Integrating Money Cycle Dynamics and Economocracy for Optimal Resource Allocation and Economic Stability
<p>Comparison of Money Cycle (author’s results, see <a href="#app1-jrfm-17-00422" class="html-app">Appendix A</a>).</p> "> Figure 2
<p>Metrics with and without of Money Cycle & Economocracy (author’s results, see <a href="#app2-jrfm-17-00422" class="html-app">Appendix B</a>).</p> "> Figure 3
<p>Box plot of F-statistics (author’s results, see <a href="#app3-jrfm-17-00422" class="html-app">Appendix C</a>).</p> "> Figure 4
<p>Line plot of R<sup>2</sup> (author’s results, see <a href="#app4-jrfm-17-00422" class="html-app">Appendix D</a>).</p> "> Figure 5
<p>Line 2D-plot of F-statistics (author’s results, see <a href="#app5-jrfm-17-00422" class="html-app">Appendix E</a>).</p> "> Figure 6
<p>Line 3D-plot of F-statistics (author’s results, see <a href="#app5-jrfm-17-00422" class="html-app">Appendix E</a>).</p> ">
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Literature Review
2.1. Hypothetical Economy
- Production Methods: Setting rules that influence the choice of processes varying in land and labor proportions and duration. In regulating production methods, the authority focuses on determining how land and labor are utilized in the production process. By setting rules that guide the choice of production techniques, the authority aims to optimize the efficiency with which inputs are converted into outputs. This involves balancing land-intensive and labor-intensive methods, and determining the duration of production processes to ensure that resources are used in the most effective manner. The authority may introduce standards for technology use, promote sustainable practices, and incentivize innovations that improve productivity. Such regulation ensures that production is both cost-effective and resource-efficient, leading to higher overall output and reduced waste.
- Distribution: Creating regulations to ensure the efficient allocation of outputs among consumers. The authority’s role in distribution is to create regulations that ensure goods and services are allocated efficiently among consumers. This involves setting up mechanisms to prevent market distortions such as monopolies, price gouging, and hoarding (Castaño et al. 2016; Cruz-Castro and Sanz-Menéndez 2016; Moreno-Jiménez et al. 2014; Rumayya et al. 2020; Urwannachotima et al. 2020; Woody and Viney 2017). The authority may implement policies such as price controls, anti-monopoly laws, and social safety nets to ensure that essential goods are accessible to all segments of society. Effective distribution regulations aim to balance market efficiency with equity, ensuring that goods are available to those who need them and that resources are not concentrated in the hands of a few. By addressing these concerns, the authority helps to promote fairness and stability in the economy.
- Timing: Providing a framework for when outputs should be made available. Timing regulations set by the authority address the scheduling of production and the availability of goods. Proper timing ensures that production aligns with consumer demand, preventing issues such as shortages or surpluses (Bourdin and Nadou 2018; dos Santos Benso Maciel et al. 2020; Dybowski and Adämmer 2018; Kanthak and Spies 2018; Liu et al. 2018; Tvaronavičienė et al. 2018). The authority provides frameworks for production schedules and supply chain management to help producers plan their activities effectively. This includes managing inventory, transportation, and storage to ensure a steady supply of goods. Additionally, the authority establishes contingency plans to handle unexpected disruptions, such as natural disasters or supply chain issues. These measures help to maintain economic stability and reliability in the supply of goods.
- Detailed Analysis of the Authority’s Role: The authority’s role is integral to achieving economic efficiency and welfare through its regulations on production methods, distribution, and timing. By setting comprehensive and adaptable rules, the authority ensures that each component of the economy works harmoniously.
- Production Methods: Effective regulation of production methods maximizes the efficiency of resource use, leading to higher productivity and reduced waste. The authority’s guidelines help in optimizing the combination of inputs and the duration of production processes.
- Distribution: Regulations for distribution ensure that goods are allocated fairly and efficiently. By implementing measures to prevent market distortions and ensuring access to essential goods, the authority promotes equity and market stability.
