Nothing Special   »   [go: up one dir, main page]

Skip to main content

Threshold Tests as Quality Signals: Optimal Strategies, Equilibria, and Price of Anarchy

  • Conference paper
  • First Online:
Web and Internet Economics (WINE 2021)

Part of the book series: Lecture Notes in Computer Science ((LNISA,volume 13112))

Included in the following conference series:

Abstract

We study a signaling game between two firms competing to have their product chosen by a principal. The products have (real-valued) qualities, which are drawn i.i.d. from a common prior. The principal aims to choose the better of the two products, but the quality of a product can only be estimated via a coarse-grained threshold test: given a threshold \(\theta \), the principal learns whether a product’s quality exceeds \(\theta \) or fails to do so.

We study this selection problem under two types of interactions. In the first, the principal does the testing herself, and can choose tests optimally from a class of allowable tests. We show that the optimum strategy for the principal is to administer different tests to the two products: one which is passed with probability \(\frac{1}{3}\) and the other with probability \(\frac{2}{3}\). If, however, the principal is required to choose the tests in a symmetric manner (i.e., via an i.i.d. distribution), then the optimal strategy is to choose tests whose probability of passing is drawn uniformly from \([\frac{1}{4}, \frac{3}{4}]\).

In our second interaction model, test difficulties are selected endogenously by the two firms. This corresponds to a setting in which the firms must commit to their testing (quality control) procedures before knowing the quality of their products. This interaction model naturally gives rise to a signaling game with two senders and one receiver. We characterize the unique Bayes-Nash Equilibrium of this game, which happens to be symmetric. We then calculate its Price of Anarchy in terms of the principal’s probability of choosing the worse product. Finally, we show that by restricting both firms’ set of available thresholds to choose from, the principal can lower the Price of Anarchy of the resulting equilibrium; however, there is a limit, in that for every (common) restricted set of tests, the equilibrium failure probability is strictly larger than under the optimal i.i.d. distribution.

S. Banerjee—Supported by the NSF under grants CNS-1955997, DMS-1839346 and ECCS-1847393.

R. Kleinberg—Supported by the NSF under grant CCF-1512964.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 79.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    This is the more common view of signaling in the economics community: a signaling scheme is interpreted as a device (physical or otherwise) that maps relevant states of the world to observable signals. Fixing a device constitutes committing to a signaling scheme. In contrast, recent works in computer science apply signaling/persuasion to scenarios such as communications where it is less clear whether the sender has the ability to commit to a mapping.

  2. 2.

    Lerner and Tirole [13] do briefly discuss a multi-firm setting, but only consider one extremely limited example.

  3. 3.

    However, we note that in addressing the same real-world scenario, Gill and Sgroi [11] instead consider a model where the owner knows the state before choosing the certifier; see the full version [3] for details.

  4. 4.

    We adopt the convention that the cumulative distribution function (cdf) of a probability measure on \(\mathbb {R} \) is defined by setting F(x) to be the measure of the set \((-\infty ,x]\) under the distribution.

  5. 5.

    Alternatively, the setting may be such that the agents naturally have the choice of test difficulty, such as in external certification of product quality [10, 11, 13] or students’ selection of which classes to attempt [18]. In these settings, it is still frequently assumed that agents are not aware of their private quality value when they make their choice of difficulty; see for example [13] for a model of certification and [16] for a model of contracting between students and employers.

  6. 6.

    There are naturally other objectives in between these two extremes.

  7. 7.

    Recall that the Kendall \(\tau \) distance between two rankings is the number of inversions between the rankings, i.e., the number of pairs of elements that are in different order.

  8. 8.

    Recall from Sect. 2.2 that this assumption is without loss of generality.

  9. 9.

    As will be established in Theorem 9.

  10. 10.

    Recall that we write \(I(F) = \mathbb {E}\left[ {I(\mathcal {T}_{F})}\right] \).

  11. 11.

