Abstract
A dilemma between economic growth and environmental deterioration has never been recognized so seriously until the environmental problem has been impacting everyone’s daily life cogently (e.g., the serious fog and haze in China). Simultaneously, the rising environment awareness of consumers leads to the close attention to the product’s carbon performance reflected in the carbon concerned demand, which provides opportunity to rebuild our business ecosystem. The paper expands the environment view to supply chain operations. A Stackelberg-like model is developed to game-theoretically analyze the decentralized decisions of the manufacturer and retailer. Low-carbon effort is brought into decision by both sides. The centralized decision-making is also investigated as a benchmark to evaluate the supply chain performance. Additionally,we propose a carbon-related price–discount sharing-like scheme to achieve the channel coordination and discuss the possibility of Pareto improvement. Several interesting managerial insights on low-carbon factors are concluded.
Similar content being viewed by others
References
Aguilar, F. X., & Vlosky, R. P. (2007). Consumer willingness to pay price premiums for environmentally certified wood products in the US. Forest Policy and Economics, 9(8), 1100–1112.
Benjaafar, S., Li, Y., & Daskin, M. (2013). Carbon footprint and the management of supply chains: Insights from simple models. IEEE Transactions on Automation Science and Engineering, 10(1), 99–116.
Bernstein, F., & Federgruen, A. (2005). Decentralized supply chains with competing retailers under demand uncertainty. Management Science, 51(1), 18–29.
Bhatia, P., Cummis, C., Rich, D., Draucker, L., Lahd, H., & Brown, A. (2011). Greenhouse gas protocol corporate value chain (scope 3) accounting and reporting standard. Technical report, World Resources Institute (WRI) and World Business Council for Sustainable Development (WBCSD). http://www.wri.org/sites/default/files/pdf/ghgp_corporate_value_chain_scope_3_standard.pdf
Bonini, S., & Oppenheim, J. (2008). Cultivating the green consumer. Stanfold Social Innovation Review, 6(4), 56–61.
Cachon, G. P. (2003). Supply chain coordination with contracts. In A. de Kok & S. Graves (Eds.), Supply chain management: Design, coordination and operation, handbooks in operations research and management science (Vol. 11, pp. 227–339). Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Cachon, G. P. (2014). Retail store density and the cost of greenhouse gas emissions. Management Science, 60(8), 1907–1925.
Chen, F., Federgruen, A., & Zheng, Y. S. (2001). Coordination mechanisms for a distribution system with one supplier and multiple retailers. Management Science, 47(5), 693–708.
Conrad, K. (2005). Price competition and product differentiation when consumers care for the environment. Environmental and Resource Economics, 31(1), 1–19.
Dong, C., Shen, B., Chow, P. S., Yang, L., & Ng, C. T. (2014). Sustainability investment under cap-and-trade regulation. Annals of Operations Research. doi:10.1007/s10479-013-1514-1
Du, S., Ma, F., Fu, Z., Zhu, L., & Zhang, J. (2011). Game-theoretic analysis for an emission-dependent supply chain in a ‘cap-and-trade’system. Annals of Operations Research. doi:10.1007/s10479-011-0964-6
El Ouardighi, F., Benchekroun, H., & Grass, D. (2014). Controlling pollution and environmental absorption capacity. Annals of Operations Research, 220(1), 111–133.
Ellerman, A. D., Convery, F. J., & de Perthuis, C. (2010). Pricing carbon: The European Union emissions trading scheme. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Gallego, G., & van Ryzin, G. (1994). Optimal dynamic pricing of inventories with stochastic demand over finite horizons. Management Science, 40(8), 999–1020.
Hoen, K. M., Tan, T., Fransoo, J. C., & van Houtum, G. J. (2014). Switching transport modes to meet voluntary carbon emission targets. Transportation Science, 48(4), 592–608.
Hua, G., Cheng, T., & Wang, S. (2011). Managing carbon footprints in inventory management. International Journal of Production Economics, 132(2), 178–185.
Jeuland, A. P., & Shugan, S. M. (1988). Channel of distribution profits when channel members from conjectures. Marketing Science, 7(2), 202–210.
Jira, C., & Toffel, M. W. (2013). Engaging supply chains in climate change. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 15(4), 559–577.
Kainuma, Y., & Tawara, N. (2006). A multiple attribute utility theory approach to lean and green supply chain management. International Journal of Production Economics, 101(1), 99–108.
Kolk, A., Levy, D., & Pinkse, J. (2008). Corporate responses in an emerging climate regime: The institutionalization and commensuration of carbon disclosure. European Accounting Review, 17(4), 719–745.
Laroche, M., Bergeron, J., & Barbaro-Forleo, G. (2001). Targeting consumers who are willing to pay more for environmentally friendly products. Journal of Consumer Marketing, 18(6), 503–520.