- Timing: The authority’s frameworks for timing help synchronize production with consumer demand, avoiding shortages and surpluses. Proper management of production schedules and supply chains, along with contingency planning, ensures stability and reliability in the availability of goods.
2.2. Authority’s Role
3. Materials and Methods
4. Results
5. Discussion
6. Conclusions
Funding
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
# 2024 © ® All Rights Reserved Constantinos Challoumis | ||
import pandas as pd | ||
import matplotlib.pyplot as plt | ||
# Define the data for the metrics | ||
data = { | ||
‘Metric’: [ | ||
‘R2 (Production Efficiency)’, | ||
‘Labor Coefficient’, | ||
‘Land Coefficient’, | ||
‘F-Statistic (Production Efficiency)’, | ||
‘R2 (Distributive Efficiency)’, | ||
‘Income Inequality Coefficient’, | ||
‘Welfare Programs Coefficient’, | ||
‘F-Statistic (Distributive Efficiency)’, | ||
‘R2 (Money Cycle Impact)’, | ||
‘Enforcement Savings Coefficient’, | ||
‘Escape Savings Coefficient’, | ||
‘F-Statistic (Money Cycle Impact)’ | ||
], | ||
‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’: [ | ||
0.85, 2.00, 5.00, 45.30, | ||
0.78, −0.30, 0.40, 35.00, | ||
0.72, 0.30, −0.10, 20.00 | ||
], | ||
‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’: [ | ||
0.87, 2.10, 5.10, 50.00, | ||
0.81, −0.35, 0.45, 40.00, | ||
0.75, 0.35, −0.05, 25.00 | ||
] | ||
} | ||
# Create a DataFrame | ||
df = pd.DataFrame(data) | ||
# Set the index to ‘Metric’ | ||
df.set_index(‘Metric’, inplace = True) | ||
# Plot Production Efficiency Model with lines | ||
plt.figure(figsize = (12, 6)) | ||
plt.plot(df.index, df[‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’], marker = ‘o’, linestyle = ‘-’, color = ‘b’, label = ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’) | ||
plt.plot(df.index, df[‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’], marker = ‘o’, linestyle = ‘-’, color = ‘r’, label = ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’) | ||
plt.title(‘Comparison of Production Efficiency Model Metrics’) | ||
plt.xlabel(‘Metric’) | ||
plt.ylabel(‘Value’) | ||
plt.xticks(rotation = 45, ha = ‘right’) | ||
plt.legend() | ||
plt.grid(True) | ||
plt.tight_layout() | ||
plt.show() | ||
# Plot Distributive Efficiency Model with lines | ||
plt.figure(figsize = (12, 6)) | ||
plt.plot(df.index, df[‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’], marker = ‘o’, linestyle = ‘-’, color = ‘b’, label = ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’) | ||
plt.plot(df.index, df[‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’], marker = ‘o’, linestyle = ‘-’, color = ‘r’, label = ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’) | ||
plt.title(‘Comparison of Distributive Efficiency Model Metrics’) | ||
plt.xlabel(‘Metric’) | ||
plt.ylabel(‘Value’) | ||
plt.xticks(rotation = 45, ha = ‘right’) | ||
plt.legend() | ||
plt.grid(True) | ||
plt.tight_layout() | ||
plt.show() | ||
# Plot Money Cycle Impact Model with lines | ||
plt.figure(figsize = (12, 6)) | ||
plt.plot(df.index, df[‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’], marker = ‘o’, linestyle = ‘-’, color = ‘b’, label = ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’) | ||
plt.plot(df.index, df[‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’], marker = ‘o’, linestyle = ‘-’, color = ‘r’, label = ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’) | ||
plt.title(‘Comparison of Money Cycle Impact Model Metrics’) | ||
plt.xlabel(‘Metric’) | ||
plt.ylabel(‘Value’) | ||
plt.xticks(rotation = 45, ha = ‘right’) | ||
plt.legend() | ||
plt.grid(True) | ||
plt.tight_layout() | ||
plt.show() |
