Abstract
This paper analyzes two incentive schemes available for a closed-loop supply chain (CLSC) in which a manufacturer and a retailer contribute to the return rate dynamics through their investments in green activity programs. Both firms have economic motivations to perform the return rate because customers who return end-of-use goods also repurchase new ones. In addition, the manufacturer exploits the returns’ residual value in operations to increase profits. Because the manufacturer has both operational and marketing motivations to close the loop, he can provide an incentive to the retailer to boost her investments in green activity programs. The incentive can be either state dependent or control dependent. The former assumes that the incentive depends on the fraction of customers who are willing to return end-of-use products; the latter is proportional to the retailer’s green activity programs efforts. Our results show that a state-dependent incentive is profit-Pareto-improving only when the retailer’s environmental effectiveness is large. In contrast, a control-dependent incentive mechanism is profit-Pareto-improving for low incentive values, high retailer’s environmental effectiveness, and customers’ repurchasing intention. In all other cases, players have divergent preferences and neither mechanism coordinates the CLSC.
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
We assume \(\kappa _{i}=1\) as it will be always possible to evaluate the marginal impact on profits function through the effectiveness that GAP strategies exert inside the state equation.
As it will be demonstrated later, \(M\) is willing to incentivize \(R\) to perform the return rate as long as she shows a larger operational effectiveness.
We use the superscript \(P\) to refer to a per-return incentive.
References
Bhattacharya S, Guide VDR, Van Wassenhove LN (2006) Optimal order quantities with remanufacturing across new product generations. Prod Oper Manag 15(3):421–431
Cachon GP (2003) Supply chain coordination with contracts. In: Graves S, de Kok T (eds) Handbooks in operations research and management science: supply chain management. North-Holland, Amsterdam
Corbett C, DeCroix G (2001) Shared savings contracts in supply chains. Manag Sci 47(7):881–893
Corbett CJ, Savaskan RC (2003) Contracting and coordination in closed-loop supply chains. In: Daniel V, Guide R Jr, Van Wassenhove LN (eds) Business aspects of closed-loop supply chains: exploring the issues. Carnegie Mellon University Press, Pittsburgh, PA
De Giovanni P (2014) Environmental collaboration through a reverse revenue sharing contract. Ann Oper Research 6:1–23
De Giovanni P, Roselli (2012) Overcoming the drawbacks of a revenue sharing contract through a coop program. Ann Oper Research 196(1):201–222
De Giovanni P, Zaccour G (2013) Cost-revenue sharing in a closed loop supply chain. Ann Int Soc Dyn Games 12:395–421
De Giovanni P, Zaccour G (2014) A two period model of closed-loop supply chain. Eur J Oper Res 1(1):22–24
Debo LG, Toktay LB, Van Wassenhove LN (2005) Market segmentation and product technology selection for remanufacturable products. Manag Sci 51(8):1193–1205
Ferguson ME, Toktay LB (2006) The effect of competition on recovery strategies. Prod Oper Manag 15(3):351–368
Ferrer G, Swaminathan JM (2006) Managing new and remanufactured products. Manag Sci 52(1):15–26
Fleischmann M, Krikke HR, Dekker R, Flapper SDP (2000) A characterisation of logistics networks for product. Omega Int J Manag Sci 28(6):653–666
Fleischmann M, van Nunen J, Grave B (2003) Integrating closed-loop supply chains and spare parts in IBM. Interface 33(6):44–56
Geyer R, Van Wassenhove LN, Atasu A (2007) The economics of remanufacturing under limited component durability and finite product life cycles. Manag Sci 53(1):88–10
Guide VDR Jr (2000) Production planning and control for remanufacturing: industry practice and research needs. J Oper Manag 18(4):467–483
Guide VDR, Van Wassenhove LN (2009) The evolution of closed-loop supply chain research. Oper Res 57(1):10–18
Ingene C, Taboubi S, Zaccour G (2012) Game-theoretic coordination mechanisms in distribution channels: integration and extensions for models without competition. J Retail 88(4):476–496
Jørgensen S (2011) Intertemporal contracting in a supply chain. Dyn Games Appl 1(2):280–300
Kang S, Hur WM (2012) Investigating the antecedents of green brand equity: a sustainable development perspective. Corp Soc Responsib Environ Mgmt 1(9):306–316
Majumder P, Groenevelt H (2001) Competition in remanufacturing. Prod Oper Manag 10(2):125–141
Savaskan RC, Bhattacharya S, Van Wassenhove LN (2004) Closed loop supply chain models with product remanufacturing. Manag Sci 50(2):239–252
Savaskan RC, Van Wassenhove LN (2006) Reverse channel design: the case of competing retailers. Manag Sci 52(1):1–14
Scholt A, De Giovanni P, Esposito Vinzi V (2014) Is environmental management an economically sustainable business? J Environ Manag 144(1):73–82
Seitz MA, Peattie K (2004) Meeting the closed-loop challenge: the case of remanufacturing. Calif Manag Rev 46(2):74–89
Souza GC (2013) Closed-loop supply chains: a critical review, and future research. Decis Sci 44(1):7–38
van Hoek RI (1999) From reversed logistics to green supply chains. Supply Chain Manag Int J 4(3):129–134
Yusof JM, Musa R, Rahman SA (2012) The effects of green image of retailers on shopping value and store loyalty. Proc Soc Behav Sci 50:710–721
Websites
Acknowledgments
I wish to thank three anonymous reviewers and Editor Georges Zaccour for very helpful comments. Any remaining errors are the responsibility of the author.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendices
Appendix 1
Proof of Proposition 1
In the non-coordinated scenario, we search for a pair of bounded and continuously differentiable value functions \( V_{M}^{B}\left( r^{B}\right) ,V_{R}^{B}\left( r^{B}\right) \) for which a unique solution for \(r^{B}\left( t\right) \) does exist, and the Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman (HJB) equations:
are satisfied for any value of \(r^{B}\in (0,1].\) Maximization of the \(R\)’s HJB gives pricing and \(R\)’s GAP strategies.
Substituting Eqs. (38) and (39) inside \(M\)’s HJB provides:
Maximization of Eq. (40) with respect to \(M\prime s\) GAP strategies and wholesale price gives