Liu, Z. L., Anderson, T. D., & Cruz, J. M. (2012). Consumer environmental awareness and competition in two-stage supply chains. European Journal of Operational Research, 218(3), 602–613.
Loureiro, M. L., McCluskey, J. J., & Mittelhammer, R. C. (2002). Will consumers pay a premium for eco-labeled apples? Journal of Consumer Affairs, 36(2), 203–219.
MacLeod, C., & Eversley, M. (2014). U.S., China reach ‘historic’ deal to cut emissions. USA Today. Accessed November 20, 2014 from http://www.usatoday.com/story/news/world/2014/11/11/china-climate-change-deal/18895661/
Moon, W., Florkowski, W. J., Brückner, B., & Schonhof, I. (2002). Willingness to pay for environmental practices: Implications for eco-labeling. Land Economics, 78(1), 88–102.
NCDR. (2014). China National Commission for disaster reduction releases the 2013 national natural disasters report. Accessed November 13, 2014 from http://www.jianzai.gov.cn/DRpublish/jzdt/0000000000002216.html
Nielsen Company. (2001). The green gap between environmental concerns and the cash register. Accessed January 5, 2014 from http://www.nielsen.com/us/en/insights/news/2011/the-green-gap-between-environmental-concerns-and-the-cash-register.html
Nordhaus, W. D. (1991). To slow or not to slow: The economics of the greenhouse effect. The Economic Journal, 101(407), 920–937.
Pachauri, R., & Reisinger, A. (2008). Climate change 2007: Synthesis report: Contribution of working groups I, II and III to the fourth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. Technical report, IPCC. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_ipcc_fourth_assessment_report_synthesis_report.htm
Parry, M., Canziani, O., Palutikof, J., van der Linden, P., & Hanson, C. (2007). Climate change 2007: Impacts, adaptation and vulnerability: Contribution of working group II to the fourth assessment report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Pasternack, B. A. (1985). Optimal pricing and return policies for perishable commodities. Marketing Science, 4(2), 166–176.
P&G. (2013). P&G 2013 Sustainability Report. Technical report, Procter & Gamble. http://image.pg.com.cn/Csr/File/PG_2013_Sustainability_Report.pdf
Ranganathan, J., Corbier, L., Bhatia, P., Schmitz, S., Gage, P., & Oren, K. (2004). The greenhouse gas protocol: A corporate accounting and reporting standard (revised edition). Technical report, World Resources Institute (WRI) and World Business Council for Sustainable Development (WBCSD). http://pdf.wri.org/ghg_protocol_2004.pdf
Roheim, C. A., Asche, F., & Santos, J. I. (2011). The elusive price premium for ecolabelled products: Evidence from seafood in the UK market. Journal of Agricultural Economics, 62(3), 655–668.
Savaskan, R. C., Bhattacharya, S., & van Wassenhove, L. N. (2004). Closed-loop supply chain models with product remanufacturing. Management Science, 50(2), 239–252.
Srivastava, S. K. (2007). Green supply-chain management: A state-of-the-art literature review. International Journal of Management Reviews, 9(1), 53–80.
Toptal, A., & Çetinkaya, B. (2015). How supply chain coordination affects the environment: A carbon footprint perspective. Annals of Operations Research. doi:10.1007/s10479-015-1858-9
Zhang, Q., He, K., & Huo, H. (2012). Policy: Cleaning China’s air. Nature, 484(7393), 161–162.
Acknowledgments
The authors gratefully acknowledge Prof. Zhimin Huang for his patience and valuable suggestions. This research was supported by National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant Nos. 71571171, 71271199), Program for New Century Excellent Talents in University (Grant No. NCET-13-0538), the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities of China (No. WK2040160008) and Youth Innovation Promotion Association CAS.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendices
Appendix 1: Proof of Proposition 1
Proof
We solve the dynamic game of the retailer and the manufacturer using the standard backward induction. We assume all parameters are positive.
Step 1: Solve Retailer’s profit maximization problem
The profit function faced by retailer has been defined in Eq. (4).
The first derivation of \(\pi _r\) regarding p and \(x_r\) respectively is:
The stationary point \((p,x_r)\) of the \(\pi _r\) can be calculated through simultaneous equations. And \((p,x_r)\) can be denoted in Eqs. (5) and (6).
It has been verified that the determinant of the Hessian matrix at the stationary point is negative definite:
So the \(\pi _r\) reaches the maximum at the stationary point.
Step 2: Solve manufacturer’s profit maximization problem
As the Stackelberg leader, the manufacturer anticipates the retailer’s best response, shown by Eqs. (5) and (6), and incorporate it to her profit function, we have Eq. (7).
The first derivation of \(\pi _m\) regarding w and \(x_m\) respectively is:
The stationary point \((w,x_m)\) of the \(\pi _m\) can be calculated through simultaneous equations, denoted in Eq. (8).
