Nothing Special   »   [go: up one dir, main page]

Academia.eduAcademia.edu
KEDGE BUSINESS SCHOOL Master’s Thesis A comparative study of the strategic decision making processes in established corporations and startups Nicolas MORIN 30/06/2017 Table of contents Introduction: ............................................................................................................................... 1 I) The fundamental differences between entrepreneurial ventures and established corporations ................................................................................................................................ 4 A) General characteristics ................................................................................................. 4 1) Definition of a startup .............................................................................................. 4 2) General characteristics of an established corporation: ............................................. 8 3) The general characteristics that differentiate a startup from an established corporation........................................................................................................................ 10 B) Differences in terms of objectives ............................................................................. 14 1) The approach towards innovation .......................................................................... 14 2) Business objectives ................................................................................................ 20 C) II) The external forces of the firms ................................................................................. 23 1) Organizational ecology and Industry forces. ......................................................... 23 2) The institutional environment for entrepreneurship and established business ...... 29 A traditional perspective on strategic decision making.................................................... 35 A) 1) The profile of the CEO and top management vs Entrepreneur ................................. 35 Psychological attributes ......................................................................................... 35 Decision-making differences between an Entrepreneur and a CEO ......................... 45 2) B) Non-psychological attributes ................................................................................. 45 A utility function perspective on strategic decision making ..................................... 49 1) The utility function of the entrepreneur ................................................................. 49 2) The utility function of the CEO ............................................................................. 53 C) The traditional strategic orientation derived from a top management perspective ... 54 III) A systematic review on the impact of Entrepreneurial Marketing in developing corporations .............................................................................................................................. 60 A) Definitions ................................................................................................................. 60 B) H1: The younger the firm, the more power the founder has on decision making ..... 65 C) H2: The younger the firm, the less structured their business processes are .............. 69 D) H3: network and a strong personal brand are key for EM to succeed ....................... 73 Conclusion and limitations. ...................................................................................................... 78 References ................................................................................................................................ 80 Table of illustrations ................................................................................................................. 85 About the author: My name is Nicolas Morin – a French graduate student from KEDGE Business School. I speak three languages and have been passionate about entrepreneurship and strategy since a very young age. I pursued this interest by setting up a mechanic workshop at 15 and by getting involved in different startup projects. I also founded a publishing company and wrote two books about fitness and nutrition. Different cultures are another passion of mine and I’ve had the privilege of living in five different countries – thanks to various internships, exchange semesters, and other such programs. These experiences have allowed me to learn about decision making processes in various contexts and environments – which explains my thesis. Before working for UPS as a Global Product Strategy Analyst (part of the AIESEC traineeship program), most of my professional experience lay in startups. While these and small businesses rely on a combination of intuition and statistics for making decisions, established corporations must be even more critical about how they evaluate opportunities due to their impact on stakeholders. The UPS policy book, itself, states that: “We look for opportunities to expand into new markets and we evaluate the impact of our expansion on our company, people, customers, shareowners, and communities.” I therefore want to take an empirical look into the factors which affect decision-making, and how such differs between startups and established corporations. You can reach me at renner.morin.n@gmail.com or through my LinkedIn profile at https://www.linkedin.com/in/nicolas-morin-69388a100/ 0 Introduction: This section provides a greater overview of the topic by linking it with current business trends and explains how this paper is structured. The 21st century is seeing massive disruptions in established industries by creating new trends. Tesla, Airbnb, and Uber are new players that are changing existing ways of doing business. Their visionary founders challenge the status-quo and are redefining the way value is delivered. We live in very interesting times. Intense competition, entry barriers, and industry forces created by very established players are being challenged or made irrelevant. Not too long ago, the taxi industry could never have imagined the threat that Uber now poses to their business. The latter’s “Blitzkrieg” policies have succeeded in grabbing more than 50% of the market share in the United States, alone1. The same goes for the hotel industry. Airbnb was the product of two entrepreneurs who had to go through almost 30 credit cards between them before they finally hit the big time. Their big time meant that anyone anywhere can make money by renting their property out to anyone. But such also had a big impact on the profit margins of a hotel industry that cannot compete in terms of price – burdened as they are by industry regulations that they, themselves, helped to pass. These examples are just the tip of the iceberg. The result is that many traditional industries are under threat, while those that still survive will never be the same. These changes are fueled by the development of new technologies, as well as the capacity of entrepreneurs to recombine or rethink established business models. To be competitive and profitable, a company must find a way to deliver greater value than its competitors. This is the basic definition of “competitive advantage” as described by Porter2 in the early 1980s. To outperform the competition, firms must either provide solutions at cheaper prices than the competition (cost leadership), or be seen as unique (differentiation). Those who are very innovative can redefine markets and pursue both strategies simultaneously. Consumers have also changed a lot. New technologies allow them to quickly compare alternatives, get instant feedback, and engage in the development process of the final product. They have switched from one-way unilateral communication sustained by traditional marketing approaches, to a two-way responsive communication thanks to the development of social media. According to the television bureau of advertising (2009), social media, defined by “online technologies, practices, or communities that people use to generate content and share opinions, insights, experiences, and perspectives with each other,” are enabling a shift from a traditional 1 https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2017-01-26/uber-takes-majority-of-ground-transport-market-for-u-sbusiness-travelers 2 Porter, (1980) identified a competitive advantage as: "A function of either providing comparable buyer value more efficiently than competitors, which is low cost, or performing activities at comparable costs, but in unique ways that create more buyer value than competitors; and hence, command a premium price, which is differentiation." 1 perspective to “an expanded dialogue between company and consumer” (Matthews, 2011). New ventures are capitalizing on this change to deliver a version of the company’s capabilities that match the needs of customers. The macro-environment is also being transformed and emerging markets are on the rise, changing the way we produce and consume. A greater concern towards the environment, sustainability, and fairness is also opening new ways for companies to differentiate themselves. Almost everyone knows of Mark Zuckerberg (Facebook), Drew Houston (Dropbox), and Elon Musk (Tesla). Chances are, however, that the same does not apply to Jeffrey R. Immelt (CEO of General Electric – the 4th largest company in the world as per market capitalization in 2016), Daren Woods (CE of Exxon Mobile – the 5th largest company in the world as per market capitalization in 2016), or Matthias Müller (CEO of Volkswagen – the 8th largest company in the world in terms of revenue as of 2016). Driven by their vision and passion, entrepreneurs are already distinguishing themselves from the traditional top-management of a firm. There seems to be specific psychological characteristics, as well as leadership styles, that enable entrepreneurs to be considered as “men apart” (Gartner, 1989). According to Lumpkin, G.T. and Dess, G. (1996), “the history of entrepreneurship is filled with stories of self-determined pioneers who had a unique, new idea – a better idea – and made a business out of it.” A lot of research has been focused on the role of entrepreneurs and their startups. Few, however, have tried to explain what differentiates entrepreneurs and startups from the CEOs of established players. More specifically, how do we define an entrepreneur and a startup in terms of orientation, goals, and aspirations, and what makes them so different from all the established firms? What are the key strategic decision making processes that make startups so innovative, yet also very risky compared to key industry players who are always late in catching the new trends? The goal of this paper is to examine the key differences in the strategic decision making processes that exists between CEOs and entrepreneurs, as well as between startups and established corporations. To do so, we will first start by defining what a startup is and how different it is from an established corporation. After carefully reviewing all of the main characteristics, we will move to an economic perspective (approach towards innovation) and an ecology perspective (industry forces and founding rates), and finally, to a macro-environment perspective (New Institutional Economics and PEST framework). We will then focus on describing who the CEOs are and how different their thought process is as compared to founders and entrepreneurs. Psychological characteristics and nonpsychological attributes will be considered in order to derive, from the current research stream, some specific heuristics and their utility function. This will allow us to get an understanding of the traditional marketing approach and orientation of established corporations. 2 In the last section, we will look into what defines an entrepreneur and provide a systematic review of what is now called Entrepreneurial Marketing (EM), as well as the Entrepreneurial Orientation (EO) of the firm. Three hypotheses will be tested and verified by looking at the current results in empirical research. • • • H1: The younger the firm, the more power the founder has on the decision-making process. H2: The younger the firm, the less structured their marketing processes are. H3: A strong personal brand and network are vital for EMs to succeed. We will then present our conclusions, discuss the limitations of this paper, and suggest new perspectives for empirical research. 3 I) The fundamental differences between entrepreneurial ventures and established corporations A) General characteristics 1) Definition of a startup This section defines a startup by analyzing its core characteristics and purpose. It will then integrate different theories and definitions with a focus on the one most relevant for our analysis. Startups have always been a very difficult concept to scientifically define. First, how do we make a clear distinction between a startup and a Small and Medium Sized Enterprise (SME)? Both are new businesses and correspond to the definition of Storey & Greene (2010), that: “A new business is a new transacting entity that did not exist in a previous time period, is not owned by an existing business, and is not a simple change of ownership.” A better definition could involve the following characteristics (Woywode, M., 2014): • Is its own entity or is separate from the existing personal activities of the owner/s • Involves some activity (transactions) • Is legally independent from other businesses • It was not acquired from others (i.e. a sole transfer of ownership with no other changes) • It has a unique name • It is not a change of location or a changed name of an existing business. Paul Graham, co-founder of the Y Combinator (the biggest venture capitalist firm in terms of amount invested) said that, “A company five years old can still be a startup, ten [years old] would start to be a stretch.” The Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM), the largest international study of the adult population engaged in entrepreneurial activity, considers the early-stage entrepreneurship profile as follows: it is a combination of the nascent entrepreneur stage (0 – 3 months) and the owner manager of a new-business (up to 3.5 years old). 4 The following graph presents an overview established by the GEM in 2014. Figure 1: Entrepreneurship Stages Representation (GEM, 2014) Both startups and SMEs are in the Total early-stage Entrepreneurial Activity (TEA). We can therefore argue that being a newly established business is not enough to differentiate a startup from an SME. Startups have mostly been exclusively associated in the press with new technologies. Most journalists, in fact, consider startups as being a newly started tech company. This definition is incomplete, however. It fails to consider the degree of innovation a startup represents. Can a new time management app be considered a startup, for example? Especially since there are already more than a hundred alternatives available on the market? According to Adora Cheung3, cofounder and CEO of Homejoy, a “startup is a state of mind. It’s when people join your company and are still making the explicit decision to forgo stability in exchange for the promise of tremendous growth and the excitement of making immediate impact [sic].” Nor is she the only one who thinks so. Russel D’Souza4, cofounder of Seatgeek, suggests that, “It stops being a startup when people don’t feel as though what they are doing has impact.” The central idea behind a startup could therefore be about making an impact and challenging the status-quo. Guy Kawasaki5, a Silicon Valley based author, speaker, and entrepreneur goes even further by saying that, “Entrepreneurship is no longer a job title. It is the state of mind of people who want to change the future.” 3 https://www.forbes.com/pictures/emjl45hjge/adora-cheung-left-cofounder-of-homejoy/#66c9d2993894 https://www.forbes.com/sites/natalierobehmed/2013/12/16/what-is-a-startup/#40440c914044 5 In the introduction of his book, the Art of the Start (2004) 4 5 It is an entrepreneur’s passion (defined by the Merriam-Webster6 website as an “intense, driving, or overmastering feeling or conviction”) that may make the difference between startups and SMEs. To challenge the status-quo, startups need to grow and they need to do it fast if they want to survive. Most do, yet most also fail after a couple of years. An entrants’ life is “nasty, brutish and short” (Geroski, 2011). According to a study published by the U.S Small Business Administration7 (SBA), only 66% of newly established businesses survive more than two years, and 44% survive after five. So are startups rising stars or dying meteors? This growth orientation or willingness to become a “dynamic capitalist” contributes, in a very disproportionate way, to employment and to the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of a country. In fact, 4% of entrants create up to 50% of jobs (Kirchhoff, 1994). It also corresponds to the concept of “Gazelles” identified by Birch (1981) as agile growth oriented to “at least 20% growth a year for four years” and with above average profitability (Birch, 1981). This contrasts with the idea of mice (small businesses) that are very flexible but likely to stay small compared to elephants (large corporations that have significant market power but are very slow in adapting to change). There is therefore a need to develop a definition that integrates the newness of a firm together with its purpose. Researchers have failed to come up with a real scientific definition of a startup, so we will have to turn to definitions from the business world. The definition that best fits the context of a startup, according to Steve Blank, serialentrepreneur and academician, is “a temporary structure, designed to find a repeatable and scalable business model.” A business model is commonly defined by the answer to the following question: “how are we going to generate money?” It is therefore the core of any business. Joan Magretta, author of “Why Business Models Matter?”8, takes it a step further by splitting the business model into two perspectives: • • The first part is mostly related to the production and design processes: “Part one includes all the activities associated with making something: designing it, purchasing raw materials, manufacturing, and so on.” The second part is the second and final step of the business model: “Now that we have a product or a service ready to be sold, how do we manage to reach the market and find consumers?” 6 https://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/passion https://www.sba.gov/sites/default/files/Business-Survival.pdf 8 https://hbr.org/2002/05/why-business-models-matter 7 6 Magretta adds another interesting perspective to distinguish between business models and competitive strategies – a business model is how you intend to run your business whereas a competitive strategy relies on the willingness to find ways to outperform the competition. Another definition of a business model is given by Osterwalder and Pigneur in “Business Model Generation”9 – a business model summarizes how an organization “creates, delivers, and captures value.” Thanks to these definitions, we can understand that a startup’s function is not to exist forever. It is driven by the willingness to find a unique way of sustainably creating, delivering, and capturing value. It is putting into practice the entrepreneur’s vision into a viable and profitable venture. 9 https://strategyzer.com/books/business-model-generation 7 2) General characteristics of an established corporation: Startups are a challenging concept to define and the same can be said of established corporations. Though more stable characteristics exist to define a Multinational Corporation (MNC), we will also explain the specific characteristics of dominant industry players. Existing business literature has not yet clearly defined what an established corporation is. For the sake of our analysis, we will focus on key industry players that can be defined as follows: • Businesses that have been around for more than 3.5 years. It means that the business has already gathered some experience and networks within a specific industry, and therefore does not suffer from the liability of newness. This term, originally defined by Stinchcombe in 1965, argues that younger firms tend to have a higher death rate. This is due to the constellation of problems they face related to the founding of their firm – such as the lack of networks or the reliance on a small set of customers. • • • • We also need to consider the size of the firm. Those that have more than 250 employees are usually considered to be large. Also, according to investor words, a large-sized company should achieve more than $5.75 million of turnover per year to be considered “large.” Key industry players are those that have a significant relative market share in the industry they operate in. We will focus on companies with more than 10% relative market share and therefore have reasonable industry power. This definition is extremely important since we will be talking about organizational ecology and network influences. Firms should be stock-listed, and therefore answer to a wide-array of stakeholders – including the shareholders of the company. It means that established players face both internal and external pressure from various stakeholders. It should already have an established corporate structure, with a top management and a top-down hierarchy. Though some very established players (such as Zappos, for example) have more of a flat structure, everyone knows who does what and who has more decision-making power than another (as per tenure, position occupied, or shares of the company owned). Defining an established corporation in these terms allows us to compare startups with established corporations. In terms of objectives, key industry players have already found their business model. Their objective is therefore limited to keeping or improving their competitive position and reaping the most profit. 