Appendix B
# 2024 © ® All Rights Reserved Constantinos Challoumis | ||
import matplotlib.pyplot as plt | ||
import pandas as pd | ||
import seaborn as sns | ||
# Define data for the bar plot | ||
bar_data = { | ||
‘Metric’: [ | ||
‘R2 (Production Efficiency)’, ‘Labor Coefficient (Production Efficiency)’, ‘Land Coefficient (Production Efficiency)’, ‘F-Statistic (Production Efficiency)’, | ||
‘R2 (Distributive Efficiency)’, ‘Income Inequality Coefficient (Distributive Efficiency)’, ‘Welfare Programs Coefficient (Distributive Efficiency)’, ‘F-Statistic (Distributive Efficiency)’, | ||
‘R2 (Money Cycle Impact)’, ‘Enforcement Savings Coefficient (Money Cycle Impact)’, ‘Escape Savings Coefficient (Money Cycle Impact)’, ‘F-Statistic (Money Cycle Impact)’, | ||
‘R2 (Production Efficiency)’, ‘Labor Coefficient (Production Efficiency)’, ‘Land Coefficient (Production Efficiency)’, ‘F-Statistic (Production Efficiency)’, | ||
‘R2 (Distributive Efficiency)’, ‘Income Inequality Coefficient (Distributive Efficiency)’, ‘Welfare Programs Coefficient (Distributive Efficiency)’, ‘F-Statistic (Distributive Efficiency)’, | ||
‘R2 (Money Cycle Impact)’, ‘Enforcement Savings Coefficient (Money Cycle Impact)’, ‘Escape Savings Coefficient (Money Cycle Impact)’, ‘F-Statistic (Money Cycle Impact)’ | ||
], | ||
‘Condition’: [ | ||
‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, | ||
‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, | ||
‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, | ||
‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, | ||
‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, | ||
‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’ | ||
], | ||
‘Value’: [ | ||
0.85, 2.00, 5.00, 45.30, | ||
0.78, −0.30, 0.40, 35.00, | ||
0.72, 0.30, −0.10, 20.00, | ||
0.87, 2.10, 5.10, 50.00, | ||
0.81, −0.35, 0.45, 40.00, | ||
0.75, 0.35, −0.05, 25.00 | ||
] | ||
} | ||
# Create a DataFrame | ||
df_bar = pd.DataFrame(bar_data) | ||
# Plotting | ||
plt.figure(figsize = (14, 8)) | ||
sns.barplot(data = df_bar, x = ‘Metric’, y = ‘Value’, hue = ‘Condition’, palette = ‘Set1’) | ||
plt.title(‘Comparison of Metrics with and without Money Cycle & Economocracy’) | ||
plt.xticks(rotation = 90) | ||
plt.ylabel(‘Value’) | ||
plt.show() |
Appendix C
# 2024 © ® All Rights Reserved Constantinos Challoumis | ||
# Define data for the box plot | ||
box_data = { | ||
‘Model’: [ | ||
‘Production Efficiency Model’, ‘Production Efficiency Model’, ‘Production Efficiency Model’, | ||
‘Distributive Efficiency Model’, ‘Distributive Efficiency Model’, ‘Distributive Efficiency Model’, | ||
‘Money Cycle Impact Model’, ‘Money Cycle Impact Model’, ‘Money Cycle Impact Model’, | ||
‘Production Efficiency Model’, ‘Production Efficiency Model’, ‘Production Efficiency Model’, | ||
‘Distributive Efficiency Model’, ‘Distributive Efficiency Model’, ‘Distributive Efficiency Model’, | ||
‘Money Cycle Impact Model’, ‘Money Cycle Impact Model’, ‘Money Cycle Impact Model’ | ||
], | ||
‘F-Statistic’: [ | ||
45.30, 50.00, 35.00, | ||
40.00, 25.00, 35.00, | ||
20.00, 25.00, 30.00, | ||
50.00, 60.00, 45.00, | ||
35.00, 45.00, 40.00, | ||
25.00, 30.00, 35.00 | ||
], | ||
‘Condition’: [ | ||
‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, | ||
‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, | ||
‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’, | ||
‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, | ||
‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, | ||
‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’, ‘With Money Cycle & Economocracy’ | ||
] | ||
} | ||
# Create a DataFrame | ||
df_box = pd.DataFrame(box_data) | ||
