Nothing Special   »   [go: up one dir, main page]

Skip to main content
Log in

Investment strategies of duopoly firms with asymmetric time-to-build under a jump-diffusion model

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Mathematical Methods of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper employs a two-factor jump-diffusion model to investigate the optimal investment timing and capacity choice of the duopoly firms in the presence of uncertain and asymmetric time-to-build. By assuming that both the market demand and investment cost follow the jump-diffusion process, we show that the impacts of uncertainty of time-to-build on duopoly firms’ the optimal investment decisions depend on the directions of jumps in demand and investment cost. Moreover, the asymmetry of time-to-build makes it possible for the dominated firm to preempt the market successfully and becomes the leader. The leader’s capacity level increases with the dominated firm’s time-to-build and the follower’s decreases, even if the dominated firm is the leader. We also apply numerical simulation to compare the main results between two-factor diffusion model and two-factor jump-diffusion model.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Availability of data and material

All data generated or analyzed during this study are included in this paper.

References

  • Aguerrevere FL (2003) Equilibrium investment strategies and output price behavior: a real-options approach. Rev Financ Stud 16(4):1239–1272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agliardi E, Koussis N (2013) Optimal capital structure and the impact of time-to-build. Financ Res Lett 10(3):124–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azevedo A, Paxson D (2014) Developing real option game models. Eur J Oper Res 237(3):909–920

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Bar-Ilan A, Strange WC (1996) Investment lags. Am Econ Rev 86(3):610–622

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit AK, Pindyck RS (1994) Investment under uncertainty. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Eberlein E, Glau K (2014) Variational solutions of the pricing PIDEs for European options in Lévy models. Appl Math Financ 21(5):417–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg D, Tirole J (1985) Preemption and rent equalization in te adoption of new technology. Rev Econ Stud 52(3):192–207

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grenadier SR (1996) The strategic exercise of options: development cascades and over-building in real estate markets. J Financ 51(5):1653–1679

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grenadier SR (2000) Equilibrium with time-to-build. In: Brennan M, Trigeorgis L (eds) Project flexibility, agency, and competition. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 275–296

    Google Scholar 

  • Genc TS (2017) The impact of lead time on capital investments. J Econ Dyn Control 82(1):142–164

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • He H, Pindyck R (1992) Investment in flexible production capacity. J Econ Dyn Control 16:575–599

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huisman KJM, Kort PM (2004) Strategic technology adoption taking into account future technological improvement: a real options approach. Eur J Oper Res 159(3):705–728

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Hagspiel V, Huisman KJM, Nunes C (2015) Optimal technology adoption when the arrival rate of new technologies changes. Eur J Oper Res 243(3):897–911

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Huisman KJM, Kort PM (2015) Strategic capacity investment under uncertainty. Rand J Econ 46(2):376–408

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huberts NED, Dawid H, Huisman KJM, Kort PM (2019) Entry deterrence by timing rather than overinvestment in a strategic real options framework. Eur J Oper Res 274(1):165–185

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Johannes M (2004) The statistical and economic role of jumps in continuous-time interest rate models. J Financ 59(1):227–260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jeon H (2021) Investment timing and capacity decisions with time-to-build in a Duopoly market. J Econ Dyn Control 122:104028

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Koeva P (2000) The facts about time-to-build. Working Paper no. WP/00/138, International Monetary Fund

  • Kauppinen L, Siddiqui AS, Salo A (2018) Investing in time-to-build projects with uncertain revenues and costs: a real options approach. IEEE Trans Eng Manag 65(3):448–459

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee SS, Mykland PA (2008) Jumps in financial markets: a new nonparametric test and jump dynamics. Rev Financ Stud 21(6):2535–2563

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liang J, Yang M, Jiang L (2013) A closed-form solution for the exercise strategy in a real options model with a jump-diffusion process. SIAM J Appl Math 73(1):549–571

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Lavrutich MN, Huisman KJM, Kort PM (2016) Entry deterrence and hidden competition. J Econ Dyn Control 69:409–435

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Lavrutich MN (2017) Capacity choice under uncertainty in a duopoly with endogenous exit. Eur J Oper Res 258(3):1033–1053

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC (1976) Option pricing when underlying stock returns are discontinuous. J Financ Econ 3(1–2):125–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McDonald R, Siegel D (1986) The value of waiting to invest. J Econ 101(4):707–727

