Nothing Special   »   [go: up one dir, main page]

skip to main content
research-article

Breaking the Metric Voting Distortion Barrier

Published: 08 November 2024 Publication History

Abstract

We consider the following well-studied problem of metric distortion in social choice. Suppose that we have an election with n voters and m candidates located in a shared metric space. We would like to design a voting rule that chooses a candidate whose average distance to the voters is small. However, instead of having direct access to the distances in the metric space, the voting rule obtains, from each voter, a ranked list of the candidates in order of distance. Can we design a rule that, regardless of the election instance and underlying metric space, chooses a candidate whose cost differs from the true optimum by only a small factor (known as the distortion)?
A long line of work culminated in finding optimal deterministic voting rules with metric distortion 3. However, for randomized voting rules, there is still a significant gap in our understanding: even though the best lower bound is substantially lower at 2.112, the best upper bound is still 3, which is attained even by simple rules such as Random Dictatorship. Finding a randomized rule that guarantees distortion 3 - ɛ for some constant ɛ has been a major challenge in computational social choice, as prevalent approaches to designing voting rules are known to be insufficient. In particular, such a voting rule must use information beyond aggregate comparisons between pairs of candidates, and cannot only assign positive probability to candidates that are voters’ top choices.
In this work, we give a rule that guarantees distortion less than 2.753. To do so, we study a handful of voting rules that are new to the problem. One is Maximal Lotteries, a rule based on the Nash equilibrium of a natural zero-sum game that dates back to the 1960s. The others are novel rules that can be thought of as hybrids of Random Dictatorship and the Copeland rule. None of these rules can beat distortion 3 alone; however, a careful randomization between Maximal Lotteries and any of the novel rules can.