# Plotting | ||
plt.figure(figsize = (14, 8)) | ||
sns.boxplot(data = df_box, x = ‘Model’, y = ‘F-Statistic’, hue = ‘Condition’, palette = ‘Set1’) | ||
plt.title(‘Box Plot of F-Statistics’) | ||
plt.xticks(rotation = 45) | ||
plt.ylabel(‘F-Statistic’) | ||
plt.show() |
Appendix D
# 2024 © ® All Rights Reserved Constantinos Challoumis | ||
# Import necessary libraries | ||
import matplotlib.pyplot as plt | ||
import pandas as pd | ||
import seaborn as sns | ||
# Define data for the scatter plot | ||
scatter_data = { | ||
‘Model’: [‘Production Efficiency’, ‘Distributive Efficiency’, ‘Money Cycle Impact’], | ||
‘R2 Without’: [0.85, 0.78, 0.72], | ||
‘R2 With’: [0.87, 0.81, 0.75], | ||
‘F-Statistic Without’: [45.30, 35.00, 20.00], | ||
‘F-Statistic With’: [50.00, 40.00, 25.00] | ||
} | ||
# Create a DataFrame | ||
df_scatter = pd.DataFrame(scatter_data) | ||
# Scatter plot for R2 values | ||
plt.figure(figsize = (14, 6)) | ||
plt.subplot(1, 2, 1) | ||
plt.scatter(df_scatter[‘R2 Without’], df_scatter[‘R2 With’], color = ‘blue’, label = ‘R2 Values’) | ||
plt.xlabel(‘R2 Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’) | ||
plt.ylabel(‘R2 With Money Cycle & Economocracy’) | ||
plt.title(‘Scatter Plot of R2 Values’) | ||
plt.legend() | ||
plt.grid(True) | ||
# Scatter plot for F-Statistic values | ||
plt.subplot(1, 2, 2) | ||
plt.scatter(df_scatter[‘F-Statistic Without’], df_scatter[‘F-Statistic With’], color = ‘red’, label = ‘F-Statistic Values’) | ||
plt.xlabel(‘F-Statistic Without Money Cycle & Economocracy’) | ||
plt.ylabel(‘F-Statistic With Money Cycle & Economocracy’) | ||
plt.title(‘Scatter Plot of F-Statistic Values’) | ||
plt.legend() | ||
plt.grid(True) | ||
plt.tight_layout() | ||
plt.show() | ||
# Line plot for R2 values | ||
plt.figure(figsize = (14, 6)) | ||
plt.plot(df_scatter[‘Model’], df_scatter[‘R2 Without’], marker = ‘o’, color = ‘blue’, label = ‘R2 Without’) | ||
plt.plot(df_scatter[‘Model’], df_scatter[‘R2 With’], marker = ‘o’, color = ‘green’, label = ‘R2 With’) | ||
plt.xlabel(‘Model’) | ||
plt.ylabel(‘R2 Value’) | ||
plt.title(‘Line Plot of R2 Values’) | ||
plt.legend() | ||
plt.grid(True) | ||
plt.show() | ||
# Line plot for F-Statistic values | ||
plt.figure(figsize = (14, 6)) | ||
plt.plot(df_scatter[‘Model’], df_scatter[‘F-Statistic Without’], marker = ‘o’, color = ‘red’, label = ‘F-Statistic Without’) | ||
plt.plot(df_scatter[‘Model’], df_scatter[‘F-Statistic With’], marker = ‘o’, color = ‘orange’, label = ‘F-Statistic With’) | ||
plt.xlabel(‘Model’) | ||
plt.ylabel(‘F-Statistic Value’) | ||
plt.title(‘Line Plot of F-Statistic Values’) | ||
plt.legend() | ||
plt.grid(True) | ||
plt.show() |
Appendix E
# 2024 © ® All Rights Reserved Constantinos Challoumis | ||
# Importing necessary libraries | ||
import pandas as pd | ||
import matplotlib.pyplot as plt | ||
from mpl_toolkits.mplot3d import Axes3D | ||
# Data for the models | ||
data = { | ||
‘Model’: [‘Production Efficiency’, ‘Production Efficiency’, | ||
‘Distributive Efficiency’, ‘Distributive Efficiency’, | ||
‘Money Cycle Impact’, ‘Money Cycle Impact’], | ||
‘Condition’: [‘Without’, ‘With’, | ||
‘Without’, ‘With’, | ||
‘Without’, ‘With’], | ||
‘R2’: [0.85, 0.87, | ||
0.78, 0.81, | ||
0.72, 0.75], | ||
‘F-Statistic’: [45.30, 50.00, | ||
35.00, 40.00, | ||
20.00, 25.00], | ||
‘Coefficient’: [2.00, 2.10, | ||
−0.30, −0.35, | ||
0.30, 0.35] | ||
} | ||
# Creating a DataFrame | ||
df = pd.DataFrame(data) | ||
# Adjust the coefficients significantly to avoid overlap | ||
df.loc[(df[‘Model’] == ‘Distributive Efficiency’) & (df[‘Condition’] == ‘With’), ‘Coefficient’] += 0.1 | ||
# Plotting the 3D graph | ||
fig = plt.figure(figsize = (14, 10)) | ||