Substituting Eq. (42) in (38), pricing results:
Plagging Eqs. (43), (42), (39), and (41) in Eqs. (40) and (37), it provides
We conjecture quadratic value functions \(V_{M}^{B}\left( r^{B}\right) =\frac{ d_{1}}{2}r^{B^{2}}+d_{2}r^{B}+d_{3}\) and \(V_{R}^{B}\left( r^{B}\right) = \frac{f_{1}}{2}r^{B^{2}}+f_{2}r^{B}+f_{3},\) where the pairs \(\left( d_{j},f_{j}\right) ,j=1\ldots 3\) are the constant parameters to be identified. Substituting our conjectures and their derivatives in Eqs. (44) and (45) gives
By identification, the constant parameters can be derived by solving the following set of coupled algebraic Riccati equations:
To derive the coefficients, we can start from Eq. (48) and obtain \(f_{1}\) as a function of \(d_{1}:f_{1}=f\left( d_{1}\right) \) where
with \(B_{3}=\varDelta \beta \left( 2\theta +\varDelta \beta \right) +\theta ^{2}\). Substituting Eq. (54) for Eqs. (49) and (52), we can derive both \(d_{2}\) and \( f_{2} \) as a function of \(d_{1}\)
with \(B_{1}=a^{2}m_{1}^{*}+b^{2}n_{1}^{*}-\delta -\rho <0,\, B_{2}=\alpha \left( \theta +\varDelta \beta \right) >0,\, B_{4}=a^{2}d_{1}+b^{2}\varOmega _{1}-\delta -\rho \). We then substitute Eqs. (55) and (56) in Eqs. (50) and (53) to derive \(d_{3}\) and \(f_{3}\) as a function of \(d_{1}\):
Finally, replacing Eq. (54) into (51) gives a nonlinear equation that we have solved numerically in Mathematica 6.0.\(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 2
To show the inefficiency of a per-return incentive mechanism, we need to search for a pair of bounded and continuously differentiable value functions \(V_{M}^{P}\left( r^{P}\right) ,V_{R}^{P}\left( r^{P}\right) \) for which a unique solution for \(r^{P}\left( t\right) \) exists, and the HJBs are as follows:
Because the coordination game also has a leader–follower structure where \(M\) is the leader, we start from the maximization of \(R\)’s HJB with respect to price and GAP strategies:
Substituting Eqs. (61) and (62) inside \(M\)’s HJB gives
whose maximization with respect to wholesale price and GAP strategies yields:
Plugging Eq. (64) in Eq. (61) leads to
Subsituiting Eqs. (64), (65), (66) and (62) in (63) and (60) gives
from which it turns out that \(V_{M}^{B}\left( r^{B}\right) =V_{M}^{P}\left( r^{P}\right) \) and \(V_{R}^{B}\left( r^{B}\right) =V_{R}^{P}\left( r^{P}\right) ,\) and thus, the implementation of a per-return incentive does not lead to any form of coordination.\(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 3
Here we follow the same steps as in the proof of Proposition 1 to derive the equilibrium strategies under the assumption that the CLSC is coordinated through a state-dependent incentive mechanism. The HJBs for this game are given by
Maximization of \(R\)’s HJB with respect to pricing and GAP strategies gives
These expressions must be satisfied by the pricing and \(R\)’s GAP strategies. Replacing Eqs. (71) and (72) inside Eq. (69), it gives the following expression:
\(M\)’s GAP equilibrium strategy is characterized by
Plugging Eq. (74) inside (71), it gives
Substituting, (72), (74) and (75), (76) inside Eqs. (70), and (73), the HBJ become:
We can conjecture quadratic value functions also in this scenario, specifically: \(V_{M}^{S}\left( r^{S}\right) =\frac{m_{1}}{2} r^{S^{2}}+m_{2}r^{S}+m_{3}\) and \(V_{R}^{S}\left( r^{S}\right) =\frac{n_{1}}{2 }r^{S^{2}}+n_{2}r^{S}+n_{3},\) where the pairs \(\left( m_{j},n_{j}\right) ,j=1\ldots 3\) are the constant parameters to be identified. Substituting the value functions and their derivatives inside Eqs. (77) and (78), the constant parameters can be identified solving the following set of coupled Riccati equations:
The coefficients can be simply derived as \(m_{1}=d_{1}\) and \(n_{1}=f_{1}.\) Thus, we can obtain \(n_{1}\) as a function of \(d_{1}:n_{1}=f_{1}=f\left( d1\right) =\varOmega _{1}\) as it is displayed in Eq. (54). Substituting Eq. (54) for Eqs. (80) and (83), we can derive both \(m_{2}\) and \(n_{2}\) as a function of \(d_{1}\)
We then substitute Eqs. (85) and (86) in Eqs. (81) and (84) to derive \(m_{3}\) and \(n_{3}\) as a function of \(d_{1}\):
See Proof of Proposition 1 to check the solution for \(d_{1}\).\(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 6
This proof follows the proof for Proposition 2, with the difference that the incentive depends on the control \( A_{R}^{C}\left( r^{C}\right) \). The HJB functions should be written as follows:
Maximization of \(R\)’s HJB gives pricing and \(R\)’s GAP strategies:
Substituting these strategies inside Eq. (89) to get
First-order condition for \(M\)’s GAP strategy gives
Plugging Eq. (94) inside (91) gives
Substitute Eqs. (92), (94), (95), (96) in (90) and (93) to get
To obtain a solution for this game, we conjectured quadratic value functions, \(V_{M}^{C}\left( r^{C}\right) =\frac{l_{1}}{2} r^{C^{2}}+l_{2}r^{C}+l_{3}\) and \(V_{R}^{C}\left( r^{C}\right) =\frac{k_{1}}{2 }r^{C^{2}}+k_{2}r^{C}+k_{3},\) where \(\left( l_{j},k_{j}\right) ,j=1\ldots 3,\) are the constant parameters to be identified. Replacing our conjectures and their derivatives into Eqs. (97) and (98), it gives
We identified the constant parameters from the following set of coupled algebraic Riccati equations:
As for the state-dependent case, the coefficients \(l_{i},k_{i},i=1\ldots 3\) can be simply derived as \(l_{1}=d_{1}\) and \(k_{1}=f_{1}\). Thus, we can obtain \( k_{1}\) as a function of \(d_{1}:k_{1}=f_{1}=f\left( d1\right) =\varOmega _{1}\) as it is reported in Eq. (54). Substituting Eq. (54) for Eqs. (102) and (105), we can derive both \(l_{2}\) and \(k_{2}\) as a function of \( d_{1}\)
We then substitute Eqs. (107) and (108) in Eqs. (103) and (106) to derive \(l_{3}\) and \(k_{3}\) as a function of \(d_{1}\):
See Proof of Proposition 1 to check the solution for \(d_{1}\). \(\square \)
Appendix 2
Solution \({\mathcal {I}}\) | Solution \({\mathcal {II}}\) | Solution \({\mathcal {III}}\) | Solution \({\mathcal {IV}}\) | |
---|---|---|---|---|
\(A_{M}^{B}\left( r_{SS}^{B}\right) \) | .2096 | .4397 | .1098 | \(-\).4544 |
\(A_{R}^{B}\left( r_{SS}^{B}\right) \) | .1028 | .2027 | \(-\).1582 | .0687 |
\(r_{SS}^{B}\) | .3881 | .7816 | \(-\).3268 | \(-\) .1121 |
\(V_{M}^{B}\left( r_{SS}^{B}\right) \) | .192 | .5309 | 1.123 | .0284 |