8 Differentiating startups from established corporations can also be done by looking at the specific stages that define their activity. The following graph by Thierry Janssen10, an associate partner with Just in Time Management group, allows us to establish a clear distinction between established industry players and startups. Firm Stages Seed Startup Growth Established Expansion Mature Exit Figure 2: Firm Stages The graph shows that what is considered as the startup stage includes the seed (which is usually pre-startup or before the company gets started) and the real startup stage. The growth stage is a transitionary state where a startup is going to turn into an established player in a given industry. There is no specific timeline on this graph because we can argue that these stages can occur at different times for different companies. Also, this graph gives a rather high-level overview and does not necessarily consider the small transitionary phases for each step. So all the stages, from “established” to the exit of the firm (when a firm decides to leave a specific industry or is driven out of the market by going bankrupt) will be the ones we consider when it comes to distinguishing between startups and established corporations. If firms survive the growth stage, it is likely that the “established” part will represent a very significant portion of their life. 10 https://www.linkedin.com/in/thierryjanssen/?ppe=1 9 3) The general characteristics that differentiate a startup from an established corporation This section will compare the key tangible and intangible characteristics that will enable us to get a clear picture on what differentiates a startup from an established corporation. According to Storey & Greene (2010) there are a couple of key differences that are worth mentioning when it comes to comparing startups (or small businesses in general) as compared to established corporations. The first group gravitates around uncertainty – not to be confused with risk, which can be calculated or estimated through a statistical model based on previous experience (Knight, 1921). On the contrary, an uncertain situation is so unique that it is not possible to draw any kind of model to evaluate the outcomes. Startups and established corporations are very different when it comes to uncertainty. According to Storey and Greene (2010), the former tends to face more external uncertainty from the macro-economic environment and industry. Being new in a market means that they don’t have the necessary experience to know about the underlying driving forces in the industry. Though a very important cause of startup failures, these external drivers have been given only “scant attention in the literature” (Berryman, 1983). On the other hand, established businesses tend to face internal uncertainty – the strategy defined by top-management might not be implemented as planned. This probability is also next to impossible to define (Storey, 2010). Moreover, Storey and Greene (2010) identified three types of uncertainty: • Market uncertainty Small or new businesses tend to be price-takers because the volume of their output is too low to have a significant impact on price. On the other hand, large and established corporations are price-makers – meaning that they can influence the entire industry with their pricing policy. A good example of this is how Free entered the French telecommunication market. The Iliad group’s Free entered the French market back in 2012, slashed their prices, and snatched up more than 10% of the market shares within a couple of months. Being backed up by a very large company enabled Free to stand up against the retaliation of the French telecom “cartel.”11 Young firms or startups also face market uncertainty because they often depend on one large customer, have low economies of scale, and might face retaliation from established incumbents inside the specific industry they are entering. 11 https://www.nextinpact.com/archive/34135-telephonie-cartel-condamnation.htm 10 • Customer uncertainty Any new business can define its cost structure, though their selling price can remain unknown. This is tied up to the fact that newly established businesses are price takers – both from their suppliers (who are usually much bigger and therefore have a stronger bargaining power) and their customers (who, especially in the beginning, tend to be much larger). Large businesses already have an extended list of customers, making their whole operation less risky because even if one fails to pay, the portfolio is spread enough to absorb the shock. They can also rely on their previous market experience and their extensive market network to anticipate changes from all sides. • Aspirational uncertainty Entrepreneurs usually have a wide-array of motivations which aren’t always purely monetary. This is unlike CEOs who must answer to a wide range of stakeholders and are more incentivized by their pay-structure. So, entrepreneurs have a vision, even though they may not yet have their objectives clearly laid down. To foster entrepreneurship, several mechanisms can be used to limit risk and uncertainty. This includes creating a Limited Liability company which limits investment by outsourcing and focusing on a more short-term approach. Uncertainty aside, there are other differences between startups and established corporations, including: • • • Risk of failure Startups have a higher risk of failure due to the risk-taking approach of their founder and the overall degree of innovation of their business model. Though prominent firms can also fail (Enron, WorldCom, GM, etc.), such tends to be less likely because of the risk control mechanisms they have in place. Market Power Large firms have reached “a critical mass” of users (Blind, 2004) and trigger the bandwagon effect. In today’s economic environment, reaching a critical mass of users can be a key to success – especially when it comes to new technologies. Limited market power is also associated with a limited geographic presence, market image, and loyalty. Management Smaller firms tend to have a more flexible management style and a more decentralized structure. As the firm gets older, more processes are put into place to ensure efficiency, and as a consequence, the established firm tends to become more bureaucratic (Weber, 1921). Bureaucracy is defined by standardized procedures and clearly defined job roles. 11 • • • • • • Motivation of owner While the founder/entrepreneur pursues both monetary and non-monetary goals (Guth, 1990) shareowners of a company are mostly monetarily oriented (earnings per share and stock price). Brand While established players can capitalize on their brand recognition and awareness to sustain their marketing efforts and their strategy, smaller firms are not yet known on the market and must build a reputation for themselves. Wages and benefits for workers Large organizations can have a much bigger budget for their employees’ compensation and benefits. This is mostly because their business is already up and running, and has probably already broken even. Workforce Large corporations tend to be crowded with senior and experienced workers, especially in management. Startups, on the other hand, tend to have a much younger and more creative workforce. Human Resources While it is very likely that any large corporation will have a specific Human Resources (HR) department staffed with professionals, the HR management in newly established businesses tend to be taken care of by the founder. Training and recruitment Established corporations can afford a budget for training their employees to enable them to broaden their skill sets. Startups mostly rely on peer and informal training, as it is more flexible and less costly. The recruitment process is also totally different in an established corporation as compared to a startup. While the former will give a lot of importance to the educational background of the applicant, the latter will mostly focus on what the potential new employee can do and what his/her mindset is. Startups are made up of small teams for which a high degree of fit is required. • Sources of finance Big corporations can get access to financing capital easily – assuming they have sound management and a healthy balance sheet. They usually finance themselves, however, by raising extra capital, getting a loan from a bank, or even using available funds from their subsidiaries. Startups and newly founded firms will mostly rely on bootstrap. They might get a seed investment from a business angel depending on their network and their idea. It’s unlikely that they’ll get a Series A investment (usually provided by Venture Capitalists), however, unless they can show a solid proof of concept. 12 The following chart summarizes the key differences between startups and established corporations: Summary of the key differences Characteristics Startups Established corporations High Low – Medium Market Uncertainty High Low Customer Uncertainty Medium – High Low Aspirational Uncertainty High Low Risk of failure Limited Strong Market Power Flexible Bureaucratic Management Multiple Return on Investment Motivation of owner Unknown Strong Brand Comprehensive Wages and benefits for Limited workers Jack of all trades Experts Workforce Limited Specific department Human resources Informal and unplanned, Formal and planned, based Training and recruitment based on a high degree of fit on expertise Bootstrapping, business Capital raise, loan from Source of finance angels and venture capitalists banks, internal finance Figure 3: Summary of the key differences between startups and established corporations All the aforementioned factors are going to affect how both established corporations and startups define their objectives. 13 B) Differences in terms of objectives 1) The approach towards innovation This section will compare the approach of established players and startups in terms of innovation. After defining what innovation is, we will look at specific theories and use them as a support to analyze different approaches towards innovation. Innovation is about the formulation of new ideas or processes. It is defined by Fagerberg (2003) as “the first occurrence of an idea for a new product or process.” Innovation takes the whole process one step further because it is “the first commercialization of the idea” (Fagerberg, 2003). Innovation is therefore all about the practical application of new inventions into marketable products or services. The following process summarizes the steps involved: Idea: Invention: Innovation: Conceptual representation Initial development Marketable offering Figure 4: Steps in the innovation process Schumpeter sees innovation as something that changed the market in a profound way. Consequently, firms that innovate are extremely likely to become market leaders and gain a significant competitive advantage over their competitors (Schumpeter J. , 1934). Lumpkin & Dess (1996) defined it as “the firm’s tendency to engage in, and support new ideas, novelty, experimentation, and creative process or research and development activities which may result in new products, services, or technological processes.” (Lumpkin, 1996). A good example of the differences between the two is the case of MP3. This music format was invented by Karlheinz Brandenburg with his team at the FrauenhoferInstitute12. The idea was protected by a patent and licensed to other corporations which generated $143 million in licensing revenues in 2005, alone. But it was turned into an invention by Apple, which used the MP3 standard for the iPod, iTunes, and iStore. Capitalizing on this invention and turning it into a marketable product by building specific synergies, Apple increased their revenue from 2004 to 2005 by $3.2 billion. This ecosystem created a much better market appeal for the MP3 player and enabled it to reach a broader set of users, which in the end, generated a lot of revenue. 12 https://www.iis.fraunhofer.de/en/ff/amm/prod/audiocodec/audiocodecs/mp3.html 14 This example corresponds to the theory that returns from an invention are likely to be minimal as compared to an innovation (Astebro, 2003). Though most innovations are never turned into products or services, both inventions and innovations are critical to economic development (Astebro, 2003). Startups go for more radical innovations and correspond more to the profile of entrepreneurship as identified by Schumpeter. Schumpeter considers entrepreneurs to be exceptional people with a specific set of abilities that enable them to be the drivers of change in the market through radical innovations. Damanpour F. identified radical innovations as “those that produce fundamental changes in the activities of an organization and large departures from existing practices” as compared to incremental innovations which are “those that result in a lesser degree of departure from existing practices” (Damanpour, 1996). Radical innovations may also be seen as potentially generating an extraordinary economic performance and may be described as the engine of economic growth (Wiklund J., 2003). What is more, Kropp et al. (2006) identified innovativeness as a vital factor for new business success. Schumpeter’s initial theory was that innovation is driven by entrepreneurs and that their startups are a disequilibrium force which strongly contrasts with the static model of market equilibrium in neo-classical models (Schumpeter, 1934). Through the process of “creative destruction,” entrepreneurs (here labeled as innovators) will drive existing established corporations out of business by taking their market shares. In so doing, they will expand overall economic activity by destroying existing market structures. Entrepreneurs and their innovations act as a “disequilibrium” force which challenges existing market structures. New founded firms and innovations are based, according to Schumpeter, on three types of changes: • • • Technological changes Enables the allocation of resources in different and potentially more productive ways. Political and regulatory changes Re-allocates resources to new uses in more profitable ways or ways that re-distribute wealth from one member of society to another Social and demographic changes Transfers information about ways of more productive resource allocation and creating new economies of scale for some types of entrepreneurial activities. 15 Schumpeter also distinguishes five types of innovation: • Introduction of a new good or significant improvement • Introduction of a new method of production • Opening of a new market • Utilization of a new source of supply for raw materials or conquest for new types of half-manufactured goods • The creation of a new type of industrial organization Innovation in startups are therefore brutal driving forces that strongly rely on innovativeness and uniqueness. Indeed, startups tend to correspond to the dynamics of innovation model identified by Taylor and Taylor (Taylor, 2012). Figure 5: Innovation characteristics over time In its early stage, a startup relies on a low capital intensity project (especially when developing the Minimum Viable Product or MVP), but a very high degree technology or business model novelty as identified by the matrix of Ramanda Nanda13 at Harvard Business School. Startups can usually choose to innovate into one of the following dimensions according to Rama Velamuri (Professor of Entrepreneurship at the China Europe International Business School): • Business Model • Market • Product 13 https://hbr.org/2015/09/case-study-should-this-startup-take-vc-money-or-try-to-turn-a-profit 16 Figure 6: Innovation dimensions Accumulating innovation into the three dimensions is not sustainable and is therefore referred to as the suicide cube. Trying to be overly innovative is a very risky strategy, especially when it comes to startups evolving in a very hostile environment. Speaking of innovation, we can reasonably argue that startups also try to innovate to create a new market for themselves. This theory is called the Blue Ocean Theory and was identified by Kim and Mauborgne in 200414. Through innovation, startups are willing to create uncontested market spaces, make the competition irrelevant by breaking the value/cost trade-off, and overall create and capture a new market demand that did not previously exist. This is commonly referred as the “reconstructionist” view. The Blue Ocean Strategy was not necessarily developed exclusively for startups. In fact, a lot of well-known companies such as Nintendo, IKEA, and le Cirque du Soleil were successfully able to implement this type of strategy to distinguish themselves from the competition. What differentiates startups and established businesses is that startups strive to create Blue Oceans right from the start. Startups are not the result of pressure from the competition, but are rather a strong willingness to challenge the establishment. Taking this perspective into account, we can argue that most established corporations are therefore stuck in a Red Ocean environment. They are competing in existing market places, often crowded by strong incumbents. And rather than making the competition irrelevant, they are doing their best to outperform their peers. They are part of a structural view for which the goal is to build a competitive position within a closed industry. 14 https://hbr.org/2004/10/blue-ocean-strategy 17 Indeed, researchers have found that as firms grow, they develop specific hierarchies that are not up to the task of absorbing external information, especially from informal contacts (Berger, 2004). Such, therefore, diminishes the sources and variance of ideas, leading in the end, to a focus on incremental innovation (Dobrev, 2003). They are therefore, according to Kim & Mauborgne, either settlers whose value curves conform to the basic shape of the industry, or migrators who are trying to change the competitive environment through incremental innovation but are still stuck within Red Oceans. Established corporations are consequently more arbitrageurs than innovators. This concept is part of the Austrian perspective on Entrepreneurship, first presented by von Hayek in 1949. The top management of key industry players are equilibrium forces and stress the role of discovery (alertness) that recombine industry resources into a more optimal level. As opposed to Schumpeter, Hayek sees the entrepreneurial activity as an equilibrium force (Hayek & F.A, 1949). They therefore do not require new information or a very innovative approach. Rather, they are less innovative and rely on previously undetected market imperfections to outperform the competition. Their competitive advantage is based on their capacity to incrementally improve their offering at a faster rate than the competition. Hayek identified four specific roles for the entrepreneurial activity of a firm, which are to: • Fill market shortages • Whittle away surpluses • Eliminate quantity gaps • Bring the market back to equilibrium by correcting earlier entrepreneurial errors The following chart summarizes the differences between the two approaches: Schumpeterian vs Kiznerian opportunities Schumpeterian Approach Kiznerian Approach Dis-equilibrating Equilibrating Require new information Do not require new information Very innovative Lie in previously undetected imperfection Rare Common Involve creation Limited to discovery Figure 7: Difference between Schumpeterian and Kiznerian opportunities An important factor to note, however, is that though most of the established firms are very slow to innovate, they have the resources and capabilities to acquire innovative startups, and therefore, acquire new expertise or competitive advantages with a less risky approach. Nowadays, most of the very innovative startups are being acquired by strongly established firms with immense cash flows available to them (Google, Apple, Facebook, etc.). 18 This means that established corporations can also innovate and practice entrepreneurship – but in a different way. According to Schollhammer (1982), firms can use an “acquisitive” type of entrepreneurship by entering new markets only through the acquisitions of other players. This approach involves little to no innovativeness and may not involve a lot of risk, especially if the buyer has a lot of resources available. Recent examples of these acquisitions include: Apigee (acquired by Google for $625 million), Oculus (acquired by Facebook for more than $2 billion) and Turi (acquired by Apple for $200 million). It means that established companies stay innovative through a process of acquisition as well as developing their own incubators for startups. There are also companies that rely solely on imitation. A common example of this would be the difference between Sony and Matsushita (also nicknamed “Maneshita denki” in Japanese – meaning "electronics that have been copied"). While Sony keeps innovating (they invented the Walkman, for example), Matsushita will enter the market once the innovators have developed it and rely on their superior marketing and operational capabilities to capture it (Lieberman, 1988). This different approach towards innovation has an impact on a firm’s objectives, as well as on how they try to build their competitive advantage. 19 2) Business objectives This section explores the differences in terms of business objectives that condition the way both startups and established corporations base their decision making As mentioned earlier, a startup is a temporary structure designed to search for a repeatable and scalable business model (definition by Steve Blank), whereas an established corporation is looking to find the right strategic approach to outperform the competition and generate superior returns. These differences in perspective will strongly affect the way goals are planned and decisions are made. Though both strive to develop a sustainable competitive advantage (SCA) identified as valuable, rare, difficult to imitate, and organizationally viable (Barney, 1991), their approaches will be quite different. What is valuable is determined by the customer perception of the good or the service. To find a way to be competitive, a firm must produce it at a cheaper cost or at a higher perceived value by combining several processes from the value chain identified by Porter. Figure 8: The value chain identified by Porter (1985) To do so, established corporations try to accumulate key resources, achieve better economies of scale, or differentiate themselves through incremental innovation to achieve an SCA. If well executed, the chosen strategy will turn into a competitive position that is rare enough it cannot easily be copied. The resource-based view suggests that above-average returns for any firm are largely determined by the characteristics within the firm. The focus is therefore on developing or obtaining valuable resources or capabilities which are difficult or impossible for rivals to imitate (Penrose, 1959). 20 Established businesses with strong power in the industry can influence not only the market, but also all the forces in their external environment. In some cases, private firms are not only trying to generate superior returns through incremental innovation, but are also lobbying governments in order to create a more favorable environment for their activities. The resource-based view strongly fits the approach taken by established firms. Over time, they will secure heterogeneous resources in the industry that are not very mobile, and therefore, cannot be easily transferred from one firm to the other. The differences in terms of resources and how they are used will be the basis of their competitive advantage by making it difficult to imitate. Finally, for a competitive advantage to be sustainable, it has to be viable inside the organization. This means that a specific organizational structure must be in place in order to enable the strategy to succeed. This strategic perspective is mostly irrelevant for startups which rely mostly on innovativeness as their liability of newness prevents them from securing key resources in the industry. It is also because it is necessary to improve or develop new markets in order to deal with the rapidly changing and uncertain environment in which newly established businesses operate (Quaye, 2013). The following chart establishes the differences between Red and Blue Ocean Strategies (Kim, 2004). Red Ocean Strategy Blue Ocean Strategy Focus on current customers Focus on non-customers Compete in existing markets Create new and uncontested market spaces Beat the competition Make the competition irrelevant Exploit existing demand Create and capture new demand Make the value-cost trade-off Break the value-cost trade-off Align the whole strategic initiative in terms Align the whole strategic initiative in pursuit of cost leadership or differentiation of both differentiation and low cost Figure 9: Highlight of the key differences between Blue and Red Ocean strategies Startups are mostly based on innovation. They therefore do not have to rely on a trade-off between cost leadership and differentiation. Radical innovation is obviously rare and is costly to imitate most of the time (at least in the short to mid-term) as innovative firms get a temporary monopoly from their innovation. Unless it is a service, an innovation is also protected by a patent making it impossible to be duplicated for a specific period. Moreover, Kotler believes that startups are willing to have a “market-driving behavior” – where a firm strives to “shape the structure, preferences and behaviors of all market stakeholders” (Schindehutte, 2007). 