ax = fig.add_subplot(111, projection = ‘3d’) | ||
# Scatter plot for each model condition | ||
colors = {‘Without’: ‘blue’, ‘With’: ‘green’} | ||
markers = {‘Without’: ‘o’, ‘With’: ‘^’} | ||
for condition in df[‘Condition’].unique(): | ||
condition_df = df[df[‘Condition’] == condition] | ||
scatter = ax.scatter(condition_df[‘R2’], condition_df[‘F-Statistic’], condition_df[‘Coefficient’], | ||
color = colors[condition], marker = markers[condition], label = condition, s = 100) | ||
# Line plot to connect the points for each model | ||
for i in range(0, len(condition_df), 2): | ||
ax.plot(condition_df[‘R2’].iloc[i:i + 2], condition_df[‘F-Statistic’].iloc[i:i + 2], | ||
condition_df[‘Coefficient’].iloc[i:i + 2], color = colors[condition]) | ||
# Adding annotations with a vertical offset | ||
for i in range(len(condition_df)): | ||
ax.text(condition_df[‘R2’].iloc[i], condition_df[‘F-Statistic’].iloc[i], condition_df[‘Coefficient’].iloc[i] + 0.05, | ||
‘%s’ % condition_df[‘Model’].iloc[i], size = 10, zorder = 1, color = ‘k’) | ||
# Adding labels and title | ||
ax.set_xlabel(‘R2’, fontsize = 12) | ||
ax.set_ylabel(‘F-Statistic’, fontsize = 12) | ||
ax.set_zlabel(‘Coefficient’, fontsize = 12) | ||
ax.set_title(‘3D Scatter Plot of Economic Models Metrics with Lines and Annotations’, fontsize = 14) | ||
ax.legend() | ||
# Adding grid lines | ||
ax.grid(True) | ||
# Showing the plot | ||
plt.show() |
References
- Acs, Zoltan J., and Laszlo Szerb. 2007. Entrepreneurship, economic growth and public policy. Small Business Economics 28: 109–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Acs, Zoltan, Thomas Åstebro, David Audretsch, and David T. Robinson. 2016. Public policy to promote entrepreneurship: A call to arms. Small Business Economics 47: 35–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- AICPA. 2017. Guiding Principles of Good Tax Policy: A Framework for Evaluating Tax Proposals. Durham: American Institute of Certified Public Accountants. [Google Scholar]
- Al-Ubaydli, Omar, Min Sok Lee, John A. List, Claire L. Mackevicius, and Dana Suskind. 2021. How can experiments play a greater role in public policy? Twelve proposals from an economic model of scaling. Behavioural Public Policy 5: 2–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Biernaski, Izabel, and Christian Luiz Silva. 2018. Main variables of Brazilian public policies on biomass use and energy. Brazilian Archives of Biology and Technology 61: e18000310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bourdin, Sébastien, and Fabien Nadou. 2018. French tech: A new form of territorial mobilization to face up to global competition? In Annales de Geographie. Paris: Cairn/Publilog. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Castaño, María Soledad, María Teresa Méndez, and Miguel Ángel Galindo. 2016. The effect of public policies on entrepreneurial activity and economic growth. Journal of Business Research 69: 5280–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Castro, Edgar, and Carlos Scartascini. 2019. Imperfect Attention in Public Policy: A Field Experiment During a Tax Amnesty in Argentina. IDB Discussion Paper. Washington: IDB. [Google Scholar]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2018. Methods of Controlled Transactions and the Behavior of Companies According to the Public and Tax Policy. Economics 6: 33–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2019. The R.B.Q. (Rational, Behavioral and Quantified) Model. Ekonomika 98: 6–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2021a. Index of the cycle of money—The case of Bulgaria. Economic Alternatives 27: 225–34. Available online: https://www.unwe.bg/doi/eajournal/2021.2/EA.2021.2.04.pdf (accessed on 17 September 2024).
