Nothing Special   »   [go: up one dir, main page]

Academia.eduAcademia.edu

The Hypertrophic City Versus the Planet of Fields

In an extended critical response to Mike Davis's The City as Ark, this article dissects the urbanization and modernization teleologies which structure and inform the current interest in framing the city as humanity’s utopia. Instead, by showing how contemporary Global North urban rests rest on settler-colonialism and ecological imperialism, it shows how sustainable urbanization and urban forms ought to be based on a smooth relationship between urban forms and their surrounding agriculture hinterlands. In turn it also suggests that urban studies ought to pay greater attention to peasant movements and world-ecology, since they are the basis for a sustainable rural world, and thus a sustainable urban world.

Max Ajl In a crisp vignette, the urban planner and social critic Lewis Mumford asked, “What is a City?” He answered: the city is a “Geographic plexus, an economic organization, an institutional process, a theater of social action, and an aesthetic symbol of collective unity … It fosters art and is art; the city creates the theater and is the theater.”1 For Mumford, as for the slightly younger Paul Goodman and the slightly older Patrick Geddes, the city could encourage social complexity and be an incubator for human culture.2 But they also knew that the urban form could grow wildly: “Megalopolis is fast becoming a universal form,” Mumford wrote, with humanity moving fast towards a future “mechanized, standardized, effectively dehumanized, as the inal goal of urban evolution.”3 Mumford and his contemporaries had cuttingly diagnosed the late twentieth century urban form. They would have been chagrined, but probably not shocked, to ind that the future had not merely borne out their diagnosis, but that those charged with arresting the problem were still in denial about it. The hydrocephalic city remains the goal of most planners. Shared goals do not always mean shared means, but in this case, lying underneath that goal is a seldom acknowledged but universally shared underside: the end of the countryside and the relocation of its peoples. Nearly the entire policy spectrum and the dominant ensemble of cultural critics and development practitioners reject outright the notion that “cities grow on the planet of plants.”4 Instead, the ruling idea is that plants and the planet are there for cities. With most of the world’s population drawn into the cash nexus, and the percentage 3 POLI TI C AL S T RAT E GI E S, ST RUGGLE S AND H O RI ZO NS 32 THE HYPERTROPHIC CITY VERSUS THE PLANET OF FIELDS of people on the planet living in cities (purportedly) rising constantly, technocrats have focused debate on the urban age, and in turn swiftly dismiss both rural people and the production of food. If they even raise the still-lingering agrarian question, it is only to quickly dash it to the ground. The primary resort is to either tacitly or explicitly assert a double-helix modernization teleology: one ascending spiral, intensive rural-to-urban migration, and the second, the development of capital intense and labor light agriculture in the countryside.5 In this way, those advocating a future of megacities sidestep critiques of contemporary agricultural and metropolitan forms. Such analyses have devastatingly anatomized the ecological dislocations and the entropic modes of energy use linked to industrial agriculture, and tied such dissections to alternative models of food production—with strong implications for future development and planning regimes.6 But such stances are now on the margins, even in circles concerned with development.7 Outside the peasant international Via Campesina and its associated intellectuals, few discussions are about the relative weight of city and country, or indeed whether these categories are of any use. Instead, cities are seen as ixed and modular units, without any substantive relationship to the lows which constitute them and the effects those lows have beyond municipal borders.8 In turn, debates hinge on the technicalities of how to pack the people of the countryside into the cities. In the process, a modernization narrative becomes the background in front of which planners and politicians numbly discuss substantively identical trajectories. Indeed, from the Right, it is not even a background; it is the plan. Bevies of experts, oblivious to the fallout from their forebears’ fetishization of capitalintense agriculture and high-density, high-population urban living, shrugging at the ashes and ruins that lay behind the juggernaut of the development project (which, given the anti-rural bias of such policies, must also be viewed as an urbanization project), now peddle a second Green Revolution in agriculture, hoping to structure the sowing of the ields of Africa and Asia on a fully scientiic and rational basis: capital-intensive, labor-light, and petroleum-fueled. Yet this line of thinking is not just the province of devotees of industrial agriculture, or semi-reformed apologists for the system such as Jeffrey Sachs and Joseph Stieglitz. It is one that has captured the imagination of a broad sweep of analysts—from the boosters of capitalism, to myriad reformist tinkerers, and even on to its most prominent Cassandras. Indeed, from the Left, it is often much the same as on the Right, only with the modernization process criticized for its effects, yet simultaneously framed as unavoidable and thus as inevitable. For example, in a recent essay entitled, “Building the Ark,” urban theorist Mike Davis argues that the cities of the future and the cities of the South, the centers of both human population increase and carbon emissions, will become the arks in which the culture of twenty-irst century human civilization will ride out the loods and tempests of the In short, from Left to Right, the contemporary agrarian question is dominated by a solid wall of modernization narratives that dismiss lightly capitalized agricultural systems and embrace a nearly surreal 1950s-style progressivist-developmentalist narrative. They refuse to discuss the appropriate size for human communities, and assume that humanity can simply invent its way out of ecological crisis. It is a tableau riddled with problematic assumptions—most fundamentally, that existing patterns of rural-to-urban migration are both sustainable and desirable; and relatedly, that very large cities are the appropriate spatial units for future human development. In what follows, I begin by explicating the concept of the energy regime in order to show how the widespread view of the Euro-American pattern of industrialization as a global ideal type rests upon a naturalization of large-scale fossil fuel consumption. I then clarify that the concentration of populations in large-scale metropolitan regions in the global North has hinged upon global ecological plunder. On this basis I discuss the implications of further urbanization in the global South and its probable effects on agriculture, as well as on the planet as a whole. I argue that this process is linked both to an acceleration of entropic modes of living as well as to unsustainable forms of agriculture. I conclude with a counter-proposal focusing on the centrality of agriculture to the creation of a sustainable form of urbanization. 