21 However, radical innovations do take time before they generate returns. Rogers, in his theory of the law of diffusion of innovation, suggests that it takes time for an innovation to even reach the early majority (Rogers, 1995) . Rogers described his law of diffusion of innovation as an Sshaped curve containing five different groups: • Innovators • Early adopters • Early majority • Late majority • Laggards Simon Sinek went even further in his famous TED Talk15 where he explained the proportion in terms of percentage that each group represents. He also referred to Malcolm Gladwell’s tipping point – the point after which a movement gains a significant momentum usually triggered by small factors or changes. It corresponds to the idea that at some point, and for no real specific reason, an innovation is going to spread inside the market because the early majority started adopting it. The following graph presents his theory: Figure 10: The law of diffusion of innovation Source: Simon Barros, Coordinator at Hiive 15 https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=zU3fIEPfctQ 22 Furthermore, the strategic orientation and processes of established firms do not fit in with the need for flexibility that startups have. Nor do they fit the psychological characteristics of entrepreneurs, as we will see later. In The Lean Startup16, Eric Ries claimed that the goal of a startup is to repeat the “build, measure, learn” process to find a sustainable business model. This means that a startup’s competitive advantage won’t come from its capacity to secure key resources from the industry. It will instead rely on its capacity to rapidly develop a Minimum Viable Product (MVP) and constantly listen to the feedback of early adopters to find the right approach and the right product that fits the needs of the market. Startups therefore tend to use a rather “incrementalist” approach as identified by Tidd (2005). It is impossible to completely understand the complexity of the environment and foresee future changes (Tidd, 2005). Since startups are evolving in a very dynamic and uncertain environment, this approach makes total sense. Now that we have taken an economic perspective on what differentiates startups from established corporations, we will look at the final differentiating factor – the external environment. C) The external forces of the firms 1) Organizational ecology and Industry forces. This section looks at specific frameworks to analyze the immediate environment of a startup and an established corporation. Even though different approaches can be linked, specific factors are tailored for startups and established corporations. Evaluating the startup environment from an organizational ecology perspective: Organizational ecology is a research term used to investigate the establishment of new organizations (Hannan, 1989). It studies how the organization’s population evolves over time, especially through the demographic processes of foundation, death, and growth. The original concept of ecology comes from biology. According to Dr. Bergstrom17, some environmental factors can strongly influence the firm’s success over time. Several concepts are associated with organizational ecology to predict how the population of a business is going to evolve over time. To describe the environment of a startup ecology, we will focus on: • Intra-population processes • Inter-population processes 16 17 http://theleanstartup.com/ https://www.biology.washington.edu/people/profile/carl-bergstrom 23 Intra-population processes: According to Aldrich (1990), intra population processes have the strongest impact on founding rates. Density dependent phenomenon are related to the early birth and death of firms. Research has shown that when a lot of companies get started at the same time, it triggers the entry of even more firms. This is because a high founding rate within a certain industry makes it attractive for aspiring entrepreneurs. It implies that new ventures are more likely to succeed because the possibility of favorable outcomes motivates many new entrepreneurs. It also implies higher rates of organizing attempts because more entrepreneurs saw future conditions as favorable and enough found success to make it worthwhile. The latter was due to those who had to work harder in order to enter, and were more likely to secure resources from gatekeepers and others who agreed that the future indeed held favorable conditions. When a lot of atomized entrants are in the market, it reduces the cost of accessing information and makes the opportunity more attractive because the entrepreneur feels that s/he’s not the only one seeing this. It therefore has a legitimizing effect (Aldrich, 1990). Gaining legitimacy is especially important when there is a high degree of novelty involved. This rapid entry of new firms in the industry, however, can also be responsible for “Boom and Bust” cycles because there is only a finite amount of resources and a customer base for a given market (Hannan, 1989). Density therefore affects the underlying drivers of the competition. If a lot of firms enter at the same time, they might not be able to reach the Minimum Scale Efficiency (the minimum production they need to achieve to cover their initial investment), and therefore, be driven out of business because they are not able to cover their fixed costs. When failures are high, founders will then fear the same fate because it seems that the given industry has already reached its carrying capacity because the greater the number of competitors, the lesser the potential gain. It might therefore be a signal that the opportunity is not so attractive anymore. These factors are responsible for “Boom and Bust” cycles. The boom corresponds to the high birth of new firms whereas the bust is a natural consequence of the industry reaching its carrying capacity. Ruef (2004) identifies boom and bust cycles as the common result of entrepreneurial inertia – when entrepreneurs delay starting a business because they feel it’s not the right time. When a lot of players enter the market, they do not want to miss it and so get started without a good plan in mind. 24 Boom and bust cycles can be found in many industries throughout history as shown in the following graph: Figure 11: Example of Boom and Bust Cycle in the Automotive industry18 Inter-population processes: Inter-population processes can be defined as processes taking place between players from two different, yet related, industries. To understand the following, we will take the example of the industry A and industry B. Aldrich (1990), identified six specific inter-population processes: • • • • 18 Full competition (-;-), when both players fight for the same resources and end up neutralizing each other, which has a negative impact on both. The founding rates will therefore affect both as the expected profit from the opportunity decreases. Partial competition (-;0), when A is negatively affected by B while the activity of A has no significant effect on B. In this case, while the founding rates stay the same for B, they decrease for A. Predatory competition (+;-), when A expands at the expense of B, making B a much less attractive industry than A. Neutrality (0;0), when neither affects the growth of each other. http://fortune.com/2010/10/07/will-solar-in-2011-look-like-automobiles-in-1911/ 25 • • Commensalism (+;0), when A benefits from the presence of B but B is not affected by A. A typical example would be a fast food restaurant (A) in the vicinity of offices (B). Symbiosis (+;+), when both benefits from each other’s presence as the two complement each other. This is the ideal scenario which strongly favors founding rates. A framework tailored to the mechanisms for established corporations: Porter’s five forces The organizational ecology is only relevant for newly established businesses. If we talk about key industry players or incumbents, we should focus on the key industry forces identified by Porter (1980). Though useful to understand the competitive environment of a startup, it is most likely that the startup will find itself in very unfavorable conditions at the beginning. Due to their limited market scope and power, it is also unlikely that a startup will be able to influence any of the market forces at first. Also, since startups pursue innovation and a Blue Ocean Strategy, it is even likelier that their industry cannot, as yet, be defined. Figure 12: Porter's 5 Forces (1980) The framework identified by Porter comprises five dimensions: 1) The threat of new entrants 2) The bargaining power of suppliers 3) The bargaining power of buyers 4) The threat of substitutes 5) All of these elements influence the core of the model – known as the industry rivalry. Before we dive into these concepts and identify how they are especially tailored for established corporations, we need to define them first: • Threat of New Entrants: any attractive industry is subject to having potentially new entrants. Established players try to protect themselves from new entrants by creating entry barriers (capital requirement, economies of scale, minimum scale efficiency, and brand power or product differentiation). If a company is brave enough to enter an already crowded industry, the key players might retaliate and slash their prices in a way that cannot be matched by the new entrant. 26 The problem related to new entrants in a specific industry (be it an established corporation or a new startup) can be analyzed in terms of the strategic outcomes of a game. Though not always true, incumbents will retaliate in industries where the fixed costs are high and the marginal costs are low. • Threat of substitute: This relates to two different attributes: o Price/Performance ratio: When a more expensive product or service is chosen because it is more performance-effective. For example, aluminum is more expensive than steel but provides better performance, especially in the automotive industry. o Innovation: When the substitute benefits from an improvement that enhances customer satisfaction. For example, bullet trains are better than planes for short distances and are great for reaching the city center much faster. • • Bargaining power of buyers: Evaluating to what extent buyers can influence a given industry. This is based on their concentration (the more concentrated they are, the higher their bargaining power due to the higher volumes they buy), their switching cost (the integrated cost of changing to an alternative), and their ability to integrate this as part of their value chain. Bargaining power of suppliers: This comes from the fact that they are concentrated and supply very rare materials that firms cannot produce. This is especially so if they can do backward integration. For example, a software company developing a customer relationship management system might be able to lock their customers into their system by limiting the transfer possibility and designing a standard that won’t work with other alternatives. • Rivalry between competitors: A firm that offers similar products or services to the same customer group and competes in the same industry. It is distinct from substitutes, considered as alternatives, from other industries. Competition is intensified when market positions are constantly being challenged. The degree of rivalry increases when the competitors are all of equal size, when the market is mature or declining, and when there are high fixed costs that make leaving the industry expensive due to the high initial costs that will not be recovered. Competition also tends to be higher when there is a lack of differentiation or very low switching costs for the customer. 27 The following summarizes the differences between attractive and unattractive industries (from an entrant’s perspective): Unattractive Industry High entry barriers Powerful buyers Powerful suppliers Good product substitutes Intense rivalry Attractive Industry Low entry barriers Limited buyer power Limited supplier power Poor product substitutes Moderate rivalry Figure 13: Summary of key differences between an attractive and unattractive industry Having covered Porter’s five forces, we can now understand why it fits established corporations better. The better the understanding of an existing industry, the better one can decide whether to enter or leave it – corresponding to the traditional Red Ocean perspective cited earlier. 28 2) The institutional environment for entrepreneurship and established business The New Institutional Economics: New Institutional Economics (NIE) was coined by Williamson in 1975 in his paper, “Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications, a Study in the Economics of Internal Organization.” According to (North, 1990), an institution is made up of two different parts: • • Formal Institutions: These are all of the political and judicial systems that govern and enforce all economic rules and written contracts. Informal Institutions: These are all of a country’s social norms based on traditions and customs. They are usually unwritten and tacitly understood, and those who violate them are punished by social sanctions. The following figure presents the scope of NIE. Figure 14: New Institutional Economics scope overview Source: Woywoode, M. (2014) NIE focuses only on Level II and Level III, mainly known as the formal rule of the game (economics of property rights) and the play of the game (transaction cost economics). Even though NIE focuses specifically on Level II and Level III, both Level I and Level IV still influence the institutional environment. Resource allocation and employment are considered to be marginal conditions. Over time, however, these can influence governance through a process 29 of feedback. The changing governance will then have an impact on the institutional environment, and in the end, will influence society by embedding new norms and traditions. But this does not happen overnight, according to Williamson (1975). It usually takes about a century for the social theory to change in a noticeable manner. The reverse is also true – constraints from social theory (such as specific business traditions) will influence the institutional environment, the governance of the firm, and in the end, the marginal conditions (Williamson, 1975). NIE can be applied to both startups and established corporations. By allocating the resources in a different manner, key industry players and startups can influence the transaction cost of economics in their favor through a feedback process. A definition of institutional environment for startups: The institutional environment involves the economic, political, and social rules. It will influence the uncertainty and the transaction costs, (Smallbone, 2001) and therefore, the willingness of individuals to engage in entrepreneurship (Shane, 2003). When it comes to the specific factors which influence entrepreneurial activity, the findings are as follows: Figure 15: Summary on findings of external influence on startup success Strong economic growth and societal wealth have positive effects on the success of entrepreneurial ventures by increasing the demand for goods and services, and making it possible to get bank loans. Furthermore, a wealthy society provides capital for entrepreneurs who want to self-finance their venture and encourages positive attitudes towards entrepreneurship. 30 Stable economic and monetary policies also encourage entrepreneurs. Steady economic environments allow entrepreneurs to make more forward looking decisions. Currency stability also plays a very big factor, especially for Born Global firms. When capital (especially venture capital from business angels) is more available, it is easier for entrepreneurs to obtain financing. Moreover, entrepreneurship will always be fostered by low interest rates which induce a lower cost of capital. Tax structures and rates also have a strong impact on the willingness of entrepreneurs to start their own businesses. When marginal taxes are high, it reduces the perception of nascent entrepreneurs about the profitability of entrepreneurship. According to empirical research, high taxes also encourage shadowy economic activities (de Soto, 1989). High tax rates are therefore detrimental to entrepreneurial activity. Political freedom plays a very important role, as well. When entrepreneurs are subject to arbitrary political decisions, they tend to have a lesser internal locus of control, and therefore, are less inclined to start their own venture. A lack of political freedom also discourages the exchange of information – which is key to innovation. In his video, “Where good ideas come from,” Steven Johnson claims that great ideas are “chunks of ideas” from different people gathered into one idea. So, the lack of information exchange prevents great ideas from being discovered. There is also the matter of the rule of law and property rights. Under the rule of law, formal statutes and judicial agencies offer and deliver equal protection to citizens. If someone violates the law, a credible system of effective punishment is meted out to them. So, the rule of law means that the ¨rules of the game” are known before-hand. This gives entrepreneurs assurances that their gains won’t be taken away from them arbitrarily. And finally, there is the centralization of power. The more central a political environment is, the less say people have on economic, social, and political activities. When centralization is prevalent in an economy, it discourages nascent entrepreneurs from setting up their own businesses as they do not have control over the course of events. Such can be seen in China, whose centrist government results in a lower degree of entrepreneurship. In fact, China stood in the 61st position when it comes to entrepreneurship according to the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor in 201519. When entrepreneurship is considered to be socially desirable, it fosters entrepreneurial activity. An example of this lies in the differences between opportunity-driven entrepreneurial activities (as compared to necessity-based entrepreneurship) in Anglo-Saxon countries as compared to developing ones. In the United States, failure is an opportunity to learn. We are not quite there yet in Europe, or even in developing countries where failure is not an option due to the lack of state support. 19 https://www.forbes.com/sites/panosmourdoukoutas/2014/11/19/why-japan-and-china-cannot-compete-withamerica-in-entrepreneurship/#3f830d979cdf 31 Necessity-based entrepreneurship is when people become entrepreneurs because of the lack of financial opportunities. Opportunity-driven entrepreneurship, on the other hand, is based on the attractiveness of the opportunity. According to the 2014 Global Entrepreneurship Monitor, nascent entrepreneurs in factor-driven economies (focused on the extraction of raw materials) are going to be more necessity-driven compared to nascent entrepreneurs in innovation driven-economies (mainly developed countries). Figure 16: Necessity vs Opportunity driven entrepreneurship Entrepreneurial role models are also very important. Successful startup ecosystems (such as Silicon Valley) provide a lot of entrepreneurial role models (Cooper Cary, 2015). They offer mentorship by successful peers increasing the likelihood that new entrepreneurs will get started. Some cafes in San Francisco provide venues where mentors and aspiring entrepreneurs meet, such as the Coupa Café and the University Café, both in Palo Alto, California. Cultural beliefs also play a role – such as the belief in serendipity. According to Cooper Cary et al. (2015), there must be a culture of “paying it forward.” This means that there is strong trust among the actors of an ecosystem, and therefore, a lively exchange of information without any expectation of return. Zak and Knack (2001) agree, insisting that trust is very important in ensuring economic performance. The “anything is possible” belief is also very important. It’s about “thinking big” and believing that anyone can make it to the top – the classical definition of the American Dream. It includes a tolerance for the different and strange with a strong culture of experimentation. As mentioned earlier, it’s also important to view failure as a positive because it presents an opportunity to learn and improve. 32 One bit that is implicitly identified by this model but explicitly identified by Aldrich (1990) is the importance of the spatial location. Indeed, good transportation infrastructure, a strong education system, and the strong presence of public, private, or non-profit research institutes, can also have a strong effect on founding rates. A framework for established corporations: PESTEL This is a strategic tool used to evaluate the environmental impact of a firm’s strategic orientation. Though it includes most of the same factors that NIE considers, the PEST framework better suits the needs of established corporations. The following best summarizes what the PESTEL stands for: Figure 17: Overview of the PEST Framework20 PESTEL is an acronym for: • • 20 Political: Political factors involve the government and the decisions it makes in terms of trade, taxation, rules, and regulations. This political arena has a very strong impact on the outcome of an investment (ROI, IRR). New reforms can turn an attractive opportunity (a “Star” as identified by the BCG matrix) into a “dog” and is why established businesses try to influence politics through lobbying. For example, new regulations (such as higher taxation) might deter customers and make them look for alternatives. This can turn a previously attractive and growing industry into a sluggish and unattractive one. Economic: Economic factors affect the decision making and daily operations of businesses. For example, a strong foreign currency (such as the dollar) can strongly influence the exporting activities of a firm. Moreover, it could also influence the cost of raw materials, which established firms would like to have maximum control over. Source: Studydroid.com 33 • • Social: Social factors cover population growth rate, age distribution, etc. It also considers various social and cultural factors such as health consciousness, which enables firms to evaluate the impact of a new product launch. Technological: Technological factors determine entry barriers for new entrants and influence outsourcing decisions. It is therefore critical for established corporations to be aware of the technological environment and not miss any key changes – especially those that might affect the business. Examples of this include VHS vs Betamax, traditional cameras vs digital ones. In network economics, the bandwagon effect (the number of users which tips growth or starts a self-reinforcing process) can only be triggered by a substantial number of users, and therefore, cannot be achieved by all (Shapiro, 1999). This is called the standards war, and over time, losers must use the standards of their competitors. • • Legal: Legal factors cover existing regulations. They affect the daily operations of the business by introducing new standards and regulatory requirements based on the firm’s size. For example, Germany has a strong rule regarding employee representation in the board of directors – up to 50% for a public or private company having more than 2,000 employees. Environmental: Environmental factors cover climate change and the growing awareness among consumers for more sustainable products. This, too, has a major impact on the way companies do business. 