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2021b. Index of the cycle of money—The case of Greece. IJBESAR (International Journal of Business and Economic Sciences Applied Research) 14: 58–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2022a. Conditions of the CM (Cycle of Money). In Social and Economic Studies within the Framework of Emerging Global Developments, Volume 1. Edited by Muhammed Veysel Kaya. Lausanne: Peter Lang, pp. 13–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2022b. Economocracy versus capitalism. Acta Universitatis Bohemiae Meridionalis 25: 33–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2022c. Index of the cycle of money—The case of Poland. Research Papers in Economics and Finance 6: 72–86. Available online: https://journals.ue.poznan.pl/REF/article/view/126/83 (accessed on 17 September 2024). [CrossRef]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2023a. A comparison of the velocities of minimum escaped savings and financial liquidity. In Social and Economic Studies within the Framework of Emerging Global Developments, Volume 4. Edited by Haşim Özüdoğru, Muhammed Veysel Kaya and Ufuk Kaya. Lausanne: Peter Lang, pp. 41–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2023b. From savings to escape and enforcement savings. Cogito 15: 206–16. [Google Scholar]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2023c. Impact Factor of Liability of Tax System According to the Theory of Cycle of Money. In Social and Economic Studies within the Framework of Emerging Global Developments Volume 3. Edited by Muhammed Veysel Kaya. Lausanne: Peter Lang, pp. 31–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2023d. Index of the cycle of money: The case of Costa Rica. Sapienza 4: e23041. Available online: https://journals.sapienzaeditorial.com/index.php/SIJIS (accessed on 17 September 2024). [CrossRef]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2023e. Risk on the tax system of the E.U. from 2016 to 2022. Economics 11: 55–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2023f. Utility of Cycle of Money without the Escaping Savings (Protection of the Economy). In Social and Economic Studies within the Framework of Emerging Global Developments Volume 2. Edited by Muhammed Veysel Kaya. Lausanne: Peter Lang, pp. 53–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2024a. Economocracy’s Equalizer. In International Conference on Science, Innovations and Global Solutions. Berlin: ResearchGate, pp. 320–24. [Google Scholar]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2024b. From Economics to Economic Engineering (The Cycle of Money): The case of Romania. Cogito XVII: 161. [Google Scholar]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2024c. Impact Factor of Liability Using the Sensitivity Method. Frankfurt: Peter Lang. [Google Scholar]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2024d. Rewarding Taxes on the Cycle of Money. Social and Economic Studies within the Framework of Emerging Global Developments. Frankfurt: Peter Lang, vol. 5. [Google Scholar]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2024e. The Index of the Cycle of Money: The Case of Switzerland. Risk and Financial Management 17: 135. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Challoumis, Constantinos. 2024f. Transfer Pricing and Tax Avoidance Effects on Global and Government Revenue. Athens: National and Kapodistrian University of Athens. Available online: https://www.didaktorika.gr/eadd/handle/10442/56562 (accessed on 17 September 2024).
