Nothing Special   »   [go: up one dir, main page]

Skip to main content
Log in

Fragility of arbitrage and bubbles in local martingale diffusion models

  • Published:
Finance and Stochastics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

For any positive diffusion with minimal regularity, there exists a semimartingale with uniformly close paths that is a martingale under an equivalent probability. As a result, in models of asset prices based on such diffusions, arbitrage and bubbles alike disappear under proportional transaction costs or under small model mis-specifications. Thus, local martingale diffusion models of arbitrage and bubbles are not robust to small trading and monitoring frictions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. By the dual characterization of superhedging prices [2, 12], this definition is equivalent to (ii) in Definition 3.1.

  2. These processes are H (t)=μ +([0,t]) and H (t)=μ ([0,t]), where μ=μ +μ is the usual Hahn decomposition of the signed measure defined by μ([0,t])=H(t).

  3. To be precise, with a bid price less than or equal to S/(1+ε) and an ask price greater than or equal to S(1+ε). Definition 4.2 considers the buying price S(T)(1+ε) at time T and the selling price S(0)/(1+ε) at time zero, to ensure that the superreplication is robust to the initial cash/stock allocation and to settlement either in cash or in stock. To wit, in the worst case, the strategy ends in cash (i.e., H(T)=0), and delivering one share requires S(T)(1+ε). Likewise, in the worst case, the strategy begins in cash (H(0)=0), but the initial capital is all in stock, and its cash value is S(0)/(1+ε).

  4. Regrettably, in (c) of the statement of Theorem 3.1’’’, there is a misprint: there should be \(\mathcal{D}(Y)\) instead of \(\mathcal{K}(Y)\), which is clear from the ensuing remarks. See p. 372 of Michael [24] for the definition of \(\mathcal{D}(Y)\). This family contains finite-dimensional convex sets; hence, we may indeed apply Theorem 3.1’’’ in the current setting.

References

  1. Andersen, L.: Option pricing with quadratic volatility: a revisit. Finance Stoch. 15, 191–219 (2011)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  2. Ansel, J.-P., Stricker, C.: Couverture des actifs contingents et prix maximum. Ann. Inst. Henri Poincaré B, Probab. Stat. 30, 303–315 (1994)

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  3. Brossard, J.: Deux notions équivalentes d’unicité en loi pour les équations différentielles stochastiques. In: Azéma, J., Émery, M., Ledoux, M., Yor, M. (eds.) Séminaire de Probabilités XXXVII. Lecture Notes in Math., vol. 1832, pp. 246–250. Springer, Berlin (2003)

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  4. Chernyĭ, A.S.: On the uniqueness in law and pathwise uniqueness for stochastic differential equations. Theory Probab. Appl. 46, 406–419 (2003)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  5. Chung, K.L., Williams, R.J.: Introduction to Stochastic Integration, 2nd edn. Birkhäuser, Boston (1990)

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  6. Cox, A.M.G., Hobson, D.G.: Local martingales, bubbles and option prices. Finance Stoch. 9, 477–492 (2005)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  7. Delbaen, F., Schachermayer, W.: A general version of the fundamental theorem of asset pricing. Math. Ann. 300, 463–520 (1994)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  8. Delbaen, F., Schachermayer, W.: Arbitrage possibilities in Bessel processes and their relations to local martingales. Probab. Theory Relat. Fields 102, 357–366 (1995)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  9. Delbaen, F., Schachermayer, W.: A simple counterexample to several problems in the theory of asset pricing. Math. Finance 8, 1–11 (1998)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  10. Fernholz, D., Karatzas, I.: On optimal arbitrage. Ann. Appl. Probab. 20, 1179–1204 (2010)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  11. Fernholz, R., Karatzas, I., Kardaras, C.: Diversity and relative arbitrage in equity markets. Finance Stoch. 9, 1–27 (2005)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  12. Föllmer, H., Kabanov, Y.M.: Optional decomposition and Lagrange multipliers. Finance Stoch. 2, 69–81 (1998)