5 POLI TI C AL S T RAT E GI E S, ST RUGGLE S AND H O RI ZO NS ecological devastation wrought by twentieth century carbon civilization.9 With suficient care to safeguard public space, to make public the city’s private riches, Davis argues, the metropolis might be transformed from one of the major causes of climate change into the Great Ark. For others, the question of agricultural production in the global North is transformed into a problem of massive technological advance braided with socialist revolution. One proponent argues for “solar arrays, green fuels, new food sources and vertical farms necessary to feed billions of people in an ecologically sustainable fashion,” suggesting that such infrastructures would entail a “wholesale technological transformation of existing agriculture.”10 Through this resort to agro-Prometheanism, lessons from the global South are made irrelevant. The second historical regime is a society based on non-fossil-input-based farming, in which people skim off a surplus from the biome while managing it so as to increase the quantity of primary production usable by human beings in the form of cereals or other kinds of caloric or non-caloric goods. Agriculture is a sine qua non for urbanization, because to concentrate a population into cities one needs to produce an excess to supply non-farmers with food.14 Ecologically speaking, farming represents a massive intrusion into biological cycles, as natural cycles of succession, in which increasingly dense and big forms of lora replace simpler ones, are continuously interrupted by human ingenuity and intervention. And then there is a third energy regime, the one in which basically the entire global North and large swathes of the global South live, work and die. This is the industrial energy regime, which relies on the subterranean forests that previous generations have left us, and which has used them up at an astonishingly fast rate. This regime increasingly relies on industrial forms of agriculture, substituting dead biotic energy in the form of fossil fuels for human and living biotic energy that has been displaced from the countryside.15 Such forms of agriculture go hand-in-hand both historically and practically with high industrial civilization—the making of modern cities, modern slums, and the factories and workshops within which the working classes labor. Capitalism is conceptually distinct from the types of energy that power it. It is also distinct from industrialization, an entropic mode of material production which takes in concentrated materials from far-lung places, processes them using machines and non-human energy, and produces inished products and waste. For that reason it abrades the rest of the ecology: “Industry does not have environmentally good and bad forms. Industry just is inherently disruptive, and ignorant of its own effects.”16 Capitalism is also conceptually distinct from urbanization, “a process of continual sociospatial transformation, a relentless ‘churning’ of settlement types and morphologies that encompasses entire territories and not just isolated ‘points’ or ‘zones’ within them.”17 Nevertheless, historically, each of these processes has been tightly intertwined. This intersection was particularly stark in eighteenth and nineteenth century Britain, where industrialization, urbanization, and capitalism developed in a synergistic whirl, generating social and ecological changes on increasingly large scales. Fossil Capitalism and Energy Regimes Ecological Imperialism and the Limits to Limitless Growth First, consider forms of energy, which we can interpret using the concept of the energy regime.11 In the earliest regime, that of hunter-gatherers, the human population took what it needed from foraging in the surrounding environs, with living standards corresponding to what Marshall Sahlins describes as stone-age afluence.12 That regime was extremely low-impact. It also could not support more than a tiny population.13 Whatever the abstract merits of such societies—large amounts of leisure among them—they offer nothing to the massive populations inundating the cities and countrysides of the contemporary global South. As Kenneth Pomeranz has pointed out, British industrial development came to rely on extra-territorial supplies of land to overcome the land squeeze and the equilibrium trap it would have entailed, and fortuitously located coal supplies to overcome the timber squeeze.18 The cotton which fueled it was grown by slave labor in the American South. The slaves who worked that land were stolen from West Africa, whose land and resources England and the US planter class effectively pillaged in the form of the human bodies which that land and resources had nurtured to adulthood.19 Although hydrocarbons did not set capitalism in motion, they did enable it to increase its size and scope by temporarily Oil only aggravated this dynamic, contributing to “the new conception of the economy as an object that could grow without limit in several ways.”23 Oil initially declined in price for the entire 1920 – 1970 period of national developmentalism, making it so that “the cost of energy did not appear to represent a limit to economic growth.”24 This in turn allowed the new discipline of economics, which would soon spawn the step-child discipline of development economics, to “conceive of long-run growth as something unrestrained by the availability of energy.”25 Furthermore, both the European and American periods of pronounced national development, from 1945 to 1970, were periods when oil proits were modulated as part of a planning regime which in its American form locked together several disparate social practices and physical infrastructures into a very particular kind of modernity. Suburbs, cheap food, massive employment, continuous GDP growth, the spread of the interstate highway system, the universalization of the automobile—these parts were all linked into a spectacularly energy-intense regime of accumulation which, in turn, activated the inal destruction of the American countryside.26 Those processes and institutions encouraged a presentist morality, one which was locked into a tight afinity with corporate institutions that privileged a short time-horizon, foreshortened constantly by capital lows calibrated to quarterly proit reports.27 So for the North there has been enough, at least for some, but only because its dominant accumulation regime has been grounded upon the theft of resources, both spatially and temporally, from the present inhabitants of the Third World and from the future inhabitants of the whole world. 7 POLI TI C AL S T RAT E GI E S, ST RUGGLE S AND H O RI ZO NS allowing the material processes which capitalists order and re-order to increase substantially in size, drawing on ancient energy from the sun as well as that lying beyond the immediate geographical conines of England—and later, Europe.20 If capitalism is a system premised on the growth and differential accumulation of capital, it also tends to rely on the growth of the material structure of production and consumption which that social hierarchy restlessly shapes and molds.21 And such growth leads to geographical expansion, at least when the choice is between that and increasing domestic consumption.22 temporal theft, in this case from the future.30 Since the energy stocks condensed in carbon fuels cannot currently be replaced, and since there is no viable technology for scrubbing carbon dioxide from the atmosphere on human time scales, the market is incapable of accurately pricing hydrocarbons and most metals. The corollary of the market’s failure in this domain is that consumption patterns and social institutions should be organized such that future inheritors of the earth will have as much ability to use carbon and metallic ores as the inhabitants of the industrial epoch have had. As I will show, this proposition has strong implications for planning patterns, and for the question of when, how, and where necessarily scarce and dificult-to-process metals and dense and compact energy sources should be used. The question of sustainable planning is thrown into even sharper relief with the dawn of the Anthropocene, and amidst increasing public clarity, if not yet consensus, on the unsustainability of fossil capitalism.31 Still, the question is not, pace the peak-oilers, whether the planet will run out of oil. The question is not even one of whether burning that oil will emit so much carbon dioxide as to destabilize entire continents. By now, such destabilization is a foregone conclusion. Rather, the most urgent question is how societies will deal with the socio-ecological chaos such transformations will induce, a situation that is transforming the question of development into one of “managing the future,” and of the terms on which that future will be managed.32 To put it differently, the world’s future inhabitants will have to deal with a “full planet” in ways that the world’s past and current inhabitants have not.33 This fact, too, has unavoidable implications for development planning. Institutions are interlaced with the physical material which they arrange. That being so, sustainable social institutions and their physical infrastructures will have to be made of renewable materials. Much that is currently constructed out of petroleum and metal will soon have to be procured and fabricated in other ways. That means that the massive metal-and-glass cities of today are not likely to be the cities of tomorrow. End of the World’s Smallholders? William Rees and Mathis Wackernagel, who have formalized the notion of the ecological footprint to capture the