- Cruz-Castro, Laura, and Luis Sanz-Menéndez. 2016. The effects of the economic crisis on public research: Spanish budgetary policies and research organizations. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 113: 157–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- dos Santos Benso Maciel, Leticia, Benedito Donizeti Bonatto, Hector Arango, and Lucas Gustavo Arango. 2020. Evaluating public policies for fair social tariffs of electricity in Brazil by using an economic market model. Energies 13: 4811. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dybowski, T. Philipp, and Philipp Adämmer. 2018. The economic effects of U.S. presidential tax communication: Evidence from a correlated topic model. European Journal of Political Economy 55: 511–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Engström, Gustav, Johan Gars, Niko Jaakkola, Therese Lindahl, Daniel Spiro, and Arthur A. van Benthem. 2020. What Policies Address Both the Coronavirus Crisis and the Climate Crisis? Environmental and Resource Economics 76: 789–810. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Feinschreiber, Robert. 2004. Transfer pricing Methods An Application Guide. Hoboken: John Wiley & Sons. [Google Scholar]
- Gong, Binlei, Shurui Zhang, Lingran Yuan, and Kevin Z. Chen. 2020. A balance act: Minimizing economic loss while controlling novel coronavirus pneumonia. Journal of Chinese Governance 5: 249–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Herzog, Bodo. 2021. Sustainable consumer tax evasion theory under information inattention. Sustainability 13: 562. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hussain, Zahid, Bilal Mehmood, Muhammad Kaleem Khan, and Raymondo Sandra Marcelline Tsimisaraka. 2022. Green Growth, Green Technology, and Environmental Health: Evidence From High-GDP Countries. Frontiers in Public Health 9: 816697. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kanthak, Leon, and Dennis C. Spies. 2018. Public support for European Union economic policies. European Union Politics 19: 97–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. San Diego: Harcourt Brace. [Google Scholar]
- Ladvocat, Marcelo, and Vander Lucas. 2019. Regional disparities, public policies and economic growth in Brazil. Revista Baru—Revista Brasileira de Assuntos Regionais e Urbanos 5: 264–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lal, Anita, Marjory Moodie, Anna Peeters, and Rob Carter. 2018. Inclusion of equity in economic analyses of public health policies: Systematic review and future directions. Australian and New Zealand Journal of Public Health 42: 207–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, Nannan, Rong Liu, Jian Huang, and Lingshuang Chen. 2018. Pollution, happiness and willingness to pay taxes: The value effect of public environmental policies. Problemy Ekorozwoju 13: 75–86. [Google Scholar]
- Mangoting, Yenni, Oviliani Yenty Yuliana, Jesslyn Effendy, Lovena Hariono, and Viennie Melinda Lians. 2021. The Effect of Tax Risk on Tax Avoidance. Jurnal Keuangan Dan Perbankan 25: 570–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Moreno-Jiménez, José María, Cristina Pérez-Espés, and Manuela Velázquez. 2014. E-Cognocracy and the design of public policies. Government Information Quarterly 31: 185–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Penchev, Pencho. 2014. The “Alternative” Socialism of Professor Alexander Tsankov. Economic Alternatives 2: 61–75. [Google Scholar]
- Richardson, George Barclay. 1964. Economic Theory. London and New York: Routledge Taylor & Francis Croup. [Google Scholar]
- Rumayya, Anu Rammohan, Rudi Purwono, and Iman Harymawan. 2020. The local economy and Re-election of incumbent district leaders in Indonesia. Heliyon 6: e04098. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sikka, Prem. 2018. Combating corporate tax avoidance by requiring large companies to file their tax returns. Journal of Capital Markets Studies 2: 9–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2002. Globalization and Its Discontents. New York: W.W. Norton & Company. [Google Scholar]