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  13. Guasoni, P., Rásonyi, M., Schachermayer, W.: Consistent price systems and face-lifting pricing under transaction costs. Ann. Appl. Probab. 18, 491–520 (2008)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  14. Heston, S., Loewenstein, M., Willard, G.: Options and bubbles. Rev. Financ. Stud. 20, 359–390 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Jarrow, R.A., Protter, P., Shimbo, K.: Asset price bubbles in complete markets. In: Fu, M.C., Jarrow, R.A., Yen, J.-Y.J., Elliott, R.J. (eds.) Advances in Mathematical Finance. Appl. Numer. Harmon. Anal., pp. 97–121. Birkhäuser Boston, Boston, MA (2007)

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  16. Jarrow, R.A., Protter, P., Shimbo, K.: Asset price bubbles in incomplete markets. Math. Finance 20, 145–185 (2010)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  17. Jarrow, R., Kchia, Y., Protter, P.: A gold bubble? Bloomberg’s Risk Newsletter, 8–9 (2011). Available online http://www.kamakuraco.com/LinkClick.aspx?fileticket=h1eVPApgzqQ

  18. Jarrow, R., Kchia, Y., Protter, P.: How to detect an asset bubble. SIAM J. Financ. Math. 1, 839–865 (2011)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  19. Jarrow, R., Kchia, Y., Protter, P.: Is there a bubble in Linkedin’s stock price? J. Portf. Manag. 38, 125–130 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Kabanov, Y., Stricker, C.: On equivalent martingale measures with bounded densities. In: Azéma, J., Émery, M., Ledoux, M., Yor, M. (eds.) Séminaire de Probabilités, XXXV. Lecture Notes in Math., vol. 1755, pp. 139–148. Springer, Berlin (2001)

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  21. Karatzas, I., Kardaras, C.: The numéraire portfolio in semimartingale financial models. Finance Stoch. 11, 447–493 (2007)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  22. Loewenstein, M., Willard, G.A.: Rational equilibrium asset-pricing bubbles in continuous trading models. J. Econ. Theory 91, 17–58 (2000)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  23. Madan, D.B., Yor, M.: Itô’s integrated formula for strict local martingales. In: Émery, M., Yor, M. (eds.) In memoriam Paul-André Meyer, Séminaire de Probabilités XXXIX. Lecture Notes in Math., vol. 1874, pp. 157–170. Springer, Berlin (2006)

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  24. Michael, E.: Continuous selections, I. Ann. Math. 63, 361–382 (1956)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  25. Pal, S., Protter, P.: Analysis of continuous strict local martingales via h-transforms. Stoch. Process. Appl. 120, 1424–1443 (2010)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  26. Platen, E.: A benchmark approach to finance. Math. Finance 16, 131–151 (2006)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  27. Prokaj, V., Rásonyi, M.: Local and true martingales in discrete time. Teor. Veroâtn. Ee Primen. 55, 398–405 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Protter, P.: A mathematical theory of financial bubbles. In: Le Cam, L.M., Neyman, J., Scott, E.L. (eds.) Paris–Princeton Lect. N. Math. 2013, pp. 1–108. Springer, Berlin (2013)

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  29. Ruf, J.: Hedging under arbitrage. Math. Finance 23, 297–317 (2013)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  30. Soner, H.M., Shreve, S.E., Cvitanić, J.: There is no nontrivial hedging portfolio for option pricing with transaction costs. Ann. Appl. Probab. 5, 327–355 (1995)

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  31. Stroock, D.W., Varadhan, S.R.S.: Diffusion processes with continuous coefficients. I. Commun. Pure Appl. Math. 22, 345–400 (1969)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  32. Stroock, D.W., Varadhan, S.R.S.: On the support of diffusion processes with applications to the strong maximum principle. In: Le Cam, L.M., Neyman, J., Scott, E.L. (eds.) Proceedings of the Sixth Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probability, Probability Theory, vol. 3, Univ. California, Berkeley, Calif. 1970/1971. pp. 333–359. University of California Press, Berkeley (1972)

    Google Scholar 

  33. Stroock, D.W., Varadhan, S.R.S.: Multidimensional Diffusion Processes. Classics in Mathematics. Springer, Berlin (2006). Reprint of the 1997 edition

    MATH  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Paolo Guasoni.