spatial aspect of this dynamic, point out that: material lows in trade thus represent a form of thermodynamic imperialism. The low cost energy represented by commodity imports is required to sustain growth and maintain the internal order of the so-called ‘advanced economies’ of the urban North.28 As they go on to write, the “toys and tools” of industrial man, the “human-made ‘capital’ of economists” should be characterized as the “exosomatic equivalent of organs.”29 And much like organs, they require circulatory lows in the form of continuous inputs of energy to keep them functioning. However, it is impossible to put any reasonable price on those inputs when they come from fossil fuels that are not renewable on human time scales—the The notion that there are no glass and metal megacities on offer for the future denizens of the global South may sound anti-developmentalist. In fact, it undercuts one of the ideologies that has long justiied faith in the development project: the chimera of inclusion. Pushing for the remainder of the world’s peasants to lood the already-massive cities of the South means forced migrations, whether as drawn out and excruciating as the British enclosure of the commons, or as rapid as the modern day sales of state land in Africa.34 The growth of megacities is not a natural phenomenon. It is the result of a plan, one whose human-made outlines are concealed by naturalistic metaphors that turn the topology constructed by political and economic forces into preexisting contours of the social landscape.35 Moreover, it is a plan for catastrophe. Poor countries simply lack adequate resources to construct these planners’ dream cities—neither vertical farms nor capital-intense hydroponics are feasible in the medium-run for developing countries, nor are well-constructed eco-towers In concert with such post-developmentalist planning, others argue for eliminating the last remaining vestiges of small-scale agriculture—or, at least, roughly incorporating them into large-scale international commodity markets—on the assumption that urban productivity increases are what will necessarily lead to “development.” For example, as Collier and Dercon argue, “there are good reasons to suspect that larger farmers have an important role to play in experimenting and pushing the technological frontier in agriculture,” since they are the ones with enough spare capital to invest in modern production technology.38 Rural-urban migration is thereby turned into a natural law, delecting the question of where former smallholders will live, never mind how they will ind work, in the African and Latin American cities that are now either deindustrializing or which never industrialized to begin with. Just as importantly, in such arguments, the question of why peasants should relocate to cities instead of cities being built around peasants is never raised—an astounding omission that uncritically relects the agro-export agenda lurking behind such models. In any case, the assumptions supporting a large-farm and agro-export-centered development schema dissolve for being breathed upon, not least the contention that such processes can promote developmental take-off in the cities of the global South. Such models miss or ignore the silent violence of throwing millions of peasants off their land, and they are based upon naïve and inaccurate assumptions regarding the degree to which, under a global neoliberal regime, agro-export-based accumulation strategies can inance internal growth, much less social reproduction.39 Furthermore, even putative success in this project would amount to failure, for projected productivity increases cannot compensate for both the loss of the situated knowledge in contemporary smallholders’ hands and minds, as well as their by now well-established advantages in productivity per unit-of-land.40 If, with enough innovation and investment, it should actually come to pass that those ushering in the new pattern of rural development could somehow conjure up Collier and Dercon’s “technological frontier in agriculture,” it would be a hollow victory, for with it would come the permanent disappearance of the remainder of the rural smallholders, overwhelmingly women, who still produce 70 percent of the planet’s food – most food is not traded on international markets.41 Indeed, the role of smallholders in overall world food production is overwhelmingly unknown, perhaps because of whose hands are actually carrying out such production. Megacity formation in the global South presents other social problems, too. As consumers move into cities, they produce less of their own food, and increasingly have to buy food produced under conditions in which proits accrue to multinationals. Urban eaters 9 POLI TI C AL S T RAT E GI E S, ST RUGGLE S AND H O RI ZO NS or stunning, sprawling, and comprehensive subterranean public transportation systems. On the social horizon of megacity schemes is not an urban utopia but rather the total denuding of the countryside of people, and their ever-more dense enclosure into the favelas, barrios, and shantytowns of Rio de Janeiro, Caracas, Mumbai, Shanghai, Lagos and Dakar.36 There is no planet of cities on offer. Only a planet of slums.37 “shift from sorghum, millet, maize and root crops to rice and wheat (often processed into bread).”42 Rice and wheat are traded on international commodity markets. Roots and cassava are not. The urban poor become subject to price variations in the global market.43 The rural poor retain a thick protective buffer. Moreover, that rural-based buffer is one that can extend to inhabitants of cities, since the families of irst-generation migrants often retain small plots in the countryside even as younger generations lood metropolitan areas in search of work. With the right policy incentives, such a buffer could become denser yet, especially given the increasing eflorescence of urban and periurban agriculture. Cuba is the widely cited posterchild of these projects, yet such production patterns are common across Africa as well.44 But given urban agriculture’s centrality in feeding the people of countries like Senegal and Ghana, it is unclear why there is such a thrust to impose the social dislocation that drives peasants into cities in the irst place. Is it better to farm in a cityside slum than in the countryside? Given the multiple roles even minifundia play in warding off total subjection to the market, it is no surprise that the project of land alienation continues to encounter vigorous resistance.45 Indeed, some who otherwise argue for eliminating small-scale agriculture accept the role of subsistence farming in fending off food crises.46 Across Asia and Latin America, the defense of subsistence agriculture is not a dying echo of populist thought. It is an active anti-systemic struggle.47 Furthermore, those who argue for more capital-intense, commercialized agro-exports on the Brazilian model – and the accompanying rural-urban migration – seldom consider the ecological costs of shifting large quantities of food production to the entropic regime of industrial agriculture while also constructing the input-intensive cities required for such a massive population shift.48 Concerning the industrialization of agricultural production, the energetic basis for the ideal-typical modernization process, the Vandermeer Report notes, We have moved from an “ecosystem function” of energy generation to one based on fossil fuels, thus converting an agricultural system whose main purpose was to provide energy to human beings, to a system that is a net consumer of energy. Paraphrasing Richard Lewontin, it was a change from “using sun and water to grow peanuts” to “using petroleum to manufacture peanut butter.” As a consequence, it has been estimated that this industrial food system expends 1015 energy calories to produce 1 calorie of food, thereby effectively reversing the reason for the invention of agriculture in the irst place.49 Instead of paying attention to these facts, those peddling a new urban age seem to consider cities a kind of black box into which one can dump the human population and worry later. Not so. Cities come in all shapes and sizes, but they all consume a great deal of resources. And resource consumption inevitably raises the question of recycling. The knot of the problem is that modern cities are basically black holes, drawing in massive amounts of The troubles of mass urbanization and the universalization of industrial agriculture appear not