Abstract
Group decision making has been widely studied since group decision making processes are very common in many fields. Formal representation of the experts’ opinions, aggregation of assessments or selection of the best alternatives has been some of main areas addressed by scientists and researchers. In this paper, we focus on another promising area, the study of group decision making processes from the concept of influence and social networks. In order to do so, we present a novel model that gathers the experts’ initial opinions and provides a framework to represent the influence of a given expert over the other(s). With this proposal it is feasible to estimate both the evolution of the group decision making process and the final solution before carrying out the group discussion process and consequently foreseeing possible actions.
Similar content being viewed by others
Explore related subjects
Discover the latest articles, news and stories from top researchers in related subjects.References
Alonso S, Cabrerizo FJ, Chiclana F, Herrera F, Herrera-Viedma E (2009) Group decision making with incomplete fuzzy linguistic preference relations. Int J Intell Syst 24(2):201–222
Alonso S, Herrera-Viedma E, Chiclana F, Herrera F (2010) A web based consensus support system for group decision making problems and incomplete preferences. Inf Sci 180(23):4477–4495
Bezdek JC, Spillman B, Spillman R (1978) A fuzzy relation space for group decision theory. Fuzzy Sets Syst 1(4):255–268
Cabrerizo F, Chiclana F, Al-Hmouz R, Morfeq A, Balamash A, Herrera-Viedma E (2015) Fuzzy decision making and consensus: challenges. J Intell Fuzzy Syst 29(3):1109–1118
Cabrerizo F, Moreno J, Pérez I, Herrera-Viedma E (2010) Analyzing consensus approaches in fuzzy group decision making: advantages and drawbacks. Soft Comput 14(5):451–463
Calza F, Gaeta M, Loia V, Orciuoli F, Piciocchi P, Rarità L, Spohrer J, Tommasetti A (2015) Fuzzy consensus model for governance in smart service systems. Procedia Manuf 3:3567–3574
Chiclana F, Herrera-Viedma E, Alonso S, Herrera F (2007) Consistency of reciprocal preference relations. In: 2007 IEEE International Conference on Fuzzy Systems, FUZZY
Chiclana F, Herrera-Viedma E, Alonso S, Herrera F (2008) A note on the estimation of missing pairwise preference values: a uninorm consistency based method. Int J Uncertain Fuzziness Knowledge-Based Syst 16(SUPPL.2):19–32
Chiclana F, Herrera-Viedma E, Alonso S, Herrera F (2009) Cardinal consistency of reciprocal preference relations: a characterization of multiplicative transitivity. IEEE Trans Fuzzy Syst 17(1):14–23
Chiclana F, Herrera-Viedma E, Herrera F, Alonso S (2007) Some induced ordered weighted averaging operators and their use for solving group decision-making problems based on fuzzy preference relations. Eur J Oper Res 182(1):383–399
Ciasullo MV, Gaeta M, Monetta G, Rarità L (2015) E-cultural value co-creation. A proposed model for the heritage management. In: Proceedings of 18th Toulon-Verona International Conference, “Excellence in Services”, vol. U, pp 139–158
Dubois DJ, Prade H (1980) Fuzzy sets and systems: theory and application. Academic Press, New York
French JR (1956) A formal theory of social power. Psychol Rev 63(3):181–194
Friedkin NE, Johnsen EC (1990) Social influence and opinions. J Math Sociol 15:193–206
Friedkin NE, Johnsen EC (1999) Social influence networks and opinion change. Adv Gr Process 16:1–29
Gong Z, Xu X, Zhang H, Ozturk UA, Herrera-Viedma E, Xu C (2015) The consensus models with interval preference opinions and their economic interpretation. Omega 55:81–90
Harary F (1959) A criterion for unanimity in French’s theory of social power. Studies in social power. University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Oxford, pp 168–182
Kacprzyk J (1986) Group decision making with a fuzzy linguistic majority. Fuzzy Sets Syst 18(2):105–118
Kacprzyk J, Fedrizzi M, Nurmi H (1997) Consensus under fuzziness. Kluwer Academic Publishers, New York
Kacprzyk J, Roubens M (1988) Non-conventional preference relations in decision making. Springer, Berlin
Kitainik L (1993) Fuzzy decision procedures with binary relations: towards a unified theory. Springer, New York
Klement EP, Mesiar R, Pap E (1996) On the relationship of associative compensatory operators to triangular norms and conorms. Int J Uncertain Fuzziness Knowlege-Based Syst 4(2):129–144
Luce RD, Suppes, P (1965) Preferences, utility and subject probability. Handbook of mathematical psychology, vol III. Wiley, New York, pp 249–410
Massanet S, Riera JV, Torrens J, Herrera-Viedma E (2014) A new linguistic computational model based on discrete fuzzy numbers for computing with words. Inf Sci 258:277–290
Mata F, Martínez L, Herrera-Viedma E (2009) An adaptive consensus support model for group decision making problems in a multi-granular fuzzy linguistic context. IEEE Trans Fuzzy Syst 17(2):279–290
Mata F, Pérez L, Zhou SM, Chiclana F (2014) Type-1 OWA methodology to consensus reaching processes in multi-granular linguistic contexts. Knowledge-Based Syst 58:11–22
Mitchell HB, Estrakh DD (1997) A modified OWA operator and its use in lossless dpcm image compression. Int J Uncertain Fuzziness Knowledge-Based Syst 5:429–436
Morente-Molinera J, Pérez I, Ureña M, Herrera-Viedma E (2015) Building and managing fuzzy ontologies with heterogeneous linguistic information. Knowl Based Syst 88:154–164
Morente-Molinera J, Al-hmouz R, Morfeq A, Balamash A, Herrera-Viedma E (2016) A decision support system for decision making in changeable and multi-granular fuzzy linguistic contexts. J Mult Valued Logic Soft Comput (In press)
Nurmi H (1981) Approaches to collective decision making with fuzzy preference relations. Fuzzy Sets Syst 6(3):249–259
Pérez IJ, Cabrerizo FJ, Alonso S, Herrera-Viedma E (2014) A new consensus model for group decision making problems with non-homogeneous experts. Syst Man Cybern Syst IEEE Trans on 44(4):494–498
Pérez IJ, Cabrerizo FJ, Herrera-Viedma E (2010) A mobile decision support system for dynamic group decision-making problems. IEEE Trans Syst Man Cybern Part A Syst Hum 40(6):1244–1256
Pérez L, Mata F, Chiclana F (2014) Social network decision making with linguistic trustworthiness based induced OWA operators. Int J Intell Syst 29(12):1117–1137
Pérez-Asurmendi P, Chiclana F (2014) Linguistic majorities with difference in support. Appl Soft Comput 18:196–208
Roubens M (1997) Fuzzy sets and decision analysis. Fuzzy Sets Syst 90(2):199–206
Saaty T (1980) The analytic hierarchy process. McGraw-Hill, New york
Scott JP, Carrington PJ (2011) The SAGE handbook of social network analysis. SAGE, London
Seo F, Sakawa M (1985) Fuzzy multiattribute utility analysis for collective choice. IEEE Trans Syst Man Cybern 15(1):45–53
Tanino T (1984) Fuzzy preference orderings in group decision making. Fuzzy Sets Syst 12(2):117–131
Tanino T (1988) Fuzzy preference relations in group decision making. Non-conventional preference relations in decision making. Springer-Verlag, Berlin, pp 54–71
Tanino T (1990) On group decision making under fuzzy preferences. Multiperson decision making using fuzzy sets and possibility theory. Kluwer Academic Publisher, Dordrecht, pp 172–185
Ureña R, Chiclana F, Morente-Molinera J, Herrera-Viedma E (2015) Managing incomplete preference relations in decision making: a review and future trends. Inf Sci 302:14–32
Wasserman S, Faust K (1994) Social network analysis: methods and applications. Cambridge University Press, New York
Wu J, Chiclana F, Herrera-Viedma E (2015) Trust based consensus model for social network in an incomplete linguistic information context. Appl Soft Comput 35:827–839
Yager RR (1983) Quantifiers in the formulation of multiple objective decision functions. Inf Sci 31(2):107–139
Yager RR (1988) On ordered weighted averaging aggregation operators in multicriteria decision making. IEEE Trans Syst Man Cybern 18(1):183–190
Yager RR (1996) Quantifier guided aggregation using OWA operators. Int J Intell Syst 11(1):49–73
Yager RR (2003) Induced aggregation operators. Fuzzy Sets Syst 137:59–69
Yager RR, Filev D (1998) Operations for granular computing: mixing words and numbers. IEEE Int Conf Fuzzy Syst 1:123–128
Yager RR, Filev D (1999) Induced ordered weighted averaging operators. IEEE Trans Syst Man Cybern 29:141–150
Zadeh LA (1983) A computational approach to fuzzy quantifiers in natural languages. Comput Math Appl 9(1):149–184
Acknowledgments
This research work has been supported with Feder funding by the research project of Education Ministery TIN2013-40658-P. No sources of funding were used to assist in the preparation of this study.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Ethics declarations
Compliance with ethical standards
No sources of funding were used to assist in the preparation of this study.