Additional information

We thank Dörte Kreher, Johannes Muhle-Karbe, Vilmos Prokaj, and Walter Schachermayer for their helpful comments. We are especially indebted to two anonymous referees, the Associate Editor, and the Editor, Martin Schweizer, for their patient and tireless effort in improving the paper’s technical and conceptual contribution. Any remaining errors are our own.

Paolo Guasoni is partially supported by the ERC (279582), NSF (DMS-1109047), SFI (07/SK/M1189, 08/SRC/FMC1389), and the European Commission (RG-248896).

Appendix:  Proofs

Appendix:  Proofs

In the sequel, we denote by \(C_{0}^{\infty}([s,T]\times\mathbb{R}^{d})\) the space of smooth functions with compact support on \([s,T]\times\mathbb{R}^{d}\), equipped with the topology of uniform convergence. The following lemma is essentially (part of) Theorem 10.1.1 of Stroock and Varadhan [33]. The latter result is stated on the canonical space, and we could not find a convenient reference for the present setting.

Lemma A.1

Let \(R^{s}_{\omega}\) be a regular version of the conditional law of X(t),t∈[s,T] (on C[s,T]) with respect to \(\mathcal{F}^{X}_{s}\). Then for almost every ωΩ, \(R^{s}_{\omega}\) solves the martingale problem on [s,T] related to (5.1) with initial condition X(s)(ω).

Proof

Recalling the definition of martingale problems from Chaps. 6 and 10 of Stroock and Varadhan [33], we need to prove that for almost every ωΩ and for each \(f\in C^{\infty}_{0}([s,T]\times\mathbb{R}^{d})\),

$$f \bigl(t,\pi(t,\cdot) \bigr)-f \bigl(s,X(s) \bigr)-\int_s^t (L_u f) \bigl(u,\pi (u,\cdot) \bigr)\,du,\quad t\in[s,T], $$

is an \((R^{s}_{\omega},(\mathcal{G}_{u})_{u\in[s,T]})\)-martingale, where π(u,⋅),u∈[s,T], denote the coordinate mappings on the canonical space C[s,T], \(\mathcal{G}_{u}:= \sigma(\pi(r,\cdot ),s\leq r\leq u)\), and the operator L acts as

$$\begin{aligned} (L_uf) (u,p)&:=\frac{\partial}{\partial u}f(u,p)+\frac{1}{2}\sum _{i,j=1}^d \bigl(\sigma\sigma^T \bigr)_{ij}(u,p) \frac{\partial^2}{\partial p_i\partial p_j}f(u,p) \\ &\quad +\sum_{i=1}^d b_i(u,p) \frac{\partial}{ \partial p_i}f(u,p). \end{aligned}$$

Denote by w a generic element of C[s,T]. Then it is clearly sufficient to prove that for almost all ω,

$$\begin{aligned} & \int_{C[s,T]} \biggl(f \bigl(t,\pi(t,w) \bigr)-f \bigl(r,\pi(r,w) \bigr)-\int_r^t (L_u f) \bigl(u,\pi(u,w) \bigr)\,du \biggr) \\ &\quad {}\times g(u_1,\ldots,u_n) R^s_{\omega}(dw)=0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

for suitable countable collections of \(f\in C_{0}^{\infty}([s,T]\times \mathbb{R}^{d})\), bounded measurable g, and for all rationals s<r<tT and u i ∈(s,r), i=1,…,n. Equality (A.1) follows from

$$\begin{aligned} &E \biggl[g \bigl(X({u_1}),\ldots,X({u_n}) \bigr) \\ &\quad {}\times \biggl(f \bigl(t,X(t) \bigr)-f \bigl(r,X(r) \bigr)-\int _{r}^t (L_uf) \bigl(u,X(u) \bigr)\,du \biggr) \bigg\vert \mathcal{F}^X_s \biggr]=0 \end{aligned}$$

a.s. This holds by Itô’s formula, the tower law, and

$$E \biggl[ \int_r^t \frac{\partial}{\partial p}f \bigl(u,X(u) \bigr)\sigma \bigl(u,X(u) \bigr)\,dW(u) \bigg\vert \mathcal{F}_r \biggr]=0, $$

which is an elementary property of stochastic integrals since f and its derivatives have compact support and σ is continuous and hence bounded on compact sets. □