\(V_{R}^{B}\left( r_{SS}^{B}\right) \) | .0953 | .2008 | \(-\).0509 | .0873 |
Steady-state \((SS)\) value of GAP efforts, return rates, and profits in scenario \(B.\) Bold values highlight the positivity assumptions that solutions \({\mathcal {III}}\) and \({\mathcal {IV}}\) violate
Appendix 3
Parameter values | \(A_{M}^{B}\left( r_{SS}^{B}\right) \ge 0\) | \( A_{R}^{B}\left( r_{SS}^{B}\right) \ge 0\) | \(r_{SS}^{B}\in (0,1]\) | \( V_{M}^{B}\left( r_{SS}^{B}\right) \ge 0\) | \(V_{R}^{B}\left( r_{SS}^{B}\right) \ge 0\) | \(\delta -a^{2}d_{1}-b^{2}f_{1}>0\) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
\(\alpha \)(1.1;1.2;1.3) | .23;.252;.272 | .11;.12;.134 | .426;.46;.505 | .235;.284;.337 | .115;.138;.134 | .324;.324;.324 |
\(\beta \)(1.1;1.2;1.3) | .204;.2;.197 | .1;.098;.097 | .378;.371;.365 | .176;.163;.152 | .085;.079;.073 | .322;.320;.317 |
\(\varDelta \)(.6;.7;.8) | .261;.329;.426 | .127;.159;.204 | .4812;.604;.777 | .226;.287;.407 | .109;.138;.194 | .3025;.276;.246 |
\(\theta \)(.4;.5;.6) | .261;.329;.426 | .127;.159;.204 | .4812;.604;.777 | .226;.287;.407 | .109;.138;.194 | .3025;.276;.246 |
a(.6;.7;.8) | .22;.234;.253 | .109;.117;.128 | .471;.58;.726 | .211;.24;.289 | .104;.12;.146 | .312;.297;.28 |
b(1.1;.1.2;1.3) | .221;.235;.252 | .107;.113;.12 | .464;.555;.667 | .211;.238;.277 | .101;.113;.13 | .313;.3;.287 |
\(\rho \)(.95;.97;.99) | .199;.195;.191 | .097;.096;.094 | .368;.361;.354 | .177;.172;.167 | .086;.084;.081 | .327;.328;.329 |
\(\delta \)(.5;.6;.7) | .179;.158;.143 | .088;.078;.071 | .265;.196;.152 | .169;.16;.154 | .083;.078;.076 | .433;.54;.646 |
Parameter values | \(A_{M}^{B}\left( r_{SS}^{B}\right) \ge 0\) | \(A_{R}^{B}\left( r_{SS}^{B}\right) \ge 0\) | \(r^{B}\in (0,1]\) | \( V_{M}^{B}\left( r_{SS}^{B}\right) \ge 0\) | \(V_{R}^{B}\left( r_{SS}^{B}\right) \ge 0\) | \(\delta -a^{2}d_{1}-b^{2}f_{1}<0\) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
\(\alpha \)(1.1;1.2;1.3) | .484;.528;.572 | .223;.243;.263 | .86;.937;1.02 | .559;.568;.551 | .225;.247;.266 | \(-\)1.32;\(-\)1.32;\(-\)1.32 |
\(\beta \)(1.1;1.2;1.3) | .43;.425;.422 | .198;.195;.193 | .76;.754;.747 | 56;.499;.486 | .19;.184;.178 | \(-\)1.322;\(-\)1.323;\(-\)1.324 |
\(\varDelta \)(.6;.7;.8) | .581;.798;1.17 | .363;.354;.514 | 1.022;1.34;2.02 | .433;\(-\) .242;\(-\) 3.6 | .21;.105; \(-\) .626 | \(-\)1.327;\(-\)1.333;\(-\)1.339 |
\(\theta \)(.4;.5;.6) | .581;.798;1.17 | .363;.354;.514 | 1.022;1.34;2.02 | .433;\(-\) .242;\(-\) 3.6 | .21;.105; \(-\) .626 | \(-\)1.327;\(-\)1.333;\(-\)1.339 |
a(.6;.7;.8) | .471;.515;.579 | .225;.257;.302 | .987; 1.27;1.68 | .412;.207;\(-\) .268 | .198;.106;\(-\) .27 | \(-\)1.312;\(-\)1.30;\(-\)1.287 |
b(1.1;.1.2;1.3) | .481;.533;.599 | .215;.23;.25 | .95; 1.16;1.43 | .461;.173;\(-\) .6 | .195;.172;.11 | \(-\)1.33;\(-\)1.34;\(-\)1.35 |
\(\rho \)(.95;.97;.99) | .411;.4;.39 | .19;.186;.181 | .733;.715;.697 | .525;.521;.518 | .19;.188;.18 | \(-\)1.371;\(-\)1.391;\(-\)1.411 |
\(\delta \)(.5;.6;.7) | .369;.327;.298 | .172;.153;.141 | .528;.392;.308 | .471;.388;.327 | .164;.135;.117 | \(-\)1.42;\(-\)1.518;\(-\)1.617 |