- Tvaronavičienė, Manuela, Elena Tarkhanova, and Nino Durglishvili. 2018. Sustainable economic growth and innovative development of educational systems. Journal of International Studies 11: 248–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Urwannachotima, Nipaporn, Piya Hanvoravongchai, John Pastor Ansah, Piyada Prasertsom, and Victoria Rui Ying Koh. 2020. Impact of sugar-sweetened beverage tax on dental caries: A simulation analysis. BMC Oral Health 20: 76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Van de Vijver, Anne, Danny Cassimon, and Peter-Jan Engelen. 2020. A real option approach to sustainable corporate tax behavior. Sustainability 12: 5406. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Van den Bergh, Jeroen C. J. M. 2009. The GDP paradox. Journal of Economic Psychology 30: 117–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Woody, William Douglas, and Wayne Viney. 2017. A History of Psychology: The Emergence of Science and Applications, 6th ed. New York: Taylor & Francis Group, pp. 1–599. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- World Bank. 2003. World Development Report 2003: Sustainable Development in a Dynamic World. Washington, DC: World Bank. Available online: https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/5985 (accessed on 17 September 2024).
Observation | Labor (L) | Land (A) | Output (Y) |
---|---|---|---|
1 | 100 | 50 | 8000 |
2 | 120 | 60 | 10,000 |
3 | 150 | 70 | 12,000 |
4 | 130 | 65 | 11,000 |
5 | 110 | 55 | 9000 1 |
Observation | Income Inequality (Gini) | Welfare Programs (W) | Distribution Efficiency (D) |
---|---|---|---|
1 | 0.45 | 500 | 0.7 |
2 | 0.5 | 600 | 0.65 |
3 | 0.4 | 550 | 0.75 |
4 | 0.48 | 580 | 0.68 |
5 | 0.42 | 620 | 0.72 1 |
Observation | Enforcement Savings (E) | Escape Savings (S) | Economic Growth (G) |
---|---|---|---|
1 | 0.6 | 0.2 | 3.5 |
2 | 0.65 | 0.15 | 4 |
3 | 0.55 | 0.25 | 3.2 |
4 | 0.7 | 0.1 | 4.5 |
5 | 0.62 | 0.18 | 3.8 1 |
Production Efficiency Model | Without Money Cycle & Economocracy | With Money Cycle & Economocracy |
---|---|---|
Production Efficiency Model | ||
R2 | 0.85 | 0.87 |
Labor Coefficient | 2 | 2.1 |
Land Coefficient | 5 | 5.1 |
F-Statistic | 45.3 | 50 |
Distributive Efficiency Model | ||
R2 | 0.78 | 0.81 |
Income Inequality Coefficient | −0.3 | −0.35 |
Welfare Programs Coefficient | 0.4 | 0.45 |
F-Statistic | 35 | 40 |
Money Cycle Impact Model | ||
R2 | 0.72 | 0.75 |
Enforcement Savings Coefficient | 0.3 | 0.35 |
Escape Savings Coefficient | −0.1 | −0.05 |
F-Statistic | 20 | 25 1 |
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2024 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Challoumis, C. Integrating Money Cycle Dynamics and Economocracy for Optimal Resource Allocation and Economic Stability. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2024, 17, 422. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm17090422
Challoumis C. Integrating Money Cycle Dynamics and Economocracy for Optimal Resource Allocation and Economic Stability. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2024; 17(9):422. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm17090422
Chicago/Turabian StyleChalloumis, Constantinos. 2024. "Integrating Money Cycle Dynamics and Economocracy for Optimal Resource Allocation and Economic Stability" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 17, no. 9: 422. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm17090422
APA StyleChalloumis, C. (2024). Integrating Money Cycle Dynamics and Economocracy for Optimal Resource Allocation and Economic Stability. Journal of Risk and Financial Management, 17(9), 422. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm17090422