    Google Scholar 

  • Mauer DC, Ott S (2000) Agency costs, under-investment, and optimal capital structure: the effect of growth options to expand. In: Brennan M, Terigeorigis L (eds) Project flexibility, agency, and completition. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 151–180

    Google Scholar 

  • Martzoukos SH, Trigeorgis L (2002) Real (investment) options with multiple sources of rare events. Eur J Oper Res 136(3):696–706

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Murto P (2007) Timing of investment under technological and revenue-related uncertainties. J Econ Dyn Control 31(5):1473–1497

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Mason CF, Wilmot NA (2014) Jump processes in natural gas markets. Energ Econ 46(1):69–79

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nielsen MJ (2002) Competition and irreversible investments. Int J Ind Organ 20(5):731–743

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nunes C, Pimentel R (2017) Analytical solution for an investment problem under uncertainties with shocks. Eur J Oper Res 259(3):1054–1063

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Pindyck R (1988) Irreversible investment, capacity choice, and the value of the firm. Am Ecom Rev 78:969–985

    Google Scholar 

  • Pan J (2002) The jump-risk premia implicit in options: evidence from an integrated time-series study. J Financ Econ 63(1):3–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pacheco-de-Almeida G, Zemsky P (2003) The effect of time-to-build on strategic investment under uncertainty. Rand J Econ 34(1):166–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smets F (1993) Essays on foreign direct investment. Ph.D. Thesis, Yale University, New Haven

  • Siddiqui A, Takashima R (2012) Capacity switching options under rivalry and uncertainty. Eur J Oper Res 222(3):583–595

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Thijssen JJJ, Huisman KJM, Kort PM (2012) Symmetric equilibrium strategies in game theoretic real option models. J Math Econ 48(4):219–225

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Westman JJ, Hanson FB (2000) Non-linear state dynamics: computational methods and manufacturing application. Int J Control 73(6):464–480

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Weeds H (2002) Strategic delay in a real options model of R &D competition. Rev Econ Stud 69(3):729–747

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Wu MC, Yen SH (2007) Pricing real growth options when the underlying assets have jump diffusion processes: the case of R &D investments. R &D Manag 37(3):269–276

    Google Scholar 

  • Wu XQ, Hu ZJ (2022) Investment timing and capacity choice in duopolistic competition under a jump-diffusion model. Math Financ Econ 16:125–152

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

Download references

Funding

This research was funded by the Key Project of Education Science Planning in Heilongjiang Province for 2021 (No. 477) and Open topic project of Think tank (No. ZKKF2022208).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Baiqing Sun.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that there are no conflict of interest regarding the publication of this paper.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix A Linear demand function

Appendix A Linear demand function

1.1 Proof of Theorem 1

Given the current demand-to-cost ratio \(\theta \), maximizing (10) with respect to \(Q_M\), we can yield the optimal capacity as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} Q_{M}^{*}(\theta )=\underset{Q_{M}\ge 0}{\arg \max } g_{M}(\theta ,Q_{M})=\frac{1}{2\eta }\left( 1-\frac{\xi +b_{X}}{\xi +b_{Y}} \frac{1}{\theta }\right) \end{aligned}$$
(A1)

Following Wu and Hu (2022), the firm’s value under the new state variable, \(v_{M}(\theta )\) in (9), satisfies the following HJB equation

$$\begin{aligned} r v_{M}(\theta )&=\frac{1}{2}\left( \sigma _{X}^{2}+\sigma _{Y}^{2}\right) \theta ^{2}v_{M}^{''}(\theta )+(\mu _{X}-\mu _{Y})\theta v_{M}^{'}(\theta )+(\mu _{Y}-\lambda _{X}-\lambda _{Y})v_{M}(\theta )\nonumber \\&\quad +\lambda _{X} E\left[ v_{M}\left( \theta (1+U^{X})\right) \right] +\lambda _{Y} E\left[ (1+U^{Y}) v_{M}\left( \frac{\theta }{1+U^{Y}}\right) \right] \end{aligned}$$
(A2)

subject to

$$\begin{aligned}{} & {} v_{M}(0)=0 \end{aligned}$$
(A3)
$$\begin{aligned}{} & {} v_{M}\left( \theta \right) \mid _{\theta =\theta _{M}^{*}}=g_{M}\left( \theta , Q_{M}^{*}(\theta )\right) \mid _{\theta =\theta _{M}^{*}} \end{aligned}$$
(A4)
$$\begin{aligned}{} & {} \frac{\partial v_{M}(\theta )}{\partial \theta }\mid _{\theta =\theta _{M}^{*}}=\frac{\partial g_{M}(\theta ,Q_{M}^{*}(\theta )}{\partial \theta }\mid _{\theta =\theta _{M}^{*}} \end{aligned}$$
(A5)