Parameter values | \(A_{M}^{B}\left( r_{SS}^{B}\right) \ge 0\) | \(A_{R}^{B}\left( r_{SS}^{B}\right) \ge 0\) | \(r^{B}\in (0,1]\) | \( V_{M}^{B}\left( r_{SS}^{B}\right) \ge 0\) | \(V_{R}^{B}\left( r_{SS}^{B}\right) \ge 0\) | \(\delta -a^{2}d_{1}-b^{2}f_{1}<0\) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
\(\alpha \)(1.1;1.2;1.3) | .484;.528;.572 | .223;.243;.263 | .86;.937;1.02 | .559;.568;.551 | .225;.247;.266 | \(-\)1.32;\(-\)1.32;\(-\)1.32 |
\(\beta \)(1.1;1.2;1.3) | .43;.425;.422 | .198;.195;.193 | .76;.754;.747 | 56;.499;.486 | .19;.184;.178 | \(-\)1.322;\(-\)1.323;\(-\)1.324 |
\(\varDelta \)(.6;.7;.8) | .581;.798;1.17 | .363;.354;.514 | 1.022;1.34;2.02 | .433;\(-\) .242;\(-\) 3.6 | .21;.105; \(-\) .626 | \(-\)1.327;\(-\)1.333;\(-\)1.339 |
\(\theta \)(.4;.5;.6) | .581;.798;1.17 | .363;.354;.514 | 1.022;1.34;2.02 | .433;\(-\) .242;\(-\) 3.6 | .21;.105; \(-\) .626 | \(-\)1.327;\(-\)1.333;\(-\)1.339 |
a(.6;.7;.8) | .471;.515;.579 | .225;.257;.302 | .987; 1.27;1.68 | .412;.207;\(-\) .268 | .198;.106;\(-\) .27 | \(-\)1.312;\(-\)1.30;\(-\)1.287 |
b(1.1;.1.2;1.3) | .481;.533;.599 | .215;.23;.25 | .95; 1.16;1.43 | .461;.173;\(-\) .6 | .195;.172;.11 | \(-\)1.33;\(-\)1.34;\(-\)1.35 |
\(\rho \)(.95;.97;.99) | .411;.4;.39 | .19;.186;.181 | .733;.715;.697 | .525;.521;.518 | .19;.188;.18 | \(-\)1.371;\(-\)1.391;\(-\)1.411 |
\(\delta \)(.5;.6;.7) | .369;.327;.298 | .172;.153;.141 | .528;.392;.308 | .471;.388;.327 | .164;.135;.117 | \(-\)1.42;\(-\)1.518;\(-\)1.617 |
Parameter values | \(A_{M}^{C}\left( r_{SS}^{C}\right) \ge 0\) | \( A_{R}^{C}\left( r_{SS}^{C}\right) \ge 0\) | \(r^{C}\in (0,1]\) | \( V_{M}^{C}\left( r_{SS}^{C}\right) \ge 0\) | \(V_{R}^{C}\left( r_{SS}^{C}\right) \ge 0\) | \(\delta -a^{2}l_{1}-b^{2}k_{1}>0\) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
\(\alpha \)(1.1;1.2;1.3) | .23;.25;.275 | .114;.124;.135 | .43;.47;.51 | .214;.265;.321 | .158;.184;.21 | .324;.324;.324 |
\(\beta \)(1.1;1.2;1.3) | .223;.202;.199 | .101;.099;.097 | .383;.375;.369 | .152;.138;.127 | .126;.119;.114 | .322;.320;.317 |
\(\varDelta \)(.6;.7;.8) | .265;.334;.434 | .129;.162;.208 | .488;.614;.791 | .208;.276;.407 | .155;.188;.25 | .3025;.276;.246 |
\(\theta \)(.4;.5;.6) | .265;.334;.434 | .129;.162;.208 | .488;.614;.791 | .208;.276;.407 | .155;.188;.25 | .3025;.276;.246 |
a(.6;.7;.8) | .223;.238;.257 | .11;.12;.129 | .477;.588;.736 | .188;.219;.269 | .146;.163;.191 | .312;.297;.28 |
b(1.1;.1.2;1.3) | .224;.239;.257 | .109;.115;.122 | .47;.564;.678 | .191;.223;.267 | .146;.16;.18 | .313;.3;.287 |
\(\rho \)(.95;.97;.99) | .201;.197;.193 | .099;.097;.095 | .373;.366;.358 | .154;.149;.145 | .125;.122;.118 | .327;.328;.329 |
\(\delta \)(.5;.6;.7) | .18;.16;.144 | .089;.079;.0716 | .268;.198;.154 | .143;.132;.126 | .123;.116;.113 | .433;.54;.646 |
\(\mu \)(.025;.05;.2) | .210;.210;.212 | .1029;.103;.104 | .388;.390;.393 | .194;.195;.168 | .096;.099;.135 | .324;.324;.324 |
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
De Giovanni, P. State- and Control-Dependent Incentives in a Closed-Loop Supply Chain with Dynamic Returns. Dyn Games Appl 6, 20–54 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-015-0142-6
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-015-0142-6