    Of course, if the principal can choose different sets for different firms, then she can choose \(S_X = \{\frac{1}{3} \}\) and \(S_Y = \{\frac{2}{3}\}\), which would implement the optimal strategy for her. The more interesting question is to find one set S to restrict all firms to, which naturally corresponds to prescribing standards for quality control.

  12. 12.

    We thank Nicole Immorlica for suggesting this interpretation.

References

  1. Au, P.H., Kawai, K.: Competitive information disclosure by multiple senders. Games Econ. Behav. 119, 56–78 (2020)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  2. Au, P.H., Kawai, K.: Competitive disclosure of correlated information. Econ. Theory 72(3), 767–799 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-018-01171-7

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  3. Banerjee, S., Kempe, D., Kleinberg, R.: Threshold tests as quality signals: optimal strategies, equilibria, and price of anarchy. arXiv preprint arXiv:2110.10881 (2021)

  4. Boleslavsky, R., Carlin, B.I., Cotton, C.S.: Bayesian exaggeration and the (mis)allocation of scarce resources (2016, under submission)

    Google Scholar 

  5. Boleslavsky, R., Cotton, C.S.: Limited capacity in project selection: competition through evidence production. Econ. Theory 65(2), 385–421 (2018)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  6. Candogan, O.: On information design with spillovers (2020). SSRN 3537289

    Google Scholar 

  7. Dasgupta, P., Maskin, E.: The existence of equilibrium in discontinuous economic games, I: Theory. Rev. Econ. Stud. 53(1), 1–26 (1986)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  8. Dughmi, S., Kempe, D., Qiang, R.: Persuasion with limited communication. In: Proceedings of 17th ACM Conference on Economics and Computation, pp. 663–680 (2016)

    Google Scholar 

  9. Dworczak, P., Martini, G.: The simple economics of optimal persuasion. J. Polit. Econ. 127(5), 1993–2048 (2019)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Gill, D., Sgroi, D.: Sequential decisions with tests. Games Econ. Behav. 63(2), 663–678 (2008)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  11. Gill, D., Sgroi, D.: The optimal choice of pre-launch reviewer. J. Econ. Theory 147(3), 1247–1260 (2012)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  12. Hwang, I., Kim, K., Boleslavsky, R.: Competitive advertising and pricing (2019, under submission)

    Google Scholar 

  13. Lerner, J., Tirole, J.: A model of forum shopping. Am. Econ. Rev. 96(4), 1091–1113 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Li, Z., Rantakari, H., Yang, H.: Competitive cheap talk. Games Econ. Behav. 96, 65–89 (2016)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  15. Onuchic, P.F., Ray, D.: Conveying value via categories. arXiv preprint arXiv:2103.12804 (2019)

  16. Ostrovsky, M., Schwarz, M.: Information disclosure and unraveling in matching markets. Am. Econ. J.: Microecon. 2(2), 34–63 (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  17. Sobel, J.: Giving and receiving advice. In: Acemoglu, D., Arellano, M., Dekel, E. (eds.) Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Tenth World Congress (Econometric Society Monographs), pp. 305–341 (2013)

    Google Scholar 

  18. Spence, M.: Job market signaling. Q. J. Econ. 87(3), 355–374 (1973)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

We would like to thank Odilon Camara, Peter Frazier, Moshe Hoffman, Nicole Immorlica, Jonathan Libgober, Erez Yoeli, and Christina Lee Yu for useful discussions and pointers.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this paper

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this paper

Banerjee, S., Kempe, D., Kleinberg, R. (2022). Threshold Tests as Quality Signals: Optimal Strategies, Equilibria, and Price of Anarchy. In: Feldman, M., Fu, H., Talgam-Cohen, I. (eds) Web and Internet Economics. WINE 2021. Lecture Notes in Computer Science(), vol 13112. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-94676-0_17

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-94676-0_17

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-94675-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-94676-0

  • eBook Packages: Computer ScienceComputer Science (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics