Abstract
This paper employs a two-factor jump-diffusion model to investigate the optimal investment timing and capacity choice of the duopoly firms in the presence of uncertain and asymmetric time-to-build. By assuming that both the market demand and investment cost follow the jump-diffusion process, we show that the impacts of uncertainty of time-to-build on duopoly firms’ the optimal investment decisions depend on the directions of jumps in demand and investment cost. Moreover, the asymmetry of time-to-build makes it possible for the dominated firm to preempt the market successfully and becomes the leader. The leader’s capacity level increases with the dominated firm’s time-to-build and the follower’s decreases, even if the dominated firm is the leader. We also apply numerical simulation to compare the main results between two-factor diffusion model and two-factor jump-diffusion model.
Similar content being viewed by others
Availability of data and material
All data generated or analyzed during this study are included in this paper.
References
Aguerrevere FL (2003) Equilibrium investment strategies and output price behavior: a real-options approach. Rev Financ Stud 16(4):1239–1272
Agliardi E, Koussis N (2013) Optimal capital structure and the impact of time-to-build. Financ Res Lett 10(3):124–130
Azevedo A, Paxson D (2014) Developing real option game models. Eur J Oper Res 237(3):909–920
Bar-Ilan A, Strange WC (1996) Investment lags. Am Econ Rev 86(3):610–622
Dixit AK, Pindyck RS (1994) Investment under uncertainty. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Eberlein E, Glau K (2014) Variational solutions of the pricing PIDEs for European options in Lévy models. Appl Math Financ 21(5):417–450
Fudenberg D, Tirole J (1985) Preemption and rent equalization in te adoption of new technology. Rev Econ Stud 52(3):192–207
Grenadier SR (1996) The strategic exercise of options: development cascades and over-building in real estate markets. J Financ 51(5):1653–1679
Grenadier SR (2000) Equilibrium with time-to-build. In: Brennan M, Trigeorgis L (eds) Project flexibility, agency, and competition. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 275–296
Genc TS (2017) The impact of lead time on capital investments. J Econ Dyn Control 82(1):142–164
He H, Pindyck R (1992) Investment in flexible production capacity. J Econ Dyn Control 16:575–599
Huisman KJM, Kort PM (2004) Strategic technology adoption taking into account future technological improvement: a real options approach. Eur J Oper Res 159(3):705–728
Hagspiel V, Huisman KJM, Nunes C (2015) Optimal technology adoption when the arrival rate of new technologies changes. Eur J Oper Res 243(3):897–911
Huisman KJM, Kort PM (2015) Strategic capacity investment under uncertainty. Rand J Econ 46(2):376–408
Huberts NED, Dawid H, Huisman KJM, Kort PM (2019) Entry deterrence by timing rather than overinvestment in a strategic real options framework. Eur J Oper Res 274(1):165–185
Johannes M (2004) The statistical and economic role of jumps in continuous-time interest rate models. J Financ 59(1):227–260
Jeon H (2021) Investment timing and capacity decisions with time-to-build in a Duopoly market. J Econ Dyn Control 122:104028
Koeva P (2000) The facts about time-to-build. Working Paper no. WP/00/138, International Monetary Fund
Kauppinen L, Siddiqui AS, Salo A (2018) Investing in time-to-build projects with uncertain revenues and costs: a real options approach. IEEE Trans Eng Manag 65(3):448–459
Lee SS, Mykland PA (2008) Jumps in financial markets: a new nonparametric test and jump dynamics. Rev Financ Stud 21(6):2535–2563
Liang J, Yang M, Jiang L (2013) A closed-form solution for the exercise strategy in a real options model with a jump-diffusion process. SIAM J Appl Math 73(1):549–571
Lavrutich MN, Huisman KJM, Kort PM (2016) Entry deterrence and hidden competition. J Econ Dyn Control 69:409–435
Lavrutich MN (2017) Capacity choice under uncertainty in a duopoly with endogenous exit. Eur J Oper Res 258(3):1033–1053
Merton RC (1976) Option pricing when underlying stock returns are discontinuous. J Financ Econ 3(1–2):125–144
McDonald R, Siegel D (1986) The value of waiting to invest. J Econ 101(4):707–727
Mauer DC, Ott S (2000) Agency costs, under-investment, and optimal capital structure: the effect of growth options to expand. In: Brennan M, Terigeorigis L (eds) Project flexibility, agency, and completition. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 151–180
Martzoukos SH, Trigeorgis L (2002) Real (investment) options with multiple sources of rare events. Eur J Oper Res 136(3):696–706
Murto P (2007) Timing of investment under technological and revenue-related uncertainties. J Econ Dyn Control 31(5):1473–1497
Mason CF, Wilmot NA (2014) Jump processes in natural gas markets. Energ Econ 46(1):69–79
Nielsen MJ (2002) Competition and irreversible investments. Int J Ind Organ 20(5):731–743
Nunes C, Pimentel R (2017) Analytical solution for an investment problem under uncertainties with shocks. Eur J Oper Res 259(3):1054–1063