It also has been verified that the determinant of the Hessian matrix at the stationary point is negative definite:
So the \(\pi _m\) reaches the maximum at the stationary point.
Step 3: Solve the optimal solution and its applicable condition
In the Stackelberg game, the optimum decision for the manufacturer and retailer have been shown in Eqs. (8) and (9).
It is apparent that the boundary conditions of the optimal solution must be satisfied and demonstrated as:
Reducing the above inequality, we have the optimal condition:
\(\square \)
Appendix 2: Proof of Corollary 3
Proof
From the Proposition 1, the optimal retail price and wholesale price:
\(\frac{{\partial {p^*}}}{{\partial \left( {\beta /\alpha } \right) }} > 0\) which means that the retail price is always increasing to \(\beta /\alpha \) While \(\frac{{\partial {w^*}}}{{\partial \left( {\beta /\alpha } \right) }} = 1 + \left( {\frac{1}{{{\lambda _m}}} - \frac{1}{{{\lambda _r}}}} \right) \frac{\alpha }{\beta }\), Note \(\varLambda = \left( \frac{1}{{{\lambda _r}}} - \frac{1}{{{\lambda _m}}} \right) \) which captures the manufacture’s technological advantage relative to the retailer’s. So the demand characteristic of low-carbon preference compared to price sensitivity \((\beta /\alpha )\) has a piecewise impact on the wholesale price \(w^*\), i.e., \(w^*\) is increasing in \((\beta /\alpha )\) greater than \(\varLambda \), while decreasing in \(\beta /\alpha \) less than \(\varLambda \).
Obviously, the generalized technological level of carbon reduction of the manufacturer \((\psi \lambda _m)\) positively impacts both pricing decisions, however, that of the retailer \(\left( (1-\psi ) \lambda _r\right) \) has a positive impact on the retail price \(p^*\) while a negative impact on the wholesale price \(w^*\); The retail price \(p^*\) is positively correlative to both low-carbon investments respectively, while the wholesale price \(w^*\) is positively correlative to \((x_m^*-x_r^*)\), the gap that the manufacturer’s low-carbon investment is larger than the retailer’s. It is not surprising that the more the manufacturer invests, the higher she would charge. \(\square \)
Appendix 3: Proofs of Propositions and corollaries in Sect. 4.2
1.1 Proof of Proposition 2
Proof
Under the centralized decision-making system, the supply chain’s profit function is Eq. (13).
The first derivation of \({\varPi }\) regarding p, \({x_r}\) and \({x_m}\) respectively is:
The stationary point \(\left( {p,{x_r},{x_m}} \right) \) of the \({\varPi }\) can be calculated through simultaneous equations denoted in Eqs. (14) and (15).
It has been verified that the determinant of the Hessian matrix M at the stationary point is negative definite:
Its principal minors of order k is defined as M, where
So the \({\varPi }\) reaches the maximum at the stationary point. It is apparent that the boundary conditions of the optimal solution must be satisfied and demonstrated as:
Reducing the above inequality, we have the optimal condition:
Thus, the channel’s profit in the centralized decision-making system has been shown in Eq. (15). \(\square \)
1.2 Proof of Corollary 4
Proof
The supply chain optimal retail price \({p_1}^o\) can be denoted in Eq. (14), while the optimum decision \(p^*\) for the retailer in decentralized decision-making system has been shown in Eq. (9).
Hence, \({p^*} > p^o\), while \(\varPi ^o = \frac{4}{3}{\varPi ^*}\) \(\square \)
Appendix 4: Proofs of Propositions and corollaries in Sect. 4.3
1.1 Proof of Proposition 3
Proof
Substituting \(w = \left( {1 - \phi } \right) p + \phi c\) and \(\phi = \frac{{{x_r^*}}}{{{x_m^*} + {x_r^*}}}\) into \(\pi _r\) and reducing, we have:
So the individual profits affine to the channelwide one has been achieved. Therefor, we coordinate the supply chain with a fixed allocation. \(\square \)
1.2 Proof of Corollary 5
Proof
Under the centralized decision-making system with channel coordination, the retailer’s profit can be denoted as Eq. (17), and the manufacturer’s profit can be denoted as Eq. (18), while under the decentralized decision-making system, the manufacturer’s profit can be denoted as:
And the retailer’s profit can be denoted as:
If \(\pi _r^c > \pi _r^*\), \(\pi _m^c > \pi _m^*\):
So \(\frac{1}{3} < \phi < \frac{1}{2}\), \(\pi _m^c > \pi _m^*\) and \(\pi _r^c > \pi _r^*\) are satisfied. \(\square \)
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Du, S., Hu, L. & Wang, L. Low-carbon supply policies and supply chain performance with carbon concerned demand. Ann Oper Res 255, 569–590 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-015-1988-0
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-015-1988-0