just with respect to recycling, but also in relation to resource consumption. Here the limits are Malthusian—there is not enough world. Turning the global South’s remaining two billion peasants into city dwellers on the model of afluent global North urban nodes means massive population shifts. Such shifts may cause their consumption patterns decreasingly to resemble those of people living in organic economies reliant on biomass, and to be transformed into those particular to mineral economies, reliant on the buried forests of the past which time and pressure have turned into coal, oil and gas.51 An early foretaste of this catastrophic scenario is the doubling and redoubling of meat consumption amongst the massively growing Chinese middle class over the last two decades. If the 70 percent of the world’s population currently stuck in poverty—most of them rural, and most of those in China, India, and Africa—were to adopt resource-use patterns replicating those of the afluent, urban and peri-urban and suburban global North, humanity would require between 20 to 30 times the amount of annual US energy use—about equal to the potential net primary production of all of Earth’s terrestrial biota.52 That will never work, because it would not leave anything for the rest of the living species with which we share the planet, never mind what would happen to the atmosphere if we cut down all the trees. Meanwhile, if the fuel came from coal, the world would swiftly turn to Venus, one reason why more “progressive” environmentalists such as James Lovelock are having a late-stage love affair with nuclear power.53 11 POLI TI C AL S T RAT E GI E S, ST RUGGLE S AND H O RI ZO NS energy and matter, and then excreting degraded waste into the biosphere.50 Of course, all organisms do this. The vice of modern megacities is their size. Being so big, rather than having a smooth metabolism with their peripheries, they disrupt them radically. In the past, agriculture mediated waste processing, thereby not only making eficient use of wastes but also doubling as an early-warning signal for the excessive build-up of toxic efluent. But under the megacity/agro-export regime, such processing becomes impossible, as raw or manufactured materials are imported from elsewhere, and the waste products thereupon are subsequently dumped in highly concentrated form, elsewhere. To construct cities on such a huge scale has meant making much of the global South and the global North peripheries—or, to draw on a more familiar parlance, colonies. Imperialism has always had an ecological component. is now fabricated hinges upon the use of non-renewable methods and non-renewable resources—especially metals and hydrocarbons. Eventually these resources will become untenably expensive to extract, and their ecological costs will become unbearable. At that point, human societies will have to revert to direct photosynthetic processes of energy concentration to produce the raw materials upon which civilization rests. The question, then, is one of turning agriculture into a means for producing the raw materials for satisfying human needs, especially food, in a sustainable manner, and interlacing it with urban systems built according to plans that constrain, not end, the reliance upon materials acquired through disruptive forms of extraction. This means that skylines of skyscrapers should not be set up as the normative goal for architects and planners, nor should human society be made needlessly expensive from an energetic perspective.56 That means thinking about scale. For example, smaller cities could return waste to their agricultural hinterlands instead of relying on treatment plants that consume tremendous amounts of energy to do what nature can do for free. Existing cities could be carefully perforated with urban agricultures that would also help recycle wastes, and would also cool off buildings and cut down transport costs for the commodities grown on such plots. The question of land and agriculture is, ultimately, at the core of such a model. In the industrial energy system, oil is almost literally transformed into corn, turning nature’s logic on its head. In contrast, in a sustainable agricultural system, land use must yield a positive energy balance. The amount of energy put into agricultural production by human and animal traction must be less than the amount of energy that is withdrawn from it in the form of consumable harvest. Without hallucinating a pre-lapsarian idyll—agricultural civilizations have been capable of tremendous harm to their environments—societies centered on agriculture are capable of relative long-run sustainability and could take relatively good care of the people who live in them, given democratic control over both planning and the means of production.57 They also secure, rather than diminish, the amount of space available within the world for human culture. It is an ahistorical anthropocentrism to think that the environment must always contain a large place within it for human beings, summed up in the conceit of man’s supposedly increasing dominance of nature. Nature always calls the shots.58 At the moment, the environment is arranged in such a manner as to facilitate large human populations and easy living. That could change very quickly.59 Why Centralize Agriculture? If the space in the atmosphere for the waste products of this particular sort of industrial civilization is shrinking, and will soon disappear, then one way or another, a regime based To forestall misreading, this is not a polemic against civilization, or against cities, or indeed against industrialization. As Mumford recognized, all human cultures contained within them warring tendencies. Hypertrophic cities and the civilizations within which on sustainable forms of farming and a considerably less-entropic mode of production more generally must come to the fore, what environmental historian Colin Duncan refers to as the centrality of agriculture.54 As he writes, future forms of agriculture will have to provide much of the “materials and energy that we are now in the habit of procuring almost exclusively in the industrial style, from petroleum especially.”55 Much of what they were embedded rested on complex, hierarchical technologies. Mumford laid out the pathways of such megatechnics, contrasting them with democratic, organic, simple and egalitarian technologies.60 Both have existed in all human societies. The former allowed for incredible population densities, miraculous feats of engineering, and most importantly, an enormous accumulation of wealth. The latter had a different merit: they survived. This But nor is this a call for the world to return to isolated subsistence farming as a universal form, and still less for a reversion to hunting and gathering. Early twentieth century social critics, from Mumford to Peter Kropotkin to Ebenezer Howard, were not primitivists. They did not attack cities; they attacked their size, as part of a holistic vision of the appropriate scale for human communities—Howard’s notions of garden cities were one example of this tendency.62 They proposed urban forms that could incubate human creativity, interweave ields and factories, and in the process heal the metabolic rift which twentieth century capitalism was constantly stretching.63 13 POLI TI C AL S T RAT E GI E S, ST RUGGLE S AND H O RI ZO NS insight allows us to think of technology as the use of human knowledge for human ends. But technology cannot tell us anything about those ends. In and of itself, it is socially and ecologically neutral. That also means it is not limited to metabolically entropic modes: industry. Agriculture is also a technology—as Braudel noted, perhaps the irst technology, certainly for millennia the most widespread—and done properly, is the apotheosis of the democratic, resilient, and human-scale technologies which Mumford praised.61 hollowed-out urban areas have a high potential for achieving food sovereignty, matching up unemployable labor with Keynesian policies that could also lead to a relatively more socially embedded capitalism with increased backwards-and-forwards linkages, as well as healing the metabolic rift by enabling waste recycling and reducing the production of the carbon dioxide wastes for which the food production system is responsible.66 This does not mean sidestepping the question of social power. Counter-cyclical policies will not be on the table without social pressure. Here the Cuban example is entirely appropriate—Havana