu } \right) - \sqrt {\left( {\beta_{h} - \mu } \right)\left( {4\beta_{l} - \beta_{h} - \mu } \right)} } \right]w}}{4k} \). Thus, the solution set satisfying (A9), (A10), and (A11) is
If \( \theta > 1 + \frac{2}{1 + \alpha } \), which implies that \( \theta > 2 \), then we can show that \( \frac{{\left( {2\beta_{l} - \beta_{h} } \right)^{ + } w}}{4k} = 0 < \frac{{w\left[ {\left( {2\beta_{h} - \mu } \right) - \sqrt {\left( {3\beta_{h} - \mu } \right)\left( {\beta_{h} - \mu } \right)} } \right]}}{4k} \). Thus, the solution set satisfying (A9), (A10), and (A12) is
Note that the inequalities (A13) and (A14) are identical. Therefore, a pooling equilibrium exists if
from which we obtain \( \theta \le \frac{1 + \alpha }{\alpha } \) and \( \theta \le \frac{{\alpha^{2} - 2\alpha - 3}}{{\alpha^{2} - 4\alpha - 1}} \), respectively. It is easy to check that that \( \frac{{\alpha^{2} - 2\alpha - 3}}{{\alpha^{2} - 4\alpha - 1}} < \frac{1 + \alpha }{\alpha } \). Thus, a pooling equilibrium exists if \( \theta \le \frac{{\alpha^{2} - 2\alpha - 3}}{{\alpha^{2} - 4\alpha - 1}} \), i.e., \( \theta \le \bar{\theta }\left( \alpha \right). \)
In this case, the manufacturer’s most profitable pooling equilibrium is to set \( \hat{e}^{pool} = \frac{{\left( {2\beta_{l} - \mu } \right)^{ + } w}}{4k} \), and let \( e^{pool} = \hat{e}^{pool} \). Proposition 3 is proved. □
Proof of Proposition 4
When \( \theta \le \bar{\theta }\left( \alpha \right) \), where \( \bar{\theta }\left( \alpha \right) = \frac{{3 + 2\alpha - \alpha^{2} }}{{1 + 4\alpha - \alpha^{2} }} \in \left[ {1,3} \right] \), there exist pooling and separating equilibria for the manufacturer. The LMSE selects the equilibrium that is more profitable for the \( l \)-type manufacturer. Thus, to prove Proposition 4, it suffices to show that the \( l \)-type manufacturer makes a higher profit when she chooses pooling rather than separating, if and only if \( 1 < \theta \le \bar{\theta }\left( \alpha \right) \).
Consider an \( l \)-type manufacturer. From Proposition 3, the pooling profit is
and from Proposition 2, the separating profit (note the \( l \)-type manufacturer conducts costly separating when \( \theta \le \bar{\theta }\left( \alpha \right) \) is
Therefore, we have
Recall that \( \theta > 1 \). Thus, to have \( {{\Pi }}_{lp}^{M} \left( {e^{pool} } \right) - {{\Pi }}_{ll}^{M} \left( {e_{l}^{sep} } \right) \ge 0 \) is equivalent to have
Recall that \( 0 \le \alpha \le 1 \) and \( \theta > 1 \), which implies that the left-hand side of the above inequality is no negative. Therefore, the above inequality is equivalent to
solving which we obtain
Recall the definition of \( \overline{\overline{\theta }} \left( \alpha \right) \), and it is easy to check that \( \frac{{\alpha^{4} + 2\alpha^{3} + 12\alpha^{2} + 14\alpha + 8\sqrt {\alpha + 2\alpha^{2} + \alpha^{3} } + 3}}{{\alpha^{4} + 14\alpha^{2} + 1}} > 3 > \bar{\theta }\left( \alpha \right) \). Therefore, the condition to have \( {{\Pi }}_{lp}^{M} \left( {e^{pool} } \right) \ge {{\Pi }}_{ll}^{M} \left( {e_{l}^{sep} } \right) \) is \( \theta \le \overline{\overline{\theta }} \left( \alpha \right). \) Proposition 4 is proved. □
Proof of Proposition 5
We drive the optimal ex ante wholesale prices according to the value of \( \theta \). Case (i): \( \theta \le \overline{\overline{\theta }}(\alpha) \). In this case, the manufacturer will pool. Thus, the manufacturer’s ex ante expected profit is
Taking the first- and second-order derivatives on the above equation, we obtain
and
The last inequality holds from \( k > \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\alpha \theta^{2} + 1 - \alpha } \right)/8b \), and
Thus, \( {{\Pi }}^{M} \left( w \right) \) is concave, and the optimal wholesale price can be determined from the first-best condition. We obtain \( w = \frac{4ak}{{8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \left[ {1 + 2\alpha \left( {\theta - 1} \right) - 3\alpha^{2} \left( {\theta - 1} \right)^{2} } \right]}}. \)
With the optimal ex ante \( w \), it is easy to check that the optimal advertising effort and the optimal retailing price are \( e^{pool} = \frac{{a\beta_{l} \left( {1 + \alpha - \alpha \theta } \right)}}{{8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \left[ {1 + 2\alpha \left( {\theta - 1} \right) - 3\alpha^{2} \left( {\theta - 1} \right)^{2} } \right]}} \) and \( p_{p} = \frac{{a\left\{ {6bk + \alpha \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\theta - 1} \right)\left[ {\alpha \left( {\theta - 1} \right) - 1} \right]} \right\}}}{{b\left\{ {8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \left[ {1 + 2\alpha \left( {\theta - 1} \right) - 3\alpha^{2} \left( {\theta - 1} \right)^{2} } \right]} \right\}}} \), respectively.