Meanwhile, the general solution of (A2) with the initial condition (A3) takes the form

$$\begin{aligned} v_{M}(\theta )=A_{M}\theta ^{\beta _1} \end{aligned}$$
(A6)

where \(\beta _{1}\) is the positive root (\(>1\)) of (13) (e.g., Nunes and Pimentel 2017). Substituting (A6)(10) into (A4)(A5) gives

$$\begin{aligned} \theta _{M}^{*}(Q_{M})= & {} \frac{\beta _{1}}{\beta _{1}-1}\frac{b_{X}(\xi +b_{X})}{b_{Y}(\xi +b_{Y})(1-\eta Q_{M})} \end{aligned}$$
(A7)
$$\begin{aligned} A_{M}= & {} \frac{\xi }{(\beta _{1}^2-1)\eta b_{Y}(\xi +b_{Y})}(\theta _{M}^{*})^{-\beta _{1}} \end{aligned}$$
(A8)

After solving the system of Eqs. (A1) and (A8) we get the results in Theorem 1.

1.2 Duopoly market

First of all, we investigate the duopoly firms’ optimal investment decisions when the market roles are exogenous. To this end, we first formalize the firm’s value function, and consequently by maximizing the value function at the moment of investing, the optimal capacity level can be derived. By solving the HJB equation the value function satisfies, the optimal investment threshold can be obtained. According to this train of thought, we discuss the follower’s optimal investment decisions when its investment timing is earlier and later than the manufacturing timing of the leader in Appendix A.2.1 and  A.2.2. In Appendix A.2.3, we proceed to explore the leader’s investment decision. By taking the preemptive incentive into consideration, we further study the equilibrium investment strategies of duopoly enterprises under competition in Appendix A.2.4.

1.2.1 Proof of Theorem 2

Given the current demand-to-cost ratio \(\theta \) and the leader’s capacity level \(Q_L^i\), the type j follower’s profit flow obtained at the investment timing when investing with capacity \(Q_{F1}^{j}\) can be evaluated as

$$\begin{aligned} g_{F1}^{j}\left( \theta ,Q_{L}^{i},Q_{F1}^{j}\right)&=\frac{1}{Y}G_{F1}^{j}\left( X,Y,Q_{L}^{i},Q_{F1}^{j}\right) \nonumber \\&=\xi _{j}Q_{F1}^{j}\left[ \frac{\left( 1-\eta (Q_{L}^{i}+Q_{F1}^{j})\right) \theta }{b_X(\xi _{j}+b_{X})}-\frac{1}{b_Y(\xi _{j}+b_{Y})}\right] \end{aligned}$$
(A9)

maximizing (A9) with respect to \(Q_{F1}^j\), the optimal capacity level can be obtained as

$$\begin{aligned} Q_{F1}^{j*}(\theta ,Q_{L}^{i})=\frac{1}{2\eta }\left( 1-\eta Q_{L}^{i}-\frac{\xi _{j}+b_{X}}{\xi _{j}+b_{Y}} \frac{1}{\theta }\right) \end{aligned}$$
(A10)

Before investing, the follower’s value, \(v_{F1}^{j}(\theta )\), equals to the value of the investment option the firm holds, which is

$$\begin{aligned} v_{F1}^{j}(\theta )=A_{F1}^{j}\theta ^{\beta _1} \end{aligned}$$
(A11)

Substituting (A9) (A10) (A11) into the corresponding value matching and smooth pasting conditions yields

$$\begin{aligned} \theta _{F1}^{j*}(Q_{L}^{i})= & {} \frac{(\beta _{1}+1)b_X(\xi _{j}+b_{X})}{(\beta _{1}-1)b_Y(\xi _{j}+b_{Y})(1-\eta Q_{L}^{i})} \end{aligned}$$
(A12)
$$\begin{aligned} A_{F1}^{j}(Q_{L}^{i})= & {} g_{F1}^{j}(Q_{L}^{i})(\theta _{F1}^{j*}(Q_{L}^{i}))^{-\beta _{1}} \end{aligned}$$
(A13)

Substituting (A12) into (A10) we can conclude the follower’s optimal investment strategy after the leader’s product entering the market in Theorem 2.