Pindyck R (1988) Irreversible investment, capacity choice, and the value of the firm. Am Ecom Rev 78:969–985
Pan J (2002) The jump-risk premia implicit in options: evidence from an integrated time-series study. J Financ Econ 63(1):3–50
Pacheco-de-Almeida G, Zemsky P (2003) The effect of time-to-build on strategic investment under uncertainty. Rand J Econ 34(1):166–182
Smets F (1993) Essays on foreign direct investment. Ph.D. Thesis, Yale University, New Haven
Siddiqui A, Takashima R (2012) Capacity switching options under rivalry and uncertainty. Eur J Oper Res 222(3):583–595
Thijssen JJJ, Huisman KJM, Kort PM (2012) Symmetric equilibrium strategies in game theoretic real option models. J Math Econ 48(4):219–225
Westman JJ, Hanson FB (2000) Non-linear state dynamics: computational methods and manufacturing application. Int J Control 73(6):464–480
Weeds H (2002) Strategic delay in a real options model of R &D competition. Rev Econ Stud 69(3):729–747
Wu MC, Yen SH (2007) Pricing real growth options when the underlying assets have jump diffusion processes: the case of R &D investments. R &D Manag 37(3):269–276
Wu XQ, Hu ZJ (2022) Investment timing and capacity choice in duopolistic competition under a jump-diffusion model. Math Financ Econ 16:125–152
Funding
This research was funded by the Key Project of Education Science Planning in Heilongjiang Province for 2021 (No. 477) and Open topic project of Think tank (No. ZKKF2022208).
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Ethics declarations
Conflict of interest
The authors declare that there are no conflict of interest regarding the publication of this paper.
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Appendix A Linear demand function
Appendix A Linear demand function
1.1 Proof of Theorem 1
Given the current demand-to-cost ratio \(\theta \), maximizing (10) with respect to \(Q_M\), we can yield the optimal capacity as follows:
Following Wu and Hu (2022), the firm’s value under the new state variable, \(v_{M}(\theta )\) in (9), satisfies the following HJB equation
subject to
Meanwhile, the general solution of (A2) with the initial condition (A3) takes the form
where \(\beta _{1}\) is the positive root (\(>1\)) of (13) (e.g., Nunes and Pimentel 2017). Substituting (A6)(10) into (A4)(A5) gives
After solving the system of Eqs. (A1) and (A8) we get the results in Theorem 1.
1.2 Duopoly market
First of all, we investigate the duopoly firms’ optimal investment decisions when the market roles are exogenous. To this end, we first formalize the firm’s value function, and consequently by maximizing the value function at the moment of investing, the optimal capacity level can be derived. By solving the HJB equation the value function satisfies, the optimal investment threshold can be obtained. According to this train of thought, we discuss the follower’s optimal investment decisions when its investment timing is earlier and later than the manufacturing timing of the leader in Appendix A.2.1 and A.2.2. In Appendix A.2.3, we proceed to explore the leader’s investment decision. By taking the preemptive incentive into consideration, we further study the equilibrium investment strategies of duopoly enterprises under competition in Appendix A.2.4.
1.2.1 Proof of Theorem 2
Given the current demand-to-cost ratio \(\theta \) and the leader’s capacity level \(Q_L^i\), the type j follower’s profit flow obtained at the investment timing when investing with capacity \(Q_{F1}^{j}\) can be evaluated as
maximizing (A9) with respect to \(Q_{F1}^j\), the optimal capacity level can be obtained as
Before investing, the follower’s value, \(v_{F1}^{j}(\theta )\), equals to the value of the investment option the firm holds, which is
Substituting (A9) (A10) (A11) into the corresponding value matching and smooth pasting conditions yields
Substituting (A12) into (A10) we can conclude the follower’s optimal investment strategy after the leader’s product entering the market in Theorem 2.
1.2.2 Proof of Theorem 3
Given the current demand-to-cost ratio \(\theta \) and the leader’s capacity level \(Q_L^i\), assuming that the type j follower invests with capacity \(Q_{F0}^{j}\), then the expected profit flow the follower obtained at the moment of investment can be evaluated as
maximizing (A14) with respect to \(Q_{F0}^j\), the follower’s optimal capacity level can be obtained as described in (39).
In the meanwhile, before investing, the firm’s value, \(v_{F0}^{j}(\theta )\), should satisfy the following HJB equation:
where \(v_{F1}^{j}(\theta )\) is defined by (A11) through (A13). Unlike before, a general solution of (A15) with the initial condition is
where \(\gamma _i\) is the positive (\(>1\)) of the following equation
Substituting (A14), (A16) and (39) into the boundary conditions, we can derive successively the value function, optimal investment threshold as well as capacity level of the follower given in Theorem 3.