34 II) A traditional perspective on strategic decision making A) The profile of the CEO and top management vs Entrepreneur 1) Psychological attributes Understanding the thought processes behind decision making among CEOs and entrepreneurs is crucial. This section will therefore review some of the specific psychologic attributes of both. Before we explain the differences between how CEOs and entrepreneurs make decisions, it is important to first note that both must take different things into account. Entrepreneurs make decisions based on the discovery, evaluation, and exploitation of opportunities(Shane, 2003). CEOs, on the other hand, make theirs on the basis of maximizing their returns and satisfying various stakeholders. This distinction is important to make beforehand because CEOs and entrepreneurs share a lot of similar psychological characteristics, otherwise. According to Baumol, J., (1990), there are three different rationales for entrepreneurial decision making, which are: • Productive • Unproductive • Destructive We will only cover the first as being relevant to our analysis. In his introduction, Baumol states that: “The basic hypothesis is that while the total supply of entrepreneurs varies among societies, the productive contribution of the society's entrepreneurial activities varies much more because of their allocation between productive activities such as innovation and largely unproductive activities such as rent seeking or organized crime.” (Baumol, 1990). Therefore, not all types of entrepreneurship are beneficial for society. Productive entrepreneurship adds value to society by not solely focusing on the entrepreneur’s personal gain, but rather, through achieving something great from which all society benefits. The first framework can be looked at to determine the psychological characteristics of the entrepreneur and how they differ (if at all) from those of C-level management as defined by Shane (2003). Shane focused his research on the specific psychological characteristics that influence the decision to exploit an opportunity. They are split into three different categories: • Personality and Motives • Core Self-Evaluation • Cognitive Properties 35 Figure 18: The 3 categories of psychological determinants21 Personality and Motives: Extraversion is about sociability, initiative, and assertiveness. Researchers have found that extraversion strongly influences the chances that a nascent entrepreneur will exploit an opportunity. Extroverts know that they can rely on their persuasive skills, their ability to identify non-verbal cues, and gather information faster than others (Bhide, 2000). However, we can argue that extraversion is not a differentiating factor between entrepreneurs and CEOs. Green, Jame and Lock (2014) suggest that CEOs are also very extraverted, which is why they are in such a position in the first place (Bono J., 2004). Indeed, extraversion is identified in the “Big Five” model from Myers and Briggs22 as one of the key elements for leadership emergence. Leadership emergence is a process wherein a member of a group will naturally take a leadership position because of the quality of his/her interaction with followers. Agreeableness is about friendliness, trust, ability, and cooperativeness, according to Barrick and Mount (1991). Unfortunately, it’s detrimental for exploiting opportunities because the desire for social conformity prevents nascent entrepreneurs from starting their own business. Agreeableness is also not a differentiating factor between CEOs and entrepreneurs. In fact, agreeableness is also detrimental for leadership emergence (Mc Crae and Costa, 1987), meaning that CEOs would not have reached the top had they been very agreeable (Mccrae, 1987). 21 22 Source: Woywoode M. (2014) https://fr.wikipedia.org/wiki/Myers_Briggs_Type_Indicator 36 However, according to the authors, agreeableness positively influences leadership effectiveness. Indeed, leaders that are agreeable are more likely to develop better relationships with their followers, and, therefore, lead more effectively. Also, in order to lead effectively, they have to establish common ground among the various stakeholder’s (employees, suppliers, customers, stockholders, etc.) demands. The need for achievement is defined by Shane et al. (2003) as the strong desire to take on new activities that involve personal responsibility. People driven by a need to achieve are much more likely to exploit opportunities because creating a business involves combining resources in a unique way that come with challenges (Harper, 1996). Those with a high need for achievement tend to pursue a specific goal, regardless of the number of failures and setbacks they encounter. CEOs certainly tend to have a very high need for achievement. They usually graduated from top business schools and worked harder than most to reach their position. So the need for achievement is not enough to distinguish between CEOs and entrepreneurs. Risk-taking measures how likely people are to engage in risky activities, and is a fundamental part of entrepreneurship. The word “entrepreneur” was originally applied to farmers and merchants who invested a certain amount of resources for an uncertain outcome. A higher risk propensity is therefore associated with a stronger likelihood of starting a business. In established corporations, risk-taking used to be viewed positively (Tucker, 2006). After the 2008 financial crisis, however, being risk-averse, or at least limiting the amount of risk taken, is considered best (Power, 2009). There is no evidence to suggest, however, that risk-aversion or minimizing risk is a distinguishing factor between CEOs and entrepreneurs. (The approach toward risk by CEOs and entrepreneurs will be explained in greater detail when we review their respective functions.) There is also the desire for independence – working for one’s self instead of for others. The stronger the desire for independence, the greater the likelihood of starting a business (Cromie, 1987). This is a major factor in distinguishing entrepreneurs from CEOs. Though it can be argued that CEOs can sometimes prioritize their own interests over that of their firms (Enron and Tyco being cases in point) they generally exist to serve the interests of others and get very well compensated for doing so. Core self-evaluation: This involves self-efficacy (the degree of confidence one has in achieving a specific task) and the locus of control – the sense of control one has over their environment, or their capacity to influence it (Rotter, 1969)23 23 http://psych.fullerton.edu/jmearns/rotter.htm 37 Entrepreneurs believe they can easily shape the environment around them (Perry, 1990). They are different from others who believe that it’s impossible to influence their environment and that all resources are finite and given. When it comes to CEOs, the only data available focuses on small firms (Boone, 1996). Boone acknowledges that CEOs can have both an internal and external locus of control – so this cannot be seen as a meaningful differentiating factor that distinguishes them from entrepreneurs. They also established that a CEO’s locus of control is a strong predictor of their firm’s performance. Indeed, firms where the CEO has an internal locus of control were more likely to survive than those where the CEO did not believe s/he could shape its environment. Bandura (1997) defines self-efficacy as “the belief in one’s ability to perform a given task.” Since entrepreneurs must make decisions in an uncertain environment and bear the risk of their own venture, they should be confident enough in their own judgement and not in that of others (Buckley, 1995). Self-efficacy is also strong among CEOs as they must be confident enough with the responsibilities they have. So this doesn’t differentiate them from entrepreneurs, either. Cognitive properties: These influence how people make decisions. Cognitive properties are less stable over time and are dependent on their environment. Specifically, this part focuses on the use of heuristics in the context of strategic decision-making. Heuristics are also called “mental shortcuts,” as they reduce complex judgements into simple rules of thumb (Franzoi, 1996). Hodgkinson et al. (1999) refers to heuristics as a way to simplify reality for decision making in very dynamic and complex business environments. The first cognitive property analyzed by the model is overconfidence – when a person overestimates their problem solving abilities. This can be extremely dangerous because it fails to consider the information available or the feedback from others (Bernardo, 2001). Entrepreneurs do tend to be overconfident. For example, Gartner and Thomas (1989) surveyed founders of computer software firms and found that they, on average, estimated their first year’s sales as being 29% higher than the actual data. Cooper et al. (1988) also reported that about a third of the entrepreneurs they surveyed were totally certain they would succeed. This contradicts the statistics which show that four out of five businesses fail within the first five years. An example of this is Webvan – an online grocery shopping company founded back in 1999. They overestimated the market share and invested in capital intensive resources (warehouses, trucks, etc.) and went bankrupt in 2001 because the market was not there yet. 38 Another study found that entrepreneurs tend to be far more overly confident compared to toplevel managers (Busenitz and Barney, 1997). This could therefore be a differentiating characteristic between CEOs and entrepreneurs. Entrepreneurs tend to be overly optimistic about the impact of their ideas, tend to ignore negative market information, and even resist meaningful statistical result hypotheses (Hills, 1994). Some have found, however, that CEO hubris (Hayward & Hambrick, 1997; (Hiller, 2005) can result in lower performance for a firm. Indeed, CEOs who are victims of hubris are likely to miss their own forecasts for earnings (Hribar & Yang, 2006), pay higher premiums (Hayward & Hambrick, 1997), and engage in more value-destroying mergers (Malmendier & Tate, 2006). The illusion of control is yet another factor influencing CEO overconfidence. For example, in a game of chance such as rolling the dice, people feel they can control the outcome of the next roll (Langer, 1975). CEOs tend to think they have a high control over their environment (justified by the firm’s size and its market power), and as a result, fail to anticipate market uncertainties. A good example of this is the acquisition of Autonomy (a British company focused on intelligent search and data analysis) by Hewlett-Packard, back in August 2011. HP’s CEO at that time, Léo Apotheker, pushed for a very unprofitable acquisition at almost double the price that investors and analysts had valued it at.24 Representativeness is another failing associated with overconfidence. According to Shane (2003), “representativeness is the willingness to generalize from small samples that do not represent a population.” Representativeness, in the absence of information, becomes the rule of thumb. It is a cognitive bias that encourages aspiring entrepreneurs to exploit opportunities due to the innovativeness of the idea – even when there is only scant historical data available (Busenitz and Barney, 1997). Representativeness is usually reinforced by the hindsight bias, where someone believes that a highly unpredictable event is rather easy to predict (Roese, 2012). Many examples of CEO representativeness can be found in the business literature. JC Penney under its former CEO, Ron Johnson, is among these. Johnson tried to introduce Apple’s retail policy into JC Penney because it was very successful for Apple. What he failed to recognize, however, was that the two companies had almost nothing in common, so what worked for Apple wasn’t necessarily good for JC Penney.25 24 http://www.nytimes.com/2012/12/01/business/hps-autonomy-blunder-might-be-one-for-the-recordbooks.html?pagewanted=all&_r=0 25 https://hbr.org/2013/10/how-to-manage-biased-people 39 However, due to the tremendous number of stakeholders, control mechanisms, and resources involved, it is extremely unlikely that CEOs will routinely base their decisions on non-statically significant elements. The last part of this model is also a cognitive bias and is commonly referred to as intuition. In his book, “Thinking Fast and Slow,” Malcolm Gladwell26 defined it as the belief that something holds true without having data to prove its veracity. Intuition is not to be confused with insight, which corresponds to an unexpected solution to a problem (the “eureka” moment), nor with instinct which is hardwired and involves automatic reflex reactions. According to Allinson et al. (2000), intuition increases a person’s tendency to exploit opportunities. In 1934, Schumpeter also suggested that entrepreneurs must have the capacity to base their decision-making on intuition rather than on analyzing information. Entrepreneurs often base their decisions on intuition and experience (Hills and Singh, 1998), and put less emphasis on statistical facts compared to CEOs of established corporations. CEOs are also prone to intuition. John Mihalasky, a professor at the New Jersey Institute of Technology, found that CEOs with high intuition were likely to increase their business performance over those with low intuition.27 So high and low intuition levels are not necessarily a distinguishing factor between CEOs and entrepreneurs. 26 27 https://www.amazon.fr/Thinking-Fast-Slow-Daniel-Kahneman/dp/0374533555 http://www.biznews.com/thought-leaders/2014/04/22/intuition-great-ceos-great-intuition-can-learn-gut-feel/ 40 The following chart summarizes the findings for all the psychological characteristics identified by Shane (2003). Characteristic Extraversion Agreeableness Need for achievement Risk-taking Desire for independence Locus of control Core self-evaluation Overconfidence Representativeness Intuition Effect on the entrepreneurial process Positive Negative on opportunity recognition. Unknown on exploitation. Positive Risk-loving is positive for opportunity recognition and negative for exploitation. Strong Positive if internal, negative if external Positive Positive on opportunity recognition, unknown on exploitation Positive on opportunity recognition, negative on opportunity exploitation Positive on both opportunity recognition and exploitation Effect on the firm performance (CEO perspective) Positive Negative on leadership emergence, positive on firm performance. Positive Risk-aversion has a positive impact of firm performance. Differentiating factor? Weak Positive if internal, negative if external Positive Negative on firm performance Yes No Negative on firm performance Yes Positive on firm performance No No No No Yes No Yes 41 The second framework we will use to compare the decision-making processes between CEOs and entrepreneurs is the one by Dew, R. et al., (2009). Rather than focusing solely on psychological characteristics, this framework tries to compare specific elements of the decisionmaking process. The first element identified by the authors is called “vision for the future”. CEOs are usually very rational and tend to use a more predictive logic – using past, established models to foresee what will happen in the future. However, as identified in some cases, CEOs are also prone to intuition but will never base a decision solely on it. “The classical view of decision-making suggests that the decision-maker passes through a series of stages before a decision is reached.” (Vershinima, 2017). According to Hammond et al., the first stage is related to defining the problem, then clarifying the objectives to find solutions, and evaluating the impact of those solutions and their alternatives (Hammond et al., 1999). So if entrepreneurs follow Hammond’s process, have total control over their environment, and can calculate risks in a very precise manner, they should be alright. This is obviously unrealistic. Not only is total control over an environment impossible, it fails to consider all the irrational impulses and wishes that drive decision making. This latter corresponds to what is referred as the effectual logic – where entrepreneurs will define goals according to the resources they have in their possession. In that sense, intuition is more crucial for entrepreneurs which is defined as a “substantial rationality or intuitive rationality” (Mannheim, 1935). This idea is also supported by Sarasvathy’s research which found that when entrepreneurs evolve in a very uncertain environment, they tend to rely on “unconventional logic” (Sarasvathy, 2001). Therefore, the “vision for the future” can be considered as a differentiating factor between entrepreneurs and CEOs. The second component of the model is called “basis for making decisions.” CEOs of big corporations base their decision making on strategic objectives following a more rational approach. They already know their capabilities and resources, and can plan accordingly, thanks to an analysis of market conditions. Entrepreneurs, on the other hand, “create purpose.” They imagine a course of action based on their supposed capabilities and their vision for the future. The third dimension is related to the approach towards risk. CEOs are supposedly risk-averse, are very rational, and will not risk implementing a new strategy or conducting new investments if the expected Internal Rate of Return does not correspond to their expectations. And even when a project is profitable, they might delay the start or even not conduct it all because they do not want to affect the short-term situation of the firm (especially when it comes to quarterly or yearly results). 42 CEOs and top management are mostly viewed as rational thinkers, according to Taylor’s (1911) scientific management theory and Weber’s bureaucracy. Rationality is concerned with order and calculations, and tries as much as possible to stick close to reality (Taylor T. , 1911). CEOs can be considered as risk-averse because they always take the blame in case of failure. Since their reputation (and job) is on the line, they tend to be overly cautious with predictions and adopt a more conservative approach. CEOs and top management are also subject to tight controls by corporate governance mechanisms, especially the board of directors who verify and audit decisions. As we will see later, specific compensation frameworks are also put into place in order to minimize risk-taking behavior. This risk-aversion can also have some positive effects – it pushes CEOs to under promise and over deliver to positively surprise a company’s investors and stockholders. It also encourages predictive logic – meaning that CEOs will pursue opportunities that maximize outcomes. This is not always the case, however. CEO hubris, defined as their over-exaggerated confidence or pride, has also been identified as a cause of a firm’s failure. This overconfidence pushes CEOs to overestimate their own-problem solving capabilities (Camerer, 1999) and underestimate risky initiatives (Shane S. S., 2002)This causes them to make inefficient decisions and exaggerate the potential of others – such as paying higher premiums for an acquisition (Hayward, 1997) There’s also their “attitude toward outsiders.” According to Porter’s 5 forces model, existing businesses fight newcomers to maintain their profitability in a specific industry. They therefore predict the outcome of the game and act accordingly. Game theories and basic equilibrium are very prevalent when it comes to strategic decisions. For example, a firm might evaluate the possibility of retaliating as an outcome of a game. Entrepreneurs might have a more cooperative approach and look to build synergies with new players. Entrepreneurs tend to be risk-lovers and do not necessarily evaluate any of their decisions in terms of rational outcomes. They tend, for example, to pursue other goals besides purely financial ones. According to Storey & Greene (2010), risk-taking is natural to entrepreneurs who base their decisions on how much they can afford to lose. The last bit focuses on the attitude towards “unexpected contingencies.” CEOs evaluate the likelihood of a negative event and put measures in place to prevent it – a form of risk management based on predictive logic. Entrepreneurs are more flexible. They see obstacles as opportunities to create something new or to rethink their objectives. While CEOs see unexpected events as something to be avoided at all costs, entrepreneurs rely on their creative spirit to find relevant solutions in order to capitalize on unexpected situations. 43 It’s understood that those who set up companies possess more entrepreneurial qualities than non-founders. These qualities include self-efficacy in creating innovation, entrepreneurial competency and commitment, a need for achievement, a propensity for risk-taking, and a tolerance for ambiguity (Eriksen, 2002). Over-optimism is another quality. Entrepreneurs are also much better at spotting trends and common patterns between seemingly unrelated events (Baron, 2006). Hayek defines this as “entrepreneurial alertness” – a cognitive ability to spot new opportunities without having to look for them. They can “connect the dots” faster than regular people, and have a “unique preparedness to recognize opportunities” (Kirnzer 1979). They do run the risk, however, of falling into the trap of representativeness, identified earlier in the model by (Shane S. , 2003) – recognizing a pattern and assuming it is going to stay consistent throughout the entire market. While representativeness increases the chances of actually starting a company, it is not a guarantee that such a company will thrive. When firms evolve in a very competitive environment, entrepreneurs tend to become much more rational and base their decision-making processes on quantitative analyses. Results affect decision-making and the strategies for coping with a given situation. A positive effect encourages individuals to choose a “satisficing” strategy (Baron, 2008) while a negative affect will trigger the usage of a “maximizing” strategy. The former focuses on quickly choosing the first acceptable alternative while the latter is related to a granular examination of all the alternatives. Although the maximizing strategy leads to superior results (Iyengar, 2006), this approach is not suitable for entrepreneurs and the dynamic environment in which they operate in. As the firm’s survival is on the line, entrepreneurs must act in a timely manner – so they may not always be able to review information they consider irrelevant or unimportant (Isen, 2001). Amabile (1997) has demonstrated that intrinsic motivation is a crucial element for creative behavior. Such intrinsic motivation can be characterized by being interested, excited, and personally challenged by a work task – yet another key difference between entrepreneurs and CEOs. While entrepreneurs look for a quick turnaround, CEOs must evaluate the impact of their decision-making on all parties involved. The following chart summarizes the points raised in this section: Characteristic Entrepreneur Vision for the future Effectual logic – Define goals based on available resources Basis for making decisions “Create a purpose” based on their vision Risk propensity Risk-lover – how much they can afford to lose Unexpected contingencies Flexible – considered as an opportunity to change CEO Predictive logic – use models to predict Rational approach – act according to capabilities Risk-averse (supposed) – calculated risks Preventive – put measures in place to avoid them Figure 19: Differences in decision-making between entrepreneurs and CEO 44 2) Decision-making differences between an Entrepreneur and a CEO Non-psychological attributes The study of the psychological attributes, as well as the factors influencing decision-making, are not enough to establish a “clear cut” distinction between entrepreneurs and CEOs of established corporations. As seen in the previous section, both share the same psychological factors – though their dominant traits can be different. There is therefore a need to explore the non-psychological characteristics of CEOs and entrepreneurs in order to deepen our understanding of their decision-making processes. To do so, this section will focus on four major ones: • Education • Career experience • Employment • Income These attributes will later be used to calculate the utility function of entrepreneurs and CEOs. Education fosters analytic ability and improves entrepreneurial judgment and skills. These allow people to better assemble resources, bargain, lead, plan, make decisions, solve problems, develop strategy, organize, and communicate (Shane S. , 2003). Education therefore increases the perceived feasibility of becoming self-employed (Tonoyan, 2006). Nonetheless, highly educated individuals are also more likely to be found in C-Level positions. However, less educated people are also likely to become self-employed. Those from lower socio-economic groups that have less access to educational opportunities are highly likely to seek self-employment as an alternative to having a regular job (Arum, 2004). According to the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor, this might also be due to necessity: there is no regular available job on the market, therefore, individuals must create one for themselves. Such lack of a formal business education, however, may also hinder the chance of a venture’s success. According to Broom, Longenecker and Moore28, failure in small businesses is mostly due to the “lack of managerial skill and depth; and personal lack and misuse of time”. Formal business education is only one side of the equation. In fact, many successful entrepreneurs such as Mark Zuckerberg, Bill Gates, and Steve Jobs are dropouts29. Entrepreneurship involves developing a specific set of skills that cannot be easily taught. 