Proof of Theorem 5.2

To ease notation, consider d=1; the same argument carries over to the general case. Recall the concept of conditional full support: A strictly positive adapted process S defined on \((\varOmega,\mathcal{F},(\mathcal{F}_{t})_{t\in[0,T]},P)\) with continuous paths has conditional full support (CFS) if

$$\operatorname{supp} P [S\vert_{[t,T]}\in\cdot \vert\mathcal {F}_t ]=C_{S_t}^+[t,T]\quad \mbox{a.s. for all }t \in[0,T], $$

where \(\operatorname{supp} \mu\) denotes the support of a measure μ, and C v [c,d] (resp. \(C_{v}^{+}[c,d]\)) is the set of continuous functions (resp. strictly positive continuous functions) f on [c,d] with f(c)=v.

Theorem 1.2 of Guasoni et al. [13] states that for a process satisfying CFS, there exist QP and a Q-martingale \(\tilde{S}\) (with respect to \((\mathcal{F}^{X}_{t})\)) that is ε-close to S. Thus, \(M(t):=\tilde{S}(t)E[\frac{dQ}{dP}\vert{\mathcal{F}^{X}_{t}}]\) is a P-martingale (with respect to \((\mathcal{F}^{X}_{t})\)), and if \((\mathcal {F}^{X}_{t})\) is the natural filtration of some Brownian motion, then M as well as the (positive) P-martingale \((E[\frac{dQ}{dP}\vert {\mathcal{F}^{X}_{t}}])\) must have continuous paths, and so must \(\tilde{S}\).

It remains to prove the CFS property for S with respect to \((\mathcal {F}^{X}_{t})\). Let P s,y denote the law of a solution of (5.1) starting from \(\bar{X}(s)=y\) on C[s,T]. Replacing \(\mathcal{F}^{X}_{t}\), ts, by \(\mathcal{F}^{\bar{X}}_{t}\), ts, in Lemma A.1, the same argument gives that P s,y solves the martingale problem related to (5.1) with initial condition \(\bar{X}(s)=y\) (we do not even need to work with conditional expectations in this case, \(\mathcal{F}_{s}^{\bar{X}}\) being trivial). We can now take a regular version of P s,y as provided by Theorem 10.1.1 of Stroock and Varadhan [33]. Let us now notice that uniqueness in law (see Assumption 5.1) and Lemma A.1 necessarily entail \(P^{s,X(s)(\omega)}=R_{\omega}^{s}\) a.s.

Thus, it suffices to show that \(\operatorname{supp} R^{s}_{\cdot}=\operatorname{supp} P^{s,X(s)}=C_{X(s)}[s,T]\) a.s. for each 0≤s<T. To achieve this, we prove that for all \(y\in\mathbb{R}\), η∈(0,1), and gC y [s,T],

$$P^{s,y} \bigl[\bigl\{ f\in C_y[s,T]:\Vert f-g \Vert_{\infty}< \eta\bigr\} \bigr]>0. $$

Define K:=∥g+1, \(\tilde{b}(t,x):=b(t,x)1_{\{ \vert x\vert\leq K\}}\) and \(\tilde{\sigma}(t,x):=\sigma(t,x)\) for (t,x)∈[0,T]×[−K,K]. Note that by continuity there exists h>0 such that

$$\vert\tilde{\sigma}(t,x)\vert> h\quad\text{for all }(t,x)\in [0,T] \times[-K,K] . $$

Extend \(\tilde{\sigma}\) to \([0,T]\times\mathbb{R}\) so that \(|\tilde {\sigma}(t,x)|\geq h\) for all (t,x) and \(\tilde{\sigma}\) remains continuous. Since \(\tilde{b},\tilde{\sigma}\) are bounded and \(\tilde{\sigma}\) is bounded away from 0 and continuous, the martingale problem

$$d\tilde{X}(t)=\tilde{b} \bigl(t,\tilde{X}(t) \bigr)\,dt+\tilde{\sigma } \bigl(t, \tilde{X}(t) \bigr)\,dW(t),\quad \tilde{X}(s)=y, $$

admits unique solution measures \(\tilde{P}^{s,y}\) on the space C y [s,T] for all 0≤s<T; see Stroock and Varadhan [31] and Chap. 7 of Stroock and Varadhan [33].