References

[1]
Frank Frost Abbott. 1901. A History and Description of Roman Political Institutions. Ginn & Company.
[2]
Atila Abdulkadiroğlu and Tayfun Sönmez. 1998. Random serial dictatorship and the core from random endowments in house allocation problems. Econometrica 66, 3 (1998), 689–701.
[3]
Georgios Amanatidis, Georgios Birmpas, Aris Filos-Ratsikas, and Alexandros A. Voudouris. 2022. A few queries go a long way: Information-distortion tradeoffs in matching. J. Artif. Intell. Res. 74 (2022), 5078–5085. DOI:
[4]
Nima Anari, Moses Charikar, and Prasanna Ramakrishnan. 2023. Distortion in metric matching with ordinal preferences. In Proceedings of the 24th ACM Conference on Economics and Computation (EC ’23). ACM, 90–110. DOI:
[5]
Elliot Anshelevich, Onkar Bhardwaj, Edith Elkind, John Postl, and Piotr Skowron. 2018. Approximating optimal social choice under metric preferences. Artif. Intell. 264 (2018), 27–51. DOI:
[6]
Elliot Anshelevich, Onkar Bhardwaj, and John Postl. 2015. Approximating optimal social choice under metric preferences. In Proceedings of the 29th AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence (AAAI ’15). 777–783. http://www.aaai.org/ocs/index.php/AAAI/AAAI15/paper/view/9643
[7]
Elliot Anshelevich, Aris Filos-Ratsikas, Nisarg Shah, and Alexandros A. Voudouris. 2021. Distortion in social choice problems: The first 15 years and beyond. In Proceedings of the 30th International Joint Conference on Artificial Intelligence (IJCAI ’21). 4294–4301. DOI:
[8]
Elliot Anshelevich and John Postl. 2017. Randomized social choice functions under metric preferences. J. Artif. Intell. Res. 58 (2017), 797–827. DOI:
[9]
Elliot Anshelevich and Shreyas Sekar. 2016. Blind, greedy, and random: Algorithms for matching and clustering using only ordinal information. In Proceedings of the 30th AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence (AAAI ’16). 390–396. http://www.aaai.org/ocs/index.php/AAAI/AAAI16/paper/view/12099
[10]
Elliot Anshelevich and Wennan Zhu. 2021. Ordinal approximation for social choice, matching, and facility location problems given candidate positions. ACM Trans. Econ. Comput. 9, 2 (2021), Article 9, 24 pages. DOI:
[11]
David A. Armstrong, Ryan Bakker, Royce Carroll, Christopher Hare, Keith T. Poole, and Howard Rosenthal. 2020. Analyzing Spatial Models of Choice and Judgment. Chapman & Hall/CRC.
[12]
Craig Boutilier, Ioannis Caragiannis, Simi Haber, Tyler Lu, Ariel D. Procaccia, and Or Sheffet. 2015. Optimal social choice functions: A utilitarian view. Artif. Intell. 227 (2015), 190–213. DOI:
[13]
Craig Boutilier and Jeffrey S. Rosenschein. 2016. Incomplete information and communication in voting. In Handbook of Computational Social Choice. Cambridge University Press, 223–257.
[14]
Felix Brandt. 2017. Rolling the dice: Recent results in probabilistic social choice. In Trends in Computational Social Choice. AI Access, 3–26.
[15]
Ioannis Caragiannis, Aris Filos-Ratsikas, Søren Kristoffer Stiil Frederiksen, Kristoffer Arnsfelt Hansen, and Zihan Tan. 2024. Truthful facility assignment with resource augmentation: An exact analysis of serial dictatorship. Math. Program. 203, 1 (2024), 901–930.
[16]
Ioannis Caragiannis, Swaprava Nath, Ariel D. Procaccia, and Nisarg Shah. 2017. Subset selection via implicit utilitarian voting. J. Artif. Intell. Res. 58 (2017), 123–152. DOI:
[17]
Ioannis Caragiannis and Ariel D. Procaccia. 2011. Voting almost maximizes social welfare despite limited communication. Artif. Intell. 175, 9-10 (2011), 1655–1671. DOI:
[18]
Ioannis Caragiannis, Nisarg Shah, and Alexandros A. Voudouris. 2022. The metric distortion of multiwinner voting. Artif. Intell. 313 (2022), 103802. DOI:
[19]
Moses Charikar and Prasanna Ramakrishnan. 2022. Metric distortion bounds for randomized social choice. In Proceedings of the 2022 ACM-SIAM Symposium on Discrete Algorithms (SODA ’22). 2986–3004. DOI:
[20]
Yu Cheng, Shaddin Dughmi, and David Kempe. 2017. Of the people: Voting is more effective with representative candidates. In Proceedings of the 2017 ACM Conference on Economics and Computation (EC ’17). 305–322. DOI:
[21]
Yu Cheng, Shaddin Dughmi, and David Kempe. 2018. On the distortion of voting with multiple representative candidates. In Proceedings of the 32nd AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence (AAAI ’18). 973–980. https://www.aaai.org/ocs/index.php/AAAI/AAAI18/paper/view/17028
[22]
Vašek Chvátal and László Lovász. 1974. Every directed graph has a semi-kernel. In Hypergraph Seminar: Columbus, OH, USA 1972. Lecture Notes in Mathematics, Vol. 411. Springer, 175.
[23]
Cosmina Croitoru. 2015. A note on quasi-kernels in digraphs. Inform. Process. Lett. 115, 11 (2015), 863–865.
[24]
Soroush Ebadian, Anson Kahng, Dominik Peters, and Nisarg Shah. 2024. Optimized distortion and proportional fairness in voting. ACM Trans. Econ. Comput. 12, 1 (2024), Article 3, 39 pages. DOI:
[25]
James M. Enelow and Melvin J. Hinich. 1984. The Spatial Theory of Voting: An Introduction. CUP Archive.
[26]
James M. Enelow and Melvin J. Hinich. 1990. Advances in the Spatial Theory of Voting. Cambridge University Press.
[27]
Brandon Fain, Ashish Goel, Kamesh Munagala, and Nina Prabhu. 2019. Random dictators with a random referee: Constant sample complexity mechanisms for social choice. In Proceedings of the 33rd AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence (AAAI ’19). 1893–1900. DOI:
[28]
Michal Feldman, Amos Fiat, and Iddan Golomb. 2016. On voting and facility location. In Proceedings of the 2016 ACM Conference on Economics and Computation (EC ’16). 269–286. DOI:
[29]
Dan S. Felsenthal and Moshé Machover. 1992. After two centuries, should Condorcet’s voting procedure be implemented? Behav. Sci. 37, 4 (1992), 250–274.
[30]
Peter C. Fishburn. 1977. Condorcet social choice functions. SIAM J. Appl. Math. 33, 3 (1977), 469–489.
[31]
Peter C. Fishburn. 1984. Probabilistic social choice based on simple voting comparisons. Rev. Econ. Stud. 51, 4 (1984), 683–692.
[32]
David C. Fisher and Jennifer Ryan. 1995. Tournament games and positive tournaments. J. Graph Theory 19, 2 (1995), 217–236.
[33]
Bailey Flanigan, Ariel D. Procaccia, and Sven Wang. 2023. Distortion under public-spirited voting. In Proceedings of the 24th ACM Conference on Economics and Computation (EC ’23). ACM, 700. DOI:
[34]
Vasilis Gkatzelis, Daniel Halpern, and Nisarg Shah. 2020. Resolving the optimal metric distortion conjecture. In Proceedings of the 61st IEEE Annual Symposium on Foundations of Computer Science (FOCS ’20). 1427–1438. DOI:
[35]
Vasilis Gkatzelis, Mohamad Latifian, and Nisarg Shah. 2023. Best of both distortion worlds. In Proceedings of the 24th ACM Conference on Economics and Computation (EC ’23). ACM, 738–758. DOI:
[36]
Ashish Goel, Anilesh K. Krishnaswamy, and Kamesh Munagala. 2017. Metric distortion of social choice rules: Lower bounds and fairness properties. In Proceedings of the 2017 ACM Conference on Economics and Computation (EC ’17). 287–304. DOI:
[37]
Stephen Gross, Elliot Anshelevich, and Lirong Xia. 2017. Vote until two of you agree: Mechanisms with small distortion and sample complexity. In Proceedings of the 31st AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence (AAAI ’17). 544–550. http://aaai.org/ocs/index.php/AAAI/AAAI17/paper/view/14631
[38]
James Wycliffe Headlam. 1891. Election by Lot at Athens. Cambridge Historical Essays, No. 4. Cambridge University Press.
[39]
Stephen A. Jessee. 2012. Ideology and Spatial Voting in American Elections. Cambridge University Press.
[40]
David Kempe. 2020. An analysis framework for metric voting based on LP duality. In Proceedings of the 34th AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence (AAAI ’20). 2079–2086. https://ojs.aaai.org/index.php/AAAI/article/view/5581
[41]
David Kempe. 2020. Communication, distortion, and randomness in metric voting. In Proceedings of the 34th AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence (AAAI ’20). 2087–2094. https://ojs.aaai.org/index.php/AAAI/article/view/5582
[42]
Fatih Erdem Kizilkaya and David Kempe. 2022. Plurality Veto: A simple voting rule achieving optimal metric distortion. In Proceedings of the 31st International Joint Conference on Artificial Intelligence (IJCAI ’22). 349–355. DOI:
[43]
Fatih Erdem Kizilkaya and David Kempe. 2023. Generalized veto core and a practical voting rule with optimal metric distortion. In Proceedings of the 24th ACM Conference on Economics and Computation (EC ’23). ACM, 913–936. DOI:
[44]
Germain Kreweras. 1965. Aggregation of preference orderings. In Mathematics and Social Sciences I: Proceedings of the Seminars of Menton-Saint-Bernard, France (1–27 July 1960) and of Gösing, Austria (3–27 July 1962), Shlomo Sternberg (Ed.), Mouton, 73–79.
[45]
Gilbert Laffond, Jean-Francois Laslier, and Michel Le Breton. 1993. The bipartisan set of a tournament game. Games Econ. Behav. 5, 1 (1993), 182–201.
[46]
Debmalya Mandal, Ariel D. Procaccia, Nisarg Shah, and David P. Woodruff. 2019. Efficient and thrifty voting by any means necessary. In Advances in Neural Information Processing Systems 32: Annual Conference on Neural Information Processing Systems (NeurIPS ’19). 7178–7189. https://proceedings.neurips.cc/paper/2019/hash/c09f9caf5e08836d4673ccdd69bb041e-Abstract.html
[47]
Debmalya Mandal, Nisarg Shah, and David P. Woodruff. 2020. Optimal communication-distortion tradeoff in voting. In Proceedings of the 2020 ACM Conference on Economics and Computation (EC ’20). 795–813. DOI:
[48]
Samuel Merrill and Bernard Grofman. 1999. A Unified Theory of Voting: Directional and Proximity Spatial Models. Cambridge University Press.
[49]
Hervé Moulin. 1981. The proportional veto principle. Rev. Econ. Studies 48, 3 (1981), 407–416.
[50]
Kamesh Munagala and Kangning Wang. 2019. Improved metric distortion for deterministic social choice rules. In Proceedings of the 2019 ACM Conference on Economics and Computation (EC ’19). 245–262. DOI:
[51]
Ariel D. Procaccia and Jeffrey S. Rosenschein. 2006. The distortion of cardinal preferences in voting. In Proceedings of the 10th International Workshop on Cooperative Information Agents (CIA ’16). 317–331. DOI:
[52]
Haripriya Pulyassary and Chaitanya Swamy. 2021. On the randomized metric distortion conjecture. arXiv preprint arXiv:2111.08698 (2021).
[53]
Ronald L. Rivest and Emily Shen. 2010. An optimal single-winner preferential voting system based on game theory. In Proceedings of the 3rd International Workshop on Computational Social Choice (COMSOC ’10). 399–410.
[54]
T. Nicolaus Tideman and Florenz Plassmann. 2011. Modeling the outcomes of vote-casting in actual elections. In Electoral Systems: Paradoxes, Assumptions, and Procedures. Springer, 217–251.