derives a huge proportion of its produce from low-input urban gardens. Some object that this kind of occupational and spatial transition is impossible. This claim seems odd. Do people prefer working at McDonalds to receiving retraining to work in small-scale and locally controlled agriculture? The question should at least be posed in the form of progressive social policy. And if current energy prices make such a transition unfeasible by subsidizing unsustainable rates of hydrocarbon use, once again, the answer is using political tools to change such prices: massive gasoline taxes, which could then be used for all sorts of socially determined processes, not least paying suficient salaries to newly-trained urban and periurban gardeners to make their work pay a living wage. How to Centralize Agriculture Putting such theory into practice means moving beyond post-developmentalist abstractions which seek to replicate the American model of laborless agriculture, endless highways and petroleum use, and, of course, megalopolis, and impose it on the rest of the planet. There is no reason to set up skylines of skyscrapers as the normative horizon for cities. Those which are already built should remain—there is nothing else to do with them. But there seems little justiication for building more of them. They are also expensive, and need immense expenditures of energy for their steel, concrete, and infrastructure. Finally, their superabundance contributes to the kind of urbanization marked by too dense and too big core cities and the neglect of medium-size or small cities.64 This was, of course, a theme which Mumford and his contemporaries raised insistently over ive decades ago. For them, there could be no rootless and restless dreaming about an abstract urban form. Urbanization and human communal density produced culture. But too much density was damaging. As Mumford wrote, “the mere mechanical massing of the population creates dificulties which can be overcome only by an undue expenditure of capital and income on the means of existence: that is to say, on measures which, though they produce no good in themselves, are necessary in order to overcome the defects of congestion,” such as highways, the need to tap increasingly distant sources of water, and expensive mass-transit systems.65 Another short-run planning policy is to ditch entirely the notion of building or expanding existing suburbs and ex-urbs. Such sprawl is not sustainable, and new patterns are necessary. That may indeed eventually mean resettling the American countryside. John Friedmann’s agropolitan districts are one example of how to conceptualize such a shift: areas of between 20,000 and 100,000 people, largely self-suficient and capable of selfgovernance.67 This is precisely the size of the ideal cities which Howard and Kropotkin, as well as modern radical ecologists like Kirkpatrick Sale, have proposed.68 Such a transition would mean decentralizing cultural and educational institutions, and in turn drenching the new spaces in such institutions. If such districts are to be urban—that is, if they are to have high population densities and a high proportion of their populations engaged in non-farm labor—then they could be organically and symbiotically tied into the surrounding countryside on the basis of reciprocal exchange. This refocusing on agriculture has slightly different implications for the cities of the South Here some object that purposive planning patterns and any such control of population lows require a sort of authoritarian technocracy. But such objections are nothing more than a deiication of the processes of “the market” and the social arrangements which those processes produce.69 There is no reason why green Keynesianism policies could not set these shifts in motion, thereby beginning the important process of relocalizing continental or ocean-length commodity chains, and also putting people to work. Others object that commodities produced through agro-ecological methods are too expensive and the cities of the North. In the latter, to tackle the largest task, it means fundamentally rejigging American patterns of urban and spatial planning. In the short-to-medium-run, making agriculture central means massive state support for urban farming initiatives, as well as agro-ecological training for those working on such plots. While this tendency is frequently ridiculed as a form of haute couture green capitalism or localism-gone-mad, many for those without adequate purchasing power. The answer is to guarantee incomes high enough to make such goods affordable—which then immediately revives the issue of social power by putting into question how and to what ends it is used. A third objection is that “socialism” should mean a world without labor. Putting aside the oddly anti-humanist misanthropy of such a formulation, in countries with massive and structural unemployment In the global South, a sustainable model of urbanization means, perhaps counterintuitively, an immediate end to state support for policies, often enough coming from the World Bank or other transnational institutions, which provoke rural-urban migration.71 In a world of unaffordable capital and unemployed—indeed, unemployable—labor, why worsen the situation by packing people into cities, especially when labor is needed in the ield? Instead, the countries of the South should be deploying policies removing them from global commodity production loops, most importantly, through food sovereignty strategies based on heavy investment in small-holder agriculture—again, a demand that entails a massive reorganization of social power and property relations, as powerfully expressed in the ongoing struggle for local control of land use systems and redistributive agrarian reform by groups like the Landless Workers’ Movement (MST) in Brazil.72 For such currents, smallholder agriculture is far from an antiquarian curio. It is a ight for survival. A sustainable urbanism, woven into a global urban fabric, must defend that ight, rather than undermine it. Crucially, then, a wholesale shift in the form of urbanization in the global South requires revolutionary change in property relations in the countryside. 15 POLI TI C AL S T RAT E GI E S, ST RUGGLE S AND H O RI ZO NS like the United States and the southern European countries, there is nothing wrong with medium-run programs that would put that manpower to work in return for adequate reward. This is to say nothing of silvicultures that do not require a great deal of labor, but that do require immense amounts of long-term planning, or the elaborate forms of gardening exempliied by the rice farming methods in Fukuoka’s The One Straw Revolution, which require minimal, but well-timed, labor.70 There is, inally, a question of populations perhaps choosing to return to the countryside.75 Ghana experienced re-peasantization during the 1970-1984 period as its economy tumbled into disaster, a situation that was enabled by the fact that recent rural-urban migrants still had extensive knowledge of farming practices.76 The Cuban government has carried out a program of re-peasantization during the Special Period.77 Some Landless Workers’ Movement (MST) settlements are made up of former slum-dwellers from Brazil’s cities, as are some of the residents of Venezuela’s new agrarian settlements. There is no reason to rue these facts. Agriculture need not be an afterthought or an awkward adjunct to development. It could be, as Duncan writes, the framework for a sustainable socialism nested in bioregions.78 The question is not one of plopping the populations of New York and London into ields with pitchforks in their hands. It is, rather, a matter of designing social and planning policy so that the populations currently on the land are not so eager to leave it, and working forwards from there. In such a vision, megacities can hardly serve as ecological arks, and the bigness fetish of high modernism must be abandoned as a relic of industrial excess.79 Immense human population concentrations are not a value in and of themselves. Cities should be built to accommodate people, not the other way around. That includes accommodating the preexisting social fabric of their lives. Just as the countryside’s people can be brought to the cities, that which is crucial about cities—for instance, hospitals, universities, museums, art collectives, a profusion of social interaction—can be easily brought to the countryside. Conclusion Elsewhere, if urbanization is taking