Take τ(w):=inf{t>s:|w(t)|≥K}∧T, where w is the generic element of the canonical space C y [s,T]. Let us denote by π(t,⋅) the coordinate mapping on C y [s,T] corresponding to stT. Obviously, τ is a \((\mathcal{G}_{t})_{t\in[s,T]}\)-stopping time (recall that \(\mathcal{G}\) is the filtration generated by the coordinate mappings). The last part of Theorem 6.1.2 of Stroock and Varadhan [33] implies that both measure-concatenations \(\tilde{P}^{s,y}\otimes_{\tau(\cdot)}{P}^{\tau(\cdot),\pi(\tau (\cdot ),\cdot)}\) and P s,y τ(⋅) P τ(⋅),π(τ(⋅),⋅) solve the martingale problem (5.1) on [s,T] (see Theorem 6.1.2 of Stroock and Varadhan [33] for unexplained notation), and hence these measures are equal on \(\mathcal{G}_{T}\). A fortiori, \(P^{s,y}\vert\mathcal{G}_{\tau}=\tilde {P}^{s,y}\vert\mathcal{G}_{\tau}\). The event {fC y [s,T]:∥fg<η} is in \(\mathcal{G}_{\tau}\); consequently,

$$\begin{aligned} {P}^{s,y} \bigl[\bigl\{ f\in C_{y}[s,T]:\Vert f-g \Vert_{\infty}< \eta\bigr\} \bigr]= \tilde{P}^{s,y} \bigl[\bigl\{ f \in C_{y}[s,T]:\Vert f-g\Vert_{\infty}<\eta\bigr\} \bigr]. \end{aligned}$$

The functions \(\tilde{\sigma}\) and \(\tilde{b}\) satisfy the conditions of Sect. 3 in Stroock and Varadhan [32]; hence, Lemma 3.1 of Stroock and Varadhan [32] (or Exercise 6.7.5 of Stroock and Varadhan [33]) implies that \(\tilde{P}^{s,y}[\{ f\in C_{y}[s,T]:\Vert f-g\Vert_{\infty}<\eta\}]>0\), concluding the proof. □

Proof of Theorem 6.2

Let us define the multifunction

$$D(t,x):= \biggl\{ u\in\mathbb{R}^{(N-d)\times N}: \det \begin{bmatrix} \sigma(t,x)\\ u \end{bmatrix} >0 \biggr\} $$

for \((t,x)\in[0,T]\times\mathbb{R}^{d}\). Clearly, D takes convex nonempty values in a finite-dimensional space, and its graph is \(\mathcal{B}([0,T]\times \mathbb{R}^{d})\otimes\mathcal{B}(\mathbb{R}^{(N-d)\times N})\)-measurable. It is also lower semicontinuous. Indeed, by Proposition 2.1 of Michael [24] it suffices to prove that if uD(t,x) and ϵ>0, then there is δ>0 such that for all t′,x′ with |tt′|+|xx′|<δ and there is u′∈D(t′,x′) with |uu′|<ϵ. But this is obvious by the continuity of σ and of the determinant function.