Recommendations

Comments

Please enable JavaScript to view thecomments powered by Disqus.

Information & Contributors

Information

Published In

cover image Journal of the ACM
Journal of the ACM  Volume 71, Issue 6
December 2024
269 pages
EISSN:1557-735X
DOI:10.1145/3613717
Issue’s Table of Contents

Publisher

Association for Computing Machinery

New York, NY, United States

Publication History

Published: 08 November 2024
Online AM: 20 September 2024
Accepted: 04 August 2024
Revised: 05 July 2024
Received: 30 June 2023
Published in JACM Volume 71, Issue 6

Check for updates

Author Tags

  1. Social choice
  2. social welfare
  3. metric spaces
  4. tournament graphs

Qualifiers

  • Research-article

Funding Sources

  • Moses Charikar’s Simons Investigator Award and Li-Yang Tan’s NSF
  • Aviad Rubinstein’s NSF
  • ONR

Contributors

Other Metrics

Bibliometrics & Citations

Bibliometrics

Article Metrics

  • 0
    Total Citations
  • 96
    Total Downloads
  • Downloads (Last 12 months)96
  • Downloads (Last 6 weeks)75
Reflects downloads up to 19 Nov 2024

Other Metrics

Citations

View Options

Login options

Full Access

View options

PDF

View or Download as a PDF file.

PDF

eReader

View online with eReader.

eReader

Full Text

View this article in Full Text.

Full Text

Media

Figures

Other

Tables

Share

Share

Share this Publication link

Share on social media