1.2.2 Proof of Theorem 3

Given the current demand-to-cost ratio \(\theta \) and the leader’s capacity level \(Q_L^i\), assuming that the type j follower invests with capacity \(Q_{F0}^{j}\), then the expected profit flow the follower obtained at the moment of investment can be evaluated as

$$\begin{aligned} g_{F0}^{j}(\theta ,Q_{L}^{i},Q_{F0}^{j})&=\frac{Q_{F0}^{j}\xi _{i}\xi _{j}\left( 1-\eta (Q_{L}^{i}+Q_{F0}^{j})\right) \theta }{b_X(\xi _{j}+b_{X})(\xi _{i}+\xi _{j}+b_{X})}-\frac{Q_{F0}^{j}\xi _{j}}{b_Y(\xi _{j}+b_{Y})}\nonumber \\&\quad +\frac{Q_{F0}^{j}\xi _{j}\theta }{b_X(\xi _{i}+\xi _{j}+b_{X})}\left[ (1-\eta Q_{F 0}^{j})-\frac{\xi _{i}\eta Q_{L}^{i}}{\xi _{i}+b_{X}}\right] \end{aligned}$$
(A14)

maximizing (A14) with respect to \(Q_{F0}^j\), the follower’s optimal capacity level can be obtained as described in (39).

In the meanwhile, before investing, the firm’s value, \(v_{F0}^{j}(\theta )\), should satisfy the following HJB equation:

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{1}{2}(\sigma _{X}^{2}+\sigma _{Y}^{2})\theta ^{2}v_{F0}^{j''}(\theta )+(\mu _{X}-\mu _{Y})\theta v_{F0}^{j'}(\theta )-(r-\mu _{Y}+\lambda _{X}+\lambda _{Y})v_{F0}^{j}(\theta )\nonumber \\&\quad +\lambda _{X}E\left[ v_{F0}^{j}\left( (1+U^{X})\theta \right) \right] +\lambda _{Y} E\left[ (1+U^{Y})v_{F0}^{j}\left( \frac{\theta }{1+U^{Y}}\right) \right] \nonumber \\&\quad +\xi _{i}(v_{F1}^{j}(\theta )-v_{F0}^{j}(\theta ))=0 \end{aligned}$$
(A15)

where \(v_{F1}^{j}(\theta )\) is defined by (A11) through (A13). Unlike before, a general solution of (A15) with the initial condition is

$$\begin{aligned} v_{F0}^{j}(\theta )=v_{F1}^{j}(\theta )+A_{F0}^{j}\theta ^{\gamma _i} \end{aligned}$$
(A16)

where \(\gamma _i\) is the positive (\(>1\)) of the following equation

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{1}{2}(\sigma _{X}^{2}+\sigma _{Y}^{2})\gamma (\gamma -1)+(\mu _{X}-\mu _{Y}) \gamma +\lambda _{X}E\left[ (1+U^{X})^{\gamma }\right] +\lambda _{Y}E\left[ (1+U^{Y})^{1-\gamma }\right] \nonumber \\&\quad -(r+\lambda _{i}-\mu _{Y}+\lambda _{X}+\lambda _{Y})=0 \end{aligned}$$
(A17)

Substituting (A14), (A16) and (39) into the boundary conditions, we can derive successively the value function, optimal investment threshold as well as capacity level of the follower given in Theorem 3.