Case (ii): \( \bar{\bar\theta}(\alpha) < \theta \le 3 \). In this case, the manufacturer achieves costly separating, and the manufacturer’s ex ante expected profit is
Taking the first- and second-order derivatives on the above equation, we have
and
Recall that we assume \( k > \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\alpha \theta^{2} + 1 - \alpha } \right)/8b \), and we can check that
Thus, we have \( \frac{{d^{2} {{\Pi }}^{M} \left( w \right)}}{{dw^{2} }} < 0 \). Then, the optimal wholesale price can be determined from the first-best condition. We obtain \( w = \frac{4ak}{{8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} {{\gamma }}}}. \)
With the optimal ex ante \( w \), it is easy to obtain that the \( h \)-type manufacturer and the \( l \)-type manufacturer’s optimal advertising effort are \( e_{h}^{sep} = \frac{{a\beta_{l} \theta }}{{8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \gamma }} \) and \( e_{l}^{sep} = \frac{{a\beta_{l} \left( {2\theta - 1 - \sqrt {\left( {\theta - 1} \right)\left( {3\theta - 1} \right)} } \right)}}{{8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \gamma }} \), and the optimal retailing prices are \( p_{h} = \frac{{a\left[ {12bk + \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\theta^{2} - \gamma } \right)} \right]}}{{2b\left( {8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \gamma } \right)}} \) and \( p_{l} = \frac{{a\left[ {12bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {1 + \gamma - 2\theta + \sqrt {\left( {\theta - 1} \right)\left( {3\theta - 1} \right)} } \right)} \right]}}{{2b\left( {8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \gamma } \right)}} \).
Case (iii): \( \theta > 3 \). In this case, the manufacturer will attain costless separating, and the manufacturer’s ex ante expected profit is
Taking the first- and second-order derivatives on the above equation, we have
and
where the last inequality holds from \( k > \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\alpha \theta^{2} + 1 - \alpha } \right)/8b \). Then, the optimal wholesale price can be determined from the first-best condition. We obtain \( w = \frac{4ak}{{8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\alpha \theta^{2} + 1 - \alpha } \right)}} \).
With the optimal ex ante \( w \), it is easy to obtain that the \( h \)-type manufacturer and the \( l \)-type manufacturer’s optimal advertising effort are \( e_{h}^{sep} = \frac{{a\beta_{l} \theta }}{{8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\alpha \theta^{2} + 1 - \alpha } \right)}} \) and \( e_{l}^{sep} = \frac{{a\beta_{l} }}{{8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\alpha \theta^{2} + 1 - \alpha } \right)}} \), and the optimal retailing prices are \( p_{h} = \frac{{a\left[ {12bk + \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\theta^{2} - 1} \right)} \right]}}{{2{\text{b}}\left[ {8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\alpha \theta^{2} + 1 - \alpha } \right)} \right]}} \) and \( p_{l} = \frac{{a\left[ {12bk - \alpha \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\theta^{2} - 1} \right)} \right]}}{{2b\left[ {8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\alpha \theta^{2} + 1 - \alpha } \right)} \right]}} \). □
Proof of Proposition 8
From (1), the manufacturer’s ex ante profit is
Take the first- and second-order derivatives on the above equation, we have
and
where the last inequality holds from \( k > \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\alpha \theta^{2} + 1 - \alpha } \right)/8b \). Then, the optimal wholesale price can be determined by letting \( \frac{{d{\tilde{{\Pi }}}^{M} \left( w \right)}}{dw} = 0 \), which implies that \( \tilde{w} = \frac{4ak}{{8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\alpha \theta^{2} + 1 - \alpha } \right)}} \).Substituting \( \tilde{w} \) to (A15), we have \( {\tilde{{\Pi }}}^{M} = \frac{{a^{2} k}}{{8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\alpha \theta^{2} + 1 - \alpha } \right)}}. \) □
Proof of Proposition 9
We compare \( {\tilde{{\Pi }}}^{M} \) and \( {{\Pi }}^{M} \) for different values of \( \theta \).