place in situ, then there is all the more reason to focus on the qualitative aspects of germinating sustainable urban forms. This raises the question of planning, to support the growth of smaller cities linked tightly and organically to agricultural production. Indeed, shifts in occupation are inevitable as the implicit subsidy of atmospheric space for carbon wastes slowly disappears and the costs of burning so much cheap energy catch up with the planet. The question is whether they will also be calamitous.73 Since urbanization in much of the global South consists of cities swelling over and enveloping agricultural hinterlands, the question there would be one of constructing those cities in ways that respect pre-existing agricultural forms. This does not mean envelopment of agricultural plots within cities. Urban agriculture is a stop-gap measure, in the global North and South alike; it should not be raised to the level of principle. Cities are cities because they are dense. What this does mean is constructing cities so that they do not swell onto their hinterlands. If in India, for example, governments can subsidize special economic development zones for IT, they can as easily secure peasant property rights and divert development into resources that people, rather than corporations, need. The latter include, for example, electriication, healthcare and sanitation, all of which have an historical rather than necessary association with industrialization and a fossil-fuel based model of urbanization.74 As in the global North, that should also mean distributing cultural institutions in spots of relative density. The notion that in a free society, some work will still have to be done and some of it will be hard, and that is okay so long as it is evenly distributed; the view of modernization and development as having often had destructive consequences; the idea that modern society need not fetishize industry; and the assumption that cities ought respond to the needs of the countryside, which they in any case rely on, ecologically and economically, for survival— all these are commonly cast aside as a vague and retrograde populism. As arguments, they run against the grain of over one hundred years of development thinking, Marxist and mainstream alike. Yet these claims are not new. Nearly a century ago, as the Soviet Union was beginning its heavy industrial lock-in, Ivan Kremnev penned a story about a time-traveler who woke up in 1980 after having been adrift for decades after the Bolshevik Revolution. Rather than the violent concentration of the peasantry in cities amid forced collectivization, peasant forces had captured the state. They rebuilt the entire country, abolishing towns of more than 20,000 people, dispersing the massive Moscow metropolis, creating local centers at railroad junctions, perfecting the communications network, and saturating the local centers in culture—theaters, museums, peoples’ universities, sport activities, choral societies, all the classical accoutrements of city life that, he understood, did not require the dense, unsustainable conglomerations of people that inhabited Moscow.80 The text’s English translation is introduced dismissively by another Soviet writer: “The forms of the peasant economy . . . are retrograde even compared with capitalist forms of agriculture”; the “peasantry generally follows the proletariat, its politically more advanced and better organized fellow,” while the former struggles to preserve its “essentially reactionary ideals.”81 Even then, on a planet of peasants, the prevailing assumption was that farmers’ struggles were anti-modern, and destructive of the ideal of human progress. It is, though, an odd concession to the modern-day religion of progress to think that only industrialized society can secure healthy lives for people. As Halperin makes clear, it was not industrialization in and of itself that delivered social development to the North.82 Indeed, industrialization has seldom closed the North/South divergence in living standards, which continue to widen.83 Furthermore, as Duncan points out, “It is striking that those recognized elements of a ‘good life’ that are most strongly cross-cultural – good food and drink, nice garments, ine music and conversation, and comfortable housing – in no way require industry.”84 Advanced medical care, as he points out, is a separate issue, but the Cuban example shows clearly that a healthcare system capable of achieving excellent quality-of-life indicators need not be dependent on either extensive energy use or a society based on heavy industrialization and hyper-dense, large-scale urbanization. Networks of thousands of small and medium cities, linked by high-speed trains, is one such vision, and a more productive use of limited resources than concentrating them in unlivable cities, where daily commutes along desperately overcrowded and under-serviced arterial roads can exceed three hours in the global South’s megacities. 17 Notes 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 So is this a Luddite fantasy, a reincarnation of the Romantic penchant for the countryside? That is the perspective of the neoliberal clergy. Collier writes of “the middle- and upperclass love affair with peasant agriculture … With the near-total urbanization of these classes in both the United States and Europe, rural simplicity has acquired a strange allure. Peasant life is prized as organic in both its literal and its metaphoric sense.”85 And indeed, this is the same criticism those holding out the promise of perpetual growth and industrial development as a route to universal prosperity have been putting forward for over a century. But top-down industrialization has simply failed to deliver that which it has promised. Chants for bread animate the revolts of the new millennium as surely as they did 100 years ago. The idea of progress has promised so much and come through with so little, and that for so few. It must be acknowledged that people have neither wanted nor asked for industrial societies of the sort which have been relentlessly imposed upon them. Perhaps it is now time to listen to the victims of our visions.86 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Lewis Mumford, “What is a City,” Architectural Record 82 (1937) 59-62, 60. Percival Goodman and Paul Goodman, Communitas (New York: Columbia University Press, 1990). Mumford, “What is a City,” 62, 61. André Torre and Lise Bourdeau-Lepage, “When Agriculture Meets the City… a Desire for Nature or an Economic Necessity?” Metropolitics 10 (2013). http://www.metropolitiques.eu/Whenagriculture-meets-the-city.html. For a representative example, see Hiroaki Suzuki, Arish Dastur, Sebastian Moffatt, Nanae Yabuki and Hinako Maruyama, Eco2 Cities: Ecological Cities As Economic Cities (World Bank Publications, 2010). On agro-ecology, see Eric Holt-Giménez and Miguel A. Altieri, “Agroecology, Food Sovereignty, and the New Green Revolution,” Agroecology and Sustainable Food Systems 37, 1 (2013) 90-102. For a representative dismissal, see Tom Brass, “Moral Economists, Subalterns, New Social Movements, and the (re-) Emergence of a (post-) Modernized (middle) Peasant,” Journal of Peasant Studies 18, 2 (1991) 173-205. See Neil Brenner, “Theses on Urbanization,” this book, Ch. XX. It would be intriguing to develop a comparison between the historical development of this concept of the city as an analytical category immured from the lows which constitute it and the development of the concept of the economy as a free-standing sphere of life walled off from the wider world within which it is necessarily although not conceptually embedded, especially since cities can no more exist without their hinterlands than can “economies” without the world in which their so-called “externalities” are dumped. On this see Timothy Mitchell, “The Properties of Markets,” Do Economists Make Markets?, eds. Donald A. MacKenzie, Fabian Muniesa, and Lucia Siu (New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 2007) 244-75. Mike Davis, “Who Will Build the Ark?” New Left Review 61 (2010) 29-46. Greg Sharzer, “A Critique of Localist Political Economy and Urban Agriculture,” Historical Materialism 20, 4 (2012) 75-114, 105. Rolf Peter Sieferle, The Subterranean Forest (Cambridge: White Horse Press, 2010). See also Helmut Haberl “The Energetic Metabolism of Societies,” Journal of Industrial Ecology 5, 2 (2002) 71-88. Marshall Sahlins, Stone Age Economics (London: Routledge, 2012). See William