1.2.3 Proof of Theorem 4

Given the current demand-to-cost ratio \(\theta \) and the follower’s investment strategies \(\left\{ \theta _{F0}^{j},\theta _{F1}^{j}\right\} , \left\{ Q_{F0}^{j}, Q_{F1}^{j}\right\} \), the expected profit flow the type i leader obtains when invests with capacity level \(Q_{L}^{i}\) at the moment of investment can be evaluated as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&g_{L}^{i}(\theta ,Q_{L}^{i})=\frac{\xi _{i}(1-\eta Q_{L}^{i})Q_{L}^{i}\theta }{b_X(\xi _{i}+b_{X})}-\frac{\xi _{i} Q_{L}^{i}}{b_Y(\xi _{i}+b_{Y})}\nonumber \\&\quad -\left( \frac{\theta }{\theta _{F0}^{j*}(Q_{L}^{i})}\right) ^{\gamma _{i}}\frac{\xi _{i}\xi _{j}\eta Q_{L}^{i}Q_{F0}^{j*}(Q_{L}^{i})\theta _{F0}^{j*}(Q_{L}^{i})}{b_X(\xi _{i}+\xi _{j}+b_X)}\left( \frac{1}{\xi _{i}+b_{X}}+\frac{1}{\xi _{j}+b_{X}}\right) \nonumber \\&\quad -\left[ \left( \frac{\theta }{\theta _{F1}^{j*}(Q_{L}^{i})}\right) ^{\beta _{1}}-\left( \frac{\theta }{\theta _{F0}^{j*}(Q_{L}^{i})}\right) ^{\gamma _{i}} \left( \frac{\theta _{F0}^{j*}(Q_{L}^{i})}{\theta _{F1}^{j*}(Q_{L}^{i})}\right) ^{\beta _{1}}\right] \frac{\xi _{j}\eta Q_{L}^{i}Q_{F1}^{j*}(Q_{L}^{i})\theta _{F1}^{j*}(Q_{L}^{i})}{b_X(\xi _{j}+b_{X})} \end{aligned}$$
(A18)

maximizing (A18) with respect to \(Q_L^i\), the optimal capacity level can be obtained as

$$\begin{aligned} Q_{L}^{i*}(\theta )=\underset{Q_{L}^{i}\ge 0}{\arg \max }g_{L}^{i}(\theta , Q_{L}^{i}) \end{aligned}$$
(A19)

Meanwhile, the value of the leader before investing, \(v_{L}^{i}(\theta )\), equals to the value of the investment option the firm holds, which is

$$\begin{aligned} v_{L}^{i}(\theta )=A_{L}^{i} \theta ^{\beta _{1}} \end{aligned}$$
(A20)

Substituting (A18) and (A20) into the boundary conditions, we can obtain successively the value function of the leader, optimal investment threshold as well as the corresponding optimal capacity given in Theorem 4.

1.2.4 Proof of Theorem 5

Firstly, following Huisman and Kort (2015), we assume that both firms have incentives to preempt the market, that is, \(\theta _{P}^{i}\ne \emptyset \) for \(i\in \{A,B\}\), indicating that there exists at least a \(\theta \) such that \(V_{P}^{i}(\theta )\ge V_{F0}^{i}(\theta , Q_{L}^{j*}(\theta ))\) holds. With this assumption, two possible scenarios are be considered.

If \(\theta _{P}^{i*}\le \theta _{P}^{j*}\le \theta _{L}^{i*}\) for \(i\ne j\) and \(i,j\in \{A,B\}\), the type i firm succeeds in the preemption game and optimally invests at \(\theta _{P}^{j*}-\varepsilon \), which is infinitely close to \(\theta _{P}^{j*}\). Therefore, the investment is made at \(\theta _{P}^{j*}\) as \(\varepsilon \) approaches 0 and the capacity choice is \(Q_{P}^{i*}=Q_{L}^{i*}(\theta _{P}^{j*})\). Meanwhile, failure in the preemptive game leads to the type j firm implements the investment decision as a follower, whose optimal investment decisions are shown in Theorems 2 and 3. Otherwise, if \(\theta _{P}^{i*}\le \theta _{L}^{i*}\le \theta _{P}^{j*}\) for \(i\ne j\), since the type j firm will not invest before the demand-to-cost ratio reaches \(\theta _{P}^{j*}\), the type i firm’s optimal investment should be made at \(\theta _{L}^{i*}\) instead of \(\theta _{P}^{i*}\). Consequently, the firms’ investment strategies follow those in Theorem 2 through 4.

Secondly, we assume that only one firm has an incentive to preempt the market. Without loss of generality, we assume that \(\theta _{P}^{i}\ne \emptyset \) and \(\theta _{P}^{j}=\emptyset \) for \(i\ne j\) and \(i,j\in \{A,B\}\), indicating that there exists at least a \(\theta \) such that \(V_{P}^{i}(\theta )\ge V_{F0}^{i}(\theta ,Q_{L}^{j*}(\theta ))\) holds, whereas \(V_{P}^{j}(\theta )< V_{F0}^{j}(\theta ,Q_{L}^{j*}(\theta ))\) for all \(\theta \). In this case, both firms’ investment strategies follow those in Theorem 2 through 4.