28 29 https://www.amazon.com/Small-Business-Management-Halsey-Broom/dp/0538072636 http://fundersandfounders.com/entrepreneurs-who-dropped-out/ 45 According to Laukkanen (2000), we need to make distinctions between: • Education about entrepreneurship: especially as taught in business schools and universities which focus on specific theories related to the entrepreneur, the creation of the firm, and the entrepreneurial process. • Education for entrepreneurship: which usually happens in specific programs of business schools. These focus on stimulating and developing the tools and skill sets that help to set up a business. According to Mason (2000), this type of education is “proposed to develop the core skills and attributes necessary to roll out a new venture and to identify pre-start-up needs.” (Mason, 2000). CEOs of established corporations usually receive a slightly different education. They usually start out as experts in a specific field inside the company and slowly broaden their competencies in order to reach the top of management. Therefore, we can argue that education, both formal and informal, are a differentiating factor between CEOs and entrepreneurs. While both the CEO and the entrepreneur will have roughly the same knowledge in the end, the way they start out and the pace at which they acquire such knowledge, strongly differs. Career experience is also another non-psychological characteristic to consider. Through career experience, individuals learn about different aspects of the business (finance, sales, logistics, etc.), then start to develop their own expertise. General business experience helps both the aspiring CEO (who has to oversee all the departments of a company) and the nascent entrepreneur (who feels confident enough to get started). As a consequence, general business experience is not enough to differentiate entrepreneurs from CEOs. In some cases, especially those who engage in necessity entrepreneurship, the founder might not have any formal career experience. Career experience also develops functional experience which is critical for both the entrepreneur and the CEO. Functional experience is related to the development of a specific expertise in a given field of the business (usually considered as a department of the firm). CEOs usually started their career in a specific department of a firm and climbed the ladder by not only developing more functional expertise, but also by increasing their knowledge of the overall business. For the entrepreneur, their functional expertise might be more related to a specific competency they have and for which they are better than anyone else. Industry experience is yet another factor. A strong knowledge of the industry helps both the aspiring CEO and the nascent entrepreneur succeed in their endeavors because such leads to a superior understanding of the demand structure and conditions in a specific market. And because they have a better relationship with known customers and suppliers, they have an edge over outsiders. Finally, long industry experience ensures expertise (both tacit and explicit) in that respective field. Industry experience helps aspiring CEOs because it provides them with greater legitimacy and a better understanding of the business, overall. 46 Industry experience also increases the likelihood of becoming self-employed, as well as improves the chances of the firm’s success. The end result is sometimes the creation of “spinoffs” – the creation of a new organization that has split off from an existing one. Finally, career experience can also be related to previous startup experience, which is relevant for aspiring entrepreneurs. Previous startup experience helps with: • Gathering the “right information” and making effective decisions about developing and financing new organizations (Gartner, 1990). • Reducing the cost of acquiring this “right information” (Cooper, 1995). • Benefiting from a previous network of suppliers and customers, especially in the case of serial entrepreneurs (i.e. successful entrepreneurs who already sold a venture and are repeating the process with another idea) (Campbell, 1992) • Leveraging previous knowledge on product development in order to create a new idea (Reuber, 1993) and a better understanding of how to set up a new organization (Brüderl, 1992). We can therefore argue that startup experience aside, there are also no clear cut characteristics that differentiate CEOs and entrepreneurs from a career experience perspective. Income is another factor to consider. People who earn less are more likely to become entrepreneurs. For example, Amit et al. (1995) found that before leaving their jobs, Canadians between 16 and 69 (military excluded) earned, on average, $2,340 less than their employed counterparts. Evans and Leighton (1989) also found that as salaries went up, people became less willing to become self-employed. So compensation levels strongly affect the expected utility function of entrepreneurs, and therefore, can reduce the likelihood of nascent entrepreneurs starting their own businesses. CEO salaries increase at a much faster rate than that of regular workers, as shown in the graph below. Not only is the discrepancy extremely important, but so is the pace at which it grows. Figure 29 : Pay Evolution between CEOs and regular workers30 30 https://eml.berkeley.edu/~saez/lecture_saez_chicago14.pdf 47 CEOs rely on a complex pay structure often designed to limit their risk-taking and overall align their behavior with the company’s objectives to guarantee its success. They often have a very comfortable base salary making them sure to get paid no matter what the performance of the company is. CEOs are also incentivized to work harder in order to reach the corporate objectives through various mechanisms such as bonuses and stock options. Such usually ties the the CEO’s compensation to the performance of the firm, making them less likely to take risks that affect their personal wealth. Entrepreneurs, on the other hand, cannot predict what their income will be. They usually agree not to pay themselves for a specific period of time (depending on the capital intensity and the breakeven point of the company) and to reinvest any cashflow in capabilities that will allow the company to grow. Therefore, income is certainly one of the biggest differentiating factors between entrepreneurs and CEOs. While both have very stressful jobs, only one is pretty confident that they will at least be rewarded for the effort they put in. Finally, unemployment (only relevant for entrepreneurs) is yet another factor that pushes people toward self-employment. Once unemployed, opportunity cost gets lower (more on this in the utility function section). In a study of Finnish employment statistics, Risila and Tervo (2002) found that unemployment increases the probability of founding a business. As unemployment progresses, individuals become more willing to start their own businesses. CEOs hold a comfortable position within a company, and though extremely stressful, they are secure in their jobs. Unless they commit a very big mistake, they can usually find another job quite easily, given the extended reach of their network and the broad set of their skills. The following chart summarizes the points raised in this section: Characteristic Education Entrepreneur Education for entrepreneurship, sometimes learned informally and very quickly Career Experience Can be very limited, with limited general business experience, functional expertise, or startup experience. However, the more career experience, the higher the chance of success Unemployment Can be unemployed as unemployment increases the risk of starting their business (though not the success rate) Flexible – considered as an opportunity to change Income CEO Likely to have a strong formal business education and education about entrepreneurship Rarely limited, usually with strong general business experience and industry knowledge. Started with a functional expertise that was slowly leveraged to develop more skills. Holding a comfortable position inside a company and is likely to find another one. Usually well rewarded, even with poor performance Figure 20: Key non-psychological factor differences between CEO and Entrepreneurs 48 B) A utility function perspective on strategic decision making In this section, we will discuss the final element that will enable us to establish a clear profile of the entrepreneur and the CEO based on their utility function. In “Who is the Entrepreneur is the Wrong Question,” Gartner (1989) focuses on finding new ways of defining entrepreneurs and entrepreneurship, as previous definitions failed to make a clear distinction between entrepreneurs, small business owners and CEOs of established corporations. As mentioned earlier, psychological and non-psychological characteristics are not enough. The clear distinction between entrepreneurs and CEOs of established corporations is related to the type of decisions they must make as well as the influencing factors of such decision making. Regarding the former, Gartner (1989) believed that the decisions of the entrepreneur are related to discovering, evaluating, and seizing opportunities. Those of a CEO, on the other hand, are to meet normative and financial expectations from their environment which strongly influences how they get rewarded. In this section, we will establish different utility functions for the entrepreneur and the CEO based on the type of decisions they have to make, the variables influencing their utility, as well as the importance of external factors on their utility function. 1) The utility function of the entrepreneur This model is related to the transition from employment to self-employment (or nascent entrepreneur stage), as well as the factors that influence how they seize these opportunities. According to Stevenson and Jarillo (1990), there are three main components of the entrepreneurial model that will be influenced by the entrepreneur’s utility: • How entrepreneurs act (mainly what decisions they will make) • What is the outcome of their activity • Why people choose to act as entrepreneurs (i.e. what drives them?) Many researchers have argued that individuals choose career paths that maximize their maximal utility or emotional satisfaction. Whether an entrepreneur starts a business or not is based on the estimated cost of following other alternatives. This traditional model was developed by Savage (1954) and is called the Subjective Expected Utility model (SEU). It corresponds to a very traditional economic perspective where individuals are rational and will pursue opportunities only if starting a business maximizes their SEU. SEU considers various factors such as the expected earnings (with the corresponding probability of achieving them), the psychological costs of running a business (with the corresponding probability and the expected financial cost of it), and even the opportunity cost of not starting a business (such as the secure payment of an employed position). 49 The SEU model evaluates the idea of becoming an entrepreneur based on the following mathematical formula: Figure 21: SEU function31 To start a business, SEUse (self-employment) must be greater than SEUpe (paid employment). The calculation of both is based on the perceived outcomes and the probabilities of achieving them. This theory is supported by Einsenhauer (1995) who argues that the utility is also derived from the working conditions of the employment versus self-employment alternatives. The following chart gives us an overview of how this calculation could look like: Figure 22: An example of the Subjective Utility Function32 According to Holmes and Schmitz (1990), the transition to a self-employed stage also depends on the perceived entrepreneurial ability (hereby defined as the capacity to recognize new opportunities and tackle them the right way) and the perceived managerial ability (i.e. the competency to maintain the profitability of the operations) (Holmes, 1990). Another option to consider is the aspiring entrepreneur’s utility function before their transition to a self-employed stage in terms of indifference curves. If employed, they have to consider how much effort (E) they must exert for an expected profit (P). 31 32 Source: Woywoode M., 2014 Source: Woywoode M., 2014 50 However, by transitioning to a self-employed stage with a certain amount of effort, E*, the individual will increase their expected profit to P*. This expected profit P* is highly dependent on the individual’s entrepreneurial and managerial ability. Therefore, a highly capable individual will be able to generate a higher profit P*H while the less capable one will generate a profit of P*L. The effort offered by the entrepreneur, regardless of their abilities, is likely to be much higher than the effort they put into being employed. Indeed, Hofer (1976) and Schein (1987) found that entrepreneurs usually work longer hours and put their new venture ahead of anything else, including their personal and family life. These two models, however, still fail to consider the variety of psychological factors that influence the decision to become an entrepreneur. Meaning if we follow this rational approach, no one will ever start a business if they are at a perceived disutility. There is therefore a need for a more comprehensive model – one that not only explains why a person pursues entrepreneurship, but also why they might persist despite being at a stage of subjective perceived disutility. According to Bird and Jellinek (1988), entrepreneurs seem to enjoy working long hours even when there is no promise of an extraordinary financial gain. Douglas and Sheperd (1999) suggest the need to distinguish between the disutility of the work effort and the utility that can be derived from specific working conditions – such as social interaction, the joy of witnessing a technical or market success, or the perks of the job. Baumol, (1990) suggests that people become entrepreneurs if their utility (in terms of power, personal wealth, and prestige) is maximized by doing so. While personal wealth can be easily measured using the first model, the perception of power and prestige is much harder to quantify. The decision to become an entrepreneur is sometimes due to irrational impulses. Besides the desire to change the status quo, some feel that they do not “fit” into the current system, or are unhappy with a system where seniority, not achievement, is rewarded33. Such people want to help their local economy or support a broader cause that could fuel a revolution within a specific industry (Uber, AirBnB, and Apple being cases in point). An entrepreneur’s utility function can also be related to their willingness to satisfy normative and financial expectations from specific actors such as business angels and the triple F (Friends, Family, and Fools). Though not verified empirically, it can be argued that entrepreneurs experience disutility from failing or deceiving those who invested in their venture. They might also be influenced by an early form of Corporate Social Responsibility, or by some form of ethics, especially if they are willing to engage in productive entrepreneurship. It is therefore possible to upgrade Savage’s initial model by integrating all the factors that influence self-employment as described in this section. 33 https://www.boundless.com/business/textbooks/boundless-business-textbook/introduction-to-business1/introduction-to-entrepreneurship-25/the-goals-of-entrepreneurs-144-1306/ 51 Self-Employment Factors Expected earnings (or Profit) Psychological costs Opportunity cost Irrational impulses Financial and normative expectations Influenced by Entrepreneurial and managerial ability Effort level Opportunity size Tolerance for risk Desire for independence Expected level of stress Reward for pursuing alternatives Prestige and fame Expected level of power Willingness to challenge the establishment Have an impact on the local community and economy Business angels Friends, family, and fools Society Figure 23: Summary of the different cost of self-employment 52 2) The utility function of the CEO The utility function of a CEO follows a slightly different construct than an entrepreneur’s. As mentioned previously, CEOs are usually risk-averse (barring those with hubris). Most importantly, however, they are also loss-averse. Loss-aversion is the fear of reducing one’s personal wealth – especially if they failed to perform according to expectations. CEOs are generally rational actors who look to satisfy personal economic objectives, but can also pursue non-rational ones, such as power and fame. There are also those, like Steve Jobs, who want their personal wealth tied up with the financial success of their firm. It’s why Jobs used to have a US$1 salary yet also owned a significant portion of Apple’s shares. Their utility function is usually based on a specific amount of effort that leads to a specific outcome. The effort level is conditioned by the outcome, which is usually rewarded by a wage pair (WL;WH). The various ways they are compensated is not relevant to this paper, but it is important to note that there are compensation elements that occur no matter the performance – such as the base salary. Some are based on the attainment of specific corporate objectives (such as bonuses), while others depend on the market expectations or feedback regarding the CEO’s actions (such as stock options). This wage pair is usually established by the board of directors of the company. Their decisions are based on the corporate objectives, the financial expectations of stockholders, and the normative expectations from all shareholders (including public opinion). But while it can be argued that a CEO plays a critical role in their firm’s performance (Bertrand and Schoar 2003, Bennedsen et al. 2007, Kaplan et al. 2012), it is very difficult to measure the surplus of performance they generate or the actual amount of effort they put in (Albuquerque, 2013). From that perspective, the utility function of a CEO is a rather simple because they are mostly subject to rational calculations. While entrepreneurs may work hard even without financial rewards, CEOs try to find the maximum amount of effort that maximizes their personal wealth. Depending on the reward structure and control mechanisms, a CEO might choose to exert a low level of effort and still get highly rewarded for it. This explains the need to introduce other factors which influence their utility function: • The control of the board of directors and the likelihood of getting caught acting against the firm’s best interests • The power of the stockholder as external influencers • Corporate Social Responsibility and public opinion 53 C) The traditional strategic orientation derived from a top management perspective This section will explain the strategic decisions an established firm is likely to make based on its characteristics as well as its CEO’s psychological profile and utility function. By definition, strategic decision making is the process in which top managers identify organizational problems and find solutions for them (Bartol, 1994). Strategic planning is one of the managerial functions identified by Henri Fayol’s definition34. Based on a firm’s characteristics, as well as the profile of its CEO, it is likely that decisionmaking follows a rational model (March and Simon, 1958). Indeed, established firms tend to have specific processes in place based on previous experiences and because they have to answer to a variety of stakeholders. Rational decisions, or the attempt to make them, are perhaps the most crucial element that will enable us to establish a clear distinction between decisions made by startups and those by established corporations. Rational decisions have the following characteristics: • • • • • They are aimed at achieving a specific goal, such as financial (profit, Return on Investment, Return on Assets) and market ones (market shares, market penetration, etc.). They are explicit, meaning that a clear established process is laid down in order to tackle the given issue. They are fully informed in that they rely on statistically significant historical and actual data in order to establish forecasts. They are intentionally consistent and logical – also known as programmed decisions. Programmed decisions are characterized by the fact that they are structured and recur with some frequency. They establish a clear causal relationship between the actions taken and the outcome usually observed at the end of the financial period. According to this model, actors base their decisions on known objectives (satisfying financial expectations from shareholders, gaining market shares, etc.) that are usually defined (but tweaked, if necessary) for a mid to long term period. CEOs are usually tied to specific goals that come from both external and internal stakeholders, and must find the right way to tackle them effectively. 