1.2.3 Proof of Theorem 4
Given the current demand-to-cost ratio \(\theta \) and the follower’s investment strategies \(\left\{ \theta _{F0}^{j},\theta _{F1}^{j}\right\} , \left\{ Q_{F0}^{j}, Q_{F1}^{j}\right\} \), the expected profit flow the type i leader obtains when invests with capacity level \(Q_{L}^{i}\) at the moment of investment can be evaluated as follows:
maximizing (A18) with respect to \(Q_L^i\), the optimal capacity level can be obtained as
Meanwhile, the value of the leader before investing, \(v_{L}^{i}(\theta )\), equals to the value of the investment option the firm holds, which is
Substituting (A18) and (A20) into the boundary conditions, we can obtain successively the value function of the leader, optimal investment threshold as well as the corresponding optimal capacity given in Theorem 4.
1.2.4 Proof of Theorem 5
Firstly, following Huisman and Kort (2015), we assume that both firms have incentives to preempt the market, that is, \(\theta _{P}^{i}\ne \emptyset \) for \(i\in \{A,B\}\), indicating that there exists at least a \(\theta \) such that \(V_{P}^{i}(\theta )\ge V_{F0}^{i}(\theta , Q_{L}^{j*}(\theta ))\) holds. With this assumption, two possible scenarios are be considered.
If \(\theta _{P}^{i*}\le \theta _{P}^{j*}\le \theta _{L}^{i*}\) for \(i\ne j\) and \(i,j\in \{A,B\}\), the type i firm succeeds in the preemption game and optimally invests at \(\theta _{P}^{j*}-\varepsilon \), which is infinitely close to \(\theta _{P}^{j*}\). Therefore, the investment is made at \(\theta _{P}^{j*}\) as \(\varepsilon \) approaches 0 and the capacity choice is \(Q_{P}^{i*}=Q_{L}^{i*}(\theta _{P}^{j*})\). Meanwhile, failure in the preemptive game leads to the type j firm implements the investment decision as a follower, whose optimal investment decisions are shown in Theorems 2 and 3. Otherwise, if \(\theta _{P}^{i*}\le \theta _{L}^{i*}\le \theta _{P}^{j*}\) for \(i\ne j\), since the type j firm will not invest before the demand-to-cost ratio reaches \(\theta _{P}^{j*}\), the type i firm’s optimal investment should be made at \(\theta _{L}^{i*}\) instead of \(\theta _{P}^{i*}\). Consequently, the firms’ investment strategies follow those in Theorem 2 through 4.
Secondly, we assume that only one firm has an incentive to preempt the market. Without loss of generality, we assume that \(\theta _{P}^{i}\ne \emptyset \) and \(\theta _{P}^{j}=\emptyset \) for \(i\ne j\) and \(i,j\in \{A,B\}\), indicating that there exists at least a \(\theta \) such that \(V_{P}^{i}(\theta )\ge V_{F0}^{i}(\theta ,Q_{L}^{j*}(\theta ))\) holds, whereas \(V_{P}^{j}(\theta )< V_{F0}^{j}(\theta ,Q_{L}^{j*}(\theta ))\) for all \(\theta \). In this case, both firms’ investment strategies follow those in Theorem 2 through 4.
1.3 Proof of Theorem 6
Suppose that we have already assigned the type i and j firm as the market leader and follower respectively. First of all, with the assumption that the leader’s product has already entered into the market, we can examine social planner’s optimal investment decision by solving the following problem:
Combining the initial condition and boundary conditions, we can straightforward calculate the optimal investment threshold \(\theta _{F1}^{j**}(Q_{L}^{i})\) and capacity level \(Q_{F1}^{j**}(Q_{L}^{i})\) of the type j follower in view of welfare-maximizing, as shown in (62) and (63).
Secondly, we examine social planner’s optimal investment decision with the assumption that the leader’s product hasn’t entered into the market yet by solving
Similar to Appendix A.2.2, the profit flow the type j follower can obtain at the investment timing in view of social welfare-maximization can be written as follows:
Maximizing (A23) with respect to \(Q_{F0}^j\) yields the optimal capacity level. Combining the value-matching and smooth-pasting conditions, we can get the optimal investment strategies of the type j follower in light of welfare-maximizing, as shown in (64) and (65).
Finally, the social planner needs to deal with the type i leader’s investment problem as follows:
After a series of complicated calculations, we evaluate (A25) as (67), and consequently, the optimal investment strategies can be obtain as shown in (66).
Rights and permissions
Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.
About this article
Cite this article
Liu, Y., Sun, B. Investment strategies of duopoly firms with asymmetric time-to-build under a jump-diffusion model. Math Meth Oper Res 98, 377–410 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00186-023-00833-0
Received:
Revised:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00186-023-00833-0