1.3 Proof of Theorem 6

Suppose that we have already assigned the type i and j firm as the market leader and follower respectively. First of all, with the assumption that the leader’s product has already entered into the market, we can examine social planner’s optimal investment decision by solving the following problem:

$$\begin{aligned}&sw_{F1}^{ij}(\theta )=\frac{1}{Y}SW_{F1}^{ij}(X,Y)=\frac{1}{Y}\underset{T_{F1}^{j}\ge 0,Q_{F1}^{j}\ge 0}{\max }E^{(X,Y)}\left[ \int _{0}^{{\overline{T}}_{F1}^{j}}e^{-rt}\frac{X_{t} Q_{L}^{i}(2-\eta Q_{L}^{i})}{2}\right. \nonumber \\&\quad \left. dt+\int _{{\overline{T}}_{F1}^{j}}^{+\infty }e^{-rt}\left( \frac{X_{t}(Q_{L}^{i}+Q_{F1}^{j})\left( 2-\eta (Q_{L}^{i}+Q_{F1}^{j})\right) }{2}- Q_{F1}^{j}Y_{t}\right) dt\right] \end{aligned}$$
(A21)

Combining the initial condition and boundary conditions, we can straightforward calculate the optimal investment threshold \(\theta _{F1}^{j**}(Q_{L}^{i})\) and capacity level \(Q_{F1}^{j**}(Q_{L}^{i})\) of the type j follower in view of welfare-maximizing, as shown in (62) and (63).

Secondly, we examine social planner’s optimal investment decision with the assumption that the leader’s product hasn’t entered into the market yet by solving

$$\begin{aligned}&sw_{F0}^{ij}(\theta )=\frac{1}{Y}\max _{T_{F0}^j,Q_{F0}^j\ge 0}E^{(X, Y)}\left[ 1_{\left\{ {\overline{T}}_L^i<T_{F0}^j\right\} }e^{-r{\overline{T}}_L^i}SW_{F1}^{ij}(X_{{\overline{T}}_L^i},Y_{{\overline{T}}_L^i})+1_{\left\{ T_{F 0}^j \le {\overline{T}}_L^i<{\overline{T}}_{F0}^j\right\} }\right. \nonumber \\&\left\{ \int _{{\overline{T}}_L^i}^{{\overline{T}}_{F0}^j}e^{-rt}\frac{X_tQ_L^i\left( 2-\eta Q_L^i\right) }{2} dt+\int _{{\overline{T}}_{F 0}^j}^{+\infty } e^{-rt}\left[ \frac{X_t(Q_L^i+Q_{F 0}^j)\left( 2-\eta (Q_L^i+Q_{F 0}^j)\right) }{2}\right. \right. \nonumber \\&\quad -\left. \left. Q_{F0}^jY_t\right] dt\right\} +1_{\left\{ {\overline{T}}_L^i\ge {\overline{T}}_{F0}^j\right\} }\left\{ \int _{{\overline{T}}_{F 0}^j}^{{\overline{T}}_L^i} e^{-rt}\frac{X_tQ_{F0}^j(2-\eta Q_{F0}^j)}{2}dt\right. \nonumber \\&\quad \left. \left. +\int _{{\overline{T}}_L^i}^{+\infty }e^{-rt}\left[ \frac{X_t(Q_L^i+Q_{F0}^j)\left( 2-\eta (Q_L^i+Q_{F0}^j)\right) }{2}-Q_{F0}^j Y_t\right] dt\right\} \right] \end{aligned}$$
(A22)

Similar to Appendix A.2.2, the profit flow the type j follower can obtain at the investment timing in view of social welfare-maximization can be written as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\xi _{i}\theta }{2b_X(\xi _{i}+\xi _{j}+b_{X})}\left[ Q_{L}^{i}(2-\eta Q_{L}^{i})+\frac{Q_{F 0}^{j}(2-\eta Q_{F0}^{j}-2\eta Q_{L}^{i})\xi _{j}}{\xi _{j}+b_{X}}\right] \nonumber \\&\quad +\frac{\xi _{j}\theta }{2b_X(\xi _{i}+\xi _{j}+b_{X})}\left[ Q_{F0}^{j}(2-\eta Q_{F0}^{j})+\frac{Q_{L}^{i}(2-\eta Q_{L}^{i}-2\eta Q_{F0}^{j})\xi _{i}}{\xi _{i}+b_{X}}\right] -\frac{\xi _{i}Q_{F0}^{j}}{\xi _{i}+b_{Y}} \end{aligned}$$
(A23)