34 https://www.toolshero.com/management/five-functions-of-management/ 54 According to Hasmi et al. (2007), “strategic decision makings are those that determine the overall direction of an enterprise and its ultimate viability in light of the predictable, the unpredictable, and the unknowable changes that may occur in its most important surrounding environments.” Therefore, strategic decision-making shapes the true goals of the enterprise (Mintzberg & Quian, 1991). Certo (2003) suggests that the a CEO’s decision making process strongly influences a firm’s outcomes. Provan (1989) insists that they must therefore be competent, reasonably intelligent, and articulate, and therefore use a sophisticated process for decision-making to justify any decisions to the board of directors or the company stockholders. This is achieved through the following steps: • • Clearly formulating objectives by listening to all the different stakeholders (especially the board of directors and the stockholders) in order to establish realistic objectives. This enables them to elaborate the scope of the objective and know what type of resources they have to gather. Establishes relevant Key Performance Indicators (KPIs) beforehand to measure the effectiveness of the strategy. Porter (1992)35 suggests, however, that financial indicators are not enough to measure performance management indicators. Strategic tools, such as the balanced scorecard therefore integrates all the strategic dimensions together (Kaplan, 2003). The balanced scorecard is therefore widely used as it embraces all the components of a company’s long-term vision with its strategic focus area (usually customers) and operational objectives such as continuous improvement through internal business processes, learning, and growth. Figure 24: Overview of the balanced scorecard36 35 36 https://hbr.org/1992/09/capital-disadvantage-americas-failing-capital-investment-system Source: balancedscorecard.org 55 • Describes, understands, and analyzes the environment through various strategic tools such as Porter’s five forces and the BCG Matrix, or by conducting a SWOT analysis. A SWOT analysis is a very common strategic tool that examines internal and external factors that may influence the ability of the firm to achieve its target goal. Figure 25: SWOT Overview37 According to “environmental determinism,” Structured Decision Making (SDM) processes are adaptations to external opportunities and threats, and a manager’s role is to facilitate this adaptation (Lieberson and O’Connor, 1972; Hannan and Freeman, 1977). • • Determines the course of action in light of the analysis through Segmenting, Targeting and Positioning processes (STP), operational recommendations, and short-term to midterm goals. Carries out the decided course of action (4Ps or 7Ps for Product, Price, Place, Promotion, Physical evidence, People, and Process), and from an operational perspective. Using the approach of the balanced scorecard, we will now dive into the four components of the strategic decision-making identified by Kaplan and Norton (1993): • Customers (or marketing in general) • Financial • Internal business processes • Learning and growth Customers being integrated as one of the pillars of strategic planning means that established firms have usually what is referred to as a market orientation. According to Darroch et al. (2004), “market orientation is a type of organizational culture [...] that is intensely customercentric in focus, directing organizational decision making to meet explicit and latent customer needs at a profit.” 37 https://www.smartsheet.com/14-free-swot-analysis-templates 56 This profit is derived by superior performance on the company’s part arising from the capitalization of competitive advantages. According to Morrish C. (2011), firms must be strategic to sustain their competitive advantage. Firms can achieve a market orientation by having strong marketing processes in place, which is why marketing is gaining a stronger foothold in the strategic operations of the company. In order to understand this, let’s have a look at how marketing has been changing over the last five to six decades. The American Marketing Association has been responsible for the definition of marketing since 1948. The original definition of marketing, adopted by the National Association of Marketing Teachers, is “the performance of business activities that direct the flow of goods and services from producers to consumers."38. So, according to the original definition, marketing is supposed to be a support activity of the sales process rather than a function of its own – a definition that held for over 50 years. It was then revised, especially under the influence of Dr. Robert Lusch (a former AMA chairman). In the mid 1980’s the new definition stated that marketing is “the process of planning and executing the conception, pricing, promotion, and distribution of ideas, goods, and services to create exchanges that satisfy individual and organizational objectives."39 The current definition of marketing defines the scope of the marketing activities as “the activity, set of institutions, and processes for creating, communicating, delivering, and exchanging offerings that have value for customers, clients, partners, and society at large.” Dr. Marshall (another former head of the AMA) suggests that “What we have is more strategic. Now it says marketing is really something that makes the organization run." The four components of marketing concepts are: • Customer orientation. According to Kotler (1987), “The main task of the organization is to determine the perceptions, needs, and wants of target markets and to satisfy them through the design, communication, pricing, and delivery of appropriate and competitively viable offerings.” Customer orientation is achieved when the culture of the company is strongly focused on satisfying the needs of customers. Thus, organizational structure and leadership are key components for achieving customer orientation. In this sense, leadership styles will also vary between startups and established corporations. While CEOs are likely to use a transactional form of leadership, company founders are likely to use a transformational one (Bass, 1985). 38 http://www.brown.edu/Departments/Engineering/Courses/En9/spring/Population%20Services%20Marketing%2 0and%20Budget%20Overview%20handout.rev2pdf.pdf 39 https://archive.ama.org/Archive/AboutAMA/Pages/AMA%20Publications/AMA%20Journals/Journal%20of%20 Public%20Policy%20Marketing/TOCS/summary%20fall%2007/MarketingsEvolvingjppmfall07.aspx 57 Due to the company structure, the specific rewarding processes put in place and the impossibility of a CEO to have individual consideration for each employee, it is likely that they will rely on a transactional type of leadership. According to Bass (1985), transactional leadership is defined through: o Contingent reward: which rewards the efforts of followers by a specific scheme which all agreed to beforehand (such as salary and bonuses) o Management by exception: which involves positive feedback and negative criticism, and can either be active (treat the problem before it occurs) or passive (take corrective actions once the problem arises) • Customer satisfaction. A customer will be satisfied if the product or service is of superior value than the competitors’. It’s about setting the right expectations and fulfilling them. According to the consulting firm McKinsey, customer satisfaction is also about keeping the same degree of performance no matter how many times the product or service is delivered. They have therefore labeled their three Cs of customer satisfaction as: Consistency, Consistency, and Consistency40. This can be achieved by developing strong internal processes (yet another element of the balanced scorecard) and via a Total Quality Management (TQM) system. • Coordinated or integrated marketing. This is about unifying all the marketing communication tools (advertising, public relations, social media, etc.) and techniques toward a specific objective (Belch, G. E., & Belch, M. A. (2004)). Its sole focus is to deliver a unified and consistent message across all the marketing channels including online communication. Integrated marketing understands that both offline and online communication tools create dynamic synergies and drive results better. The focus has changed because customers benefit from a more individualized and personalized marketing process through online interactive platforms. Not that traditional media (TV and printed newspapers) should be ignored. They can still be a vital part of marketing communication depending on the budget and the objectives of the firm. • Focus on profitability. All actions taken by the firm must drive a positive financial result because profitability will always be the core of any business activity. This is therefore tied up to the financial component identified by the balanced scorecard model (Kaplan and Norton, 2002). 40 http://www.mckinsey.com/industries/retail/our-insights/the-three-cs-of-customer-satisfaction-consistencyconsistency-consistency 58 Market orientation can therefore be defined as the willingness of a firm to develop a superior understanding of the customer’s needs and capitalize on an integrated organizational structure for sole goal of satisfying the customer in a profitable way (Piercy, 1995). 59 III) A systematic review on the impact of Entrepreneurial Marketing in developing corporations A) Definitions This section will focus on establishing what key decisions entrepreneurs make in the startup stage. According to Miles & Snow (1978), the basic “entrepreneurial problem” is addressing the most critical question from a strategic standpoint – "What business to enter?” According to Reynolds (2002), the conventional decision making approach is not even relevant for SMEs and startups. Since this method is too strategic and too inflexible for a developing company, there was a need to develop a common approach that would encompass the needed flexibility of a startup while relying on some theoretical background. Thanks to the Schollhammer and Kurilof model (1979), we now know that startups and established corporations differentiate themselves in terms of strategic orientation on five specific characteristics: • Scope of operations: startups begin within a niche market by handcrafting their products toward first customers. According to Brian Chesky (cofounder of AirBnB), the most critical piece of advice that Paul Graham (founder of the Y combinatory) gave him was to get out and talk to his first customers. Doing so allowed AirBnB to work in a very complicated industry and successfully switch to a global scope because they built, measured, and learned from their early adopters (approach by Eric Ries, 2013) Though listening to customers is a cornerstone of market orientation for established firms, startups do not have a developed final product or service yet, and therefore, can easily tweak it based on the market’s feedback. • Scale of operations: when getting started, it is unlikely that new market entrants will become market leaders over time. It’s more likely that their market share will be relatively small within a given industry. This means that they haven’t developed the processes to support a scaling phase. Because the scale of their operations is rather small, startups have not yet gathered sufficient historical data for their decision making processes. Neither have they yet implemented fixed organizational processes. • Ownership: startups tend to be owned (at least at first) by a very limited number of people who make decisions for the company. They do not have to answer to many stakeholders as compared to established corporations. 60 From a strategic point of view, it means that the founder has more power when it comes to strategic decision making (which will be explored in our first hypothesis) because they do not have to reach specific financial or market penetration goals. • • Independence: by not being part of a complex enterprise, smaller firms are much more flexible and have a bigger room for maneuvering – even though they may be tied to financial institutions like Business Angels. Management style: owners of startups usually know all their employees by name because of their small size and tend to adopt their own managerial approach. From a leadership perspective, it means that founders tend to have a transformational leadership style. Transformational leadership is associated with four characteristics (Bass, 1985): 1) Idealized influence charisma is when leaders are seen to have high moral and ethical standards, as well as a vision and a sense of mission. 2) Inspirational motivation is about using symbols and establishing team spirit to foster the development of ambitious goals. 3) Intellectual stimulation is related to the stimulation of creativity and challenging beliefs – even those of the leader. 4) Individual consideration is about creating a supportive climate where the founder can coach and delegate in order to help his followers grow. As a consequence, these differences support the idea that the traditional market orientation of firms is not suitable for startups. There is a need for empirical research to identify a new decision-making system, one more tailored to the innovativeness and structure of startups and the psychological profile of their founders. Traditionally, the strategic decision making approach was boiled down to the 4Ps at a more tactical level (Kotler, 2001). However, it can be argued that the 4Ps miss “the fundamental point of marketing” – mainly with adaptiveness, flexibility, and responsiveness. Since entrepreneurship is the “parent of innovation” (Meyers, 1986), it is critical for entrepreneurial ventures to be flexible and innovative, and not rely on processes set in stone This is supported by the American Marketing Association which states that the 4Ps fails to consider all the key elements of entrepreneurship such as innovativeness, risk-taking, or proactiveness (Morris et al., 2002). These three elements were later identified as pillars of the Entrepreneurial Orientation (EO). Entrepreneurial orientation refers to the processes, practices, and decision-making styles of organizations that act entrepreneurially (Lumpkin, 1996). 61 Five factors can be considered actors in establishing the EO degree of a firm: • Autonomy • Competitive aggressiveness • Innovativeness • Proactiveness • Risk taking Autonomy refers to the ability of anyone within the company to develop new ideas without having to go through the corporate and bureaucratic processes that are typical of established firms. It corresponds to the idea of “Ever tried. Ever failed. No matter. Try Again. Fail again. Fail better” (Samuel Becket)41. Competitive aggressiveness is about intensely and directly challenging the competition. Given that newly established businesses operate in a very uncertain and competitive environment, competitive aggressiveness is required (Le Roux & Bengesi (2014). Peterson and Berger take this a step further by arguing that newly established startups are created in a hostile environment. Overemphasis on competitive aggressiveness should be avoided, however, as too much can reduce a firm’s performance and does not correspond to Blue Ocean thinking. Innovativeness is the willingness to develop new ideas, experiment, and going through more creative processes. It therefore departs from traditional established practices and technologies (Lumpkin and Dess, 1996). Although it can still vary in terms of “radicalness” (Hage, 1980), it represents the willingness to venture beyond the traditional perspective. Proactiveness, from an entrepreneurial point of view, is the willingness to anticipate the future needs of the market, and therefore, to capitalize on a first mover advantage. The importance of the first-mover advantage, according to Lieberman and Montgomery (1988), is the best strategy for capitalizing on a market opportunity. Proactiveness is therefore the opposite of passiveness – the inability to react to any market opportunity. Nor is it to be confused with reactiveness – when the firm reacts to the market by following an existing opportunity that another has already exploited first. According to Ventakamaran (1989), proactiveness is about seeking new opportunities which may or may not be related to an existing line of operations, introducing new products and brands ahead of competition, and strategically eliminating operations that are in the mature or declining stages of its life cycle. Proactive firms are therefore likely to be new market entrants rather than followers. This isn’t always the most efficient business strategy, however, because second entrants can be as pioneering and as innovating as the first (Miller and Camp, 1985). Startups and entrepreneurial firms must therefore be willing to commit a large of amount of resources to emergent opportunities, which explains the risk-taking component of the model (Miller and Friesen, 1978). 41 https://www.brainyquote.com/quotes/quotes/s/samuelbeck121335.html 62 According to Buzza J. (2009), "Entrepreneurship is the process of creating something different with value by devoting the necessary time and effort, assuming the accompanying financial, psychic, and social risks, and receiving the resulting monetary rewards and personal satisfaction." As a consequence, those that display a high level of innovativeness, risk-taking, and proactiveness should therefore be considered entrepreneurial (Lumpkin and Dess, 1996). Morris and Paul (1987) take it a step further, claiming that “the propensity of a company's top management to take calculated risks, to be innovative, and to demonstrate proactiveness" are key for a firm to be entrepreneurial. Therefore, the American Marketing Association defined entrepreneurial marketing as “an organizational function and a set of processes for creating, communicating, and delivering value to customers, and for managing customer relationships in ways that benefit the organization and its stakeholders.”42 Entrepreneurial Marketing (EM) is both customer and entrepreneur-centric – unlike traditional marketing. It will therefore be influenced by the entrepreneur’s personal characteristics, aspirations, and values. As such, it can only be understood by integrating entrepreneurship into the marketing process (Hultman, 1999). The following figure represents what EM consists of: Figure 26: Overview of Entrepreneurial Marketing43 According to a study from Northern Ireland (Carson, D., 1985) on small business marketing, EM can be linked with the four evolutionary stages of marketing: 42 https://archive.ama.org/archive/AboutAMA/Documents/American%20Marketing%20Association%20Releases% 20New%20Definition%20for%20Marketing.pdf 43 Adapted from Gilmore A., 2011 63 • • Initial marketing activity during the firm’s entrance into a specific industry. They do not have any formal process in place nor a customer base. The selling activity at this stage is rather limited due to the lack of resources and the core focus is on the product’s quality. Marketing is therefore performed in a “very primitive fashion” (Carson, 1985). The most commonly used promotional tool will therefore be word-of-mouth. Reactive selling is when the company starts scaling up and starts implementing some marketing components in its operation. It cannot rely solely on its network and must find new ways of communicating their products and services. The unifying process begins, but at a very limited stage. Prospects approach the firm, while selling and marketing activities are limited to answering queries. Now that the firm is attracting attention, established players might retaliate or enter this specific industry. As a result, the initial targeted niche could be close to saturation. • • The “DIY” marketing approach is when the founder realizes the importance of marketing and starts implementing “a series of spasmodic and disjointed initiatives” (Carson, D., 1985). If they come from a more production oriented background, they will fail to realize that the lack of a marketing initiative structure might do more harm than good. Integrated Proactive marketing is the last stage and refers to the transition toward more established processes which turn the firm from a startup into an established corporation. Many fail in this critical step due to the lack of marketing expertise. This also happens during the highly turbulent stage of the growth phase. As everything occurs at once, it might be tempting for the startup to rely on their DIY and ad hoc noncoordinated plans. The following summarizes these four stages (Carson, D. 1985): Figure 27: The four stages of marketing (Carson, D., 1985) 64 Some might implement a more formal marketing process at the start. This approach is a doubleedged sword because it fails to consider the customer’s feedback and might contradict the founder’s aspirations. On the other hand, it means that the culture and the decision making process within younger firms is driven by a positive attitude towards risk and innovation, and is committed to discovering, evaluating, and exploiting new opportunities. B) H1: The younger the firm, the more power the founder has on decision making This section will attempt to verify our first hypothesis – that founders have more decisionmaking power than the CEOs of established corporations. Startup founders usually start out by completely owning their business. They therefore have more room to maneuver compared to CEOs who work for the firm’s actual owners and are known as the agent of the principal. Founders therefore set up a business to be their own boss. “One of the most remarkable characteristics of entrepreneurship is that it provides individuals with the freedom to pursue their own goals, dreams, and desires in new firm creation” (Fauchard E., 2009). They must also shape the way their organization is built (Kimberly 1979). Kelly L., et al. (2000) argued that “from a strategic management perspective, the founder is likely to be particularly influential on manager mindsets, motives, values, goals, and attitudes that are central to the organization” – thus creating an organizational culture. Schein H. (1983) defines this culture as “the pattern of basic assumptions which a given group has invented, discovered, or developed in learning to cope with its problems of external adaptation and Internal Integration, which have worked well enough to be considered valid, and, therefore, to be taught to new members as the correct way to perceive, think, and feel in relation to those problems.” Founders must do this from scratch, shaping their creation in the way they wish. The entire startup culture must therefore be considered as a whole44 – a broad term that encompasses the different variations that exists among different startups. 44 https://www.wired.com/insights/2013/09/how-do-you-define-startup-culture/ 65 The founder takes the role of “an animator and a culture creator” (Schein E., 1995). According to Schein (1995), such culture creation appears in three distinctive ways: “1) The entrepreneur only hires and keeps subordinates who think and feel like he or she does; 2) The entrepreneur indoctrinates and socializes subordinates to his or her way of thinking and feeling; 3) The entrepreneur's own behavior is a role model that encourages subordinates to identify with him or her and thereby internalize the beliefs, values, and assumptions.” Founders not only shape the organizational culture, however. They also become culture maintainers with their impact, even when they are no longer in the company. For example, the words associated with Apple are still “simple, elegant and innovative.” This is because that slogan and the values it instills were those that Steve Jobs instilled in the company’s culture45. Entrepreneurs are the visionaries and the founders of the firm, those who transmit the vision and aspirational purposes of the company. They therefore influence and capture the “hearts and minds”46 of those within the organization as well as those who are impacted by that organization. Smaller firms and startups generally have fewer decision to make than large firms. This gives their founders stronger power, allowing them to work more towards business growth instead of focusing only on generating positive cash flow and returns to please external stakeholders (Runyan, 2008). The founder’s decision making power also has a lot to do with their skill sets. They can therefore be called “generalists” (Carson and Gilmore, 2000) because they must deal with a variety of issues. By acquiring a broader perspective on all sides of the business, they gain more decisionmaking power. According to the entrepreneurial press, entrepreneurs are the Jack of all trades but masters of none. In thinking of the strategies and decision making processes of emerging businesses, we often think of or emphasize the strong leader who takes all the risky and decisive actions (Mintzberg, 1973). This idea is taken further by Hart’s “command mode” and by Bourgeois and Brodwin's (1984) “commander model” – both of which consider entrepreneurship as the outcome of a vision and a strong leadership. According to Miller (1983), the more entrepreneurial the firm is, the more autonomous the leader. 