Funding
This study was funded by the research project of Education Ministery TIN2013-40658-P.
Conflict of interest
The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.
Ethical approval
This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors.
Additional information
Communicated by V. Loia.
Appendices
Appendix 1: Fuzzy quantifiers and their use to model fuzzy majority
Fuzzy majority is a soft majority concept expressed by a fuzzy quantifier. This fuzzy quantifier is manipulated by means of a fuzzy logic-based calculus of linguistically quantified propositions. Hence, the use of fuzzy-majority-guided aggregation operators allows us to incorporate the concept of majority into the computation of the solution.
Quantifiers are used to represent the amount of items satisfying a given predicate. Classic logic defines two quantifiers, there exists and for all, however, this can be seen as an important drawback because human discourse is much richer and more diverse. In order to provide a more flexible knowledge representation tool, Zadeh introduced the concept of fuzzy quantifiers (Zadeh 1983).
Zadeh suggested that the semantics of a fuzzy quantifier can be captured using fuzzy subsets for its representation. Moreover, he differentiated between two types of fuzzy quantifiers: absolute and relative ones. In this model, we have focused on relative quantifiers, such as most, at least half, etc., since they can symbolise any quantifier of natural language. These quantifiers can be represented by fuzzy subsets of the unit interval \(\left[ 0,1\right] \). For any \(r\in \left[ 0,1\right] \), \(Q\left( r\right) \) indicates the degree in which the proportion r is compatible with the meaning of the quantifier it represents.
A relative quantifier \(Q:\left[ 0,1\right] \rightarrow \left[ 0,1\right] \) satisfies
Yager (1996) identified two categories of relative quantifiers: regular increasing monotone (RIM) quantifiers and regular decreasing monotone (RDM) quantifiers. The first category is characterised by quantifiers such as all, most, many, at least \(\alpha \); and the second one by at most one, few, at most \(\alpha \), being the former one, the category used in this proposal.
A RIM quantifier satisfies
Yager (1996) considers the parameterised family of RIM quantifiers
When this family of RIM quantifiers is used with OWA and IOWA operators, it is important to realise that \(\alpha < 1\) to associate high weighting values with high consistent ones. In particular, in this paper, we use the RIM function \(Q\left( r\right) =r^{1/2}\).
Appendix 2: Example of group decision making
Let \(E=\left\{ e_{1},e_{2},e_{3},e_{4} \right\} \) be the group of four experts and \(X=\left\{ x_{1},x_{2},x_{3},x_{4}\right\} \) be the set of four alternatives. This group of experts, E, express their preferences about the set of alternatives, X, by means of fuzzy preference relations, \(\left\{ P_{1},P_{2},P_{3},P_{4}\right\} \), \(P_{k}=\left[ p_{ij}^{k}\right] \), \(p_{ij}^{k} \in \left[ 0,1\right] \), which are additive reciprocal.
Consider the following preferences over the set of alternatives X:
and their respective expert’s importance \(I=\lbrace 0.75,1,0.5,0.25\rbrace \).
We use the fuzzy linguistic quantifier ’most of’ defined by \(Q\left( r\right) =r^{1/2}\) (Yager 1996), with its corresponding weighting vector \(W=\left( 0.5, 0.21, 0.16, 0.13 \right) \). By using the I-IOWA operator, the following collective preference relation is computed:
Now, if we use the quantifier-guided dominance degree, \(QGDD_{i}\) with the weighting vector \(W_{QGDD}=(0.5,0.21,0.16,0.13)\), the following utility vector is obtained:
and, therefore, the final solution is
i.e. \(x_4\) is the preferred alternative, \(x_2\) is the second one, etc.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Pérez, L.G., Mata, F., Chiclana, F. et al. Modelling influence in group decision making. Soft Comput 20, 1653–1665 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00500-015-2002-0
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00500-015-2002-0