Now we may apply Theorem 3.1’’’ of Michael [24], which gives us a continuous \(\nu:[0,T]\times\mathbb{R}^{d}\to\mathbb {R}^{(N-d)\times N}\) such that ν(t,x)∈D(t,x) for all (t,x).Footnote 4 Let us define \(\hat{\sigma}:[0,T]\times\mathbb{R}^{d}\to\mathbb {R}^{N\times N}\) such that its first d rows equal σ and the remaining rows equal ν. Let us also consider \(\hat{b}:(t,x)\mapsto(b(x),\mathbf{0})^{T}\) (where 0 denotes an (Nd)-dimensional row vector of zeros). By abuse of notation, we write from now on \(\hat{b}(t,y):=\hat{b}(t,\bar{y}^{d})\) for all \(y\in\mathbb{R}^{N}\), where \(\bar{y}^{d}\) denotes the vector formed by the first d coordinates of y. We define \(\hat{\sigma}\) similarly and hence extend \(\hat{b},\hat{\sigma}\) to \([0,T]\times\mathbb{R}^{N}\) (note that the last Nd coordinates are dummy variables only).

Define \(\bar{X}^{i}(t):=X^{i}(t)\) for i=1,…,d and set

$$\bar{X}^i(t):=\int_0^t \hat{ \sigma}_i \bigl(s,X(s) \bigr)\,dW(s) $$

for i=d+1,…,N, where \(\hat{\sigma}_{i}\) denotes the ith row of \(\hat{\sigma}\). By construction, \(\bar{X}\) satisfies

$$d\bar{X}(t)=\hat{b} \bigl(t,\bar{X}(t) \bigr)\,dt+\hat{\sigma} \bigl(t,\bar {X}(t) \bigr)\,dW(t),\quad\bar{X}(0)=\hat{x}_0, $$

where the first d components of \(\hat{x}_{0}\) coincide with those of x 0, and the remaining components are zero. By Assumption 6.1, X is unique in law. Theorem 3.1 of [4] or the main result in [3] implies that also the law of the pair (X,W) is unique. Since \(\bar{X}\) is a functional of (X,W), its law is unique as well; so \(\hat{b},\hat{\sigma}\) clearly satisfy the conditions of Theorem 5.2, and hence for \(\bar{S}^{i}(t)=\exp(\bar{X}^{i}(t))\), i=1,…,N, we get an N-dimensional process \(\check{S}\) that is ε-close to \(\bar{S}\). Notice that the first d coordinates of \(\bar{S}\) are precisely S. Denoting by \(\tilde{S}\) the d-dimensional process consisting of the first d coordinates of \(\check{S}\), we clearly have that \(\tilde{S}\) is ε-close to S.

From Theorem 5.2 we have the existence of a probability RP such that \(\check{S}\) is a (true) R-martingale (with respect to \((\mathcal{F}^{\bar{X}}_{t})\)); in particular, \(R\in \mathcal{M}(\tilde{S})\). Note that the construction in Guasoni et al. [13] ensures that \(\check{S}(T)\in L^{2}(R)\). A fortiori, \(\tilde{S}\) is an L 2(R)-martingale, and hence \(\sup_{t\in[0,T]}|\tilde{S}_{t}|\in L^{2}(R)\). Now recall that the set of \(Q'\in\mathcal{M}(\tilde{S})\) such that dQ′/dR is bounded is dense in \(\mathcal{M}(\tilde{S})\) with respect to the total-variation norm (see Kabanov and Stricker [20]). Clearly, \(\tilde{S}\) satisfies \(\sup_{t\in[0,T]}|\tilde{S}_{t}|\in L^{2}(Q')\) as well; so it is a true Q′-martingale for all such Q′. This finishes the proof. □

Remark A.2

If in the statements of Theorems 5.2 and 6.2, the solutions X are strong and \(\mathcal{F}=\mathcal{F}^{W}\), then the proof of Lemma A.1 works with the filtration \(\mathcal{F}^{W}\) in lieu of \(\mathcal{F}^{X}\). Hence, the proofs of Theorems 5.2 and 6.2 yield \(\tilde{S}\) that are \(\mathcal{F}^{W}\)-martingales and, in particular, continuous.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Guasoni, P., Rásonyi, M. Fragility of arbitrage and bubbles in local martingale diffusion models. Finance Stoch 19, 215–231 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-015-0256-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-015-0256-0

Keywords

Mathematics Subject Classification (2010)

JEL Classification

Navigation