Cronon, Changes in the Land (London: Macmillan, 2011), for a discussion of the merits and demerits of such societies as they occurred in America. James Scott develops an intriguing argument linking forms of lowintensity agriculture to attempts to escape incorporation into cities. See James Scott, The Art of Not Being Governed (New Haven: Yale University Press, 2009). Joan Martinez-Alier, “The EROI of Agriculture and Its Use by the Via Campesina,” Journal of Peasant Studies 38, 1 (2011) 145-60. Colin A. M. Duncan, “On Identifying a Sound Environmental Ethic in History: Prolegomena to Any Future Environmental History,” Environmental History Review (1991) 15. Neil Brenner and Christian Schmid, “The ‘Urban Age’ in Question,” this book, Ch. XX. Kenneth Pomeranz, “Political Economy and Ecology on the Eve of Industrialization: Europe, China, and the Global Conjuncture,” The American Historical Review 107, 2 (2002) 425–46. Walter Rodney, How Europe Underdeveloped Africa (Baltimore: Black Classic Press, 2011). As Moore insightfully argues, the expansion of the timber frontier to the Baltic region was part of this process. For example see, Jason W. Moore, “‘Amsterdam Is Standing on Norway’ Part II: The Global North Atlantic in the Ecological Revolution of the Long Seventeenth Century,” Journal of Agrarian Change 10, 2 (2010) 188227, 196-211. 21 Jonathan Nitzan and Shimshon Bichler, Capital as Power: A Study of Order and Creorder (Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon: Routledge, 2009). 22 In three critically important works of comparative historical sociology, Sandra Halperin makes clear that human or social development in Europe was not the result of any “organic” process built into modernity but was, rather, the result of massive popular mobilizations coinciding with preparations for war. See Sandra Halperin, Re-Envisioning Global Development (London: Routledge, 2013); and Sandra Halperin, In the Mirror of the Third World: Capitalist Development in Modern Europe (New York: Cornell University Press, 1997); Sandra Halperin, War and Social Change in Modern Europe (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004). 23 Timothy Mitchell, Carbon Democracy: Political Power in the Age of Oil (London: Verso, 2011) 139. 24 Ibid. 25 Ibid; Farshad Araghi, “Food Regimes and the Production of Value: Some Methodological Issues,” Journal of Peasant Studies 30 (2003) 41-70. 26 Matt Huber, “The Use of Gasoline: Value, Oil, and the ‘American Way of Life’,” Antipode 41, 3 (2009) 465-486; Matt Huber, “Fueling Capitalism: Oil, the Regulation Approach, and the Ecology of Capital,” Economic Geography 89, 2 (2013) 171-194. On oil prices in this era, see John R. Blair, The Control of Oil (New York: Pantheon Books, 1976). 27 Duncan, “On Identifying a Sound Environmental Ethic in History,” 16-22. 28 William E. Rees and Mathis Wackernagel, “Urban Ecological Footprints: Why Cities Cannot be Sustainable and Why They are a Key to Sustainability,” Environmental Impact Assessment Review, 16 (1996) 223-48, 239. 29 Ibid, 225. 30 Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen, “Myths About Energy and Matter,” Growth & Change 10, 1 (1979) 16; Herman E. Daly, “Myths About Energy and Matter: Comment,” Growth & Change 10, 1 (1979) 24. 31 Larry Lohmann, “Capital and Climate Change,” Development and Change 42, 2 (2011) 649-68. 32 Philip McMichael, Development and Social Change (Thousand Oaks: Sage Press, 2011) xiv. 33 Joshua Farley and Herman Daly, “The Failure of the Free-Market on a Full Planet,” Vortragsskript für ISEE/RC (2001). http://www. utopia.uzh.ch/research/Farley_Daly_paper.pdf, 26. 34 See, among many critical studies of this phenomenon, Lorenzo Cotula, Land Deals in Africa: What is in the Contracts? (London: International Institute for Environment, 2011). 35 From a far more critical angle that claims to be skeptical of the “grand narrative of power and people-decentred architecture that dominate the iconic mega cities of today,” one still reads of how “Asia and Africa in particular are experiencing rapid rural to urban migration.” See Wendy Harcourt, “Editorial: Designing Urban Living,” Development 54, 3 (2011) 291-92, 292, 291. Such accounts bracket the nature of the “push” factors that were creating that rural-to-urban migration in the irst place. 36 One might object that much of the critical literature does in fact note that massive rural-urban migration is an effect of structural adjustment policies that make the countryside unlivable. But such an objection does not hold. First, the push-pull factors that produced massive and unsustainable urbanization preceded the structural adjustment policies, and were instead rooted in other kinds of unsustainable urban-biased policies—although those same structural adjustment policies are indeed intensifying and accelerating previous processes. Second, much of the literature accepts and arguably naturalizes the low of population from country to city, since they accept the demographic projections which presuppose the continuance of such lows—an odd ontology that removes from consideration a range of possible scenarios that would arrest or alleviate such lows. 37 The instant-classic reference is Mike Davis, Planet Of Slums (London: Verso, 2006). I take issue with this important landmark due to its normalization of existing rural-urban migration tendencies, and due to its downplaying of the role of rural organizing in the world’s anti-systemic movements. 38 Paul Collier and Stefan Dercon, “African Agriculture in 50 Years: Smallholders in a Rapidly Changing World?” Expert Meeting on How to Feed the World In (2009) 24-26. http://iis-db.stanford.edu/ evnts/7365/Collier_Dercon_Africa_2013_world_development. pdf. 39 Under very different circumstances, agro-export financed substantial industrialization in late nineteenth century Russia and early nineteenth century Egypt. On the latter, see Jean Batou, “Nineteenth-Century Attempted Escapes from the Periphery: the Cases of Egypt and Paraguay,” Review (Fernand Braudel Center) 16, 3 (1993) 279-318. But price volatility for agricultural commodities makes creating a development model around them chancy at best. 40 Miguel A. Altieri, “Applying Agroecology to Enhance the Productivity of Peasant Farming Systems in Latin America,” Environment, Development and Sustainability 1, 3-4 (1999) 197-217. 41 Jack Ralph Kloppenburg, First the Seed: The Political Economy of Plant Biotechnology (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 2005). The point about 70 percent of the planet’s food is a commonplace in the critical literature. As one report notes, the “ETC Group notes that there are 1.5 billion small farmers on 380 million farms; 800 million more growing urban gardens; 410 million gathering the hidden harvest of our forests and savannas; 190 million pastoralists and well over 100 million peasant ishers. At least 370 million of these are also indigenous peoples. Together these farmers make up almost half the world’s peoples and grow at least 70 per cent of the world’s food” (footnote no. 8 in Fairtrade Foundation, Powering up Smallholder Farmers to Make Food Fair (Fairtrade Foundation, 2013) 44); Nick Minot, “Transmission of World Food Price Changes to Markets in Sub-Saharan Africa,” Washington, IFPRI 34 (2011); and Jacques Morisset, “Unfair Trade? The Increasing Gap Between World and Domestic Prices in Commodity Markets During the Past 25 Years,” The World Bank Economic Review 12, 3 (1998) 503-26. 42 Marc J. Cohen and James L. Garrett, The Food Price Crisis and Urban Food (in)Security (London: IIED and UNFPA, 2009) 6. 43 Joseph Baines argues that these prices are also the product of politically instituted markets, engineered to concentrate proits in some hands and not others. See Joseph Baines, “Food Price Inlation as Redistribution: Towards a New Analysis of Corporate Power in the World Food System,” New Political Economy (2013) 1-34. 44 David Satterthwaite, Gordon McGranahan, and Cecilia Tacoli, “Urbanization and Its Implications for Food and Farming,” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 365 (2010) 2809-20. 45 Tom Lavers, “‘Land Grab’ as Development Strategy? The Political Economy of Agricultural Investment in Ethiopia,” Journal of Peasant Studies 39, 1 (2012) 105-32; and Silvia Federici, “The Debt Crisis, Africa and the New Enclosures,” Midnight Notes 10 (1992) 10-17. 