45 46 https://www.fastcompany.com/1792485/steve-jobs-apple-and-importance-company-culture https://www.entrepreneur.com/article/238883 66 The need to develop expertise in a newly established business is compensated by the founder’s ability to become their own expert. According to Mitchell et al. (2000) and Baron and Ensley (2006), entrepreneurs, especially experienced ones, acquire useful cognitive frameworks and scripts that enable them to become their own experts over time. By focusing on pragmatic techniques for problem solving, they differentiate themselves from established corporations that are mostly focused on achieving a “high co-ordination of control of specialists” (Carson, 1985). Entrepreneurs are also likely to hire experts, or at least people who have a greater degree of expertise than they do. Entrepreneurs must “have the skill and confidence to employ people who are better than them” (Pech, 2008). When it comes to the power of the founder on decision making, it does not necessarily mean that the founder will make all of the decisions themselves. They are likely to share leadership in order to survive the growth phase. Shared leadership (Pearce, 2002)is a dynamic and interactive influencing process in which the objective is to lead one another to achieve a specific goal. In this scenario, influence can be through peer or lateral influence, as well as through backward or downward influence. Shared leadership therefore becomes a property of the whole system rather than an initiative from the leader. Leadership therefore becomes a by-product of the relationship and connections among team members. Another leadership trend, especially in tech startups, is called Agile Leadership. It is derived from the Agile software development manifesto which states that: We are uncovering better ways of developing software by doing it and helping others do it. Through this work we have come to value: Individuals and interactions over processes and tools Working software over comprehensive documentation Customer collaboration over contract negotiation Responding to change over following a plan That is, while there is value in the items on the right, we value the items on the left more. Agile leadership is therefore all about self-organizing teams, continuous improvement, and flexible responses. It fosters autonomy and empowerment, as well as motivation of team members by giving them the chance to be involved in different projects and helping each other out in many ways. In this case, the self-motivated team is driven by the founder’s vision and want to help the business according to the “roots” of the company. Due to the shorter time frame involved in decision-making, entrepreneurs are also more likely to make tactical decisions as they go, and therefore, might rely solely on their expertise or gut feeling to make specific decisions. 67 Let us now look at how their activities (like marketing, sales, and finance) will look like. Chaston (1997) defined four alternative marketing styles based on two levels of entrepreneurial activity – conservative vs entrepreneurial: • • • • Conservative-transactional: standard goods/services at competitive prices with little interest in building close relationships with suppliers. Conservative-relationship: standard goods/services at a competitive price, but willing to work with suppliers to optimize quality. Entrepreneurial-transactional: innovative products/services without forming close relationships with suppliers. Entrepreneurial-relationship: participating in markets where customers work in partnership with suppliers to develop innovative new products and services. We can therefore argue that the most successful startups have an entrepreneurial-relationship type of activity. If the founder is likely to remain the final decision maker for any important strategic orientation of the firm, it does not mean that the decisions they make are solely based on their impressions or through analysis. Their network also plays a critical role in their startup’s success. When it comes to the financial management of the firm, the founder (or the founding team) also plays a crucial role. In its early stage, startups mostly focus on survival by relying on bootstrap and managing the burn rate until it reaches the growth phase and breaks even. Even when founders rely on external finances, information opacity (Klein at. al. 1978; Williamson, 1975) prevents business angels, venture capitalists (VC), and banks from having an accurate idea of what their financial situation is. Founders therefore have much more power than CEOs when it comes to financial management because there is no control mechanism limiting them, or there is a lack of enforced disclosure. This difference means little, however, in cases where VCs demand heavy monitoring of the startup’s balance sheet. According to a study by Gorman and Sahlman (1989), some VCs visit a firm they invest in an average of 19 times a year. When it comes to sales, startup founders are usually the main sales workforce in the initial stage. They therefore play a primary role in the sales process as they can decide the level of discount and commitment for the product or service they are selling. From this perspective, entrepreneurs have more power on sales due to their dealings with those who know and trust them. 68 The following summarizes the points raised in this section Criteria Strategic planning Company culture Scope of decisionmaking Marketing Finance Sales Description Hypothesis validation? Smaller set of stakeholders which YES gives greater power to the founder. Founders are animators and the YES creator of the organizational culture Develop their own expertise and make more tactical decisions than YES strategic ones Entrepreneurial-relationship, based on the scope of the founder’s YES network More power due to information opacity, but some control YES/NO mechanisms Likely to be the ones generating sales and developing contract YES structure Figure 28: Decision-making characteristics in startups As a company ages, however, they tend to put more formal processes in place and move away from their traditional roots. And as they start raising capital, the management team (initially made up of the founders) is slowly replaced by more experienced managers to ensure the firm’s long term success. C) H2: The younger the firm, the less structured their business processes are This hypothesis has already been partly verified in the previous section. Since most decisions are made by the founder and/or the founding team, there is no need to develop a specific business process. In contrast to established corporations that need to get the approval of a specific set of decision makers (usually following a tier level approval), founders can directly make decisions they deem relevant for their company’s future. This differs from the complete strategic planning of established corporations (identified earlier as the activity of planning ahead and actively structuring the situation) that use critical points or opportunistic approaches (Hacker, 1986). Opportunistic strategy is about having some type of formal plan in mind, though deviation is allowed when a new opportunity arises (Hayes-Roth, 1979). Critical point is yet another decision making process common in startups (Zempel, 1994). Critical point is about tackling the most important issues first (usually the most unclear and for which no prior planning was possible), and from there, plan the next steps. 69 Strategies Complete planning Critical Point Opportunistic Orientation to Goal Long-term Situational Proactiveness planning Responsivenes Planning & action overlap High High Low High Low High Low Middle Low Middle High High Low Middle No planning Figure 29: Differentiation in strategies, adapted from Frese, M. (2000) Based on the above chart adapted from Frese M. (2000), it can be argued that established corporations are likely to follow a complete planning strategy, while startups are usually focused on critical point or opportunistic strategies (or a combination of both). The orientation to goal is about defining a specific set of objectives before-hand through longterm strategic planning for established corporations or through the founder’s vision for the startup. The lack thereof is synonymous with a lack of clear direction, as in the case of opportunistic strategy. Long-term planning is usually aligned with the goal. While established corporations can afford to plan on a more long-term basis (as they are financially stable and are dominant industry players), startups will usually plan on a more mid-term to short-term basis depending on the urgency of the situation. Established corporations are likely to be elephants (Birch, 1981), meaning that they are very slow to move in cases where there is a sudden change of situation; whereas startups are gazelles, meaning that they are usually able to adapt more quickly. This is due to the factors that make up the first hypothesis: because founders have a lot of power over their ventures, they ca made decisions quickly. This also verifies the second hypothesis: because of the flexibility of their business processes (or the general lack of them), startup founders can move more quickly and effectively if needed. Proactiveness is one of the dimensions of Entrepreneurial Orientation. Therefore, we can argue that the critical point strategy is more suited for a startup because the more proactive the firm is, the more entrepreneurial it is. In such a case, however, proactivenes does not constitute a differentiating factor between startups and established corporations. Finally, when it comes to the planning and action overlap, it is likely that due to the lack of business processes and the lack clearly defined tasks in startups, some actions might overlap. This is especially so in cases where startups go for an opportunistic strategy. Since established corporations tend to be bureaucratic, it is rather unlikely that specific actions will overlap as functions are clearly defined. 70 In order to explain why the younger the firm the less structured their business processes are, it is important to look at the business processes that take place in startups compared to those in established corporations. One of the key business processes identified earlier is strategic marketing. According to Strokes, since EM puts a strong emphasis on the personality of the entrepreneur and on innovation, it differs from the classical marketing concept. This is because classic marketing or administrative marketing requires an assessment of the market before developing a product or going for an opportunity. Not everyone agrees with this theory. A decade ago, entrepreneurs took a more casual approach by first identifying a market need, gauging the market size, then raising capital accordingly. It’s now understood that entrepreneurs start out with an idea then use the resources at their disposal to reach the market for it (Sarasvathy, 2001). Strokes (2000) calls this “an intuitive market feel.” An entrepreneur senses an opportunity and evaluates it as they begin the process of building the product. Rather than having a top down approach (segmentation, targeting, and positioning) used by existing firms, startups have a bottom-up approach. This is done by “serving the needs of a few customers and then expanding the base gradually [and using] trial and error in the marketplace, being in contact with customers to learn their preferences, looking for customers with the same profiles so they can expand their base” (Stokes, 2000). But entrepreneurs can also be victims of the “bag mentality” – one of the biggest causes of entrepreneurial failures. Scared that their innovation will be stolen, some prefer not to collect feedback until the product is ready. This is wrong because it fails to consider the needs of the market and verify the entrepreneur’s gamble once a big investment has been made on the product or service. Entrepreneurs are generally experts in a field other than marketing (Carson et al., 1995; Stokes, 2000; Zontanos and Anderson, 2004). It’s therefore likely that their decision making will be haphazard, simplistic, and sometimes, simply an answer to a competitor (Carson and Cromie, 1989). So rather than have a formalized plan, startups tend to improvise as they go along (Zahra et al., 2006) and engage in ad hoc behaviors (i.e. specific behaviors tailored to the situation) (Covin and Slevin, 1990). Such improvisation is an attempt to adjust to customer preferences by innovating the product or the service to the market demand. EMs must therefore link creativity to innovation in order to foster both formal and informal strategic changes. The “construct of EM is not simply the nexus between the sets of marketing and entrepreneurial processes that has emerged as the conventional conceptualization of EM [...] but fully includes all aspects of AM (administrative marketing) and entrepreneurship.” (Morrish, Miles et al., 2010) 71 This is another reason why EMs are not a good fit for the traditional 4Ps model. It is much too formal for entrepreneurs who prefer direct interaction with their prospects – either through personal selling and/or relationship marketing activities. EM decisions are therefore shorter term and more immediate (Carson, 1993). New technologies allow entrepreneurs to sustain this effort in a cost-effective way. Online marketing allows entrepreneurs to advertise their product, collect feedback faster, and answer questions with very limited financial investment (Gilmore et al., 2007). When the firm is young, and due to their limited resources, they tend to use innovative marketing approaches to make themselves known through “guerilla marketing, radical marketing, expeditionary marketing, disruptive marketing, and others.” (Morris, Schindehutte et al., 2002, p. 1) It is faster and easier to target a niche or small customer base – mainly innovators and early adopters, according to the law of diffusion of innovation. Successful entrepreneurs use their depth of knowledge and understanding to specialize and attract small segments of the market (Gilmore et al., 1999; Carson and Gilmore, 2000b). From that point on, a firm can tailor their technology to the market’s needs. Not that they don’t apply any form of marketing concepts, at all. EMs often use flexible emergent strategies that are improved over time through a trial-and-error process. They may not know the vocabulary and concepts but they are keenly aware of the value of the results of good marketing (Morrish et al., 2010). As the business matures, it becomes critical to use more formal business processes to survive the competition and new market entrants. Kotler (2003, pp. 4-5) suggests that, “Most companies are started by individuals who live by their wits. They visualize an opportunity and knock on every door to gain attention.” Entrepreneurs are extremely pro-active whereas established firms are more reactive. Startups drive the change while established businesses try to cope. Kotler argues that as firms mature, they reach a second stage called “formalized marketing.” This is why the 4Ps are becoming more tailored to entrepreneurial activity. They don’t just focus on integrating marketing concepts, they also offer a holistic approach to how the entrepreneur must manage their business. Be it Perseverance, Passion, People, and Process or any variation, thereof, all 4Ps integrate both concepts of marketing and entrepreneurship. They also offer a much broader vision – allowing the entrepreneur to be more flexible. In his book, “Thinking Fast and Slow,”47 Daniel Kahneman explores the differences between what he calls “system 1” decisions and “system 2” decisions. System 1 is intuition – the instant answer given by the brain to a specific question. It is quick and very effective when it comes to urgent situations, and bases its process on previous experiences or rules of thumb. 47 https://www.amazon.fr/Thinking-Fast-Slow-Daniel-Kahneman/dp/0374533555 72 Due to the speed involved, however, the answer may be wrong. So system 2 critically analyzes a situation by using an active process of focusing. It is therefore much slower. Because of the urgency that entrepreneurs always face - depending on the nature of their activity, their burn rate might be high and they can therefore be driven out extremely fast. For that reason, decisions cannot always be based on statistical facts when speed is involved, forcing them to rely on system 1. Based on that, they can then resort to analysis and evaluation as they move forward. Such can also be risky, however. This eagerness to beat the competition using “rule of thumbs” results in a negative correlation between innovation and hostility Kreiser et al. (2002). According to Zahra and Bogner (2010), “intense hostility in these markets might make aggressive gambling of new ventures’ limited financial resources by offering radically innovative products a poor strategic choice.” Such confirms that the younger the firm, the less structured their business processes are. The final hypothesis to be discussed relates to the power of the network and the personal brand. D) H3: network and a strong personal brand are key for EM to succeed This section defines an entrepreneurial network and what role it plays in a startup’s success. It will then focus on personal branding and how a strong personal brand can amplify the network’s power. What is a network? A network is made up of nodes and connections (Davern, 2005) from a social science perspective. Nodes are actors within the network, whereas connections symbolize the links between them. Actors can have different backgrounds with a lot of different functions: • • Gatekeepers: in sociology and marketing, they are specific persons within the network that regulate and control access to it. Connectors: the bridge between other actors within the network. Connectors are the ones who enable actors to fill “structural holes,” giving them access to greater information and control benefit (Burt R. S., 1992) 73 This figure represents the concepts of a structural hole. 2 and 3 are part of the same network, but are not direct connections. 1 will therefore act as a broker and bridge a structural hole between 2 and 3, thus benefiting from their new relationship. • Regular actors make up most the network. They do not have any specific function other than interacting with other members of the network. This does not mean that all actors are the same, however, or that they have exactly the same information. Networks are extremely powerful and fundamental in the study of entrepreneurship. In “Handbook of Research on Global Competitive Advantage through Innovation and Entrepreneurship,” Luis M. Carmo Farinha claims that, “networks and networking are fundamental to how the entrepreneur does business and the intrinsic value of an entrepreneur’s business lies in its networks.” Other researchers agree. According to Singh (2000), the bigger their social network is, the greater the likelihood of their firm’s success. Entrepreneurs should not be seen as isolated and atomized actors, but rather as individuals evolving in a social context and acting according to it (Brüderl, 1995). Entrepreneurship is therefore embedded within a social context and facilitated or constrained by the position the entrepreneur has within the social network (Aldrich, 1986). It also corresponds to the social theory which claims that individuals do not exist in isolation, so building mutual trust and understanding is key to enabling the exchange of resources (Coleman, 1988). The network also plays a very big role in finding potential customers and acts as a hedge against information asymmetry. A strong network enables the firm to protect itself from the liability of newness and contributes to establishing legitimacy which helps the business grow (Zimmerman and Zeitz, 2002). Legitimacy may be defined as the process of establishing relationships with players in the market (Rao et al., 2008). This is yet another reason why networks are so much more important for startups compared to established corporations. Established corporations are known in the industry through their 74 specific brand image, and as a consequence, rely on the power of their brand rather than the power of their network. Entrepreneurial networks can even include competitors in a cooperative relationship. This is traditionally the type of relationship seen in startup ecosystems, such as Silicon Valley, where entrepreneurs meet to exchange information with a “paying it forward” perspective. The power of networks is so important that it explains why nascent entrepreneurs tend to set up their business in an industry where they have previous work experience (Stuart and Sorenson 2005). Not only they can rely on their previous knowledge, but they can also reach out to their network and gather disparate knowledge in advance. Networks allow entrepreneurs to achieve three major tasks (Adler and Kwon 2002): • • • Access to financial capital: Entrepreneurs tend to provide unreliable or over-optimistic information, while venture capitalists or business angels can make false promises. Both can therefore learn about the integrity and reliability of the other through their own network. Recruiting skilled labor: Startups face the problem of hiring highly skilled individuals who are most likely already employed in secure and well-paid jobs. A strong and cohesive network allows entrepreneurs to identify the right candidates and recruit them more easily. And since those employees come from the same network, maintaining their reputation ensures that they have a personal stake in the firm’s success. Accessing tacit knowledge: Tacit knowledge is hard to communicate, formalize, and store (Nonaka, 1995). It is usually embedded within social actors and can be transferred only through the process of social interaction (codification). This process of social exchange mostly happens when cohesive social relations exist and strong ties reduce the magnitude of transmission errors. Firms that can mobilize and use this tacit knowledge will gain a significant competitive advantage over others. A network that is rich in structural holes is extremely useful in developing innovative solutions (Rowley, 2000). So networks can also give entrepreneurs access to resources that are generally inaccessible (Ahuja, 2000). Baron (2007) agrees by claiming that an entrepreneurs’ social skills and network are a great help in acquiring the resources they need to make decisions. Other characteristics of an entrepreneurial network include (Slotte-Kock and Coviello, 2010): • Degree of formality: is the ratio between formal business contacts and informal contacts. Formal business contacts are those the entrepreneur will have with customers, business partners, etc., while informal ones include friends and family. There is also the 75 concept of strong and weak ties. From an entrepreneurial perspective, weak ties (people who know someone by their reputation or previous achievements) are extremely important. • • • Diversity: is related to the differences in background and occupations of the network. The higher the diversity, the easier it becomes for the entrepreneur to get access to a broader set of information. This is why entrepreneurs should avoid interacting only with those who share their same beliefs and come from the same background. This especially important when entrepreneurs try to target an unfamiliar market. Flexibility: is related to the speed at which new contacts are made or broken – or how fast they can enter and exit a network. Too much flexibility can be bad if the entrepreneur depends on frequent feedback to develop their offering. But it can also be good – especially if actors come and go. This allows entrepreneurs to get access to new information without having to expand to other social networks. Density: is a measure of how well the entrepreneur is connected to a network. A very dense network means that entrepreneurs can reach out to other actors more easily because they usually have first degree connections also known as strong ties (family, friends, regular business partners, etc.). And finally, networks allow entrepreneurs to influence EM by transitioning from a limited marketing scope to a more sophisticated one (Gilmore, Carson et al., 2006). As established corporations have already transitioned to this phase and leverage the resources they want, it is likely that their industry power will play a much bigger role than their network power. Another consideration is personal brand – the moderating factor between network power and business opportunities. An entrepreneur’s success depends on “being known” and “knowing who,” which acts as a hedge against the liability of newness and uncertainty. Personal branding is a relatively new concept. Previous literature used to focus on selfimprovement as a key to success, while personal branding is based on “explicit self-packaging.” (Lair J. et al., 2005) When someone has accomplished something that becomes well-known, it attracts others who spread the word. This provides entrepreneurs with a free and trusted marketing communications tool that reduces information asymmetry and helps legitimize their business. The ever increasing number of messages in corporate communication requests increases innovative communication strategies if newly founded businesses want to stand out (Blythe, 2000, Ries & Trout, 1981). And personal branding can play a strong role in it. To develop a good personal brand, however, entrepreneurs must be authentic and consistent about their values. It also takes time and is the result of hard work and dedication. The best definition of a personal brand is how others perceive the person, product, or organization that makes it stand apart from the rest. 76 According to Walumbwa (2008), being true to your values is about authentic leadership. He called this relational transparency – when workers share and maintain their leader’s core motives. There is a downside to this, however. Any deviation from such values will be noticed and have a negative impact on a business’ network and profit margins. So, though it’s important to tailor a personal brand to a specific target group, it’s equally important to remain sincere. This can only be accomplished if the company truly believes in its core values. This is where trust comes in. Trust is fostered by the strength of a personal brand as well as the endorsement of key players within the network. Personal branding comes down to an entrepreneur’s ability to do something better than anyone else. Overall, a personal brand helps entrepreneurs cope with the liability of newness, foreigness (especially in the case of Born Global), and smallness. We can therefore argue that the network plays an important role in the entrepreneurial process and that a strong personal brand is a positive moderator of the relationship between the network and its power. 