Maximizing (A23) with respect to \(Q_{F0}^j\) yields the optimal capacity level. Combining the value-matching and smooth-pasting conditions, we can get the optimal investment strategies of the type j follower in light of welfare-maximizing, as shown in (64) and (65).

Finally, the social planner needs to deal with the type i leader’s investment problem as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&sw_{L}^{ij}(\theta )=\frac{1}{Y}\max _{T_{L}^{i},Q_{L}^{i}\ge 0}E^{(X,Y)}\left[ 1_{\left\{ {\overline{T}}_{L}^{i}<T_{F0}^{j**}\right\} }\left\{ \int _{{\overline{T}}_{L}^{i}}^ {{\overline{T}}_{F1}^{j**}}e^{-rt}Q_{L}^{i}\left( \frac{X_{t}(2-\eta Q_{L}^{i})}{2}-Q_{L}^{i}Y_{t}\right) \right. \right. \end{aligned}$$
(A24)
$$\begin{aligned}&\quad \left. \left. dt+\int _{{\overline{T}}_{F1}^{j**}}^{\infty }e^{-rt}\left( \frac{(Q_{L}^{i}+Q_{F1}^{j**}(Q_{L}^{i})) \left( 2-\eta (Q_{L}^{i}+Q_{F1}^{j**}(Q_{L}^{i}))\right) X_{t}}{2}-Q_{F1}^{j**}(Q_{L}^{i})Y_{t}\right) dt\right\} \right. \nonumber \\&\quad +\left. 1_{\left\{ T_{F0}^{j**}\le {\overline{T}}_{L}^{i}<{\overline{T}}_{F0}^{j**}\right\} } \left\{ \int _{{\overline{T}}_{L}^{i}}^{{\overline{T}}_{F0}^{j**}}e^{-rt}Q_{L}^{i}\left( \frac{X_{t}(2-\eta Q_{L}^{i})}{2}- Q_{L}^{i}Y_{t}\right) dt\right. \right. \nonumber \\&\quad \left. \left. +\int _{{\overline{T}}_{F0}^{j**}}^{\infty }e^{-rt}\left( \frac{(Q_{L}^{i}+Q_{F0}^{j**}(Q_{L}^{i}))\left( 2-\eta (Q_{L}^{i} +Q_{F0}^{j**}(Q_{L}^{i}))\right) X_{t}}{2}-Q_{F0}^{j**}(Q_{L}^{i})Y_{t}\right) dt\right\} \right. \nonumber \\&\quad \left. +1_{\left\{ {\overline{T}}_{L}^{i}\ge {\overline{T}}_{F0}^{j**}\right\} }\left\{ \int _{{\overline{T}}_{F0}^{j**}}^{{\overline{T}}_{L}^{i}} e^{-rt}\frac{X_{t}Q_{F0}^{j**}(Q_{L}^{i})\left( 2-\eta Q_{F0}^{j**}(Q_{L}^{i})\right) }{2}dt\right. \right. \nonumber \\&\quad \left. \left. +\int _{{\overline{T}}_{L}^{i}}^{+\infty }e^{-rt}\left( \frac{X_{t}(Q_{L}^{i}+Q_{F0}^{j**}(Q_{L}^{i}))\left( 2-\eta (Q_{L}^{i}+Q_{F 0}^{j**}(Q_{L}^{i}))\right) }{2}-Q_{F0}^{j**}(Q_{L}^{i})Y_{t}\right) dt\right\} \right] \end{aligned}$$
(A25)

After a series of complicated calculations, we evaluate (A25) as (67), and consequently, the optimal investment strategies can be obtain as shown in (66).

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Liu, Y., Sun, B. Investment strategies of duopoly firms with asymmetric time-to-build under a jump-diffusion model. Math Meth Oper Res 98, 377–410 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00186-023-00833-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00186-023-00833-0

Keywords

Navigation