46 Alain de Janvry and Elisabeth Sadoulet, “Subsistence Farming as a Safety Net for Food-price Shocks,” Development in Practice 21, 4-5 (2011) 472-480. In Latin America, for example, the remaining rural population is living amidst the aftermath of centuries of colonial land concentration and a mid-century interlude of capitalist agrarian reforms, and rural semi-proletarianization and functional dualism in agriculture remain the dominant modes of production and social reproduction. But the question of what follows from the social organization of production is an inherently political question. On semi-proletarianization, see Cristóbal Kay, “Rural Poverty and Development Strategies in Latin America,” Journal of Agrarian Change 6, 4 (2006) 455-508; and on functional dualism, Alain de Janvry, The Agrarian Question and Reformism in Latin America (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1981). 47 María Elena Martínez-Torres and Peter M. Rosset, “La Vía 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 Campesina: the Birth and Evolution of a Transnational Social Movement,” Journal of Peasant Studies 37 (2010) 149-75; and Wendy Wolford, This Land Is Ours Now: Social Mobilization and the Meanings of Land in Brazil (Durham: Duke University Press, 2010). Collier and Dercon, “African Agriculture in 50 Years.” John Vandermeer, Gerald Smith, Ivette Perfecto, Eileen Quintero, Rachel Bezner-Kerr, Daniel Grifith, Stuart Ketcham, Steve Latta, Brenda Lin, Phil McMichael, Krista McGuire, Ron Nigh, Diana Rocheleau, and John Soluri, Effects of Industrial Agriculture on Global Warming and the Potential of Small-scale Agroecological Techniques to Reverse Those Effects. www.viacampesina.net/downloads/DOC/ ViaNWAEG-10-20-09.doc. Rees and Wackernagel, “Urban Ecological Footprints,” 237. Sieferle, The Subterranean Forest. Helmut Haberl, Fridolin Krausmann, and Simone Gingrich, “Ecological Embeddedness of the Economy: a Socioecological Perspective on Humanity’s Economic Activities 1700-2000,” Economic and Political Weekly 41, 47 (2006) 4896, 4903. James Lovelock, “Nuclear Power is the Only Green Solution,” The Independent (2004). http://www.independent.co.uk/voices/ commentators/james-lovelock-nuclear-power-is-the-only-greensolution-6169341.html Colin A. Duncan, The Centrality of Agriculture: Between Humankind and the Rest of Nature (Montreal: McGill Queens University Press, 1996). Ibid, 47. Duncan makes this point with reference to the example of wooden versus metal furniture, writing, “Perfectly cheap and proitable projects are refused a hearing in our type of modern economy if they are very long-term. This explains why along the shores of Lake Ontario you see nuclear electric power plants instead of oak forests. Oak forests have quite negligible start-up costs but are extremely slow at growing. The commitments we make in these ields are pervasive and include expensive feed-back loops. For instance, schools and universities in Ontario have hardly any more oak furniture. Instead they have mostly steel furniture. Steel production facilities are enormous consumers of electric power, as Ontario citizens were recently reminded (December, 1989) when the electric power authorities shut various factories down for a period. Inattention to long-term projects, makes our lives now, and later, simply more expensive than they need be.” Duncan, “On Identifying a Sound Environmental Ethic in History,” 21. David R. Montgomery, Dirt: the Erosion of Civilizations (Berkeley: University of California Press, 2012). The debate about whether or not nature is a useful term is rich and contentious, and makes speciic citation here useless. I use “nature” and “the environment,” interchangeably to refer to nonhuman material world around us, which includes both the ecology as well as the human built environment. For that reason, I think it is a reasonable claim to say that the environment can be arranged in such a way as to allow different maximal human populations. Duncan, “On Identifying a Sound Environmental Ethic in History,” 9. Mumford, The City in History. Fernand Braudel, The Structures of Everyday Life (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1981), 430-31; and Stephen A. Marglin, “Farmers, Seedsmen, and Scientists: Systems of Agriculture and Systems of Knowledge,” Decolonizing Knowledge, eds. Frédérique Apffel-Marglin and Stephen A. Marglin (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1996) 185-248. Peter Kropotkin and George Woodcock, Fields, Factories, and Workshops (Montreal: Black Rose Books, 1993 [1898]); and Ebenezer Howard, Garden Cities of To-Morrow (London: Routledge, 2013 [1898]). Mindi Schneider and Philip McMichael, “Deepening, and Repairing, the Metabolic Rift,” Journal of Peasant Studies 37 (2010) 461–484. New York City, for example, needs a massive hinterland to supply its 8 million people with food. In the long run, such imbalances ought to be ixed through collective processes of decision-making and society-wide planning. 19 65 Lewis Mumford, “Garden Cities and the Metropolis: a Reply,” The Journal of Land & Public Utility Economics 22, 1 (1946) 67. 66 Sharanbir S. Grewal and Parwinder S. Grewal, “Can Cities Become Self-reliant in Food?,” Cities 29, 1 (2012) 1-11. 67 John Friedmann, “Basic Needs, Agropolitan Development, and Planning from Below,” World Development 7, 6 (1979) 607-613. 68 Kirkpatrick Sale, Human Scale (New Catalyst Books, 2007). 69 Stephen Marglin, “Development as Poison: Rethinking the Western Model of Modernity,” Harvard International Review 25, 1 (2003) 7075, 73. 70 Masanobu Fukuoka, The One-Straw Revolution: an Introduction to Natural Farming (New York: New York Review Books Classics, 2009). This example is taken from Duncan’s The Centrality of Agriculture. 71 Davis, Planet of Slums, 1-19, 55-61. 72 There is an important debate within circles concerned with rural development between land reforms which are redistributive and involve minimal or no compensation for large landholders, and “market-friendly” land reform, which involves compensation for land-holders at market rates. See Saturnino M. Borras, Pro-poor Land Reform: a Critique (Ottawa: University of Ottawa Press, 2007). 73 Jörg Friedrichs, “Global Energy Crunch: How Different Parts of the World Would React to a Peak Oil Scenario,” Energy Policy 38, 8 (2010) 4562-69. 74 Michael Levien, “The Land Question: Special Economic Zones and the Political Economy of Dispossession in India,” Journal of Peasant Studies 39, 3-4 (2012) 933-969. See also John Friedmann, “Becoming Urban: On Whose Terms?” this book, Ch. XX. 75 I do not mean to sidestep the question of people being forced to stay in the countryside or being pushed there and dying as a result. For example, see Ben Kiernan, “The Demography of Genocide in Southeast Asia: the Death Tolls in Cambodia, 1975-79, and East Timor, 1975-80,” Critical Asian Studies 35, 4 (2003) 585-97. However, there is a sharp difference between inclusive, democratic modes of planning and authoritarian ones, and it was obviously the latter—not the return to the countryside as such—which produced mass death in the Cambodian context. 76 Jacob Songsore, The Urban Transition in Ghana (IIED, 2009). http:// pubs.iied.org/pdfs/G02540.pdf. 77 Carmen Diana Deere, Niurka Pérez, and Ernel Gonzales, “The View from Below: Cuban Agriculture in the ‘Special Period in Peacetime’,” The Journal of Peasant Studies 21, 2 (1994) 194-234. 78 Kirkpatrick Sale, Dwellers in the Land (Athens: University of Georgia Press, 2000). 79 James C. Scott, Seeing Like a State (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1999). 80 Ivan Kremnev, “The Journey of My Brother Alexei to the Land of Peasant Utopia,” The Journal of Peasant Studies 4, 1 (1976) 63–108. 81 P. Orlovskii, “Foreword,” The Journal of Peasant Studies 4, 1 (1976) 69, 70. 82 Industrialization worsened human welfare indicators in England and elsewhere. See John Komlos, “Shrinking in a Growing Economy? the Mystery of Physical Stature During the Industrial Revolution,” Journal of Economic History 58 (1998) 779-802. 83 Giovanni Arrighi, Beverly J. Silver, and Benjamin D. Brewer, “Industrial Convergence, Globalization, and the Persistence of the North-South Divide,” Studies in Comparative International Development 38, 1 (2003) 3-31. 84 Duncan, The Centrality of Agriculture, 182. 85 Paul Collier, “The Politics of Hunger: How Illusion and Greed Fan the Food Crisis,” Foreign Affairs 87, 6 (2008) 67-79, 69, 70. 86 I borrow the phrase “Victims of Our Visions,” from Piero Gleijeses’s review of Richard Drinnon’s “Facing West,” Washington Post (Washington) 28 September 1980.