77 Conclusion and limitations. Entrepreneurs and CEOs have to make decisions on a daily basis that affect the company’s survival. However, the types of decisions they make and the processes involved strongly differ. Because while established corporations try to reap benefits through their proven business model in given industries, startups and their founders look to disrupt them. To what extent these are different and how their profiles differ is not adequately covered in business literature, hence the need for further study into the matter. Though the fundamental differences between a startup and an established corporation are easy to define, the same doesn’t apply to CEOs and entrepreneurs. While startups are a “temporary structure designed to find a repeatable and scalable model,”48 established corporations have already found the fundamental structure by which they generate revenue. They therefore simply strive to maximize their competitive position and advantages – objectives that affect every component of their organizational structure and orientation. A startup, meanwhile, looks for radical innovation in order to differentiate itself from the competition. They are therefore likely to have a more flexible structure in order to enhance their processes in order to tackle the external uncertainties they evolve in. Despite these differences, CEOs and Entrepreneurs share some common psychological characteristics. So the decisions they make and how they make them are what distinguishes them. To test this, three hypotheses were made. First, the younger the firm, the more power the founder has on decision making. This has to do with their need to find their business model and manage the burn rate compared to CEOs who must answer to a wide array of stakeholders. Second, the younger the firm, the less structured their business processes are. This has a lot to do with the speed at which entrepreneurs have to make their decisions. Because they evolve in a very uncertain environment, they need to make decisions quickly to ensure their business’ survival. Finally, network and the founder’s personality are critical components for the business to succeed by highlighting the potential impact they can have on securing key resources and customers. Further research is therefore needed to explore this topic. 48 https://steveblank.com/2010/01/25/whats-a-startup-first-principles/ 78 Further research: Given this observation, one clear opportunity for future research is a more complex conceptualization of decision-making, the implementation of the decision as well as the environmental effects. By studying CEOs and entrepreneurs on a daily basis and monitoring all their decisions and how effective these are on the business success. As identified earlier, when and how does the shift in mindset between a founder of a startup and a CEO of an established corporation happen? Is it a gradual, slow and changing process and does it happen in a very harsh way when specific milestones are hit? A third area for further research would be to look more at decision implementation. While we have clearly established that the decision-making processes are clearly different, we had to draw a line and could not focus our research on how these decisions are implemented and how it affects business success. Overall, we can argue that this research paper is drawing a basis of the understanding, while further research would be needed to unveil a clear model and how all of the characteristics we covered play a role. 79 References Adler, P. K.-W. (2002). Social Capital: Prospects for a New Concept. The Academy of Management Review. Ahuja, G. (2000). Collaboration Networks, Structural Holes, and Innovation: A Longitudinal Study. Administrative Science Quarterly. Aldrich, H. Z. (1986). Entrepreneurship Through Social Networks. Population Perspectives on Organizations. Amabile, T. (1997). Motivating Creativity in Organizations: On doing what you love and loving what you do. CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW. Amit R., M. E. (1995). “PUSH” AND “PULL” ENTREPRENEURSHIP. Journal of Small Business & Entrepreneurship . Arum, R. M. (2004). The Reemergence of Self-Employment: A Comparative Study of SelfEmployment Dynamics and Social Inequality. Princeton University Press. Astebro, T. (2003). The Return to Independent Invention: Evidence of Unrealistic Optimism, Risk Seeking or SkewnessLoving? Economic journal, p. 113. Barney J., B. L. (1997). Differences between entrepreneurs and managers in large organizations: Biases and heuristics in strategic decision-making. Journal of Business Venturing. Barney, J. (1991). Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage. Journal of Management. Baron, R. (2008). Opportunity Recognition as Pattern Recognition: How Entrepreneurs "connect the dots" to identify new business opportunities. Academy of Management Perspectives. Barrick, M. M. (1991). THE BIG FIVE PERSONALITY DIMENSIONS AND JOB PERFORMANCE: A META-ANALYSIS. Personnel Psychology. Bartol, K. M. (1994). Management. Bass, M. (1985). model of transformational leadership. Leadership and academic librarian. Baumol, J. (1990). Entrepreneurship: Productive, Unproductive, and Destructive. Chicago Journals. Bengesi L., L. (2014). Strategic entrepreneurial response of small and medium enterprises in developing economies. International Journal of Business and Management. Berger, A. (2004). Debt maturity, risk, and asymmetric information. Finance and Economics Discussion Series . Bernardo, A. W. (2001). On the Evolution of Overconfidence and Entrepreneurs. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy. Berryman, J. (1983). Small business failure and bankruptcy: A survey of the literature. Bhide. (2000). The Origin And Evolution Of New Businesses. Birch, D. (1981). Who Creates Jobs?,. The Public Interest. Bird, B. J. (1988). The Operation of Entrepreneurial Intentions. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice. Blind, K. (2004). The economics of standards: theory, evidence, policy. Edward Elgar Publishing., pp. ISBN 978-1-84376-793-0. Bono J., J. T. (2004). Personality and Transformational and Transactional Leadership:. Journal of Applied Psychology. Boone, P. (1996). Politics and the effectiveness of foreign aid. European Economic Review. 80 Brüderl, J. P. (1992). Survival chances of newly founded business organizations. American SociologicalReview,. Brüderl, J. P. (1995). Der Erfolg neugegründeter Betriebe. Berlin: Duncker& Humblot. Buckley, C. a. (1995). A Theory of International Operations. Burt, R. (1992). The Social Structure of Competition . Burt, R. S. (1992). Structural holes: The social structure of competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Buzza, J. M. (2009). Create The Plan, Work The Plan: A Look At Why The Independent Business Owner Has Trouble Calling A Franchisee A True Entrepreneur. American Journal of Business Education. Camerer, C. L. (1999). Overconfidence and Excess Entry: An Experimental Approach. The American Economic Review. Campbell, C. (1992). A decision theory model for entrepreneurial acts. . Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice. Carson, D. (1985). The Evolution of Marketing in Small Firms. Certo, S. T. (2003). Influencing initial public offering investors with prestige. Academy of Management Review. Chaston, I. (1997). Small firm performance: assessing the interaction between entrepreneurial style and organizational structure. European Journal of Marketing. Coleman, J. (1988). Social capital in the creation of human capital. American Journal of Sociology. Cooper Cary, L. e. (2015). Entrepreneurship and Talent from a global perspective. new horizons in management. Cooper, A. F. (1995). Entrepreneurial information search. Journal of Business Venturing. Cromie, S. (1987). Motivations of aspiring male and female entrepreneurs. Journal of Organizational Behavior. Damanpour, F. (1996). Organizational complexity and innovation: developing and testing multiple contingency models. Management Science, pp. 42(5), pp 693-716. de Soto, H. (1989). The other path: The invisible revolution in the third world. New York: Harper & Row. Dobrev, S. e. (2003). Shifting Gears, Shifting Niches: Organizational Inertia and Change in the Evolution of the. Organization Science. Douglas, E. S. (2002). Self-employment as a Carrer choice: Attitudes, Entrepreneurial intention and utility maximization . Entrepreneurial Theory and Practice. Eriksen, T. (2002). Ethnicity and Nationalism: Anthropological Perspectives. Evans, D. L. (1989). Some Empirical Aspects of Entrepreneurship. The American Economic Review. Fagerberg, J. (2003). Schumpeter and the revival of evolutionary economics: an appraisal of the literature. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, pp. 13, 125-159. Fragerberg, J. (2003). Innovation: A Guide to the Literature. Working Paper on Innovation Studies. Center for Technology, Innovation and Culture., University of Oslo. Franzoi, S. (1996). Social Psychology. McGraw-Hill Education. Gartner, D. D. (1990). A profile of new venture success and failure in an emerging industry. Journal of Business Venturing. Gartner, W. (1989). "Who Is an Entrepreneur?" Is the Wrong Question. Geroski, P. (2011). Market Dynamics and Entry. Basil Blackwell, Oxford. Gorman, M. .. (1989). What do venture capitalists do? Journal of Business Venturing . 81 Guth, W. G. (1990). Guest Editors' Introduction: Corporate Entrepreneurship. Strategic Management Journal. Hage, J. (1980). Theories of Organizations: Form, Process, and Transformation. Hambrick, D. M. (1984). Upper Echelons: The Organization as a Reflection of Its Top Managers. The Academy of Management Review. Hannan, M. F. (1989). Organizations and Social Structure. Organizational Ecology. Hayek, & F.A. (1949). The Intellectuals and Socialism. The University of Chicago Law Review. Hayes-Roth, B. (1979). A Cognitive Model of Planning. Cognitive Science. Hayward, M. H. (1997). Explaining the Premiums Paid for Large Acquisitions: Evidence of CEO Hubris. Sage Publications. Hiller, N. H. (2005). Conceptualizing executive hubris: the role of (hyper-)core self-evaluations in strategic decision-making. Strategic Management Journal. Hills, G. (1994). Marketing and Entrepreneurship: Research Ideas and Opportunities. Hoang, H. a. (2003). Network-Based Research in Entrepreneurship –A Critical. Review. Journal of Business Venturing,. Holmes, T. S. (1990). A Theory of Entrepreneurship and Its Application to the Study of Business Transfers. Journal of Political Economy,. Hribar, P. Y. (2015). CEO Overconfidence and Management Forecasting. Contemporary accounting research. Hultman, C. (1999). Nordic Perspectives on Marketing and Research in the Marketing /. Journal of Research in Marketing and Entrepreneurship. Isen, A. (2001). An Influence of Positive Affect on Decision Making in Complex Situations: Theoretical Issues With Practical Implications . JOURNAL OF CONSUMER PSYCHOLOGY. Iyengar, S. W. (2006). Doing better but feeling worse. Looking for the "best" job undermines satisfaction. Psychol Sci. Kaplan, S. (2003). Conceptual Foundations of the balanced scorecard. Harvard Business Review. Kim, W. M. (2004). Blue Ocean Strategy. Harvard Business Review. Kirchhoff, B. (1994). Entrepreneurship and Dynamic Capitalism: The Economics of Business firm formation and growth. Knight, F. (1921). Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit. Boston MA: Hart, Schaffnerand Marx; Houghton Mifflin. Kotler, P. (1987). Marketing - an Introduction. Kotler, P. (2001). Marketing Management. Langer, E. (1975). The illusion of control. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. Lieberman, M. M. (1988). First-Mover Advantage. Strategic Management Journal. Lumpkin, G. D. (1996). Clarifying the Entrepreneurial Orientation Construct and Linking It to Performance. The Academy of Management Review, pp. Vol. 21, No. 1. Mannheim. (1935). Man and society in the age of reconstruction. Mason, C. (2000). Teaching entrepreneurship to undergraduate: lessons from leading centers of entrepreneurship education. Matthews, L. (2011). Social Media and the Evolution of Corporate Communications. Mccrae, R. C. (1987). Validation of the five-factor model of personality across instruments and observers. J Pers Soc Psychol. Miles, R. E. (1978). Organizational Strategy, structure and process. The Academy of Management Review. 82 Miller, A. B. (1985). Exploring determinants of success in corporate ventures. Journal of Business Venturing. Miller, D. F. (1978). Archetypes of Strategy Formulation. Management Science. Morris, M. P. (1987). The Relationship Between Entrepreneurship and Marketing in Established Firms. Naman, J. S. (1993). Entrepreneurship and the Concept of Fit: A Model and Empirical Tests. Strategic Management Journal. Nonaka, I. T. (1995). The Knowledge-creating Company:. Oxford University Press. North, D. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University. Pearce, C. C. (2002). Shared Leadership reframing the hows and whys of leadership. Sage Publishing. Pech, R. (2008). Employee disengagement: is there evidence of a growing problem? Handbook of Business Strategy. Penrose, E. T. (1959). The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. New York: John Wiley. Perez, M. a. (2002). Lean Production and Technology Networks in the Spanish Automotive Supplier Industry. Management International Review. Perry, J. (1990). The Motivation Bases of Public Service. Piercy, N. C. (1995). Sources of effectiveness in the business‐to‐business sales organization. Journal of Marketing Practice: Applied Marketing Science. Quaye, D. A. (2013). Are SME Owner-Managers Entrepreneurs? Evidence from. European Journal of Business and Management . Reuber, R. &. (1993). The learning experiences of entrepreneurs. Frontiers of entrepreneurship research. Roese, N. V. (2012). Hindsight Bias. Sage Journals. Rogers, E. (1995). Diffusion of Innovation. Rogers, E. (1995). Diffusion of Innovations. Rowley, T. B. (2000). Redundant governance structures: An analysis of structural and relational embeddednessin the steel and semiconductor industry. Strategic Management Journal. Runyan, R. (2008). Entrepreneurial Orientation versus Small Business Orientation: What Are Their Relationships to Firm Performance? Journal of Small Business Management. Sarasvathy, S. (2001). Causation and Effectuation: Toward a Theoretical Shift from Economic Inevitability to Entrepreneurial Contingency. The Academy of Management Review. Savage. (1954). The Foundations of Statistics. SC., M. (2011). Entrepreneurial marketing: a strategy for the twenty-first century? Schein, E. (1990). Organizational Culture . American Psychology. Schindehutte, M. e. (2007, Dec). Understanding Market-Driving Behavior: The Role of Entrepreneurship. Journal of Small Business Management. Schollhammer H., K. A. (1979). Entrepreneurship and Small Business Management. Schumpeter, J. (1934). The Theory of Economic Development: An inquiry into Profits, Capital, Credit, Interest and the Business Cycle,. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Schumpeter, J. (2013). Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. Allan & Unwin. Shane, S. (2003). A General Theory of Entrepreneurship. Shane, S. S. (2002). Organizational Endowments and the Performance of. Management Science. Shapiro, C. V. (1999). Information Rules. Harvard Business School Press, pp. ISBN 0-87584863-X. 83 Smallbone, D. W. (2001). The Distinctiveness of Entrepreneurship in Transition Economies. Small Business Economics. Stevenson H., J. C. (1990). A Paradigm of Entrepreneurship: Entrepreneurial Management. Strategic Management Journal. Storey, G. (2010). Small business and entrepreneurship. Taylor, M. T. (2012). The technology life cycle: Conceptualization and managerial implications. Int. J. Production Economics. Taylor, T. (1911). The Principles of Scientific Management. Tervo, H. (2002). Rakkaudesta teknologiaan: Toimijaverkostonäkökulma Oulun IT-keskittymn rakentumiseen [For the love of technology: An actor network approach to the construction and. Tidd, J. B. (2005). Managing Innovation: Integrating Technological, Market and Organizational Change. Wiley. Tonoyan, V. S. (2006). WOMEN’S ENTRY INTO (NON-) PROFESSIONAL SELFEMPLOYMENT: DOES FAMILY BACKGROUND MATTER? CROSS-COUNTRY COMPARISON IN WESTERN AND EASTERN EUROPE. Entrepreneurship Research. Tucker, J. Z. (2006). Does Income Smoothing Improve earnings informativeness? THE ACCOUNTING REVIEW. Vershinima, N. e. (2017). Logics and rationalisations. Journal of Small Business and Entreprise Development. Walumbwa, F. (2008). Authentic Leadership: Development and Validation of a Theory-Based Measure. Wiklund J., S. D. (2003). Knowledge-based resources, entrepreneurial orientation, and the performance of small and medium-sized businesses. Strategic Management Journal. Williamson. (1975). Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications, a Study in the Economics of Internal Organization.” . Zak, P. K. (2001). Trust and Growth. The Economic Journal. 84 Table of illustrations Figure 1: Entrepreneurship Stages Representation (GEM, 2014) .............................................. 5 Figure 2: Firm Stages ................................................................................................................. 9 Figure 3: Summary of the key differences between startups and established corporations ..... 13 Figure 4: Steps in the innovation process ................................................................................. 14 Figure 5: Innovation characteristics over time ......................................................................... 16 Figure 6: Innovation dimensions .............................................................................................. 17 Figure 7: Difference between Schumpeterian and Kiznerian opportunities ............................ 18 Figure 8: The value chain identified by Porter (1985) ............................................................. 20 Figure 9: Highlight of the key differences between Blue and Red Ocean strategies ............... 21 Figure 10: The law of diffusion of innovation ......................................................................... 22 Figure 11: Example of Boom and Bust Cycle in the Automotive industry ............................. 25 Figure 12: Porter's 5 Forces (1980) .......................................................................................... 26 Figure 13: Summary of key differences between an attractive and unattractive industry ....... 28 Figure 14: New Institutional Economics scope overview ........................................................ 29 Figure 15: Summary on findings of external influence on startup success .............................. 30 Figure 16: Necessity vs Opportunity driven entrepreneurship ................................................. 32 Figure 17: Overview of the PEST Framework ......................................................................... 33 Figure 18: The 3 categories of psychological determinants ..................................................... 36 Figure 19: Differences in decision-making between entrepreneurs and CEO ......................... 44 Figure 20: Key non-psychological factor differences between CEO and Entrepreneurs......... 48 Figure 21: SEU function .......................................................................................................... 50 Figure 22: An example of the Subjective Utility Function ...................................................... 50 Figure 23: Summary of the different cost of self-employment ................................................ 52 Figure 24: Overview of the balanced scorecard ....................................................................... 55 Figure 25: SWOT Overview .................................................................................................... 56 Figure 26: Overview of Entrepreneurial Marketing ................................................................. 63 Figure 27: The four stages of marketing (Carson, D., 1985) ................................................... 64 Figure 28: Decision-making characteristics in startups ........................................................... 69 Figure 29: Differentiation in strategies, adapted from Frese, M. (2000) ................................. 70 85