If \( \theta \le \overline{\overline{\theta }}(\alpha) \), from Proposition 5, \( {{\Pi }}^{M} = \frac{{a^{2} k}}{{8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \left[ {1 + 2\alpha \left( {\theta - 1} \right) - 3\alpha^{2} \left( {\theta - 1} \right)^{2} } \right]}}. \) Thus, we have
In the right-hand side of (A16), the denominator \( k - \frac{{\beta_{l}^{2} }}{8b}\left( {\alpha \theta^{2} + 1 - \alpha } \right) > 0 \) from assumption \( k > \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\alpha \theta^{2} + 1 - \alpha } \right)/8b \), and the numerator \( \frac{{\beta_{l}^{2} }}{8b}\alpha \left( {1 + 3\alpha } \right)\left( {\theta - 1} \right)^{2} > 0 \) has been shown in proof of Proposition 5. Therefore, the right-hand side of (A15) is greater than 1, i.e., \( \frac{{{\tilde{{\Pi }}}^{M} }}{{{{\Pi }}^{M} }} > 1 \). In this case, we have \( {\tilde{{\Pi }}}^{M} > {{\Pi }}^{M} . \)
If \( \overline{\overline{\theta }}(\alpha) < \theta \le 3 \), from Proposition 5, \( {{\Pi }}^{M} = \frac{{a^{2} k}}{{8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \gamma }} \). In this case, we have
In the right-hand side of (A17), the denominator \( k - \frac{{\beta_{l}^{2} }}{8b}\left( {\alpha \theta^{2} + 1 - \alpha } \right) > 0 \) from assumption \( k > \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\alpha \theta^{2} + 1 - \alpha } \right)/8b \), and the numerator \( \frac{{\beta_{l}^{2} }}{8b}\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\theta - 1} \right)\left( {7\theta - 4\sqrt {1 - 4\theta + 3\theta^{2} } - 5} \right) > 0 \) has been shown in the proof of Proposition 5. Thus, Therefore, the right-hand side of (A17) is greater than 1. In this case, \( {\tilde{{\Pi }}}^{M} > {{\Pi }}^{M} \).
If \( \theta > 3 \), from Propositions 5 and 7, we have \( {\tilde{{\Pi }}}^{M} = {{\Pi }}^{M} \).
To summarize, we always have \( {\tilde{{\Pi }}}^{M} \ge {{\Pi }}^{M} \). □
Proof of Proposition 10
We establish the proof by considering the \( h \)-type manufacturer and the \( l \)-type manufacturer separately.
First, we consider the \( h \)-type manufacturer. From Table 1 and Proposition 7, we have
Recall that in the proof of Proposition 9, we have shown that \( \frac{{8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \left[ {1 + 2\alpha \left( {\theta - 1} \right) - 3\alpha^{2} \left( {\theta - 1} \right)^{2} } \right]}}{{8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\alpha \theta^{2} + 1 - \alpha } \right)}} > 1 \) and \( \frac{{8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \gamma }}{{8bk - \beta_{l}^{2} \left( {\alpha \theta^{2} + 1 - \alpha } \right)}} > 1 \). Also, it is easy to demonstrate that \( \theta - \left( {1 + \alpha - \alpha \theta } \right) = \left( {1 + \alpha } \right)\left( {\theta - 1} \right) > 0 \), which implies that \( \frac{\theta }{{\left( {1 + \alpha - \alpha \theta } \right)}} > 1 \). Thus, for the \( h \)-type manufacturer, we always have \( \frac{{\tilde{e}}}{e} \ge 1 \), i.e., \( e \le \tilde{e}. \)
Second, we consider the \( l \)-type manufacturer. Similarly, from Table 1 and Proposition 7, we have
It is easy to show that \( \frac{1}{{\left( {1 + \alpha - \alpha \theta } \right)}} > 1 \) and \( \frac{1}{{2\theta - 1 - \sqrt {\left( {\theta - 1} \right)\left( {3\theta - 1} \right)} }} \ge 1 \) for any \( \theta \le 3 \). Thus, in this case, \( \frac{{\tilde{e}}}{e} \ge 1 \), i.e., \( e \le \tilde{e} \).
To summarize, we always have \( e \le \tilde{e} \). □
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Li, Q., Ding, H., Shi, T. et al. To share or not to share: the optimal advertising effort with asymmetric advertising effectiveness. Ann Oper Res 329, 249–276 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-020-03711-8
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-020-03711-8